Productivity Concepts and Measurement: A Literature Review
Productivity Concepts and Measurement: A Literature Review
A LITERATURE REVIEW
2.1 Introduction
This chapter presents a review of the literature on the basic productivity concepts;
industry of Singapore.
Based on this literature review, the chapter attempts to answer the questions: (1) what
productivity performance? and (2) what is the most appropriate method to measure
There exists a lot of productivity concepts and measures. Different measures serve
defined in Section 2.2. Section 2.3 discusses the significance of productivity. Section
2.4 provides a historical view of the development and definition of basic productivity
concepts. Partial productivity and total factor productivity are discussed, respectively,
in this section. Section 2.5 reviews the existing productivity concepts and
19
performance. Section 2.7 provides answers to what is an appropriate method to
measure TFP growth in the construction industry through a comparison between the
Chau’s method and the Jorgenson’s method. Section 2.8 reviews the existing
construction industry of Singapore. Section 2.9 highlights the current need for having
Broadly defined, productivity is the relationship between output produced and one or
more of associated inputs used in the production process (National Research Council,
1979). The divergence in opinion among researchers centers on the choice of concept
for a specific measurement purpose, and how to measure output and inputs. In essence,
Productivity can be evaluated with respect to level or growth rate. A high productivity
level represents good use of resources and high returns. High growth rates indicate a
dynamic and growing economy or industry with great potential. Hence, nations or their
individual industry, no matter the forerunner with high productivity or the fall-behinds,
20
At the national level, productivity drives economic growth and development, and
indicates potential for improved material standards and increase in the society’s
general welfare as well as more leisure time for the inhabitants. The construction
industry can provide impetus for economic growth owing to its size and particular
wages for construction workers, and expanded profits for contractors and building
owners, which in turn leads to increase in investment, more working opportunity and,
productivity over time, should be systematically built on and derived from production
Gollop, 1985). When output and inputs have been measured in constant prices over
time, ratios of real output to individual real input can be calculated to obtain single
productivity measures; and ratios of real output to all associated real inputs can be
calculated to obtain a MFP or TFP. One should be aware that in most previous
21
productivity studies, no distinction is made between the use of terms MFP and TFP1.
However, this study will strictly classify the situations under which each of them
Single productivity measures are useful in showing the savings that have been
achieved over time in the use of each input per unit of output. Their changes however
reflect not only changes in productive efficiency but also factor substitutions that result
from changes in relative factor prices. In contrast, TFP has been widely accepted as a
labour input used. Since labour is only one of the factor inputs, changes in labour
intermediate productivity, which measure the relationship between output and capital
input and the relationship between output and intermediate input, respectively. Among
the three single productivity concepts, the most widely used measure is labour
1
The output-labour-capital-materials productivity is known as “MFP” in UK (Oulton, 1994). In
USA, it was known as “TFP” (Jorgenson, 1987). In HK, it is known as “TFP” (Chau, 1988;
1993). In Singapore, value-added labour capital productivity is known as “MFP” by DOS
(1997), by SPRING as “TFP”. In HK, it was known as “VATFP” (Chau, 1993).
22
As different levels of the study are associated with different kinds of production
At the economy level, as the objective for production is to satisfy human wants
through deliveries to end users, the proper measure of output is final demand or
aggregate value-added, and the primary inputs are labour and capital. Intermediate
V = f ( L, K , T ) (2-1)
Hence, at the economy level, labour productivity is the ratio of V to L, which is usually
indexes, indexes are obtained as the difference between the level of productivity at
The objective of individual industry is different from that of the entire economy.
23
sectors satisfy human wants through the production of gross output. Therefore, at the
industry level, the proper measure of the industry’s output is its total production, the
sum of its deliveries to intermediate and final demands (Gollop, 1985). Consequently,
the volume of output (Q) is a function of the volume of services of the basic factors of
production, labour (L) and capital (K), of the intermediate goods and services
purchased from other industry (X), and of the level of productive efficiency, which
Q = f ( L, K , X , t ) (2-2)
Based on the production function, labour productivity can be defined as Q/L, the ratio
of the ratio of output produced to labour input used. Similarly, capital productivity can
be defined as Q/K, the ratio output produced to capital input used. It should be noted
that at the macro-economy level, value-added is the proper measure for output; while
at the industry level, gross output is the proper measure for output. However, in
indexes are computed as the difference between the level of productivity at time T and
T-1.
