0% found this document useful (0 votes)
106 views

A Cost-Benefit Analysis of The First Nuclear Power Plant in Poland

This thesis conducts a cost-benefit analysis of building Poland's first nuclear power plant compared to investing in a new coal-fired power plant. The analysis monetizes six costs and three benefits over a time horizon of 60 years using a social discount rate. The results show that the nuclear power plant is socially beneficial in most scenarios by providing lower-cost electricity generation and reducing greenhouse gas emissions and energy import dependence. However, there are uncertainties regarding construction costs and timelines for the nuclear plant, as well as future fuel and carbon prices, that could impact the findings. The thesis recommends moving forward with the nuclear project but cautions that risks around accidents, cost overruns, and technological lock-in must be carefully considered.

Uploaded by

Mohib Haque
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
106 views

A Cost-Benefit Analysis of The First Nuclear Power Plant in Poland

This thesis conducts a cost-benefit analysis of building Poland's first nuclear power plant compared to investing in a new coal-fired power plant. The analysis monetizes six costs and three benefits over a time horizon of 60 years using a social discount rate. The results show that the nuclear power plant is socially beneficial in most scenarios by providing lower-cost electricity generation and reducing greenhouse gas emissions and energy import dependence. However, there are uncertainties regarding construction costs and timelines for the nuclear plant, as well as future fuel and carbon prices, that could impact the findings. The thesis recommends moving forward with the nuclear project but cautions that risks around accidents, cost overruns, and technological lock-in must be carefully considered.

Uploaded by

Mohib Haque
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 73

Master thesis submitted for the degree of Master of Science in International Economic Consulting

A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF THE FIRST NUCLEAR POWER PLANT IN POLAND

Author: Marta Rozylow MSc in International Economic Consulting Academic supervisor: Prof. Jan Bentzen Department of Economics

Aarhus University, Business and Social Sciences January 2013

Abstract
In the last few years, Poland started facing some difficulties in its energy sector. The situation has been caused by the growing demand for energy and the need for sustainable development reducing greenhouse gas emissions. The main challenge is the overdependence on coal- and lignite-fuel power plants as well as single-source oil, gas and coal (despite its own resources) imports from Russia causing insecurity of supply. In addition, Poland might face problems with the end of useful lifetime of the present electricity generating plants. The government has already designed plans to build the first nuclear power plant in order to cope with the existing problems.

Concerned with the situation in the Polish energy sector, the author of this thesis performed a social cost-benefit analysis of the first nuclear power plant project as opposition to the counter-factual of investing in a coal-fired electricity generation. Six costs and three benefits were identified, monetized and used in the NPV calculation with the levelised cost methodology. The results showed that the nuclear power plant would be beneficial in most cases relative to the alternative and would result in increasing welfare of the Polish society. Apart from the direct advantages (like lower environmental impact or increased energy security), there would be also other positive effects, like the development of research facilities or specific courses in higher education institutions. Therefore, despite some opposition from the Polish society, the nuclear project is justified under the socio-economic assessment.

However, the exact magnitude of the welfare gain is uncertain due to the long timeframe applied. There are some disadvantages that must be taken into consideration. The government should be aware of the accident risk, moral hazard and terrorism, intergenerational issues or technological lock-in. Moreover, despite careful planning there are still uncertainties regarding nuclear construction costs and time (meaning falling behind schedule), as well as future uranium, coal or carbon prices. Also the employment and education benefits should be considered with caution.

Table of contents
1. Introduction ............................................................................................ 1 1.1. Problem statement ........................................................................... 2 1.2. Methodology.................................................................................... 2 1.3. Structure of the thesis ...................................................................... 3 2. Energy sector.......................................................................................... 4 2.1. General characteristics..................................................................... 4 2.2. Polish energy sector......................................................................... 5 2.3. Characteristics of nuclear power energy ......................................... 9 3. Theoretical background........................................................................ 13 3.1. Steps in CBA ................................................................................. 13 3.2. Shadow price of capital ................................................................. 17 3.3. Levelised costs............................................................................... 18 3.4. Social discount rate........................................................................ 19 4. Analysis ................................................................................................ 22 4.1. Project description ......................................................................... 22 4.1.1. Background............................................................................. 22 4.1.2. Time horizon........................................................................... 24 4.1.3. Site .......................................................................................... 26 4.1.4. Reactor.................................................................................... 27 4.2. Alternative project ......................................................................... 29 4.3. Scope and standing ........................................................................ 30 4.4. Identification of costs and benefits................................................ 31 4.4.1. Costs ....................................................................................... 31 4.4.2. Benefits ................................................................................... 35 4.5. Quantification and monetization of costs and benefits ................. 37 4.5.1. Costs ....................................................................................... 38 4.5.2. Benefits ................................................................................... 43 4.6. NPV calculation............................................................................. 45 4.7. Sensivity analysis .......................................................................... 49 4.8. Recommendation........................................................................... 55 5. Conclusion............................................................................................ 57 Bibliography................................................................................................ 60

List of figures
Figure 1. Energy production in Poland in 2009 .............................................................. 8 Figure 2. Energy production in Poland in 2030 .............................................................. 9 Figure 3. Nuclear fuel cycle ........................................................................................... 11 Figure 4. Steps in CBA ................................................................................................... 14 Figure 5. Polish Nuclear Energy Programme Phases ................................................... 25 Figure 6. Proportions of electricity generating costs..................................................... 30 Figure 7. NPV value with change of STPR .................................................................... 50 Figure 8. Histogram of 1 000 projected NPVs ............................................................... 51 Figure 9. Scatter plot of 1 000 projected NPVs ............................................................. 52 Figure 10. Environmental benefit variation in the worst case scenario ........................ 54

List of tables
Table 1. Comparison of potential reactors..................................................................... 28 Table 2. Costs and benefits of the nuclear power plant ................................................. 31 Table 3. Nuclear power plant costs estimation .............................................................. 39 Table 4. Coal-fuel power plant costs estimation ............................................................ 41 Table 5. Nuclear power plant benefits estimation .......................................................... 43 Table 6. STPR derivation ............................................................................................... 46 Table 7. Nuclear power plant levelised cost advantage ................................................. 47 Table 8. NPV calculation ............................................................................................... 49 Table 9. IRR calculation ................................................................................................. 50 Table 10. CO2 emission mitigation costs ........................................................................ 53 Table 11. Security supply benefit variation .................................................................... 55

List of Acronyms and Abbreviations


BWR Boiling Water Reactor CBA Cost-Benefit Analysis CO2 Carbon Dioxide EPR European Power Reactor EU European Union GDP Gross Domestic Product GUS Gwny Urzd Statystyczny (Central Statistical Office of Poland) GW Gigawatt IAEA International Atomic Energy Agency IEA International Energy Agency IRR Internal Rate of Return kV kilovolt kW Kilowatt kWh Kilowatt hours MRTP Marginal Rate of Time Preference MW Megawatt MWh Megawatt hours mSv milisievert NAEA National Atomic Energy Agency NEA Nuclear Energy Agency NPP Nuclear Power Plant NPV Net Present Value OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development O&M Operation and Management PAA Polish Atomic Agency SDR Social Discount Rate STPR Social Time Preference Rate TWh Terawatt hours WNA World Nuclear Association ZUOP Zakad Uzdatniania Odpadw Przemysowych (Industrial Waste Treatment Plant) zl Polish zloty

1. Introduction
The primary objective of the energy policy is to ensure that energy needs of both entrepreneurs and citizens are adequately met at competitive prices and in accordance with the requirements of environmental protection. In Poland, implementation of this goal will be determined by investment needs associated with the development of productive infrastructure and participation in the European climate policy. As a result, it will be necessary to change the structure of energy production power, seeking different ways to move away from sources of high CO2 emissions to low-carbon technologies. In 2010, a report of a nuclear programme in Poland was provided to the public, picturing nuclear power expansion as a necessity. A number of actions have already been taken in order to make it a reality. New government bodies were formed, schedules were made, the law was streamlined and documents prepared. Currently, Poland is at the milestone of establishing the final location and negotiating contracts with the potential investors.

According to WNA (2005) in most industrialized countries today, new nuclear power plants (NPPs) offer the most economical way to generate electricity, even without consideration of the geopolitical and environmental advantages. This thesis aimed to research and check if it is so in the Polish case as well. It was chosen to compare the project with building a typical Polish coal-fuel power plant despite the requirements for Poland to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.

In this thesis, a cost-benefit analysis of the first NPP in Poland was conducted. It was of a particular interest to the author as she comes from Poland and is generally interested in sustainability and environmental issues. The project of building the NPP has caused heated debates as many people oppose to it, especially after the damage of the Japans NPP after tsunami in 2011. It must be underlined that the author of this thesis does not entirely believe the authenticity of the poll of public opinion which supposedly has shown that the majority of Poles support nuclear power. As given by Swiadomie o atomie (2012) in answer to the question do you support building NPPs in order to limit Polish dependence on oil and coal? there were only 30% YES answers in 2006, 46% YES answers in 2008 and 60% YES answers in September 2009. She regrets that there was no data about the frequency.

This paper differs from the existing literature, because nobody has made a cost-benefit analysis of the NPP project in Poland so far, or at least the author could not find any that would have been publicly available. This thesis assessed an extremely controversial topic that Poland has to deal with. The author is positive that her Master thesis gives some more insight to the topic of NPPs and building one in Poland as well as enriches the existing literature in this area.

1.1.

Problem statement

This analysis attempted to look at the range of costs and benefits associated with investments in nuclear power. The main goal of the thesis was to conduct a social costbenefit analysis of the potential first NPP in Poland, which would show the impact of the project, whether the investment would result in a net gain or loss to the Polish society as a whole. It was realized based on the algorithm of following steps as given by Boardman et al. (2006). The approach was economic rather than financial and thus cannot be used as a basis for determining commercial interest. The analysis considered costs associated with a NPP relative to the alternative of a coal-fired one. The assumption was that in a do nothing scenario, investment would probably flow to coalfired generation. This provided the benchmark against which the nuclear investment was compared. The relative cost of a NPP could be then regarded as a cost/benefit, depending on whether the nuclear is more/less expensive than a coal-fired plant.

1.2.

Methodology

The basic research method in the thesis was a cost-benefit analysis assessing effects on the Polish society of building the first NPP in the country. First, the costs and benefits from the project were identified and monetized, taking into account also environmental externalities. Then, they were compared and the net present value was calculated. Finally, there was conducted a sensivity analysis. The alternative project necessary for comparison was building a coal-fired power plant.

A wide range of literature was used, such as books, articles, reports and web sources. A valuable amount of information was derived from Boardman et al. (2006) as well as European Commission (2008). These positions were both the basis for the third,

theoretical chapter, and a starting point for calculations made in the fourth, empirical chapter. In description of the Polish energy sector, the most important source was the report made by Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) and IEA (2011). Kaplan (2008) and various web sources helped in understanding the specifics of NPPs.

Data for the analysis was obtained from the GUS (Central Statistical Office of Poland), e. g. the structure of energy resources, energy usage in Poland, consumption and investment structure, GDP. Further figures were derived from the European Commision, like the description of the energy market in Europe or the price of energy. Finally, the approximate costs and benefits of the investment were assessed on the basis of the figures provided by the Ministry of Economy of Poland, especially in Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) and nuclear organisations (like IAEA, IEA, WNC). The author of the thesis used also several internet sources to clarify some uncertainties and broaden the knowledge about the nuclear energy and power plants, besides the fact that the data from the organizations were obtained from their official websites.

1.3.

Structure of the thesis

The thesis has been organized into four major sections and a conclusion. The first part is the introduction, which aimed to give the reader a broad idea about the contents of this paper. The second provided the basics of the energy sector, also in Poland where stress was put on its structure resulting from the past governmental decisions. Finally, it outlined the fundamentals of nuclear power energy production. The third chapter described theoretical foundations of CBA, how the whole deduction and calculation process looks like, what approaches are used and which aspects are vital. In the fourth chapter, the analysis of the first NPP was conducted. The steps were followed as suggested by Boardman et al. (2006) consisting of identification and monetization of costs and benefits, NPV calculation and sensivity analysis. In the last part of the thesis, the conclusion, all findings and thoughts were summed up.

2. Energy sector
In this chapter the energy sector was briefly described. The first section dealt with the general characteristics and trends in this area. The next section was dedicated to the Polish energy sector which was crucial for understanding why the Polish government wants to build NPPs. In the third part, the nuclear energy was described in an as nonscientifically way as possible.

2.1.

General characteristics

Most of todays societies are extremely dependent on energy and electricity. There are two primary energy sources: non-renewable fossil fuels and renewable. Climate change concerns, high oil prices, fear of shortages of fossil fuels, large subsidies for fossil fuels and increasing government support towards clean energy drive renewable energy legislation and incentives. In this part of the paper, the stress was put on nuclear energy and fossil fuels because both of them were relevant for the analysis.

Renewable sources come from natural resources which are easy to replenish such as sun, wind, water, geothermal heat, and biomass. They are sustainable which means that the needs of the current population are satisfied without endangering needs satisfaction of the future society. Renewable energy is experiencing a continued to grow in all end-use sectors (power, heat and transport). The share in final energy generation is currently around 19% (16% comes from hydroelectricity). (European Commission, 2010).

