MAFS5030 Topic 4 PDF
MAFS5030 Topic 4 PDF
4.3 Quanto options – equity options with exchange rate risk expo-
sure
1
4.1 Continuous dividend yield models
Let q denote the constant continuous dividend yield, that is, the
holder receives dividend of amount equal to qS dt within the in-
finitesimal interval (t, t + dt). The asset price dynamics is assumed
to follow the Geometric Brownian motion
dS
= ρ dt + σ dZ P .
S
−dc + △ dS + q△S dt )
dΠ = (
( )
∂c σ 2 2 ∂ 2c ∂c
= − − S + q△S dt + △ − dS.
∂t 2 ∂S 2 ∂S
2
The last term q△S dt is the wealth added to the portfolio due to
∂c
the dividend payment received. By choosing △ = , we obtain
∂S
a riskless hedge for the portfolio. By no-arbitrage argument, the
hedged portfolio should earn the riskless interest rate.
We then have
( ) ( )
∂c σ2 ∂ 2c
∂c ∂c
dΠ = − − S 2 2 + qS dt = r −c + S dt,
∂t 2 ∂S ∂S ∂S
which leads to
∂c σ 2 2 ∂ 2c ∂c
= S 2
+ (r − q)S − rc, τ = T − t, 0 < S < ∞, τ > 0.
∂τ 2 ∂S ∂S
3
Martingale pricing approach
Sbt = eqtSt,
where eqt represents the growth factor in the number of units. The
wealth process Sbt follows
dSbt P.
= (ρ + q) dt + σ dZ t
Sbt
We would like to find the equivalent risk neutral measure Q under
which the discounted wealth process Sbt∗ is Q-martingale. We choose
γ(t) in the Radon-Nikodym derivative to be
ρ+q−r
γ(t) = .
σ
4
Q
Now Zt is a Q-Brownian motion and
Q P ρ+q−r
dZt = dZt + dt.
σ
Also, Sbt∗ becomes Q-martingale since
dSbt∗ Q
b ∗
= σ dZt .
St
The asset price St under the equivalent risk neutral measure Q be-
comes
dSt Q
= (r − q) dt + σ dZt .
St
Hence, the risk neutral drift rate of St is r − q.
6
Alternatively, knowing that the expected rate of return of St under
Q is δS = r − q, we can deduce that
The new put and call prices satisfy the put-call parity relation
p = c − Se−qτ + Xe−rτ .
That is, the put price formula can be obtained from the correspond-
ing call price formula by interchanging S with X and r with q in the
formula.
8
• Recall that a call option entitles its holder the right to exchange
the riskless asset for the risky asset, and vice versa for a put
option. The dividend yield earned from the risky asset is q while
that from the riskless asset is r.
• If we interchange the roles of the riskless asset and risky asset
in a call option, the call becomes a put option, thus giving the
justification for the put-call symmetry relation.
As a verification, consider
( )
ln X + q−r− σ2 τ
S 2
p(X, τ ; S, q, r) = Se−qτ N
− √
σ τ
( )
ln X + q−r+ σ2 τ
−rτ S 2
− Xe
N − √
σ τ
9
Time dependent parameters
When
∫τ we apply the following transformations: y = ln S and w =
e 0 r(u) duV , then
[ ]
∂w σ 2(τ ) ∂ 2w σ 2(τ ) ∂w
= + r(τ ) − q(τ ) − .
∂τ 2 ∂y 2 2 ∂y
Consider the following form of the fundamental solution
( )
1 [y + e(τ )]2
f (y, τ ) = √ exp − ,
2πs(τ ) 2s(τ )
10
By direct differentiation, it can be shown that f (y, τ ) satisfies the
parabolic equation
∂f 1 ′ ∂ 2f ∂f
= s (τ ) 2 + e′(τ ) .
∂τ 2 ∂y ∂y
Suppose we let
∫ τ
s(τ ) = σ 2(u) du
∫0τ
s(τ )
e(τ ) = [r(u) − q(u)] du −
,
0 2
then f satisfies the same differential equation as that for w(y, τ ).