The development of measures of MFP has lagged behind that of labour productivity.
The increasing capital intensity in the 1950s forced economists to restructure their
24
(National Research Council, 1979). The development of national economic accounting
systems and production function theory in the 1950s has made the empirical analysis
Early estimates of MFP were conducted by Jan Tinbergan in 1942 and by George
Stigler in 1947, and Barton and Cooper in 1948. The basic concept of MFP underlying
Q
MFP = (2-3)
aL + bK
In this formulation, Q is the real product of the industry; L is labour input, measured as
stocks in the various industry; and a and b are the percentage shares of labour and
capital in the factor income generated in the industry. However, this concept was
development, education and training are not included with the tangible factor inputs
At the same time, MFP was being measured within the framework of an economic
accounts framework. Solow (1957) initiated the estimation of MFP using the Cobb-
Q = TLα K β (2-4)
25
In this formulation, the exponents α and β is the elasticity of output with respect to
labour and capital input or, when index numbers are used, the income shares of factors.
In time series analysis, the scalar T measures the change in MFP over time. The rate of
change in T is the difference between the rates of change in output and the weighted
∆T ∆Q ∆L ∆K
= −α −β (2-5)
T Q L K
MFP is the residual part of the rate of growth of output which cannot be accounted by
Following Solow’s work, there has been considerable further development of the
assumes neutral technological change, Jorgenson and his associates (1987) use a
TFP by assuming “biased technological change”. The advantage of using the translog
production function is that it allows the researchers to estimate TFP growth without
having to estimate the parameters of the production function. Under constant returns to
scale and producer equilibrium, the average rate of productivity growth can be
expressed as the difference between the growth rate of output and the weighted
average growth rate of intermediate, capital and labour inputs. Biased technological
change means that the value-shares of the factors in total output may be changing over
time, which is more realistic than Cobb-Douglas formulation which assumes constant
value-shares of the factors in total output (i.e. neutral technological change). Moreover,
unlike Cobb-Douglas method which considers only capital and labour inputs,
26
Jorgenson’s method measures industry-level productivity growth in a more accurate
As stated before, the conceptual framework for productivity growth can be derived
economy level, the relevant production function for the macro-economy is:
V = f ( L, K , T ) (2-6)
Because aggregate productivity is concerned with how well the economy transforms
inputs into output, the rate of productivity growth can be defined as the rate of growth
of value-added with respect to time, holding labour input and capital input constant.
Here, the term MFP is used to represent the aggregate productivity growth of the
economy level. By taking the total logarithmic derivative of Equation (2-6) with
respect to time:
d ln V ∂ ln f ∂ ln V d ln L ∂ ln V d ln K
= + ⋅ + ⋅ (2-7)
dT ∂T ∂ ln L dT ∂ ln K dT
∂ ln f
where, ∆ ln MFP =
∂T
p L L ∂ ln V
vL = =
qV V ∂ ln L
27
p K K ∂ ln V
vK = = (2-8)
qV V ∂ ln K
and
pL L pK K
+ =1 (2-9)
qV V qV V
∂ ln f d ln V ∂ ln V d ln L ∂ ln V d ln K
∆ ln MFP = = − ⋅ − ⋅ (2-10)
∂T dT ∂ ln L dT ∂ ln K dT
Consider the data at any two discrete points of time, say t and t-1, the growth rate of
MFP can be expressed as the growth rate of value-added minus weighted average
− −
∆ ln MFP = [ln Vt − ln Vt −1 ] − v L [ln Lt − ln Lt −1 ] − v K [ln K t − ln K t −1 ] (2-11)
At the industry level, two different TFP concepts have been used. One is MFP (some
researchers like to call it TFP, but essentially it is MFP), which relates to value-added
production function and takes account of labour and capital inputs in its measurement.