Nuclear power is considered a clean energy because it does not pollute the environment in the way fossil fuels do. However, the fuel (uranium in most cases or thorium) is not renewable, extraction diminishes its deposits inside the Earts. The crucial problems with NPPs are the breakdowns, leakages or meltdowns. In the most recent one, in 2011, a magnitude 9.0 earthquake and the consequent tsunami triggered meltdowns in three reactors at Tokyo Electric Powers Fukushima Daiichi NPP (Pernick R., Wilder C., Winnie T., 2012). Although they were brought under control, the accident made an impact on the nuclear energy future because people became even more unwilling towards it. Currently, Japan is taking steps to change course toward renewable energy production. In Europe, for example Germany or Belgium shut down their reactors. 4

European Commission (2010) predicts, based on power plants under construction or under confirmed planning, a decrease in the number of nuclear power plants. Despite these new trends, the Polish government is firm in its decision to build the NPP.

Fossil fuel sources are coal, lignite, petroleum or gas, which are the remains of the decomposition of plants and animals millions years ago. The most important problem with these energy sources is the greenhouse gas and other pollutant, like e.g. dust, emission. One of the key characteristics of this sector is also unjustified in most cases government subsidies. Fossil fuel industries have historically received, and continue today, six times as many subsidies as the clean-energy industry (Pernick R., Wilder C., Winnie T., 2012). According to European Commission (2010), fossil fuels contribution in energy generation until 2030 is going to decrease by 13% in comparison with 2009.

Generally regardless of the energy sources, the sector is characterized by significant fluctuations in energy prices, growing demand for energy from developing countries, striving for efficiency both in production and usage, major system failures, and rising pollution of the environment. Due to these features, a new approach to energy policy was required, so the EU set targets for environmental commitments. They are the so called 3x20%, ie: reducing greenhouse gas emissions by 20% compared to 1990, reducing energy consumption by 20% compared to projections for the EU in 2020, increasing the share of renewable energy sources to 20% of total consumption energy in the EU (the Polish goal is for 15% of the final consumption), including increased use of renewable energy sources in transport of 10% (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). There is the need to diversify energy sources and the need for new investment replacing depreciated power system so that it will not be environmentally harmful (meaning minimum emissions of CO2, NOx, SxOy, dust and metal). Further, in this section the details of the Polish energy sectors specifics were given and some key characteristics of nuclear energy production.

2.2.

Polish energy sector

In Poland, there is a dominance of coal and lignite in the power industry, which was formed after World War II when the state had based production on domestic resources due to deficit of foreign exchange for any fuel imports (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej

Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). While coals dominance in the nations fuel mix has weakened from a share of 76% in 1990 to 55% in 2009, the share of fossil fuels put together fell only from 98% to 93%. It results in negative consequences for the fulfillment of environment protection obligations, especially in terms of CO2 emissions. To meet the requirements for Poland's 15% share of renewables in gross final energy structure in 2020, there will be a high increase in the share clean energy sources despite the high costs of production.

Polands energy market is based on free transactions, there are no government subsidies. The country relies heavily on indigenous coal that accounts for 55% of its primary energy supply and 90% of electricity generation. Polands coal resources are perceived as a major guarantor of energy security. However, coal reserves accessible from established mines are declining very fast. Hard coal production is likely to decrease by 2030. Lignite production will also fall sharply until 2030 as shortages can be expected from 2015. In 2008, Poland became a net coal importer for the first time as coal production was insufficient to meet demand. Imports from Russia have accounted for 70% of total coal imports in 2009. Moreover, Poland is dependent on imports for 95% of its crude oil demand and for about two-thirds (68%) of its gas demand. Over 94% of oil and over 80% of gas imports come from Russia (IEA, 2011). The government is thus trying to diversify import sources and transport routes to decrease the over-dependence on Russia.

For several years the Polish energy sector has been facing other serious challenges, such as growing energy demand associated with economic development, ageing manufacturing assets, inadequate level of infrastructure development. Although Poland remains a net electricity exporter, it increased its electricity imports, which nearly tripled between 2000 and 2009. According to IEA (2011) Polish demand for electricity grew since the mid-1990s, closely following economic growth. In years 2000-2009, demand for energy in services grew at the rate of 3.1% per year (services represent over represent well over a third of Polands electricity demand), while consumer demand increased by 3% per year and industrial demand by 1.1%. Despite the growth in electricity demand, in 2008 per capita electricity demand in the country was around 3 733 kWh, substantially lower than the OECD Europe average of 6 287 kWh. According to Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) Poland has 6

the 24th place among EU countries in terms of electricity consumption per capita per year. It is significantly below the EU average of approximately 7 500 kWh. It is expected that the electricity consumption will grow in Poland, mainly due to its relatively low level at present, which is impossible to maintain in the long run. The forecast for fuel and energy to 2030 predicts an increase in gross energy demand from 141.0 TWh in 2010 to 217.4 TWh in 2030, so by 54% (Ministerstwo Gospodarki, 2009).

The Polish transmission grid is connected with Sweden, Germany, the Czech Republic, the Slovak Republic, Ukraine and Belarus. However, connections to the last two countries are not in operation. Construction of a 400 kV line to Lithuania, a new line to Germany and network reinforcements at the connection points with the Czech and Slovak Republics have been planned to expand capacity. The planned electricity bridge between Poland and Lithuania is to be an important element of the so-called Baltic Ring, comprising of electricity systems of the surrounding Baltic countries. It has been a priority project under trans-European energy networks (TEN-E). The implementation of this project will improve the energy security not only of Poland and Lithuania, but also of the whole region. Another aim is to improve and invest into the whole electricity grid, because nearly 80% of 400 kV lines and 99% of 220 kV lines are over 20 years old. Poland was able to reduce network losses from 8%, although it remains higher than the 6% in the OECD countries. Electricity consumption at power plants was also reduced to around 15%. However, it is still high, twice as high as the OECD average (IEA, 2011).

The total installed capacity in the Polish power plants was 35.6 GW in 2009, of which 31.6 GW was coal-fired. The remaining capacity was split between hydropower (2.3 GW), gas (0.9 GW), biomass (0.6 GW), oil (0.5 GW) and wind (0.4 GW). Coal-fired power plants produce around 10 GW of electricity and heat at the same time. It is worth noting that Poland is one of few countries in the world to make such an extensive use of combined heat and power (IEA, 2011).

To satisfy the growing needs of electricity consumption, it will be necessary to increase its production. In addition to current coal-fired power plants it would required to develop other sources, like nuclear or renewables. Despite increasingly stringent

environmental standards, coal will remain the most important energy source used to 7

produce electricity and heat in Poland. Over the next 20 years, until 2030, it is assumed that the coal sector should ensure the supply of fuel, which will maintain production of electricity (from hard coal and lignite together) at the same level of about 110 TWh, ie: 112.9 TWh in 2010, 102.7 TWh in 2020 and 114.1 TWh in 2030. Because the dependence on it will not diminished, new mines will have to be opened or imports will have to be increased. After 2020, the primary energy structure should be characterized by increasing the share of nuclear energy, which will allow the reduction of CO2 emissions and ease the rise in electricity prices (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). Figure 1 and Figure 2 presents the structure of energy production in 2009 and 2030.

Figure 1. Energy production in Poland in 2009


10% 0% 5% 1% Coal and lignite Oil Gas Renewables Other 84%

Source: Own elaboration based on IEA (2011).

Figure 2. Energy production in Poland in 2030

16%

0% Coal 36% Lignite Oil Gas Renewables Nuclear Other

19%

7% 1% 21%

Source: Penomocnik ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010).

In 2009, coal and lignite are counted together and amount to 84% of the total production. If summed up for year 2030, they will make only 57%, so over the 20 years there is a significant decrease in these two non-renewable energy sources. From 2020, there appears nuclear energy in calculations and after 10 years from opening the first block, the prognosis is that it will produce about 16% of energy. There is forecasted also a 9% increase in energy production from renewable sources. It was not shown on the graph, but in Poland according to IEA (2011) almost all renewable energy sources come from waste recycling. Energy produced from wind power plants is predicted to be about 1%, while hydro, solar and geothermal plants will contribute to less than 1% of energy production each.

2.3.

Characteristics of nuclear power energy

NPPs use sustained nuclear fission to generate heat and electricity. Just as conventional power stations generate electricity from the thermal energy released from burning fossil fuels, NPPs convert the energy released from nuclear fission in a nuclear reactor. Then steam is generated and it drives a steam turbine connected to a generator producing electricity (Elektrownia jdrowa, 2012).

Energy is generated when U-235 in a critical amount undergoes fissioning. When a U235 atom is struck by a neutron, it breaks into fragments known as fission products

(consisting of other atoms near the middle of the table of atomic numbers) and also releases neutrons which strike other U-235 atoms, thereby maintaining a chain reaction. Every fission releases about 200-million electron volts of heat which can be used to drive a steam power plant. There are objections to the sole use of U-235 because of its scarcity and the large amounts of energy required to separate it from U-238. Much importance is attached to converting other materials, U-238 and Th-232, into fissionable materials by means of the breeder reaction. In such a case, the neutrons from the fissioning of U-235 are used to cause a radioactive transformation of U-238 or Th-232 to Pu-239 or U-233 respectively, which are then fissionable. It is worth noting here that NPPs need much less fuel than the coal-fuel plants, one pound of U-235 is equivalent to 1400 tons of coal in its energy production, the fissioning of 1 gram of U-235 releases 2.28 x 104 kWh of heat, which is equivalent to the heat of combustion of 3 tons of coal (Hubbert, 2006).

A nuclear reactor is only a part of the life-cycle for nuclear power. Figure 3 shows the nuclear fuel cycle. The process starts with mining, the extraction of uranium ore that may be either underground or open pit. During milling uranium is extracted from the ore. The process produces a uranium oxide concentrate which is then shipped. It is called yellowcake (since it is dried and concentrated) and contains more than 80% uranium. The remainder of the ore, mostly all the rock material, becomes tailings. They need to be isolated from the environment because they are radioactive. Since uranium oxide cannot be used as fuel in a nuclear reactor, enrichment is necessary to convert it into gas. It is then stored in containers and shipped to enrichment plants because for nuclear reactors the concentration of the fissile U-235 isotope needs to be increased to between 3.5% and 5% U-235. The fuel is made in the form of ceramic pellets encased in metal tubes to form fuel rods. Rods are then transported into NPPs, where the fission process, described earlier, takes place to produce energy used to heat water and turn it into steam and thus generate electricity. Some of the U-238 in the fuel is turned into plutonium which is then fissile yields about one third of the energy in a nuclear reactor. With time, the concentration of fission fragments and heavy elements increases to the point where it is no longer practical to continue to use the fuel (3-6 years). It is unloaded into a storage pond adjacent to the reactor to allow the radiation to decrease. It takes several months to several years. It may be then transferred to naturally-ventilated dry 10

storage on site or to central storage facilities. Finally, used fuel must be either reprocessed or prepared for permanent disposal (by vitrification transforming into a glass to obtain a stable compound). During reprocessing the used fuel is separated into components: uranium, plutonium and waste. This process enables recycling of uranium and plutonium into fresh fuel and reduces amount of waste. Plutonium can be made into mixed oxide (MOX) fuel, in which uranium and plutonium oxides are combined. Plutonium then substitutes for the U-235 in normal uranium oxide fuel. (Elektrownia jdrowa, 2012; WNA, 2012).

Figure 3. Nuclear fuel cycle

Source: WNA (2012).

Generally, the fissionable fuel used is uranium, although, as mentioned earlier, other materials may be used as well. For many years the price of uranium was low, which prevented exploration and extraction of new uranium deposits. As it increased in the recent years, it caused a growth in the intensity of the search. This happens with all the

11

minerals and uranium is no exception. The size of the known deposits of uranium, whose extraction is profitable at the current market price, is increasing with each year. Progress in the technique of extraction and purification of uranium ore means that there are highly profitable mines extracting poor uranium ore (IEA, 2011). The uranium ore deposits in Poland examined so far contain from 250 to 1100 ppm uranium, while very profitable ore mines use a content 300 ppm (Rossing in Namibia), and even 126 ppm (Trekkopje in Namibia). Uranium deposits exploited in Poland in the 1950s typically contained about 2000 ppm. At present, uranium mining would be uneconomic, because it can be bought cheaper abroad (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010).

All operations from mining uranium ore to producing fuel are carried out at a low level of nuclear radiation. The operations of spent fuel from fuel discharge from reactor core to radioactive waste disposal in landfills are conducted at a high nuclear radiation level. In the case of high-active waste and spent fuel deep storage is envisaged. In the world there are built deep repositories for this purpose. Practically all activities linked to production or use of isotopes are accompanied by the formation of radioactive nuclear waste. Due to the specific nature, radioactive waste requires special handling. This applies to the collection, processing, solidification, transportation, temporary storage and final disposal. The primary objective of all activities is the safety of radioactive waste so that they create no danger to humans and the environment (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). In countries with nuclear power, radioactive waste comprises less than 1% of total industrial toxic wastes, much of which remains hazardous indefinitely. Overall, nuclear power produces far less waste by volume than fossil-fuel based power plants. Coalburning plants are particularly noted for producing large amounts of toxic and mildly radioactive ash due to concentrating naturally occurring metals (Elektrownia jdrowa, 2012). According to Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) emissions of radioactive substances in NPPs have steadily decreased. Data collected systematically by the nuclear regulatory authorities in different countries indicate that the annual dose of radiation at the border zone of the reactor is from 0.01 to 0.03 mSv/year. To compare, the dose from natural background in Poland is 2.5 mSv and in Finland 7 mSv/year. This means that the additional radiation exposure from NPPs is minimal and one hundred lower than the difference between Poland and Finland. 12

3. Theoretical background
In this chapter the theoretical background of a CBA was discussed. The first section dealt with the foundations of a CBA where the procedure was described. Then the focus was on shadow prices and levelised costs. Moreover, the concept of a social discount rate was introduced.