One can deduce that the fundamental solution is given by
∫τ 2
σ (u)
1 {y + 0 [r(u) − q(u) − ] du}2
ϕ(y, τ ) = √ ∫ exp − ∫τ
2
2
.
τ
2π 0 σ 2(u) du 2 0 σ (u) du
Given the initial condition w(y, 0), the solution can be expressed as
∫ ∞
w(y, τ ) = w(ξ, 0) ϕ(y − ξ, τ ) dξ.
−∞
11
Note that the time dependency of the coefficients r(τ ), q(τ ) and
σ 2(τ ) will not affect the spatial integration with respect to ξ. We
may simply make the following substitutions in the option price
formulas
∫
1 τ
r is replaced by r(u) du
τ ∫0
1 τ
q is replaced by q(u) du
τ 0∫
2 1 τ 2
σ is replaced by σ (u) du.
τ 0
12
4.2 Exchange options
13
Numeraire Invariance Theorem
(∫ t )
With the use of the money market account M (t) = exp rudu
0
as the numeraire (accounting unit), the effect of the time value of
money with respect to normalized asset values becomes immaterial.
Discounted security price St/Mt is a martingale under a risk neutral
measure Q.
N ∫T
It is observed that Nt∗ = = e− 0 ruduNt is an Ft-martingale under
t
Mt
Q since Nt is a traded asset.
dQN NT∗ ∫
− 0T ru du NT
= ∗ =e .
dQ N0 N0
This is equivalent to stating that
∫ ∫ ∫
− 0T ru du NT
X(ω) dQN (ω) = e X(ω) dQ(ω).
Ω Ω N0
For any integrable FT -measurable random variable X, we have
[ ∫T ]
ru du NT
EQN [X] = EQ e− 0 X .
N0
15
From the martingale property of Nt∗, we deduce that
[ ] [ ] ∫T
dQN ∫ Nte− 0 ru du Nt∗
− 0T ru du NT
EQ Ft = EQ e Ft = = ∗.
dQ N0 N0 N0
By the tower rule, for any Ft-measurable random variable G and
integrable random variable X, we obtain
[ ∫T ]
− 0 ru du NT
EQN [GX] = EQ GXe
N0
[ [ ]]
∫
Nt − t ru du ∫ T NT
− r du
= EQ G e 0 EQ Xe t u Ft
N0 Nt
[ [ ] [ ]]
dQN ∫
− t ru du NT
T
= EQ GEQ Ft EQ Xe Ft
dQ Nt
[ [ ]]
dQN ∫
− t ru du NT
T
= EQ G EQ Xe Ft
dQ Nt
[ [ ]]
∫T
− t ru du NT
= EQN GEQ Xe Ft .
Nt
16
By comparing with
C
provided that ∈ L1[QN , FT ].
NT
Let Vt denote the time-t price of the contingent claim, where VT =
C. We then deduce that
[ ]
Vt VT
= EQN Ft
Nt NT
so that the deflated price Vt/Nt is QN -martingale.
17
Remark One motivation of choosing another tradeable security
(discount bond) as the numeraire arises from the pricing of an equity
Mt ∫T
option under stochastic interest rate. Recall = e− t ru du when
MT
the interest rate is stochastic so that
[ ∫T ]
t e−
Vt = EQ t ru du
V (ST ) .
18
Use of the underlying asset as the numeraire (share measure) and
the associated change of measure
Recall that the risk neutral measure uses the money market account
as the numeraire. Let the starting time be time zero for notation-
al convenience. Consider the Radon-Nikodym derivative Lt as a
stochastic process that is defined by taking the ratio of the asset
numeraire and the money market account
/
S
dQ St Mt
Lt = = eqt , t ∈ (0, T ],
dQ F S0 M0
0
19
The inclusion of the factor eqt means one unit of the risky asset
initially grows to eqt units after time t if all dividends are invested
into the purchase of new units of the risky asset.