Another is TFP, which relates to gross output production function and incorporates
28
At the industry level, the methodology currently employed to measure MFP is
basically similar to the one used at the economy level. The format is the same as
equation 2-11, except that each term is accordance with an industry scale instead of
Similarly, the microeconomic theory of production provides the basis for measurement
of productivity growth at the industry level. The proper measure of productivity can
Q = f ( L, K , X , t ) (2-12)
where, Q is gross output, L, K and X are labour and capital and intermediate inputs,
and t is time.
Again, as industrial productivity is concerned with how efficiently inputs are converted
into outputs, the rate of productivity growth can be defined as the rate of growth of
output with respect to time, holding labour, capital and intermediate inputs constant.
At the industry level, the term TFP is used to represent productivity growth. By taking
d ln Q ∂ ln f ∂ ln Q d ln L ∂ ln Q d ln K ∂ ln Q d ln X
= + ⋅ + ⋅ + ⋅ (2-13)
dT ∂T ∂ ln L dT ∂ ln K dT ∂ ln X dT
∂ ln f
where, ∆ ln TFP =
∂T
p L L ∂ ln Q
vL = =
qQ ∂ ln L
29
p K K ∂ ln Q
vK = =
qQ ∂ ln K
p X X ∂ ln Q
vX = = (2-14)
qQ ∂ ln K
and
pL L pK K p X X
+ + =1 (2-15)
qQ qQ qQ
where q, p L , p K , and p X denote the prices of output, labour, capital and intermediate
inputs, respectively.
∂ ln f d ln Q ∂ ln Q d ln L ∂ ln Q d ln K ∂ ln Q d ln X
∆ ln TFP = = − ⋅ − ⋅ − ⋅ (2-16)
∂T dT ∂ ln L dT ∂ ln K dT ∂ ln X dT
Consider the data at any two discrete points of time, say t and t-1, the growth rate of
TFP can be expressed as the growth rate of gross output minus weighted average
− − −
∆ ln TFP = [ln Vt − ln Vt −1 ] − v L [ln Lt − ln Lt −1 ] − v K [ln K t − ln K t −1 ] − v X [ln X t − ln X t −1 ]
(2-17)
30
and TFP. Again, situations at the economy level and industry level are discussed
2.4.3.1 Relationship between single productivity and MFP at the economy level
V f ( L, K , T )
= (2-18)
L L
Taking the total logarithmic derivative of Equation 2-18 with respect to T, one obtains:
V
d ln
L = ∂ ln f + ∂ ln V ⋅ d ln L + ∂ ln V ⋅ d ln K − d ln L (2-19)
dT ∂T ∂ ln L dT ∂ ln K dT dT
V
d ln
L is labour productivity growth (LP growth) and ∂ ln f
where, is the rate of
dT ∂T
p L L ∂ ln V
vL = =
qV V ∂ ln L
p K K ∂ ln V
vK = =
qV V ∂ ln K
and
pL L pK K
+ =1
qV V qV V
31
where, qV is the price associated with aggregate value-added, p L and p K and
− K K
ln LP (T ) − ln LP (T − 1) = [ln MFP(T ) − ln MFP(T − 1)] + v K [ln (T ) − ln (T − 1)]
L L
(2-20)
At any two discrete points of time, say T and T-1, the growth rate of labour
productivity can be expressed as the growth rate of MFP plus the weighted average of
the growth rate of capital intensity K/L. Similarly, capital productivity growth can be
expressed as the growth rate of MFP plus weighted average of the growth rate of L/K.
− L L
ln KP (T ) − ln KP (T − 1) = [ln MFP(T ) − ln MFP(T − 1)] + v L [ln (T ) − ln (T − 1)]
K K
(2-21)
From Equation 2-20, labour productivity growth is attributed to two factors-- MFP
growth and growth of capital intensity. Labour productivity may rise as long as capital
intensity K/L rise, although technological change (MFP growth) declines. One way of
enhancing labour productivity is through substitution of capital for labour (rise K/L) in
the production process. However, labour productivity growth will not be driven so
much by higher capital intensity K/L because of the limit to which capital investments
can increase before diminishing returns set in. A great deal of historical evidence
suggests that labour productivity have depended primarily on the level of investment
32
rather than on the rate of rise of TFP in Singapore during the last twenty decades.