3.1.

Steps in CBA

This section dealt with the theoretical background necessary to understand the idea of a cost-benefit analysis and the procedure that was used in the empirical part of the thesis. Boardman et al. (2006) defines CBA as a policy assessment method that quantifies in monetary terms the value of all consequences of a policy to all members of society (Boardman et al., 2006, p. 2). It deals with all the costs and benefits to the society as a whole. The results from the analysis are a tool for helping decision makers in determining whether a project should be implemented and which allocation of resources is optimal. There exists a fixed algorithm, a framework, to help analysts to perform a CBA. It was presented in Figure 4. Consequently, in the analytical part of the thesis, in Chapter 4, these steps were followed.

The first step involves identification of the project that is to be assessed. Clear and feasible goals should be established. It would help analysts to concentrate on the right issues and make the workload more precise and organised. It this case it was the governments project of the first NPP in Poland.

Having done that, the alternative projects should be found for comparison purposes. In reality one can come up with a very large number of alternatives by imposing minor changes in the main option. They might differ by e.g. contractors, locations, fees, the outsourced services or the horizon of investment. To keep the analysis manageable one has to be strict in choosing alternatives. Introducing more of them might cause focus diversion and in turn make the analysis more superficial. Where no obvious alternatives exist one has to compare the project with the counter-factual alternative that is often just the status quo or the do-nothing baseline (Boardman et al., 2006). The alternative for the NPP was chosen to be a coal-fuel power plant producing the same amount of energy.

13

Figure 4. Steps in CBA Project and objectives identification

Alternatives definition

Scope and standing delimination

Costs and benefits identification

Costs and benefits quantification and monetization

NPV calculation

Sensivity and risk analysis

Recommendation
Source: Own elaboration based on Boardman (et al., 2006).

The next step is deciding whose benefits and costs count, who has standing in the project. Analysts have to decide on the perspective, whether to carry out the evaluation taking into account only local residents, all citizens of a country, or all people in the world. It is also important to decide whether to include environmental issues and other externalities (Boardman et al., 2006). In this paper the focus was on the Polish society.

Later on, it is necessary to identify and catalogue costs and benefits. Boardman et al. (2006) mentions that one should include only these impacts that affect the utility of individuals with standing. Impacts that do not have any value to human beings ought to be omitted. At the same time measurement indicators should be specified, like for example currency-unit value of saved costs or the value of reduced CO2 emissions. The choice depends on data availability and ease of monetization.

14

Then, the impacts are predicted quantitatively over time. This part might be especially difficult for projects that are unique, long-run and complex. Each of the impacts should be monetized, that is expressed in currency units. Some impacts might be cumbersome to assess, especially the environment-related ones. The value of output is typically measured by willingness-to-pay, how much the society is ready to pay for the good. Where markets do not exist or do not work well, one can use shadow prices or values from guidelines and previous research (Boardman et al., 2006). Shadow prices are mostly used when observable market prices are distorted in some way, are biased or not accurately describe the true value to society (European Commission, 2008). They might over- or underestimate the real social benefits or costs. The concept is also used in case of externalities. The conversion factor, analogous market good, hedonic pricing, averting costs or contingent evaluation method can be applied to appropriately reflect the preferences of population. In this CBA there were identified several costs and benefits, but only six and three of them respectively were monetized. Shadow prices for the environmental benefit were assessed on the basis of the CO2 equivalent price in the EU because it reflects societys willingness-to-pay to mitigate the impact of coal-fuel power plants.

The net present value (NPV) is probably the most widely known method for discounting future costs and benefits into present values. It assumes that members of a particular population give up present consumption to invest in a project that over time is expected to yield a return. The impacts that occur in each year of the project need to be aggregated. This step is necessary as there is an opportunity cost to resources and people prefer current consumption (consumption today is worth more than future consumption unless one is compensated for deferring it), so future money has a lower value. By discounting it can be assessed if the project is likely to earn a greater return than in case the resources had been alternatively used. Each cash flow that occurs in year t is discounted to its present value by dividing it by (1 + s)t. It is given by the equation (Boardman et al., 2006):

15

where: t the time of the cash flow, s the social discount rate, NBt the net cash flow (the amount of cash, inflow minus outflow) at time t, Bt the benefits at time t, Ct the costs at time t. Projects should be accepted if NPV > 0, then it adds value to the society. In case, where there are several exclusive projects only the one with the highest NPV ought to be chosen if there is no particular goal other than efficiency. If NPV is negative, the social costs of the project exceed its benefits and therefore the project should be rejected because it is not a feasible investment possibility. With intergenerational projects Boardman et al. (2006) recommends to use time-declining discount rates. Such rates were used in this thesis, because the NPP is a long-run investment.

Often along with NPV, internal rate of return (IRR) is calculated. Boardman et al. (2006, p. 158) defines it as the discount rate at which the NPV is zero. If it is bigger than the discount rate used for the NPV calculations, then the project should be implemented. It means that the project gives the society higher return than could be earned by investing these resources elsewhere.

Having calculated the NPV, sensivity analysis is required. It investigates robustness of net benefit estimates, how sensitive the predictions are to change. It is essential in any analysis because the longer life of the project, the more uncertain things become as assumptions are projected further out in time. It should include for instance forecast of demand dynamics, unexpected occurrences and shocks, variation in fees, taxes and tariffs, forecasts of costs dynamics. In Boardman et al. (2006) it is suggested to conduct a Monte Carlo analysis, the best and worse case scenario or a partial analysis.

The last step in CBA is the recommendation. As mentioned earlier, the project with the highest NPV should be chosen. However, sometimes the sensivity analysis might suggest that an alternative with a lower NPV is the best solution given the circumstances as it reduces risks. It is worth noting that Boardman et al. (2006) underlines that analysts do not take decisions, they only make recommendations. They 16

are not responsible for the actual resources allocation because they only attempt to help decision-makers in a more efficient allocation. The recommended project does not always succeed as the future is uncertain and the environment changeable.

3.2.

Shadow price of capital

With calculating the NPV there is sometimes the so-called reinvestment problem that arises when some of the benefits in the later years are reinvested while others are consumed. As a result, different discount rates are used depending on whether the consumption or the investments are crowded out. Boardman et al. (2006) suggests using the shadow price of capital method, in which investment and consumption flows are also treated differently. This method allows correcting the displaced investments, as private-sector displacement is more costly to the society than consumption displacement and increments to private-sector are more beneficial than increments to consumption. Shadow price of capital can be ignored if a government project is financed from taxes and there is only consumption displacement (investments are not displaced). Because it is not the case with the NPP, it was necessary to briefly describe the method. It consists of several steps. The first one is to define and divide costs and benefits in each period into those that affect consumption and investment. Next, the flows affecting investments are multiplied by the shadow price of capital and converted into consumption equivalents. Finally, the changes in consumption and consumption equivalents are added together and all flows are discounted with the relevant consumption discount rate. Shadow price of capital is given by:

where:

the depreciation rate of capital invested,


f fraction of the gross return that is reinvested, pz social marginal rate of time preference, rz the net return on capital after depreciation.

17

It takes a value larger than one since, rz > pz, and can be interpreted as the present value of consumption from investing 1 unit in the private sector. For instance, a value of 1.5 means that investments are 50% more costly than consumption and 1 of private investment would produce a flow of consumption benefits with a NPV equal to 1.50 .

3.3.

Levelised costs

To compare power plants, it is necessary to introduce the idea of levelised costs. This method provides a good assessment on the cost of electricity (IEA, 2005). The formula assumes that a power plant is continuously replaced to generate incremental power to meet new increasing demand. The time series of expenditures are discounted to their present values in a specified base year by applying a discount rate. The levelised lifetime cost per kWh of electricity generated is the ratio of total lifetime expenses to total expected outputs, expressed in present value. The formula provided by IEA (2005) is as follows:

where: EGC average lifetime levelised electricity generation cost, It capital investment in year t, Mt operating and maintenance cost in the year t, Ft fuel cycle cost in the year t, Et electricity output in year t (in this case Et = plant capacity load factor), r cost of capital (suggested by Kennedy (2007) to be 5 or 10%).

This cost is equivalent to the average price that consumers will have to pay for the plant operators and investors to offset the expenditure and to repay a proper amount of return. It varies according to country, depending on costs in the area, the regulatory regime and consequent financial and other risks, as well as the availability and cost of financing. It is also depend on geographic factors such as availability of cooling water, the likelihood of earthquakes, or availability of suitable power grid connections.

18

It must be noted that the levelised costs exclude environmental and social costs. However, in this CBA the environmental and social (employment) impact has been dealt with in another way by classifying it into the advantage of the NPP over a coalfuel power plant.

3.4.

Social discount rate

Choosing a social discount rate is of utmost importance while assessing a project because it influences the NPV calculation and the final results. The level of the discount rate reflects governments propensity for a certain type of projects. A government interested in long-term or back-end loaded projects (with a high return in the future) should prescribe a low discount rate in which more weight is put weight on the impacts occurring further out in time (Boardman et al., 2006). There are two main approaches to derive the appropriate SDR (Boardman et al., 2006): 1) market-based rates: marginal rate of return on private investments, social marginal rate of time preference, government borrowing rate, weighted average rate of the above rates,

2) non-market-based rates: social time preference rate.

Only in perfectly competitive markets, where allocation is efficient, the above different social discounting rates are equal. In real life, the decision makers have to choose the second-best alternative, because there are distortions and imperfections in the markets (such as taxes, subsidies, information asymmetries, externalities or others).

The marginal rate of return on private investments is based on the assumption that the resources used by government will earn a greater return that would have been in the case they had remained in the private sector. In Boardman et al. (2006) is evaluated to be around 4.5%. However that might be too high for the social analysis; it is more appropriate from the perspective of a purely financial analysis.

19

The next rate, the social marginal rate of time preference (MRTP) takes into account peoples willingness to withhold current consumption in return for greater consumption in the future. Boardman et al. (2006) suggest using it when a project is fully financed by domestic taxes and displaces only consumption. It is around 1.5%.

The third option is the government borrowing rate that reflects the actual cost of financing a project. It is calculated (using yield on Treasury bonds) to be approximately 2.7%. It should be used when projects are financed by public borrowing rather than taxes (Boardman et al., 2006).

There is also the weighted average rate given by Boardman et al. (2006) to be around 2.5%. It deals with the imperfections of the three above discount rates. It is based on the social opportunity cost of the different sources weighted by the relative contribution of each source. However, it is not so often used by governments because of the difficulty in using several discount rates.

The only rate not based on the market interest rates is the social time preference rate (STPR). As its use is suggested by the European Commission (2008), a detailed insight was given to it in the thesis. In HM Treasury (2003) the general formula is as follows:

r = + g,

where:

the rate at which individuals discount the future consumption over present
consumption assuming that there is no change in per capita consumption; it consists of catastrophe risk (the likelihood that there will be some devastating event and all returns from policies will be eliminated or altered) and pure time preference (reflecting individuals preference for consumption now rather than in the future),

the elasticity of marginal utility of consumption; it measures the speed with which
the social marginal utility of consumption falls as the per capita consumption increases, g the product of annual growth on per capita consumption.

STPR is defined as the value which society attaches to present consumption as opposed to the future one. It takes into account peoples willingness to withhold current 20

consumption in return for greater consumption in the future. It compares the utility across different points in time. The main argument for using this rate is that the market is imperfect, consumers are inconsistent and irrational and there is information asymmetry as well as other distortions, so the rate should not be based on the market variables. Moreover, this rate takes into account future generations. However, it is criticized because it is not easy to estimate the long-run growth rate g. Furthermore, the national income used to measure the growth rate might not accurately measure consumption. The parameters and g are based on the judgments about intergenerational equality, which might be wrong (Boardman et al., 2006). There are some instances of European countries that set SDR on the basis of STPR. For example, France uses SDR of 4%, Germany 3% and UK 3.5% (Evans, 2006). European Commission (2008) suggests using SDR in the range 3-5% (for mature European countries 3.5% and for lag-behind countries 5%). Higher discount rate may reflect the need for worse-off regions to invest at a higher rate of return to achieve a rate of growth higher than the average for the EU countries and catch up. Evans (2006) considers different views on estimating this rate and concludes that an appropriate range should be between 0-2%. However, he underlines that the safest option is to use 1%. In Chapter 4, the STPR rate for Poland was calculated.

21

4. Analysis
In the following chapter the theory of CBA was used to evaluate the real project of building the first NPP in Poland. In the first paragraph the project was described. Then a list of costs and benefits was presented and discussed in detail. Some of them were not monetized or considered further in the analysis. The calculations of NPV and sensivity analysis were tackled in the penultimate part of this chapter. Finally, the recommendation was drawn up.