Let Sbt = eqtSt, then Sbt∗ = Sbt/ert is a martingale under Q. Note that
Sbt is chosen as the numeraire asset instead of St since we require
the discounted numeraire asset is a Q-martingale.
20
Symbolically, we write the Radon-Nikodym derivative as
dQ
S
Lt = , t ∈ (0, T ].
dQ F0
Under the risk neutral measure Q, the dynamics of St is governed
by
dSt Q Q
= (r − q) dt + σ dZt , Zt is Q-Brownian.
St
The solution to St is given by
( 2
)
σ Q
r−q− 2 t+σZt
St = S0e
so that
/
St 2 Q
− σ2 t+σZt
Lt = eqt rt
e =e , t ∈ (0, T ].
S0
21
Recall from p.41, Topic 3 that under the Radon-Nikodym derivative:
dPe 2
− γ2 t−γZtP
=e ,
dP
the Brownian motion with drift defined by ZeP (t) = ZP (t) + γt be-
comes Pe -Brownian. Here, ZP (t) is P -Brownian.
22
As a check, we recall
[ / ]
S
dQ
−rT −rT
V0 = e EQ[VT (ST )|F0] = e EQS VT (ST ) F0
dQ
[ / ]
−rT rT qT
= e EQS VT (ST )e S0 e ST F0
[ ]
VT (ST )
= S0EQS F0 ,
ST e
qT
so that
[ ]
V0 VT (ST )
b
= EQS , where SbT = eqT ST and Sb0 = S0.
S0 SbT
This verifies that Vt/Sbt is QS -martingale.
23
Write QX as the share measure with respect to the asset price
process Xt. We have shown that
QX Q
ZX,t = ZX,t − σX t
is QX -Brownian.
QX Q
How to verify that ZY,t = ZY,t − ρσX t is QX -Brownian?
24
By considering the moment generating function, a random variable
U is normal with mean m and variance σ 2 under QX if and only if
( )
α2
EQX [exp(αU )] = exp αm + σ2 .
2
It suffices to show
( )
QX Q α2
EQX [exp(αZY (T ))] = EQX [exp(αZY (T ) − αρσX T )] = exp T .
2
Recall the Radon-Nikodym derivative, where
( )
dQ X σX2
Q
LT = = exp − T + σX ZX (T ) , so
dQ 2
QX
EQX [exp(αZY (T ))]
[ ( )]
σX2
Q Q
= EQ exp(αZY (T ) − αρσX T ) exp − T + σX ZX (T )
2
( )
2
σX ( )
Q Q
= exp − T − αρσX T EQ[exp αZY (T ) + σX ZX (T ) ]
2
( ) ( ) ( )
2
σX 2
α + 2ρασX + σX 2 α 2
= exp − T − αρσX T exp T = exp T .
2 2 2
25
Derivation of the price formula of an exchange option
Suppose we choose eqX tXt as the numeraire, and MT /M0 = erT , the
corresponding Radon-Nikodym derivative that effects the change
from Q to QX is given by
(qX −r)T XT
LT = e .
X0
The price function of the exchange option with maturity T and initial
asset values X0 and Y0 is given by
QX Q QX Q
dZX,t = dZX,t − σX dt and dZY,t = dZY,t − ρσX dt
27
We may write
dWt QX
= (qX − qY )dt + σW dZW,t ,
Wt
QX
where ZW,t is QX -Brownian.
We retain the nice analytical tractability for Yt/Xt since the ratio of
the two lognormal distributions Xt and Yt remains to be lognormal.
However, the difference Xt − Yt has no nice analytic form of joint
distribution function. This explains why we choose to normalize
the payoff function by XT instead of choosing the apparently more
obvious choice of Wf =X −Y .
T T T
28
The payoff (1 − WT )1{WT <1} resembles a put payoff with unit strike
and underlying Wt. Using the put price formula, we deduce
Y0
EQX [(1 − WT )1{WT <1}] = N (dX ) − W0e(qX −qY )T N (dY ), W0 = ,
X0
where
2
σW 2
σW
X0 X0
ln Y + (qY − qX )T + 2 T ln Y + (qY − qX )T − 2 T
dX = 0 √ , dY = 0 √ .