However, labour productivity growth will not be driven so much by higher capital
intensity K/L because of the limit to which capital investments can increase before
diminishing returns set in. As the capital-labour ratio rises, returns to new investment
will tend to decline (Radelet, Sachs and Lee, 1997). Thus, it can be concluded that at
economy over time (i.e. qualitative improvements that allow output to increase without
any use of additional inputs), is a more fundamental productivity concept than single
productivity.
2.4.3.2 Relationship between single productivity and TFP at the industry level
Q f ( L, K , X , T )
= (2-22)
L L
Taking the total logarithmic derivative of Equation 2-22 with respect to T, one obtains:
Q
d ln
L = ∂ ln f + ∂ ln Q ⋅ d ln L + ∂ ln Q ⋅ d ln K + ∂ ln Q ⋅ d ln X − d ln L (2-23)
dT ∂T ∂ ln L dT ∂ ln K dT ∂ ln X dT dT
Q
d ln
L is labour productivity growth (LP growth) and ∂ ln f
where, is the rate of
dT ∂T
p L L ∂ ln Q
vL = =
qQ Q ∂ ln L
33
p K K ∂ ln Q
vK = =
qQ Q ∂ ln K
p X X ∂ ln Q
vX = =
qQ Q ∂ ln X
and
pL L pK K p X X
+ + =1.
qQ Q qQ Q qQ Q
− K K
ln LP(T ) − ln LP(T − 1) = [ln TFP(T ) − ln TFP(T − 1)] + v K [ln (T) − ln (T − 1)]
L L
− X X
+ v X [ln (T) − ln (T − 1)]
L L
(2-24)
At any two discrete points of time, say T and T-1, the growth rate of labour
productivity can be expressed as the growth rate of TFP plus the weighted average of
the growth rate of capital intensity K/L and intermediate intensity X/L.
Similarly, capital productivity growth can be expressed as the growth rate of TFP plus
− L L
ln KP (T ) − ln KP (T − 1) = [ln TFP (T ) − ln TFP (T − 1)] + v L [ln (T ) − ln (T − 1)]
K K
− X X
+ v X [ln (T ) − ln (T − 1)]
K K
(2-25)
34
From Equation 2-23, labour productivity growth is attributed to three factors-- TFP
growth and growth of capital intensity and intermediate intensity. Again, it can be
concluded that at the industry level, TFP, which represents technological change over
time in the specific industry, is a more fundamental productivity concept than single
productivity.
2.4.3.3 Relationship between MFP growth at the aggregate economy level and
sectoral TFP growth
The rate of aggregate productivity growth for the economy as a whole can be
decomposed into a weighted sum of sectoral productivity growth and weighted sums
of rates of growth of value-added, capital input, and labor input, reflecting the
Jorgenson (1987), the weighted sum of sectoral productivity growth is the most
−
− wj − j −
vT = ∑ ⋅ v T + [ln V(T) − ln V(T − 1) − ∑ w j [ln Vj (T) − ln Vj (T − 1)
− j
vV
− j
− vK − j − −
+∑wj ⋅ ∑ v Kk [ln K kj (T) − ln K kj (T − 1)] − v K ⋅ ∑ v Kk [ln K k (T) − ln K k (T − 1)]
− j
vV
− j
− vL − j − −
+ ∑wj ⋅ ∑ v Ll [ln L lj (T) − ln L lj (T − 1)] − v L ⋅ ∑ v Ll [ln L l (T) − ln L l (T − 1)]
− j
vV
(2-26)
35
where,
−
v T -----aggregate rate of productivity growth, i.e. MFP growth at the economy level;
−
w j -----average ratio of value-added in the jth sector to value-added in all sectors;
− 1
w j = [ w j (T ) + w j (T − 1)];
2
p Vj Vj
wj = ;
∑ p Vj Vj
− j
v V ----average value share of value-added in output of the jth sector;
− j
v T ----average TFP growth of jth sector;
− j
v K ---- average value share of capital in output of the jth sector;
− j
v Kk ----average value share of kth type of capital of the jth sector in the total capital of
−
v K ----average of value share of total capital in total output for all sector;
−
∑ v Kk ----average value share of kth type of capital for all sector in the total capital for
all sector;
− j
v L ---- average value share of labour input in output of the jth sector;
− j
v Ll ----average value share of lth type of labour inpur of the jth sector in the total
36
L lj ----quantity of lth type labour input in the jth sector;
−
v L ----average of value share of total labour input in total output for all sector;
−
∑ v Ll ----average value share of lth type of labour input for all sector in the total labour
In the construction industry, productivity can be measured at three levels, that is,
site/project, firm and industry. Productivity concepts that have been adopted in the
construction industry include labour productivity, multi factor productivity (MFP) and
project and most of them relate to the measurement of labour productivity. Shaddad
and Pilcher (1984) developed a causal research model at the project or site level. The
view was widely held that factors at the head office and site level are the main
involved in any project, and the interfaces among them, this view is not necessarily
productivity at a higher level (Horner et al., 1987). Kellogg et al. (1981) proposed a
hierarchical model for the study of construction industry productivity, which is too