4.1. Project description


4.1.1. Background
Currently, there are the following nuclear facilities in Poland (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010): 1) research reactor "Maria" along with a swimming pool technology, which is located at the Institute Atomic Energy POLATOM (POLATOM IEA) in Otwock-wierk, 2) research reactor "Ewa" (liquidated) in ZUOP in Otwock-wierk, 3) two storage facilities for spent nuclear fuel in ZUOP in Otwock-wierk. There is not and there was not any isotopic enrichment plant, nuclear fuel fabrication facility or a processing NPP. In the 1980s, there were plans of construction of a NPP in

arnowiec. However, they halted in 1989 by a resolution of the Council of Ministers


due to a failure in nuclear cooperation in the field of nuclear safety and radiological protection.

Kennedy (2007) underlines that new investment in power plants should only take place when there is a need for capacity, to replace existing capacity upon retirement and to meet growth in demand. Due to the growing needs for energy and the European climate policy Poland has to change its energy production sources. Diversification of electricity production will be achieved mainly through the introduction of nuclear power (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). The NPP will provide stability and predictability in the long run, lower production costs of electricity compared to other energy technologies and certainty of return on invested capital.

22

There are, however, certain basic conditions that should be complied with while designing a NPP, e. g. in terms of nuclear safety and radiological protection, or safe operation of technical equipment. Any project should take into account the need to ensure safety protection during construction, commissioning, operation, including repairs, upgrading and decommissioning of the facility as well as in the event of an incident (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010).

According to Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) the first investor in nuclear power will be a company with direct or indirect majority of shareholders from the Treasury. This will mean designation of the largest Polish energy group, PGE Polish Group Energy S.A., the organizer of the first investment in NPPs in Poland. Government ownership with a majority stakes makes it easier to raise debt financing for the company. Operator actions in the first NPP will be conducted by the company and its subsidiaries. Its main goal should be to achieve the position at least comparable with the main competitors in the region. The selection of suppliers and contractors of NPPs will be made on the principles of competitiveness and transparency within European and national legislation. In accordance with the recommendations of the IAEA, responsibility for the administration and project management of nuclear power development should be entrusted to a specially created for this purpose organizational unit. There has been created among others the Polish Atomic Agency (PAA), the National Atomic Energy Agency (NAEA) and the Nuclear Energy Department of the Ministry of Economy with Government Commissioner for Nuclear Energy.

To finance construction of any NPP two methods can be used: guaranteed loans and corporate financing (in case of non-state investor if he has sufficient credibility and financial potential). Sources of financing the preparation and implementation of investment may come either from the investor's own or with foreign capital external sources (loans, credits, bonds), or a combination of both of them, taking into account the amount of expected cost of capital and financing structure. The availability of appropriate financing, domestic and foreign, is one of the most important factors influencing the construction of the NPP investment. NEA (2009) points out that the most popular is a mixture of debt and equity financing, with equity beeing more expensive than debt, but differentiation leading to risk reduction is important. There are 23

also international financial institutions providing funding for major projects, such as European Bank for Restruction and Development or European Investment Bank. Poland has an agreement with OECD which is going to support building of the NPP. Because of the scale, complexity and the high level of risk of the project investment, it may be necessary for the state to have an active role in supporting investors action in the provision of funding, using various tools of support, for example, by providing a state guarantee (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). Kaplan (2008) points out that private investments in power plants are characterized by lower financing costs and generally they are built and run more effectively. In this thesis, similarly like in the base case in Kaplan (2008), government incentives were excluded from calculation. The reason behind this was that both are based on a case-by-case analysis of individual projects and thus difficult to predict.

Building of the NPP in Poland would also require changes in the national energy transmission system to ensure a reliable power outlet and a power reserve (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). The national transmission network includes voltage 110, 220 and 400 kV. The 220 kV network is well developed and frequently used, and the 400 kV network is relatively well developed in the south, while in the east and north lines are "radial" and particularly vulnerable to disturbance and long-term exclusion. One of the major barriers to introduction of the new national electricity system with generating units of a capacity over 1000 MW, including nuclear units, is the lack of appropriate extensive grid of 400 kV. In parallel with the development of nuclear power, there should be acceleration of the development of network infrastructure. It is necessary to develop intensively the 400 kV network in the northern part of Poland and gradually limit the role of the 220 kV network.

4.1.2. Time horizon


Polish Nuclear Energy Programme has to be implemented to ensure safe and efficient operation of nuclear facilities, decommissioning after the end of operation and the safety of used nuclear fuel and radioactive waste. Its duration covers the years 20112030 (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). According to the recommendations of the IAEA, the introduction of nuclear power requires from 10 to 15 years of preparatory work, including the first power plant construction. This time is

24

dependent on the level of development of a country. In the Polish case, the implementation of nuclear power requires building almost the entire technical infrastructure necessary from scrap (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). Figure 5 presents the schedule for building the first NPP in Poland.

Figure 5. Polish Nuclear Energy Programme Phases Phase I Legislation 30.06.2011 Phase II 31.12.2013 Phase III 31.12.2015 Phase IV 31.12.2020 Phase V 31.12.2030
25

Source: Own elaboration.

As can be seen, Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) divided the process of the NPP construction into five stages: I. Adoption of legislation necessary for development and operation of the NPP and formation of necessary government bodies, II. Location choice and conclusion of the contract to build the first NPP, III. Implementation of technical design and legal requirements, IV. Building permit and construction of the first block of the NPP, starting to build more units/NPPs, V. Continuation and building more units/NPPs.

At the moment of writing this paper the first stage has already been completed. Locations were narrowed to three possibilities, but the exact one has not been chosen yet. Public tenders to find the optimal investor ought to completed in late 2013. Then there will be the process of licensing and obtaining permits. The administrative procedures will be conducted by the mid-2016 years. Construction of power plant will take 45 months. During this stage it will be necessary carry out trial operation after the presentation and positive assessment by the nuclear surveillance of the safety report. Positive results of the tests will allow the start of normal operation after obtaining the appropriate permit. Construction work will be accompanied by investment in the modernization and development of the network of the highest transmission voltage.

Operation

Location

Building

Design

The first effects of the installed capacity in nuclear blocks should appear in 2020, and by 2030 there should work both of them with a total net capacity of at least 4500 MW producing 40 TWh of energy anually. At present there is assumed a 60-year period of operation of NPPs, so the first block should be decommissioned around 2080 (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010).

4.1.3. Site
The choice of location is an important element of the nuclear power station. It requires consideration of the two aspects (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010):

the impact of the NPP on the environment both during normal operation and in the event of failure,

the impact of the environment and human actions on the NPP.

The location of a NPP in Poland will be conducted according to international standards, and in particular the IAEA guidelines and the European and American requirements.

In Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) it is mentioned that until 1990 several studies were conducted with regard to location of the NPP. The first choice was arnowiec, where, as mentioned earlier, construction had been started. Localization studies for a second NPP were carried out mainly in the northern part of the country (north of the line between Warsaw-Poznan) due to occurrence of major water resources there and the location of domestic raw materials base (coal and lignite) in the southern part of the country. Based on studies and research, the Council of Ministers expressed a positive opinion on location of the Warta-Klempicz NPP. Parallel localization studies were conducted in order to prepare for the third and subsequent plants. In the first stage, analysis was performed to find possible nuclear plant locations throughout Poland and resulted in the choice of 62 areas. Then the list was limited to 29 sites. Further studies and research were interrupted due to the resignation of the development of nuclear energy programme. In 2009, the Ministry of Economy made an upgrade of nuclear localization proposals contemplated in 1990. On this basis, a list of 28 potential sites for NPP was constructed. It is presented on a map in Appendix 1. The most important factors that were considered in the process of site selection were: available land area, facilities for power plant 26

construction, water cooling possibilities, geological structure and stability of seismic terrain, population density, distribution of surrounding plants, reducing the construction and operation costs due to environmental conditions, environmental protection and land use, access to transportation routes, the lack of threats from nature and human activities, and appropriate wheather conditions (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). arnowiec, Gski and Choczewo are are the most probable locations, all of them situated at the Polish coast, so they have a good water access. arnowiec was chosen as the first one because of the benefits of some basic infrastructure that was left after 1980s. It is situated on the banks of arnowieckie Lake and only 10 km from the Baltic coast. Preliminary estimates suggest that the water resources of the lake will allow cooling one large NPP (such as EPR or AP1000) at the use of a closed cooling system with a wet cooling tower with natural draft.

4.1.4. Reactor
Poland is interested in nuclear technology from France, Japan, Korea and the United States, and has signed or is negotiating co-operation agreements with these countries. In Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) there is stated that the chosen reactors will be of Generation III or III+ design, which complies with European European Utilities Requirements and U.S. Utility Requirements Document. The EU accepted 7 types of nuclaer reactors to be used in the Member States: EP 1000, EPR, BWR 90/90+, ABWR, SWR 1000, AP 1000, WER AES92. Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) informed that there are 3 types of potential reactors: European Power Reactor (EPR), Simplified Boiling Water Reactor (BWR) or Advanced Boiling Water Reactor (ABWR). In EPR, the coolant is water under a pressure of 15 MPa. These reactors are safe and the most common (about 65% of all). In Boiling Water Reactors water is also the coolant, but in contrast it circulates in a loop (Elektrownia jdrowa, 2012). The final choice of technology will be made by the consortium building the plant. One of the potential manufacturers is Areva. It has 2 possible reactors: EPRTM and KERENATM. Table 1 presents some basic features of both types.

27

Table 1. Comparison of potential reactors Feature


Type Generation Capacity (MW) Safety system Fuel production costs Waste production Construction time Power output adjustment rate Fuel Life (years)

EPRTM
European Power Reactor III+ 1650 (one of the most powerful) passive and active with special safety components reduced by 10% reduced by 15% standard 5% per minute 5% uranium enriched/5% repossessed uranium/mixed oxide fuel 60

KERENATM
Advanced Boiling Water Reactor III+ 1250 passive and active reduced reduced by 15% reduced 5% per minute 5% uranium enriched/5% repossessed uranium/mixed oxide fuel 60

Source: Own elaboration based on Areva (2012).

The major difference between them, excluding the type, is the capacity and construction time. Predictably, higher capacity means longer building period. Other characteristics are similar, both are predicted to operate 60 years, use uranium as fuel and have the same power adjustment rate. Areva (2012) underlines that its nuclear reactors comply with the highest safety requirements and are environmentally friendly as they minimize fuel consumption as well as waste production (and thus operating costs).

It is planned that until 2030 there should be two nuclear power blocks having the total capacity of 4 500 MW. The first power block will have the capacity of 2 000 MW and will start operating around 2020. The second block was designed to have capacity of 1 000 MW, it will be finished around 2030. The exact capacity and number of units are likely to depend on the reactor technology chosen, and, as mentioned above, several options are being considered. According to the governments projections, NPPs will provide about 7% of electricity by 2022, rising to 16% in 2030.

28

4.2.

Alternative project

A CBA appraisal needs to identify the counter-factual, a project which would be developed if a potential investment took place. It is used because CBA requires comparing net benefits of a potential policy to the net benefits of the policys best alternative (Boardman et al, 2006). For the purpose of the thesis, it was assumed that there would be built a hypothetical new coal-fuel power plant with capacity of 4 700 MW, producing 40 TWh of energy annually (85% of operational performance, the so called load factor). Most assumptions were based on the figures characteristic to the Polish reality, where the old and inefficient blocks of coal-fired plants are being replaced with new and more environmentally friendly ones.

Coal-fired power plants produce electricity by burning coal in a boiler to heat water to produce steam. The steam, at tremendous pressure, flows into a turbine, which spins a generator to produce electricity. The steam is cooled, condensed back into water, and returned to the boiler to start the process over again (WNA, 2012). Presently, they have the operational life of about 35-40 years and load factor at the level of 85-90% (IEA, 2005). Based on the information in IEA (2005) the construction period would be 4 years and about 90% of expenditure would be incurred in the last years. Investment costs for a Polish coal-fuel power plant would be between 1 800 /kW to 2 000 /kW, so for a plant of 4 700 MW, the total costs should reach between 37.7-41.9 billion zl (Energetyka jdrowa, 2012). More costs connected with the coal-fuel plant and its operation were given in Table 4 in part 4.5.1. Construction would start, as with the NPP, in the middle of 2016.

It is worth noting that coal-fuel power plants have a different costs structure than the nuclear ones. While NPP require high investment costs but then cheap fuel, with coal power generation it is opposite. The proportions were illustrated in Figure 6.

29

Figure 6. Proportions of electricity generating costs


100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% Nuclear Coal

O&M Fuel Capital

Source: Own elaboration based on Kennedy (2007), IEA (2005).

4.3.

Scope and standing

In this section the boundaries of the CBA were fixed. As mentioned in the theoretical part of the thesis, after delimitating standing analysts take into account only these groups of people whose welfare changes count. The assumptions made at this stage have strong implications for the overall results. The conclusions of the same analysis might change completely if one were to change standing.

Generally, in the governmental projects the group that has standing is the nation, as it is in this case as well. As a result, while estimating the impact of the NPP on the Polish societys welfare, the welfare changes of foreigners were omitted. Consequently, it has been decided to narrow down the analysis to the national level as it regards Polish energy policy which aims to maximize the welfare of the Polish population subject to constraints set by the EU and other organizations. However, opting for the national perspective does not mean that individuals outside Poland will not be affected. The Polish electricity market is not a closed circuit but is connected to the whole Baltic region both physically through cables and in the market term through the Baltic energy system. This means that any effects on the market price of electricity arising from the introduction of more electricity into the grid will also influence electricity prices in these neighbouring countries as the equilibrium price level might change. Moreover, environmental impact is also considered to be global as it affects people all over the planet. Changing the structure of energy production by adding a NPP might cause significant effects on climate (European Commission, 2008).