σW T σW T
Finally, the price function of the exchange option is given by
V (X0 , Y0 ; T ) = e−qX T X0 N (dX ) − e−qY T Y0 N (dY ).
[ 2
]
σW
ln Y0 + (r − qX ) − (r − qY ) + 2 T
X0
−rT (r−qX )T
= e e X0 N √
σW T
[ 2
]
σW
ln X0 + (r − qY ) − (r − qX ) + 2 T
Y0
− e (r−qY )T
Y0 N − √ .
σW T
29
4.3 Quanto option – equity options with exchange rate risk
exposure
30
2. Foreign equity call struck in domestic currency
c3(ST , T ) = F0 max(ST − Xf , 0)
Here, F0 is some predetermined fixed exchange rate.
31
Quanto prewashing techniques
32
• Under the domestic risk neutral measure Qd, the drift rate of S ∗
and F are
d =r −q
δS and d =r −r .
δF
∗ d d f
• The drift rate of S and 1/F under the foreign risk neutral mea-
sure Qf are given by
f f
δ S = rf − q and δ1/F = rf − rd,
respectively. Note that the dividend yield is the same for the
foreign asset in the two-currency world.
33
Quanto-prewashing formula
The extra drift rate ρσF σS arises from the correlated diffusion move-
ments of Ft and St, where dZSd dZFd = ρ dt. We then obtain
d = δ d − δ d − ρσ σ = (r − q) − (r − r ) − ρσ σ = r − q − ρσ σ .
δS S∗ F F S d d f F S f F S
f
d = δ − ρσ σ . It is necessary to add the quanto pre-
We obtain δS S F S
washing term −ρσF σS when we specify the dynamics of St changing
from Qf to Qd.
34
f
d
Siegel’s paradox δ1/F = rf − rd + σF
2 =δ
1/F
+ σ 2
F
36
An interesting application of Siegel’s paradox
37
d f 2 and observing σ = σ
From δ1/F = δ1/F + σF F 1/F , we deduce that
f d + σ2 .
δF = δF F
This result is consistent with the Siegel formula if we interchange
the foreign and domestic currency worlds. We obtain
d f −rf (T −t) −rd τ dτ
δF
V (F, t) = F V (F, t) = e F N (d) = e e F N (d)
where τ = T − t and
( 2 ) ( 2 )
F + f σF F + σF
ln K δF − 2 τ ln K rd − rf + 2 τ
d = √ = √ .
σF τ σF τ
Note that the discount factor is e−rf τ in the foreign currency world
and it becomes e−rdτ in the domestic currency world. Also, observe
that
[ ]
t
EQf 1{F >K} = N (d)
[ ] d
δF
t
EQd F 1{F >K} = e F N (d).
38
Price formulas of various quanto options
39
[ ]
c1(S, F, τ ) = F c1(S, τ ) = F Se−qτ N (d1 ) − Xf e−rf τ N (d2 ) ,
f (1) (1)
where
( 2 )
f σS
ln XS + δS + 2 τ √
(1) f (1) (1)
d1 = √ , d2 = d1 − σS τ ,
σS τ
f
δS = rf − q.
Note that both the correlation risk ρ and exchange rate risk σF do
not appear in the price formula! This is reasonable since we allow
the exchange rate to float and do not set the exchange rate to some
fixed value F0.
40
2. Foreign equity call struck in domestic currency
The terminal payoff in domestic currency is
where
( )
∗ 2
σS
S d + ∗
ln X + δS ∗ τ
(2) d 2
(2) (2) √
d1 = √ , d2 = d1 − σS ∗ τ .
σS ∗ τ
Note that rf does not appear since we perform valuation in the
domestic currency world and no foreign-denominated asset is
involved. However, ρ and σF are involved since the volatility of
S ∗ comes into play.