conceptual to be of immediate use for an empirical study. Due to the complexity of the
measurement method and lack of data required (Hillebrandt, 1984), only a few
37
empirical research studies at the industry-level have been undertaken and even then,
measurement method.
• The fact that construction work done by establishments not classified as being
• Price effect of business cycles will artificially affect data on output and inputs.
The deflators used to obtain real output data are mainly developed from indices
productivity.
38
Until 1980s, empirical research at the industry level has captured extensive attention as
the productivity slowdown in the construction industry plagued almost every country
after the 1973 oil crisis. In the UK, research was led by Hillebrandt (1984) and NEDO
(1989). In the US, series work included Solow (1957), Dacy (1965), Koch and
Maovenzadeh (1979), Stokes (1981), the Business Roundtable (1982), Schriver and
Bowley (1985), Allen (1985), and the Building Research Board (1986). However,
The increasing capital intensity has forced economists to restructure their measurement
of productivity growth to incorporate both labour and capital inputs. Using translog
value-added production function and Tornqvist index, the major statistical agencies
Bureau of Statistics) have published MFP indices at both the national and industry
level. In the construction industry, using translog value-added production function and
Tornqvist index, Tan (2000) estimated the index of MFP for the Singapore
construction industry.
While MFP, in general, takes into account two factors, a few studies in the
construction industry incorporated all the three factor inputs---labour, capital and
problems in the construction industry they tended to use indirect ways. Koch and
Maovenzaden (1979) estimated TFP and technology change in the highway sector of
the construction industry in the United States through its components, i.e. the
productivities of labour, capital and materials. Chau and Walker’s approaches (1988;
and 1993) are to measure TFP indirectly from construction cost and price data. By
39
defining TFP as the ratio of quantity of output to quantity of aggregate input calculated
constant to return, Chau and Walkers represented TFP growth as the sum of weighted
change in the price of factor inputs: labour, capital and materials, minus the change in
productivity concepts are adopted (Wolff, 1981). The purpose of this section is to
productivity concepts (labour productivity, MFP and TFP), which is the better
already begun earlier in 1980s within the framework of macro economic productivity
studies. Bronfenbrenner (1985) argues that when two or more distinct inputs worked
on the productivity of one input while neglecting the others. Gollop (1985) believes
that the appropriate productivity measurement should follow directly from economic
principles, i.e., the well-defined indexes of productivity growth must measure how
well the economy allocates and the industries use all scarce resources. The notion of
scarcity is no more appropriate to any one primary input than another. The
40
characteristics of sector productivity growth differ importantly from its aggregate
individual sectors satisfy human wants through the production of gross output. He
argued that the proper measures of sectoral productivity must be evaluated in the
context of total-factor productivity. All labour, capital and material inputs are equally
primary to sectoral producers. Jorgenson (1987) further tested that the value-added
function must exist in the economy as a whole, but there is no existence of a value-
the sectoral level. Instead, he uses a translog production function which treats labour,
In the construction industry, many researchers have recognized the limits of labour
productivity and the need to consider total factor productivity (Lowe, 1987;
Rapporteur, 1987; Chau, 1993). Rapporteur (1987) disputed that change in the value of
changes in labour efficiency when, in fact, some other factors such as mechanization,
prefabrication, and change in demand may well have influenced the equation. He
suggests that researchers ought to be concerned with the total process of conversion of
raw materials to finally positioned components in buildings. Chau (1993) argued that
the contribution of new materials that are of better quality and easier to handle with to
Based on the literature review, one can conclude that the appropriate production
function for the construction industry should take gross output as a function of
41
intermediate, capital and labour inputs and time and thus TFP is the appropriate
construction.