30

4.4.

Identification of costs and benefits

The next step in this thesis covered the identification of costs and benefits, specified the measurement indicators and put the money value to them. Boardman et al. (2006) underlines that while listing the impacts of a policy it is essential to take into account only those which affect the welfare of people with standing and their utility. It must be mentioned that the costs of grid balancing and improving the energy transmission system were excluded from the analysis as they are not the direct expenditure. Table 2 presents the main costs and benefits, which were then further described.

Table 2. Costs and benefits of the nuclear power plant Costs


Pre-development costs Investment costs Operating costs - fuel costs - waste costs - management costs Decommissioning costs Other costs
Source: Own elaboration based on Kennedy (2007).

Benefits
Environmental benefits Security of supply

Employment benefits

Other benefits

4.4.1. Costs
NPPs typically have high capital costs for building the plant, but low direct fuel costs (with much of the costs of fuel extraction, processing, use and long term storage externalized). Therefore, comparison with other power generation methods is strongly dependent on assumptions about construction timescales and capital financing for NPPs. Cost estimates also need to take into account decommissioning and nuclear waste storage costs. Measures to mitigate global warming favour nuclear power (Elektrownia jdrowa., 2012).

31

Pre-development costs
Pre-development costs are the expenditure previous to the building phase. They include, e.g. R&D of the site, setting up necessary governmental bodies or streamlining the law. They are crucial as they lay the foundations for any investment. In the Polish case, some of these have already been incurred, some will be in the following years (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010).

Investment costs
According to WNA (2005) capital costs are incurred while the plant is under construction and consist of expenditure on the necessary equipment, engineering and labour. They are often called overnight costs, which are exclusive of interest accruing during the construction period, and include engineer-procure-construct costs, owners costs and various contingencies. Once the plant is completed and electricity sales begin, the plant owners begin to repay the sum of overnight costs and accrued interest charges. The price charged must cover not only these costs, but also operating costs (annual fuel costs and expenditure on operation and maintenance (O&M)). One of the biggest problems with nuclear power is the enormous upfront cost. Reactors are extremely expensive to build and while returns might be high, but they are also very slow. A further difficulty is that due to the liberalized electricity market future income is unpredictable. Because of the large capital costs for NPP, and the relatively long construction period before revenue is returned, the investment can contribute about 7080% of the costs of electricity. The chosen discount rate is therefore the most sensitive parameter to overall costs. Modern NPPs are planned for construction in four years or less. Construction delays can add significantly to the cost of a plant. Because a power plant does not earn income during construction, longer construction period translates directly into higher finance charges (Elektrownia jdrowa, 2012).

Operating costs
In general, coal and nuclear plants have the same type of operating costs (operations and maintenance plus fuel costs). However, nuclear has lower fuel costs but higher operating and maintenance costs. Operations and maintenance (O&M) costs are very variable for NPPs, depending on such factors as plant size and age, but on average they account for 20% of the total costs per year (WNA, 2005). Liberalization of electricity 32

markets has helped in introducing best practices in reducing O&M costs throughout the industry, while maintaining or improving high safety standards.

Fuel As stated in Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) the supply of nuclear fuel, that is uranium, for the NPP planned in Poland will come from imports. Two-thirds of the supply of uranium globally come from primary sources or from mines in Canada, Australia, Kazakhstan and Niger. Security of supply of nuclear fuel depends on the certainty of supply of uranium ore and concentrate uranium, access to fuel cycle services, as well as a reliable and secure transport of finished nuclear fuel. According to the EU requirements regarding uranium supply there should be: diversification of supply, maintaining an appropriate level of its own uranium reserves, optimal use of the uranium market opportunities, striving to cover the demand for uranium on a contractual basis and meeting the needs of the fuel cycle services in the EU. Poland at the beginning will not produce the fuel, but buy it from one of the several global fuel suppliers. Purchase of fuel will be bound, at least in the first phase operation of NPP, with the purchase of technology. The world practice is that the technology provider also provides the fuel supply for the first 5-10 years operation. Due to the developed market for the fuel, the introduction of the NPP will not cause Polish addiction to foreign suppliers.

Waste The problem of disposal of radioactive waste was made in Poland in 1958 at the start of the Institute for Nuclear Research in wierk and the first research nuclear reactor EWA. Significant development of isotopic techniques and associated increasing usage of radioactive isotopes in different areas of the economy in the early 1960's have caused an urgent need to solve the problem of radioactive waste management. The solution was found by the location of the nuclear waste treatment plant in Rana. Nowadays, the main source of liquid and solid waste is the reactor MARIA and the manufacturing plant of radioactive isotopes, such as the Institute POLATOM Atomic Energy Radioisotope Centre. Other waste comes from located throughout the country hospitals, clinics and different institutions using isotopic techniques. Due to the NPP project there are plans to construct a deep, underground repository for high-radioactive waste and spent fuel in the future. According to the experiences of other countries the necessity of 33

building such a repository will appear after 30-40 years since the release of first NPP, this means the earliest around 2050 (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010).

Decommissioning
At the end of a NPP's lifetime the plant must be decommissioned. It begins immediately after final and permanent closure and continues ideally to the point of leaving a clear site where the facility had once stood. The process incorporates some or all of the following activities: the safe management of nuclear materials held in the facility as well as radioactive and other wastes, decontamination, plant dismantling, demolition and site remediation. This entails dismantling, safe storage or entombment. Operators are usually required to build up a fund to cover these costs while the plant is operating to limit the financial risk from operator bankruptcy (Elektrownia jdrowa, 2012). Provision for decommissioning costs is made by making financial contributions over the economic life of the plant towards plant dismantling and eventual site restoration. Given that plants are expected to have long lives, the contributions are not significant. WNA (2005) states that they amount to less than 1% of the overall costs per year.

Other
There are also other costs connected with NPPs, however, these were excluded from monetization. Unlike other power plants, NPPs must be carefully guarded against both attempted sabotage and possible theft of nuclear material. Thus security costs of both protecting the physical plant and the screening of workers must be considered. Since nuclear reactors contain a core of highly radioactive fuel, NPP operators need to invest considerable resources in keeping these structures intact and isolated from the environment. Whereas a conventional power plant can break down without large environmental effects, this has to be prevented at a NPP at all cost. Also insurance is required (Elektrownia jdrowa, 2012). Rosenkranz, (2006, p.12) underlined that There is no other technology for which a single event can trigger the collapse of an entire pillar of energy supply. As evidence of the long-run repercussions of a break-down Chernobyl can be used. The United Nations estimated the death toll at 4 000. In 2010, newly released documents indicated that millions more were affected by the fallout and cleanup than originally thought, which in turn led to tens of thousands of deaths as well as hundreds of thousands of sick children born long after the initial meltdown. To make 34

matters more complex, the concrete entombing is now beginning to crack (Zehner, 2012). The costs are still rising after almost 30 years from the disaster.

4.4.2. Benefits
WNA (2005) enlisted the following benefits of developing nuclear energy: - national: price stability and security of energy supply, - global: positive environmental impact by near-zero greenhouse gas emissions. However, there are also for instance employment advantages.

Environmental benefits
In practice it is difficult to assess, not to mention monetize, all environmental impacts. Nuclear electricity generation is environmentally friendly as it does not release greenhouse gases, such as carbon dioxide (CO2), methane (CH4), nitrous oxide (N2O), hydro fluorocarbons (HFCs), perfluoro carbons (PFCs) or sulphur hexafluoride (SF6) (NEA, 2011). There is also no dust or mercury production as in opposition to coal electricity production. From the perspective of the full nuclear fuel lifecycle, a very small amount of pollution is produced indirectly while mining, transporting or processing uranium and during the construction phase of a NPP (Kennedy, 2007). Based on Kennedy (2007) the environmental benefits of nuclear power were chosen to be evaluated as a reduction of CO2 emission relative to the counter-factual case of a coal-fired power plant. In this way the reduction was equalized to the level of emissions that would have occurred if coal-fired plant were to be added rather than nuclear. The CO2 equivalent was used, because nuclear power expansion would result in the reduction of different pollutants, not only the CO2. Then carbon emissions associated with the construction and operation of NPP, and with the mining, transport and processing of uranium should be subtracted from the total emissions reduction above to give a net value.

Security of supply
The amount of uranium needed to operate a NPP of 1 000 MW can easily bring in any country, and can easily store a supply for a few years of running the plant. Fluctuations in the price of uranium ore have very little impact on the cost of electricity production at NPPs, due to the low share of fuel costs in the total costs of energy production.

35

According to data from Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) the uranium price increase by 100% increases the cost of electricity production in NPP by 5%. Once built NPP supplies electricity generated with a stable cost, almost regardless of price fluctuations on the world market of raw materials. This helps to maintain the stability of electricity prices on the market, which promotes sustainable development. As mentioned earlier, energy security is the key priority of the Polish energy policy. Diversification of energy sources through building a NPP will not only ease the heavy reliance on imports from Russia and thus enhance energy security but will also allow Poland to negotiate better prices thanks to competitive pressure on suppliers (IEA, 2011). In this analysis it has been chosen to model the security of supply benefit based on Kennedy (2007) as the avoided cost related to mitigating the risk of a major supply interruption. However, security of supply relating to avoided GDP losses is very difficult to quantify accurately.

Employment benefits
Employment benefits are an important positive externality and are especially emphasized by the politicians in cases of large-scale projects. Clearly, a NPP would directly create various jobs related to the planning, construction, operation and decommissioning of the plant. Strupczewski (2012) claims that there might be a demand for 7 140 people to construct the plant and then permanently 2 400 to operate it. Moreover, new jobs would be created across a range of industrial sectors. However, despite these prospects, it must be remembered that the employment opportunities also exist for the alternative plant. Furthermore, additional employment is a social opportunity cost, because it uses labour resources that become unavailable for alternative social purposes (Boardman, 2006). To estimate the social benefit of additional employment accounting or shadow wages should be used. It was chosen to calculate it in this paper as the number of workers employed multiplied by the wage for which the workers would be employed. It was not halved, as one of Boardman at el.s (2006) approach suggests, because the salary in Poland is rather low and not many workers would be willing to work for less than their wage as it would not suffice for their basic needs.

36

Other benefits
NPP will cause more positive effects than the three above-mentioned ones. Strupczewski (2012) states that it should allow the economic recovery of some regions and thus boost the domestic industry. Moreover, it should accelerate research and innovation as well as higher education in the relevant areas. Finally, across the economy new job positions ought to be created.

4.5.

Quantification and monetization of costs and benefits

To evaluate the costs correctly, the shadow price of capital for Poland was calculated. Based on the theoretical section, it was assumed that rz = 4.5% and pz = 1.5%. Boardman et al. (2006) suggests = 10%. Finally, f was equalized to 13.9% after estimation of the average of the real gross capital formation in GDP in Poland in 19952010. The calculation has been presented in Appendix 2. The shadow price of capital is:

= [(0.045 + 0.1)(1 0.139)]/[0.015 0.1* 0.139 + 0.1(1 0.139)] = 1.43

In this thesis, it was assumed that only costs pertaining to pre-investment (that would be government expenditure) would fully crowd out private investments as these resources might had been employed on other investment projects. With respect to the remaining costs, as there was no information available about the actual distribution of government subsidies (if any), they were assumed to be incurred by the investor only. Consequently, only pre-investment costs were converted to consumption equivalents by multiplying them by the shadow price of capital factor of 1.43.

Further in this section costs and benefits of both the project and its alternative were estimated for the NPV calculations. For the purpose of the following sensivity analysis pessimistic and optimistic case costs were also presented in Table 3 and 4. All prices were converted to Polish zloty at the rate exchange on 1.01.2012 of for euro of 4.4640, for pound of 5.3480 and for U.S. dollar of 3.4454. It is worth noting, that this exchange rate was exceptionally high, at the moment of writing this thesis for example for euro it was around 4.1-4.2. For the calculation of levelised costs (based on section 3.3.) cost of capital was assumed as given by Kennedy (2007) and WNA (2005).

37

It must be mentioned that the analysis does not attempt to monetize all costs and benefits. In most projects, there are significant non-monetary impacts but they are difficult to express in monetary terms (Boardman et al., 2006). All of them should be listed as their magnitude could outweigh the monetary effects of the project. In this thesis, the monetary value associated with potential accidents was not estimated. Though accident risk should not be dismissed, the assumption was that this could be managed through design of regulatory and corporate governance arrangements for the nuclear industry.

4.5.1. Costs
At first, costs of the NPP were calculated, as shown in Table 3 on the next page. Further on costs of the alternative were also estimated.

Pre-investment costs
These costs would be mostly incurred by the government. Expenditures that had already been incurred in 2011 (listed in Annex 3) were added to 2012 costs. They amounted to 139 840 thousands zloty. Costs from before 2011 were excluded from calculations as there was no data available regarding the exact point in time when they occurred. These are as follows: 11 million zl for the functioning of the Polish Atomic Agency (PAA), 47.4 million zl for research and core activities, 1.7 million zl for grants for investment in construction and assembly.

The rest of pre-investment costs was taken as given by Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) and listed in Appendix 3 with a 5% sensivity range. Polish government did not state any other costs than the investment expenditure. For the purpose of the thesis, the operating costs were obtained from international reports.