41
3. Fixed exchange rate foreign equity call
The terminal payoff is denominated in the domestic currency
d of the foreign asset in Q should
world, so the drift rate δS d
be used. The price function of the fixed exchange rate foreign
equity call is given by
[ ]
c3(S, τ ) = F0e−rdτ
dτ
δS (3) (3)
Se N (d ) 1 − Xf N (d2 ) ,
where
( 2 )
σS
ln XS + d
δS + 2 τ √
(3) f (3) (3)
d1 = √ , d2 = d1 − σS τ .
σS τ
• The price formula does not depend on the exchange rate F since
the exchange rate has been chosen to be the fixed value F0.
• The currency exposure of the call is embedded in the quanto-
prewashing term −ρσS σF in δSd . This call option has exposure to
both correlation risk and exchange rate risk (in terms of ρ and
σF , respectively).
42
4. Equity-linked foreign exchange call
Write the terminal payoff in the form of an exchange option
where
( 2 )
F + σF
ln X rd − rf + ρσF σS + 2 τ √
(4) (4) (4)
d1 = √ , d2 = d1 − σF τ .
σF τ
43
Digital quanto option relating 3 currency worlds
Example 1
Digital quanto option payoff: pay one HKD if FS\U is above some
strike level K.
dFS\U
= (rSGD − rU SD ) dt + σFS\U dZFS .
FS\U S\U
44
S
Given δF = rSGD − rU SD , how to find δF
H , the risk neutral drift
S\U S\U
rate of the SGD asset denominated in Hong Kong dollar?
where
2
FS\U σF
ln K + δF
H − 2
S\U
τ
S\U
d= √ .
σFS\U τ
45
Example 2
The quanto option pays FH\S Hong Kong dollars when FS\U > K.
This is equivalent to pay one Singaporean dollar. Value of the
quanto option in Singaporean dollar is
[ ]
e−rSGD τ EQ
t
S 1{FS\U >K} = e−rSGD τ N (d)
b
where
2
FS\U σF
ln K + δF
S − 2
S\U τ
S\U
db = √ , S
δF = rSGD − rU SD .
σFS\U τ S\U
The quanto option pays FH\U Hong Kong dollars when FS\U > K.
This is equivalent to pay one US dollars.
where
2
FS\U σF
ln K + rSGD − rU SD + S\U
2 τ
d1 = √ .
σFS\U τ
The quanto option pays one US dollars when FS\U > K ⇔ K 1 >
1 =F
FS\U U \S . Later, we multiply the option value in US currency by
the exchange rate FH\U to convert into Hong Kong dollars.
FH\U e−rU SD τ EQ
t 1{
U
} = F
H\U e−rU DS τ N (−d ),
2
<1
FU \S K
where
2
F σF
U \S U \S
ln 1/K + rU SD − rSGD − 2 τ
d2 = √ = −d1.
σFU \S τ
By noting σFU \S = σFS\U , we can check easily that the quanto option
value in Hong Kong dollars using the two approaches agree with each
other.
48
4.4 Implied volatilities and volatility smiles
49
Remark
50
Volatility smiles and volatility term structures
51
Implied volatility surface
52
Volatility skew
The plots of the implied volatility σimp against moneyness K/S for
traded call and put options with the same maturity date typically
show the skew shape as shown in the following figure.
ı LPS
SXW
FDOO
.6
RXWRIWKH PRQH\ RXWRIWKHPRQH\
IRUFDOOV IRUSXWV
53
• The volatility skew across moneyness occurs since the option
prices for deep out-of-the-money options are bid up higher than
around-the-money counterparts.
54
Comparison of the risk neutral probability density of asset price
(solid curve) implied from market data and the theoretical lognormal
distribution (dotted curve). The risk neutral probability density is
thicker at the left tail and thinner at the right tail, indicating that
there is a higher change of more acute drop when S is low and a
lower chance of further increase when S is high.
55
Negative correlation between stock price process and volatility pro-
cess
56
Extreme events in stock price movements
Examples
1. On October 19, 1987, the two-month S&P 500 futures price
fell 29%. Under the lognormal hypothesis of annualized volatility
of 20%, this is a −27 standard deviation event with probability
10−160 (virtually impossible).