In the construction industry, the existing TFP measure is Chau and Walker’s
approaches (1988; and 1993), which measure TFP indirectly from construction cost
and price data. In macroeconomics, the best-known TFP measure is that of Jorgenson
(1987). Therefore, these two approaches will be presented separately in the following
sections. To answer the question of which is the more appropriate method to measure
TFP growth, a critique of Chau’s approach (1988; and 1993) is conducted to draw
some conclusions.
Q0
T= (2-27)
g (QI1 , QI 2 ,..., QI n )
Under the assumption of Hicks Neutral Technical change and constant returns to scale
and using the Divisia index, TFP growth can be expressed as:
42
n −
∆ (ln T ) t = ∑ s it ∆(ln PIi ) t − ∆(ln PO ) t (2-28)
i =1
where, the ∆ sign denotes the difference in the value of the corresponding variable
between two successive periods and the bar sign denotes the average of the same two
successive periods, Po is the price of output and the PIi the price of ith input.
Thus, Chau (1993) made an empirical estimation of TFP growth in the Hong Kong
building industry by computing the difference between the sum of weighted change in
the prices of factor inputs-- labour, capital and materials, and the change in the price of
output.
Building on the pioneer works of Solow (1957), Denison (1967) and Jorgenson and
Z = F ( X , K , L, T ) (2-29)
43
The rate of productivity growth, called TFP growth, is defined as the rate of growth of
output with respect to time, holding intermediate input, capital input and labour input
constant:
∂ ln Z
vT = ( X , K , L, T ) (2-30)
∂T
Under the condition of constant returns to scale and producer equilibrium, the average
growth rate of TFP can be expressed as the growth rate of output less the sum of
− −
VT = [ln Z (T ) − ln Z (T − 1)] − V X [ln X (T ) − ln X (T − 1)] −
− − (2-31)
V K [ln K (T ) − ln K (T − 1)] − VL [ln L(T ) − ln L (T − 1)]
Where
− 1
V X = [V X (T ) + V X (T − 1)]
2
− 1
VK = [V K (T ) + VK (T − 1)]
2
− 1
VL = [V L (T ) + VL (T − 1)] (2-32)
2
− 1
VT = [VT (T ) + VT (T − 1)]
2
p X p K pL L
VX = X VK = K VL =
qZ qZ qZ
− − −
where, V X , VK , VL represent the respective shares of intermediate, capital and labour
inputs averaged over time T and T-1, while q, px, pk, pL denote the prices of the output
Each input can be defined as a translog function of its individual inputs. Under
constant returns to scale and producer equilibrium, the growth rate of each input can be
44
expressed as a weighted average of growth rates of individual input, with weights
−
ln X (T ) − ln X (T − 1) = ∑ V Xi [ln X i (T ) − ln X i (T − 1)] (2-33)
−
ln K (T ) − ln K (T − 1) = ∑ V Kj [ln K j (T ) − ln K j (T − 1)] (2-34)
−
ln L(T ) − ln L(T − 1) = ∑ V Li [ln Li (T ) − ln Li (T − 1)] (2-35)
Due to limited data available, physical measurement of inputs and outputs is not
possible in HK (Chau, 1988). Chau then modified the method of measuring TFP to suit
the HK’s case: that is to measure TFP growth of HK’s building industry indirectly
through construction cost and price data using Hicks neutral Technology change. This
as follows.