Investment costs
Building a NPP is a long and costly process. According to Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) construction costs of third-generation reactors amount to 3-3.5 million euros per MW of capacity built. This means that the construction of two power plants with a total capacity of 4 500 MW will cost 13.5-15.75 billion euros. In this thesis, it was assumed that these expenditure consist of overnight

38

costs and capital institutions interest. Thomas (2005) underlines that often the quoted costs must be treated with care as they tend to underestimate the total expenditure. In the Polsih case, there might be the risk of the lack of experience and the governemnt wanting to show nuclear energy in the positive light. The costs might also change due to changes in labour costs and raw materials (like steel or concrete). Regarding the volume of expenditure spent each year, IEA (2005) notes that around 90% of the construction costs are incurred within the first 5 years. Therefore, such fractions of expenditures were assumed while performing calculations, starting from mid-2016.

Table 3. Nuclear power plant costs estimation Costs


Pre-investment Pre-investment* Investment Fuel

Optimistic
816.7

Base
859.7 1 229.4 65 286 786 152 1 648 3.2 60 years 90% 7.5%

Pessimistic
902.7 1 290.8 70 308 830 157 1 813 4.7 60 years 90% 10%

total

1 167. 9 60 264

million zl

680 137 1 483 1.8 60 years 90% 5%

Management Decommissioning Operation period Performance Cost of capital

TOTAL LEVELISED TOTAL LEVELISED with pre-investment*


Source: Own elaboration.

per year

Waste

91.84 zl/MWh 92.20 zl/MWh

106.54 zl/MWh 107.04 zl/MWh

117.00 zl/MWh 117.63/MWh

39

Operating costs
Fuel The only significant economic use of naturally occurring uranium is to use it to produce nuclear fuel necessary in nuclear reactors. It has so large amounts of energy that the annual operating NPP with a capacity of 1 000 MW needs only about 25 tons of nuclear fuel, so 112.5 tons are necessary for a NPP of 4 500 MW capacity. The costs of fuel are low and relatively stable (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010). The Ux Consulting Company publishes daily price for uranium (The Ux Consulting Company, 2012). The cost of fuel per MWh is about 4.4 (Energetyka jdrowa, 2012), so around 19-20 zl/MWh. If assumed that the plant would produce approximately 40 TWh per year (4 500 MW capacity*0.9% operational performance), then the annual cost of fuel would be 786 million zl. In Poland, the price is also dependent on exchange rate, not only on the global markets value, if the exchange rate were only 4.2, then it would give the cost of 739 million zl. Consequently, for the sensivity analysis, the following range was assumed, giving the figure between 680 and 730 million zl, This estimates seem reasonable and give comparable results if based on Kennedy (2007).

Waste It has been chosen to base the assumption on nuclear waste disposal costs using the projection of Kennedy (2007) of around 0.7/MWh (3.8 zl/MWh), resulting in the annual cost of waste for a 4 500 MW NPP to be around 152 million zl per year. According to WNA (2005) levels of 1 /MWh have been achieved in Finland and Sweden, so this price was chosen for the pessimistic case. The range for the sensivity analysis was assumed to be from 137 to 167 million zl.

Management O&M according to Kennedy (2007) amounts to 7.7/MWh (41.2 zl/MWh), which was assumed for the base case in this thesis. It gave 1 648 million zl annually. The range of O&M was chosen to vary between 1 483 and 1 813 million zl/year.

40

Decommissioning
Since it may cost $300 million (around 1 032 million zl) or more to shut down and decommission a plant, it is required for the plant owners to set aside money when the plant is still operating to pay for the future shutdown costs (WNA, 2005). Kennedy (2007) gives an even higher estimate of 200-500 million (1 069-2674 million zl). If assumed 60 years of operation and the discount rate of 5.8%, then the annual contribution ought to be from around 1.81 to 4.7 million zl.

Coal-fuel plant costs


Table 4 presents cost estimates for the coal-fuel power plant.

Table 4. Coal-fuel power plant costs estimation Costs


Investment Fuel Management Operation period Performance Cost of capital

Optimistic per year total million zl


37 765 5 629 1 076.2 40 years 85% 5%

Base
39 868 5 925 1 227.3 40 years 85% 7.5%

Pessimistic
41 971 6 221 1 378.4 40 years 85% 10%

TOTAL LEVELISED
Source: Own elaboration.

144.21 zl/MWh

142.86 zl/MWh

139.90 zl/MWh

It was assumed that there would be no government pre-investment costs, because the resources have already been well-estimated, labour force is educated and experienced, no new government body is required, etc.

Investment costs for a coal-fuel power plant in Poland are evaluated at between 1 800 /kW to 2 000 /kW, so about 1.8-2 million euro per MW. For a plant of 4 700 MW the

41

total costs should be between 37.7-41.9 billion zl (Energetyka jdrowa, 2012). There would be no crowding out of private investment because the investment would not be financed from the public funds.

The price of coal was assumed to be $106/t, the price at 30.12.2011 (http://gornictwo.wnp.pl, 2012). It gives 365 zl/t, excluding transportation costs of approximately 30 zl/t. For a hypothetical coal-fuel power plant of 4 700 MW, producing 40 TWh annually and using 15 million tons of coal, the fuel cost is 5 925 million zl/year (http://elektrownia-jdrowa.pl, 2012). The assumed range for the sensivity analysis was only 5% as coal price is relatively stable over years.

In IEA (2005) different annual O&M costs were given, ranging from 9.29 /kW (41.5 zl/kW) in Romania to 96.9 /kW (432 zl/kW) in Germany, for the Czech Republic they were around 28 /kW (125 zl/kW). Assuming that the Czech Republic and Germany as neighbouring countries might have similar conditions, it gives the range between 587.5 and 2 030.4 million zl. Kaplan (2008) divided O&M costs into fixed and variable. Fixed costs differed between $28-35/kW (94.5-120.5 zl/kW) and variable between $4.65.9/MWh (15.8-20.3 zl/MWh). This is about 1 076.15-1 378.35 million zl for the power plant under analysis. The estimates based on Kaplan (2008) seem more reasonable as they are comparable to the NPP costs and Kennedy (2007) mentioned that these two types of power plants (also oil-fuel power plants) have comparable O&M. Consequently, these estimates were taken for the purpose of this analysis.

Coal-fuel power plants produce a lot of different kinds of waste, most of them are toxic, they include carbon dioxide (CO2), nitrogen oxides (NOx), chlorofluorocarbon (CFC), sulphur oxides (SxOx), dust, soot, mercury (Hg) and other pollutants (Kaplan, 2008). However, waste cost was not estimated, it was assumed to be incorporated into O&M costs, as no data was available. In U.S. there are emission allowances for SO2, NOx and mercury that the plants have to buy (Kaplan, 2008), but in Poland there are no such requirements. In the normal analysis of a coal-fuel plants profitability and an electricity price calculation CO2 emissions are taken into account. Here however, they were classified as a benefit of the NPP (the classification choice was strictly for the comparison reason and to obtain an advantage of the NPP). Coal-fuel power plants do

42

not have to pay annually contribution to decommissioning fund as there are no decommissioning costs at the end of their lifetime.

4.5.2. Benefits
According to Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) in 2020 there will be a large advantage in power generation in NPPs. Table 5 presents the benefits of the NPP that were taken into account for the socio-economic calculation.

Table 5. Nuclear power plant benefits estimation Benefits


Environmental benefits Supply security Employment benefits
Source: Own elaboration.

Optimistic
6 400

Base
5 536

Pessimistic
2 144

million zl

per year

GDP*1.03*0.004 219.8/ 100.8

GDP*1.03*0.003 157.5/ 67.7

GDP*1.03*0.002 95.2/ 34.6

Environmental benefits
Coal-fired power plants emissions are a function of thermal efficiency, which was assumed to be 43% (http://elektrownia-jdrowa.pl, 2012). Emissions increase as the level of thermal efficiency falls, in this thesis an average efficiency was assumed. A coal-fuel power plant generating 40 TWh of energy annually produces approximately 31.8 million tons of CO2 equivalent per year (http://elektrownia-jdrowa.pl, 2012). Because carbon dioxide consists of oxygen fractions which are not considered as pollutants, sometimes these fractions are excluded and only carbon atoms are estimated. Using the conversion rate of 12/44, carbon dioxide can be converted to carbon (Kennedy, 2007). Consequently, it would give 8.7 million of coal produced annually. In IEA (2005) the range was given between 0.8-1.26 tCO2/MWh, so for the plant under analysis from 32-50 million tons of CO2 emitted annually. As the technology improves, emissions are reduced, so the lower figure was assumed for calculations in this thesis.

43

Kennedy (2007) notes that CO2 emissions for a NPP range between 5 to 20 g/kWh. So for production of 40 TWh, there are from 200 to 800 tons of CO2 emitted. In his study, he takes the value of 10 g/kWh, consequently in this analysis it would give 400 tons of CO2 emitted annually. This figure is negligible and thus not incorporated into calculation. After inclusion of CO2 mitigation costs of 39 /tCO2 (173 zl/tCO2) and 32 million tons of CO2 emitted (http://elektrownia-jdrowa.pl, 2012) the advantage of the NPP increases by 5 536 million zl/year. If 50 million tons of CO2 were emitted, then the costs rise to 86 500 million zl/year. According to Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010) nuclear reactors with light-water will be competitive at CO2 emission cost of 15 /tCO2 (67 zl/tCO2). Similar figures were given by NEA (2011). For the purpose of the analysis it was assumed that the coal-fuel plant would emit 32 million tons of CO2 pe year. In the base case the price would be 39 /tCO2. For the optimistic and pessimistic scenario calculations it would reach the value of 15 and 45 /tCO2 (200 zl/tCO2). The lower and middle figures are consistent with the prices observed at the EU, with the higher value trying to represent the expected price for 2020-2030. It is worth noting that even higher allowance prices in the future should not be excluded if climate negotiations are successful and more stringent targets are set (Kennedy, 2007).

Security of supply
According to IEA (2005) the actual GDP losses associated with increasing coal prices are estimated to be around 0.5% of GDP from a 10% increase in the price of coal. Coal price is rather stable (WCA, 2012), so this effect would not have a huge impact. In IEA (2005) different price rate growths were given based on the manufacturers prognoses. When prices were assumed to increase, the average rate was of around 50% between 2010 and the end of the plant economic lifetime in 2050. Predicting a 75% increase in 60 years of the NPPs operation, the security supply benefit would reach 0.06% of GDP each year, which for the year 2011 would give 849 million zl (Polish GDP was equal to 1 415 385 million zl as given by GUS, 2012). With 3% of GDP growth each year and 5.8% discount rate the average benefit would be around 145.13 million zl. However, if coal price was stable, there would be no benefit at all. There are too many uncertainties to assess this figure accurately. According to European Commission (2010) the average GDP growth for the EU countries until 2030 will be only 2%. The author of this thesis 44

thus chose the range for the benefit at 3% growth in GDP to be from 75 to 25% increase in coal price over 60 years. 3% growth in GDP was assumed as after 2030 the economy might accelerate and recover from the 2008 financial crisis and moreover Poland has to catch up to the EU 15.

Employment benefits
For calculating employment benefits it was assumed that there would be 7 140 new people employed while building the plant and 2 400 permanently afterwards (Strupczewski, 2012). The net salary was taken from GUS (2012) to be between the legal minimum of 1 111 zl/month (13 332 zl/year) and the average of 2 562 zl/month (30 780 zl/year) for years 2016-2030 and between 1 200 zl/month and 3 500 zl/month afterwards. The reality in Poland is that most of the new employees get the lowest required wage. For the later years wage increases were taken into account, both the legal minimum as with tenure. The estimates were shown in Table 5, the lower figures are the benefits from 2030, when the whole construction period would end. Employment created in other industry sectors was excluded from calculations as it might be difficult to estimate correctly all the connections.

4.6.

NPV calculation

This section can be called the essence of the cost-benefit analysis as it deals with the NPV establishment. At first, the STPR was assessed and the total levelised costs compared to be followed by the NPV calculation. Since the Polish government bodies have not published in any official guideline for usage of social discount rate, for the purpose of this paper it was calculated by its author. The assessment was based on the STPR methodology described in section 2.1.5. The pure rate of time preference () and the elasticity of marginal utility of consumption () are affected by the social and individual preferences, so their estimation might be difficult. In Boardman et al. (2006) it is recommended that should be equalized to 1%. For it is suggested to give it the value of 1.3, with sensivity analysis at 1.0 and 2.0. Evans (2006) bases its estimate of on tax data and foreign aid contributions, because the behavioural approach causes empirical problems. He concludes that the parameter should be equalized to unity. If is equal to one, the relative weight on societys

45

consumption in each time period equals the inverse of its relative per capita consumption (Boardman et al., 2006, p. 248). In other words, a 1% reduction in consumption today is accepted by society if there is a 1% increase in consumption at a richer, future time. It deals with the problem of intergenerational inequality and assumes that consumption units received today are treated by society in a different way than consumption units received in the future. In order to estimate the annual growth in per capita consumption (g) in Poland historical data from the national statistics were retrieved. The annual change in these parameters in the period 2000-2010 is enclosed in Appendix 4. The results indicate that the real consumption per capita grew by 3.7% on average. Boardman et al. (2006) based his calculation on the data from the United States and got 2.3% of the average growth rate in consumption per capita in years 1947-2002. Consequently, he used g of 2% with a sensivity analysis at 1.5% and 2.5%. Poland has a higher rate because of the catchingup effect. Calculations based on the equation: r = + g, were presented in Table 6,

Table 6. STPR derivation Case


optimistic base pessimistic

1% 1% 1%

1% 1.3% 2%

g
1.5% 3.7% 4.5%

STPR I
2.5% 5.8% 10%

STPR II
2% 5.3% 9.5%

Source: Own elaboration.

In the base case the discount rate of 5.8% is close to the European Commission (2008) recommendation and supports the argument that SDR for cohesion countries should be higher relative to the developed EU countries. Evans (2005) derived STPR for Poland equal to 6.1%, assuming = 1.0%, = 1.1% and g = 4.6% (it was much higher as it was assessed before the financial crisis in 2008).

However, the problem of intergenerational equity should be addressed. Due to the fact that NPP would disperse the costs and benefits through a long period of time, individuals not yet born might be affected by the project. Consequently, individuals that incur some of the costs might not be alive to get the benefits. Moreover, the longer the

46

project, the more uncertain is the growth rate and other aspects of the economy. To deal with these dilemmas and take into account sustainability a time-declining SDR ought to be applied (Boardman et al., 2006). HM Treasury (2003) also suggests using a decreasing SDR rates depending on project duration to give more weight to the costs and benefits that occur further in the future. Boardman et al. (2006) recommends using 3.5% from year 0 to year 50, 2.5% from year 50 to year 100, 1.5% from year 100 to 200, 0.5% from year 200 to year 300, and 0 thereafter. Similar procedure was followed in this thesis. For the base case STPR of 5.8% was applied for the first 40 years and 5.3% for the rest (similarly with the remaining cases). The range of 40 years was chosen, because starting from 2012 and assuming that the NPP will be finished until 2020, it will operate until 2080, so 50 years might be to long. As a justification can be the fact that Kennedy (2007) used the highest rate only for the first 30 years, but his power plant was assumed to run only for 40 years.

In Table 7 levelised costs were compared and cost benefit/penalty for the NPP calculated.

Table 7. Nuclear power plant levelised cost advantage Costs


Coal-fuel levelised cost Nuclear levelised cost Cost advantage

Optimistic
144.21 zl/MWh 92.20 zl/MWh + 52.01 zl/MWh

Base
142.6 zl/MWh 107.4 zl/MWh + 35.82 zl/MWh

Pessimistic
139.0 zl/MWh 117.3/MWh + 22.27 zl/MWh

Annual cost advantage (million)


Source: Own elaboration.

2 080.4 zl

1 432.8 zl

890.8 zl

Obtained results of levelised costs seem to be reasonable and find reflection in other research studies. According to IEA (2005) levelised costs for a coal-fuel plant (without CO2 emission costs) are approximately between $25 to $60 per MWh (84-206 zl/MWh) and for a NPP between $21-50/MWh (72-172 zl/MWh). Such a wide range was the consequence of choosing different countries to be analysed. Kennedy (2007) also

47

evaluated levelised costs for a NPP and got the estimate of approximately 22-38/MW (117,6-203,2 zl/MW). It is worth noting here that despite such cost levels for producing electricity, the average energy price from a NPP for a typical load factor of 0.9 is approximately 57 /MWh (253 zl/MW), while the next in order lignite-fired power plant with a pulverized coal boiler will produce energy at the cost of about 80 /MWh (355 zl/MW), mailny due to pollution mitigating costs (Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej, 2010), for coal-fuel plant the costs are even higher. Strupczewski (2012) informs that in France energy price from NPPs is as in the range of 40 /MWh. In the next step, levelised costs of the two plant types were compared over the assumed operational life of a NPP. As can be seen in Table 7, the NPP has cost advantage over the alternative in all cases (lower levelised cost than coal-fuel power plant). Under the taken assumptions, it has the benefit ranging from 22.27 to 52.01 zl/MWh. In other words, nuclear electricity production cost is lower by these figures relative to coal-fuel production. Cost differentials were then multiplied by annual output to give an annual nuclear cost advantage.

Once the project impacts had been converted into their cash flows, the appropriate discount rate estimated and the levelised cost method applied, NPV could have been obtained to measure the projects viability and welfare effects. The results were shown in Table 8. The cost advantage was regarded as a social benefit. All benefits and costs were discounted for the base case at the STPR of 5.8% for the first 40 years and 5.3% for the rest (similarly with the remaining cases necessary for the upcoming sensivity analysis).

The project can be accepted in the base case as the NPV value is equal to 18 606 million zl. It may be only 0.0013% of the GDP in 2011, but still the first NPP would improve the welfare of the Polish society and give to it over 18.5 billion zl. The results were taken into further consideration in part 3.7., in the sensivity analysis to check how they would differ with changes in key variables.

48

Table 8. NPV calculation Optimistic


STPR Total discounted benefits (thousand) Total discounted costs (thousand) 2.5%; 2.0% 287 457 726.4 zl

Base
5.8%; 5.3% 93 761 483 zl

Pessimistic
10.0%; 9.5% 18 979 016 zl

117 156 543.7 zl

75 155 550 zl

51 841 865 zl

NPV (thousand)
Source: Own elaboration.

170 301 182.7 zl

18 605 933 zl

- 32 862 849 zl

4.7.

Sensivity analysis

It was of paramount importance to check the responsiveness of the solution to changes in the base assumptions. The aim of this procedure was to find a balance between the relative uncertainty and the relative magnitude of contingencies on the overall results. The analysis covers a range of scenarios for nuclear costs, coal prices and carbon fees. Boardman et al. (2006) advises to undertake Monte Carlo analysis of expected net benefits as it takes into account all the available information about the values of parameters. In this paper, the approach was to model the worst and best case scenarios for key variables, the Monte Carlo analysis for the base case as well as to perform a partial analysis for environmental and security benefits.

Table 8 presents besides the base case, also the optimistic and pessimistic case, necessary for sensivity analysis. As can be seen the project should be accepted in the optimistic and base case. However, in the pessimistic case the NPV value is negative. The difference between the NPV values in the optimistic and base case is enormous, much bigger than between the base and pessimistic. In the best case scenario the project would give Poland over 170 billion zl which is around 0.012% of the GDP in 2011. However, in the worst case scenario, the NPP should not be built as it would cause welfare loss of almost 33 million zl which is around 0.002% of the GDP in 2011.

49

Internal rate of return (IRR), the discount rate at which NPV is equal to zero, was calculated as well. The results for the optimistic and base cases, which are higher than STPR, mean that the project ought to be implemented. STPR higher than 12% for optimistic or 8% for base scenario makes the NPV value turn negative and favours the coal-fuel power plant. Regardless of the chosen discount rate in the worse scenario the NPP project should be terminated, because even for the discount rate of 0% the NPV value is negative (approximately 6 643 million zl) and thus as the IRR not calculable. Table 9 and Figure 7 show the results numerically and graphically.

Table 9. IRR calculation Optimistic


NPV (million) 170 301 zl

Base
18 606 zl

Pessimistic
- 32 863 zl

IRR
Source: Own elaboration.

12%

8%

Figure 7. NPV value with change of STPR


NPV (mln zl) 450 Optimistic Base Pessimistic

300

150

10

12

14

16

18

-150
Source: Own elaboration.

STPR (%)

50

Monte Carlo analysis allowed to conduct a more throughout simulation as it gives a range of possible NPV values. It was calculated only for the base case. It also enabled comparison with the previous approach. Given the lack of information about the underlying probability distributions, the distribution was assumed to be standard normal. The mean values of costs and benefits were the same as in the base case scenario. Standard deviations were assumed to be 20% for the environmental benefits because of its enormous influence and much uncertainty in CO2 emission prices. For the other benefits is was 10%, while for costs 5%. The percentages were obtained from calculation of standard deviations based on base, optimistic and pessimistic scenarios for all the benefits and costs. Having stated the assumptions, in the next step 1 000 random values were calculated for the benefits and costs in the base case over the years 2012-2080. They were then discounted to obtain 1 000 NPVs. These figures were consequently used to create a histogram and a scatter plot presented in Figure 8 and 9 respectively.

Figure 8. Histogram of 1 000 projected NPVs

Frequency 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0


7 .8 .9 .0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .5 4. 12 20 29 37 45 53 61 69 77 85 .6

Frequency

Bin (NPV values, bln zl)


Source: Own elaboration.

51

Figure 9. Scatter plot of 1 000 projected NPVs


Percentage 100,% 80,% 60,% 40,% 20,% 0,% 12.8 20.9 29.0 37.1 45.2 53.3 61.4 69.5 77.5 85.6 4.7 Cumulative density function

Bin (NPV values, billion zl)

Source: Own elaboration.

The results show that in the base case the NPV is positive in all 1 000 possibilities. The predicted minimum value is 4.7 billion zl while the maximum reaches 88.3 billion zl. The range is much smaller than in the best and worse case scenarios and more concentrated around the base case value of 18.6 billion zl. From Figure 8, it can be seen that the most frequent (297 and 275 of 1 000 possibilities) are the NPV values of 20.9 and 18.2 billion zl respectively. Most of the values are between 12.8 and 29.0 billion zl. Figure 9 gives percentage values of the cumulative NPVs. With the increasing value of NPV, 18% of the possible values is below 15.5 billion zl, 20% is between 18.2 and 20.9 billion zl, 17% between 20.9 and 23.6 billion zl. At the same time, 99% of all the values is below 26.3 billion zl. To sum up, the conclusion drawn from the Monte Carlo analysis is that the first NPP is a feasible project and should be implemented. Around 37% of all the possibilities will give wealth increase for the Polish society between 18.2 and 23.6 billion zl. Only extreme variation in the variables could cause a loss to the society as was shown in the worse case scenario.

52

Due to the importance of CO2 price (the higher the price, the more beneficial the NPP), partial sensivity analysis was carried out. In the former NPV as well as the worse and best case scenario analyses only the price of coal was allowed to change. However, as mentioned earlier emissions depend among others on e.g. the technology applied or coal quality (IEA, 2010), so for the partial analysis it was assumed that there would not be a huge improvement in technology and coal used would be of worse quality and as a consequence emissions increase. Table 10 summarises this reasoning. Kaplan (2007) also noticed that in the really extreme case the price of coal might reach 100 /tCO2 (446 zl/tCO2), so this was also taken into consideration. There is a huge range of the mitigation price (from 67 to 446 zl/tCO2) which causes the costs between 2.1 to 22.3 million zloty. There is much uncertainty about this trend; however the extreme outcomes are rather unlikely. It must be noted that in the analysis these costs were classified as environmental benefits, so the very pessimistic cost scenario gave the biggest advantage to the NPP.

Table 10. CO2 emission mitigation costs Optimistic


CO2 emission (million t/year) Price (zl/tCO2) 32 67

Base
41 173

Pessimistic
50 200

Very pessimistic
50 446

TOTAL (million zl)


Source: Own elaboration.

2 144

7 093

10 000

22 300

The break-even values (the values at which net benefits switch the sign) were calculated in order to find out under which circumstances the new NPP project is justified under the worst case scenario. The NPVs derived in part 3.6. of the thesis for the optimistic and base case were positive, so the author concluded that varying environmental benefit for them would not change the sign, only increase their value. Thus calculations were made only for the worst case. The results were presented in Figure 10. The break-even point shows that there is not such a large scope for the price of CO2 to change the sign of the worst cases outcome. As soon as the environmental benefit reaches 4.8 billion zl per year, the first NPP in Poland becomes feasible. Maybe, it is

53

two times bigger than the original value, but it is still lower than the CO2 price assumption for the base case in part 3.6. of the thesis. With emissions at the level of 32 million tons per year for the NPP project to break even the CO2 price should be around 150 zl/tCO2 or 33 /tCO2. With emissions at the level of 41 million tons per year the price should be about 117 zl/tCO2 or 26 /tCO2. Because it is rather improbable that CO2 emission price will be as low as 15 /tCO2 (67 zl/tCO2), especially in the long run and with the growing stress the EU puts on the environment, it might be concluded that the NPV would be positive in most cases and the NPP would increase the welfare of the Polish society.

Figure 10. Environmental benefit variation in the worst case scenario


Environmental benefit (bln zl) 25 20 15 NPV 10 5 0 13.8 0 11.7 26.7 90.3 4,828

NPV (bln zl)


Source: Own elaboration.

Partial analysis was also conducted for the supply security benefit. The results were presented in Table 11. The supply security benefit was allowed to change in three different cases: 1) a 75% increase in coal price over 60 years and a 3.5% growth in GDP each year, 2) a 37.5% increase in coal price over 60 years and a 3% growth in GDP each year, 3) a 0% increase in coal price over 60 years. Remaining assumptions were held constant at the level from the original analysis in part 3.6. As can be seen, the supply security benefit does not change the outcome. With no

54

benefit at all, the optimistic and base scenarios would be still acceptable. And even if the opposite was assumed, i.e. a 75% increase in coal price the worse case scenario the project would be still rejected and the NPP infeasible.

Table 11. Security supply benefit variation Optimistic


Supply security benefit calculation GDP*1.035*0.006 GDP*1.03*0.003 0

Base

Pessimistic

Discounted total benefits (million zl) 337 934 283 225 245 967 110 245 94 563 82 966 25 485 20 388 16 293

Discounted total costs (million zl) 117 157 75 156 NPV values (million zl) GDP*1.035*0.006 GDP*1.03*0.003 0
Source: Own elaboration.

51 842

220 777 166 069 128 810

35 090 19 407 7 810

-26 357 -31 454 -35 549

4.8.