Firstly, Chau’s method is only used for estimating TFP growth for building industry
(Chau, 1988 and 1993). It is not suitable for measuring TFP growth for the
construction industry as a whole. It is because the output price index (OPI) developed
by Chua (1990) is a price index for building work only and it should not be used as a
g(QI1, QI2, …, QIn), in which aggregate input depends on the intermediate, capital
and labour inputs and is independent of the level of technology T. An aggregate input
45
is equivalent to the assumption of Hicks Neutrality of technology change (Jorgenson et
al., 1987). According to Chau (1993), under Hicks neutrality assumption, input
and labour inputs and depends only on time, or biases of productivity growth are equal
The following sections explains what does it mean that the biased of productivity
Z = exp[α 0 + α X ln X + α K ln K + α L ln L + α T ⋅ T +
1
β XX (ln X ) 2 + β XK ln X ln K + β XL ln X ln L + β XT ln X ⋅ T +
2
1
β KK (ln K ) 2 + β KL ln K ln L + β KT ln K ⋅ T +
2
1 1
β LL (ln L) 2 + β LT ln L ⋅ T + β TT ⋅ T 2
2 2
Under necessary conditions for producer equilibrium imply that the value-shares of
intermediate, capital, and labour inputs are equal to the elasticities of output respect to
these inputs. Similarly, rates of productivity growth are equal to rates of growth of
where
1
ln X = [ln X (T ) + ln X (T − 1)]
2
1
ln K = [ln K (T ) + ln K (T − 1)]
2
46
1
ln L = [ln L(T ) + ln L(T − 1)]
2
1
T = [T + (T − 1)]
2
Under Hicks neutrality, the biases of productivity growth are zero for all three inputs,
neutrality, that is, the hypotheses that β XT = β KT = β LT = 0 and the hypotheses were
rejected. It proves that biases in productivity growth are significant and cannot be
ignored. This made Chau’s method which is based on neutral technology change
defines output as a function of intermediate input, capital input, labour input and time
Change (Jorgenson, 1987) and hence can produce more accurate results than that of
a whole.
From the above reasons, it can be concluded that the appropriate and less restrictive
Unlike the HK case, the data required by Jorgenson’s method (such as quantity of
47
2.8 A review of productivity measures at the economy level and the construction
industry of Singapore
This section starts with the problems associated with construction productivity in
Singapore. Then a literature review of productivity measures at the economy level and
stated. Finally, the importance of having a good measure for productivity of the
associated with the changing patterns of economic growth. In the 1960s and 1970s,
Singapore’s economic growth was mainly driven by labour accumulation. By the late
1970s, labour employment reaches its full capacity while the economy is still booming.
The tight labour market situation made improving productivity more pressing. In 1981,
the government launched the Productivity Movement to propel the economy from the
highlighted as the key strategy to achieve the targeted annual economic growth of 8 to
10%. At the same time, in the 1970s and early 1980s, there was a large capital
only in the medium to long term, the economic growth entered into a capital-driven
pattern only after 1980. As such the government was concerned primarily with
48
In 1995, the Productivity Movement reached an innovation-driven phase. Thus far,
labour productivity has been a major source of economic growth. As the investment-
driven S-curve was nearing the peak in 1995, productivity growth would no longer be
driven so much by higher capital investments because of the limit to which such
investments can increase before diminishing returns set in. Rather, Singapore’s
economic growth would depend very much on making the best use of labour and
capital resource to achieve greater output per unit input, also known as Total Factor
Productivity (TFP)2. Since 1995, TFP has become a very important productivity
and long-term source for economic growth. In the new millennium, the Productivity
Movement emphasizes innovation and value creation in all sectors of the economy and
segments of society.
In Singapore, low productivity in the construction industry has been identified as one
of the main problem areas of the country’s economy (Ofori, 1993). An earlier report by
the CIDB Task Force on Productivity (1992) indicated that compared with the
productivity has been registering a negative productivity growth with levels dropping
more than 13 per-cent. Alerted by this trend, in 1998, the Construction 21 Steering
Committee (1998) was initiated to deal with the problems facing the industry, in
particular, the low level of productivity and the heavy reliance on unskilled foreign
workers.
2
It is essentially MFP, that is value-added labour capital productivity.
49
The causes for this situation include insufficient use of buildable designs especially
involving many small firms, lack of site management and inadequate mechanisation
and automation (Construction 21, 1998; and CIDB Task Force, 1992).
economy. Since labour is in very short supply in Singapore while foreign workers are
quite cheap, it causes the construction industry to rely heavily on foreign workers
(about 80 per-cent of construction labour are foreign workers). This has brought about
a lot of social problems such as crimes and increased accident rates to the construction
industry. With the government policy of controlling the number of foreign workers in
Singapore, the construction industry is facing the pressure to reduce its labour
b) the foreign worker levy to discourage contractor from using foreign workers;
in construction.
50
Another important concern raised by the Construction 21 Committee in 1998 is that
the current state of affairs in the construction industry cannot be sustained. There is a
need for a major transformation of the industry to achieve better resource utilization
productivity. Value-added per worker is the simplest and often used productivity
statistical data for this indicator in Singapore started in 1975. However, “output” here
is measured in monetary value, which may not reflect the quantity of the products.
Moreover, it is difficult to use this indicator to make comparison study with the
construction industry of other countries. Aware of these problems, in 1992 the Task
value-added per worker. The indicator measures the number of mandays on site
required to put up a unit of completed floor area. Publication of data on this alternative
The development of the MFP measure has lagged behind the estimation of labour
51
Singapore published the concept and methodology for the computation of MFP growth
assumptions of constant returns to scale and competitive markets for two factor inputs
(labour and capital), MFP growth is estimated from the difference between the growth
of output and a weighted average of the growth of labour and capital. Following the
release the index of MFP growth in the construction industry of Singapore from 1996.
Meanwhile, using the Tornqvist index approach and assuming a translog value-added
production function, Tan (2000) estimated the MFP growth (value-added two factor
productivity) for the Singapore construction industry between 1980 and 1996. The
equation used for the computation of MFP by Tan (2000) is identical to the one
The current challenge in Singapore construction is that the industry is facing the
dwindling local demand. Construction orders are projected to average between $12
billion and $15 billion per year for the next 10 years. It pushes the industry to upgrade
its capabilities through greater innovation to compete against the more established
foreign construction firms. New innovative products have been developed to enhance
the use of pre-cast products in the industry. Pre-cast technology became one of the
52
prefabrication in productivity improvement. Thus, a more comprehensive measure
which incorporates all of the factors of production (labour, capital and materials
Meanwhile, the current state of affairs in the construction industry of Singapore cannot
achieve better resource utilization and efficiency, and to reduce wastage and social
costs. Thus, a good measure of productivity to evaluate the efficient use of all
results of the empirical study can be greatly affected if different productivity concepts
are applied. The three productivity indicators currently adopted in the construction
industry are misleading as they concentrate on the productivity of one or two factors
and neglect the others. A high measure of productivity from an input (labour) in
producing an output may result from a wasteful overuse of one or more associated
appropriate to treat any one input more primary than the others. Thus, it is important
that a good productivity measure is found to determine how well the industry uses all
Consequently, in order to evaluate, monitor and control the progress made by the
53
2.10 Chapter summary
This chapter has examined the basic productivity concepts including their
Productivity was defined in Sections 2.2 as the relationship between the output
produced and one or more of the associated inputs used in the production process.
Single productivity and TFP were discussed separately in Section 2.4 and each was
dealt with, respectively, at the economy level and industry levels. Also, to avoid the
productivity and MFP at the economy level, as well as single productivity and TFP at
the industry level, MFP at the economy level and TFP at the industry level, were
carried out. The equations suggested that TFP (MFP), which represents growth due to
54
In order to answer what is the appropriate productivity concept to measure
under Section 2.6 from the perspectives of production function theory, as well as
specific context of the construction industry. Combining the two, it can be clearly
What is the appropriate TFP measure method in the construction industry was
discussed in Section 2.7. A critique study of the existing TFP measure in the
construction industry, i.e., Chau’s method was conducted. The advantages of the one
recognized widely in economic academia, i.e. Jorgenson’s method, were pointed out. It
was concluded that Jorgenson’s TFP measure is the appropriate method to measure
method does not impose on the assumption of Hicks Neutral Technological Change,
which is tested unrealistic in the construction industry; (2) Chau’s method only applies
55