Recommendation

Based solely on the net present value calculation presented in part 3.6., the recommendation seems obvious. Clearly, from this perspective the project of the first NPP in Poland should be implemented. Considering the NPV of 18.6 billion zl, the country would derive a welfare gain from the nuclear power expansion. There would be not only financial benefits, but also immeasurable ones, like lower pollution of CO2 and other gasses or dust.

However, it is important not to base the recommendation on the NPV calculation alone, because there is a wide scope of uncertainty. Some basic sensivity analysis was

55

performed in part 3.7., but the paper volume and time restriction prevented a deeper insight into it that might be valuable to perform in the future. The results showed that in the worse case scenario, the NPP project would be infeasible and Poland should rather go for the coal-fuel power plant. Moreover, it was shown that the different possibilities for the base case in the Monte Carlo analysis indicate profitability of the NPP. It was also discovered that CO2 emission prices change the sign in the worse case scenario at the level of 150 zl/tCO2 if 32 million tons of the gas equivalent would be emitted per year by the coal-fuel power plant. It must be noted that despite the size, it is still lower than the CO2 price assumption for the base case in part 3.6. of the thesis. Because the probability that CO2 emission price will be as low as originally assumed in the pessimistic case (67 zl/tCO2) is scarce, especially in the long run and with the increasing environmental requirements in the EU, it might be deducted that the NPV would be positive in most cases and thus the first NPP would add to the welfare of the Polish society (in European Commission (2010) the CO2 emission price was forecast to reach 173 zl/tCO2). Furthermore, the author of this thesis proved that the security benefit is not a key variable changing the sign of the project as the environmental benefit is.

To sum up, the author recommends going for the implementation of the first NPP in Poland. Overall, it is considered unlikely that the conclusions would change even if some of the assumptions had proved too optimistic as the individual variables would have to differ very drastically to be otherwise which was proved by the Monte Carlo analysis.

56

5. Conclusion
As IEA (2011) points out, there are still some areas Poland has to improve. First, a more integrated energy and climate policy is needed for a low-carbon path while enhancing energy security. Secondly, energy policy should put more emphasis on promoting competition to make the energy markets more efficient. Nuclear energy might provide foundations for a clean and competitive energy future in Poland. Moreover, integration of energy and climate strategies would facilitate the design of effective policies to respect the obligations for sustainable development, ensuring the supply of electricity at a reasonable cost and with the environment in mind. The thesis provided an assessment of the socio-economic implications of investing in a new NPP in Poland. In order to evaluate the project the CBA methodology was adopted as this seemed best suited to answer the main research question.

After the introduction, the situation of the energy sector, especially in Poland, and nuclear power energy generation were discussed. It allowed to give the readers a broad idea about these aspects to better understand why the NPP project had been proposed by the Polish government. The next chapter gave theoretical background about CBA concentrating on the crucial aspects used further on in this paper. The fourth chapter dealt with the CBA assessment. In the following order, project was described, then scope was delimitated, costs and benefits identified and monetized, NPV was calculated and sensivity analysis performed, finished with the recommendation.

Six costs and three benefits were identified as being the measurable factors influencing the Polish society after implementation of the NPP programme. The major costs were those pertaining to investments, operation and maintenance, fuel, waste and decommissiong. However, there were also non-financial risks, excluded from the analysis, like terrorism, equipment failures or leakage. They might cause lower outputs, outages and increased costs because of additional repairs and maintenance. The three benefits identified were avoided emissions of air pollutants, security benefit and employment creation. There were also found non-financial advantages. It must be underlined that nuclear energy would allow Poland to internalize external costs (CO2 emission allowances, health, etc.) and save resources of organic fossil fuels for the future generation. Other benefits of investing in nuclear power would allow the 57

economic recovery of some regions and the possibility to boost the domestic industry. Furthermore, it would give spark to research and innovation and thus education and new jobs.

For the purpose of the analysis, the social time preference rate was evaluated for Poland as well as the shadow price of capital. Costs were converted using the levelised cost methodology. The calculations suggested that in the most cases, the project would be feasible and Poland should invest in the NPP. Only in the worst case scenario with the CO2 emission price as low as 15 /tCO2, it would be better to build the coal-fuel power plant. However, at the price level of 33 /tCO2, the NPP started to increase the welfare of the Polish society. Moreover, only very drastic changes in the assumed costs and benefits in the base case are likely to make the project infeasible.

However, it must be mentioned that Zehner (2012) underlines that one clear welfare impact cannot be assessed and wonders why governments want to spend money on nuclear energy to avoid a single ton of CO2 when the same amount could be spent elsewhere to mitigate five tons, or even more, without the risks. He finds that there is no simple answer, there are too many pros and cons. He stresses that those in favour of nuclear power should not underestimate its inescapable hazards and those against it should not underestimate its inevitable advantages. It must be noted that some other aspects were not considered in the thesis at all. As NEA (2009) points out, there might be invented some new energy production technology, especially with growing interest in nanotechnology and biotechnology. Consequently, because NPPs are long-run investments they would become less viable. On the other hand, due to learning and technology development costs of NPP might decrease and thus improve the profitability of NPPs. Some new ways for energy conversion, storage and production might be developed. Furthermore, there are electricity market uncertainties, political and regulatory aspects (energy markets are dependent on global national policy), public attitude (opposition often causes delays in construction and thus higher costs), the risk of fuel scarcity (as a consequence of embargos, political problems, transportation delays, etc.).

To sum up, surely the development of nuclear energy would be the biggest enterprise in the history of the Polish energy market and the entire post-war economy. It would, 58

however, have repercussions not only on the Polish society, but on other countries as well. The NPP would be most probably built as the government took the project very seriously, even if not finished on time within the schedule. Right now, the road to success for Poland is still long and a lot has to be done. To build the NPP, strong and consistent government support is a prerequisite. It is very important to provide legal framework (which has already been done) as well as independent, competent and professional supervision. The quality of the technology, transparency of the whole process of its implementation with reliable information should give rise to acceptance and public support for the NPP at every stage. Cooperation with other countries and relevant organizations is crucial in the Polish case, as the nation has no experience with nuclear power and that might cause delays and cost overruns. The project cannot therefore be properly implemented without support of international bodies who possess knowledge and experience.

59

Bibliography
Boardman, A., Greenberg, D., Vining, A., & Weimer, D. (2006), Cost-Benefit Analysis:

Concepts and Practice, Prentice Hall.

Committee on Climate Change (2011), Costs of low-carbon generation technologies, Manning House, London.

European Commission (2011a), Europes energy position, Annual report 2010, Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg.

European Commission (2010), EU energy trends to 2030, Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg.

European Commission (2008), Guide to Cost Benefit Analysis of Investment Projects, DG Regional Policy, European Commission, Brussels.

European Commission (2011b), Market observatory for energy. Key figures, European Commission, Brussels.

Evans, D. (2005), Social discount rates for the European Union, Journal of Economic Studies Vol. 32 No. 1.

Evans, D. (2008), Social project appraisal and discounting for the very long term, Economic Issues, Vol. 13, Part 1.

HM Treasury (2003), The Green Book: Appraisal and evaluation in Central

Government, HM Treasury, London.

Hubbert N. K. (2006), Nuclear Energy and The Fossil Fuels, Energy Bulletin, Available: http://www.energybulletin.net [11.09.2012].

60

IEA (2011), Energy Policies of IEA Countries: Poland, OECD, Paris.

IEA (2010), Power generation from coal, OECD, Paris.

IEA (2005), Projected Costs of Generating Electricity, OECD, Paris.

Kaplan, S. (2008), Power Plants: Characteristics and Costs, Congressional Research Service, Washington DC.

Kennedy, D. (2007), New nuclear power generation in the UK: Cost benefit analysis, Department of Trade and Industry, Her Majestys Government, London. Energy Policy 35: 3701-3716.

Lester, R. K., Rosner, R. (2009), The growth of nuclear power: drivers & constraints, Ddalus, No. 4: 19-30.

Ministerstwo Gospodarki (2009), Polityka Energetyczna Polski do 2030 roku, Ministerstwo Gospodarki, Warszawa.

NEA (2009), The Financing of Nuclear Plants, OECD, Paris.

NEA (2011), Carbon Pricing, Power Markets and the Competitiveness of Nuclear

Power, OECD, Paris.


Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010), Program Polskiej

Energetyki Jdrowej, Ministerstwo Gospodarki, Warszawa.

Pernick R., Wilder C., Winnie T. (2012), Clean Energy Trends, Clean Edge, Available: http://www.cleanedge.com/reports/clean-energy-trends-2012 [11.09.2012]

Rosenkranz, G. (2006), Nuclear Power Myth and Realisty, Nuclear Issues Paper No. 1.

Strupczewski A. (2012), Morski wiatr kontra atom, Ecoatom Nr 4/1 luty-marzec 2012.

61

Strupczewski A. (2010), Nie bjmy si atomu!, Stowarzyszenie Ekologw na Rzecz Energii Nuklearnej SEREN, Warszawa.

Strupczewski A. (2005), Safety of nuclear power, NUKLEONIKA 2005;50 (Supplement 3): 59-66.

Thomas, S. (2005), The Economics of Nuclear Power, Nuclear Issues Paper No. 5.

WNA (2005), The New Economics of Nuclear Power, WNA, London.

Zehner, O. (2012), Nuclear Powers Unsettled Future, World Future Society, Betsheda.

Web-references
Areva. Available: http://www.areva.com [8/11/2012].

Elektrownia jdrowa. Available: http://www.elektrownia-jdrowa.pl [2012, 20/10/2012].

Elektrownie atomowe. Available: http://atomowe.pl [2012, 1/11/2012].

Energetyka jdrowa. Available: http://www.atom.edu.pl [2012, 11/11/2012].

European

Commission,

Energy.

Available:

http://ec.europa.eu/energy

[2012,

15/11/2012].

International 11/11/2012].

Atomic

Energy

Agency.

Available:

http://www.iaea.org

[2012,

International Energy Agency. Available: http://www.iea.org [2012, 20/11/2012].

Gwny Urzd Statystyczny. Available: http://www.stat.gov.pl [2012, 23/09/2012]. Grnictwo Wglowe. Available: http://gornictwo.wnp.pl [2012, 10/10/2012].

62

Ministry of Economy of Poland. Available: http://www.mg.gov.pl [2012, 30/10/2012].

wiadomie o atomie. Available: http://www.swiadomieoatomie.pl [2012, 12/11/2012].

World

Nuclear

Association.

Available:

http://www.world-nuclear.org

[2012,

12/11/2012].

World Coal Association. Available: http://www.worldcoal.org [2012, 10/10/2012].

The Ux Consulting Company. Available: http://www.uxc.com [2012, 5/10/2012].

63

Appendixes
Appendix 1. Potential locations of the nuclear power plant in Poland

Appendix 2. Real fixed gross capital formation in Poland in 1995-2010

Appendix 3. Projected expenditure on nuclear power plant programme in Poland in 2011-2020

Appendix 4. Consumption in Poland in 2000-2010

64

Appendix 1. Potential locations of the nuclear power plant in Poland

Source: Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010).

Appendix 2. Real fixed gross capital formation in Poland in 1995-2010 Gross fixed capital formation share of private sector in GDP (%)
9.7 10.9 13.8 15.7 16.2 17.3 14.5 13.2 13.0 13.0 13.1 13.8 15.4 15.2 13.5

Year
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

13.9

Average

Source: Own elaboration based on data from the GUS.

Appendix 3. Projected expenditure on nuclear power plant programme in Poland in 2011-2020 Expenditure (thousands zl) Objective 2011
Functioning of NAEA Legislative analyses Atomic Programme analyses Human resources education Information campaign Preparation of PAA for atomic surveillance NPP location analyses Nuclear waste management plant location analyses Streamlining R & D sector Searching for uranium ore sources in Poland Streamlining the Polish industry Expenditure on memberships in international organizations 600 200

2012
8 200 500 200

2013
9 100 400 100

2014
9 200 400 200

Until 2020
85 000 5 000 2 000

9 000 8 000 2 580 12 000

9 300 8 000 5 860 12 000

9 300 6 000 9 460 -

8 300 5 000 12 710 -

50 000 50 000 175 700 48 000

5 000

28 000

22 000

25 000

260 000

8 000

20 000

20 000

20 000

160 000

10 000

200

200

400

300

4 000

1 000

1 000

1 000

1 000

10 000

TOTAL

46 580

93 260

77 760

82 110

859 700

Source: Own elaboration based on Penomocnik Rzdu ds. Polskiej Energetyki Jdrowej (2010).

Appendix 4. Consumption in Poland in 2000-2010 Nominal Real Consumption increase in increase in Consumption Population per capita consumption consumption (mln zlotych) (thousands) (mln zlotych) per per capita capita (%) (%)
607 206 646 210 685 992 707 815 760 730 801 145 856 020 922 899 1 021 218 1 068 789 1 136 030 38254.0 38242.2 38218.5 38190.6 38173.8 38157.1 38125.5 38115.6 38135.9 38167.3 38200.0 15873.01 16897.82 17949.21 18533.75 19928.07 20995.96 22452.69 24213.16 26778.39 28002.74 29739.01

Year

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

6.5 6.2 3.3 7.5 5.4 6.9 7.8 10.6 4.8 6.2

1.0 4.3 2.5 4.0 3.3 5.9 5.3 6.4 1.1 3.6

Average

3.7

Source: Own elaboration based on data from the GUS.

You might also like