2. On October 13, 1989, the S&P 500 index fell about 6%, a −5
standard deviation event. Under the maintained hypothesis, this
should occur only once in 14, 756 years.
57
Implied volatilities across time
58
Implied volatilities for different strike prices
59
2. Commodity options – higher implied volatilities at higher strike
and lower implied volatilities at lower strikes
60
Term structure of volatility
How to obtain the term structure of volatility σ(t) given the implied
volatility measured at time t∗ of a European option expiring at time
t? For an option with time to expiry t − t∗, the substitution of the
implied volatility σimp(t∗, t) into the standard Black-Scholes formula
under constant volatility gives the option price.
Remark
The implied volatility σimp(t∗, t) may be obtained by averaging the
implied volatility values for options at different strikes but with same
maturity t. This treatment is acceptable since we focus on the
consideration of the term structure of volatility.
61
The equivalence of giving the same observed option price by adopt-
ing the two different forms of volatility in the two separate option
price formulas leads to
∫ t
2 (t∗, t)(t − t∗ ).
σ(u)2 du = σimp
t∗
The left hand side is the assumption of time dependent volatility σ(t)
and the right hand side is the application of the implied volatility
formula based on constant volatility in the Black-Scholes pricing
formula.
62
Approximation of σ(t) as a piecewise constant function
63
Risk neutral density function
r(T −t) ∂ 2c
ψ(X, T ; St, t) = e .
∂X 2
• Suppose that market European option prices at all strikes are
available, the risk neutral density function can be inferred com-
pletely from the market prices of options with the same maturity
and different strikes, without knowing the volatility function.
64
Dupire equation and local volatility function
Assuming that the asset price dynamics under the risk neutral mea-
sure is governed by
dSt
= (r − q)dt + σ(St, t)dZt,
St
where the local volatility function σ(St, t) is assumed to have both
state and time dependence.
65
Proof
See Problem 3.8 on P.166 in Kwok’s text for a proof of the forward
Fokker-Planck equation.
66
Combining the above equations and eliminating the common factor
er(T −t), we have
∂ 2c ∂ 2 ∂c
r +
∂X [ ∂X 2 ∂T
2
] [ ]
∂ 2 2 2
σ (X, T ) 2 ∂ c ∂ 2
∂ c
= X − (r − q)X .
∂X 2 2 ∂X 2 ∂X ∂X 2
Integrating the above equation with respect to X twice, we obtain
( )
∂c ∂c
+ rc + (r − q) X −c
∂T ∂X
2
σ (X, T ) 2 ∂ c2
= X 2
+ α(T )X + β(T ),
2 ∂X
where α(T ) and β(T ) are arbitrary functions of T .
67
From the Dupire equation, we may express the local volatility σ(X, T )
explicitly in terms of the call price function and its derivatives, where
[ ]
∂c ∂c
2 ∂T + qc + (r − q)X ∂X
2
σ (X, T ) = .
∂ 2c
X 2 ∂X 2
68
Relationship between local volatility and implied volatility
where
[ ]
2 (X,T )
σimp
S + r−q+
ln X T
2
d1 = √ .
σimp(X, T ) T
69
4.5 Volatility exposure generated by delta hedging options
70
Let σti be the time dependent implied volatility derived from traded
option prices at varying times. We write the time-t option price
as Vti = V (St, t; σti) with reference to implied volatility σti. Sup-
pose an option trader sells an option at time zero priced at the
current market implied volatility σ0i , the option price is given by
V0i = V (S0, 0; σ0i ).
71
After selling one unit of the option, the hedger replicates the option
by holding ∆h t units of stock and money market account. These
three instruments constitute the delta hedged portfolio that hedges
against the stock price risk. However, variance risk remains since
only stock is used as the hedging instrument.
The P&L of the delta hedged portfolio over the infinitesimal time
interval [t, t + dt] consists of the following three components:
72
At time t, the hedger adopts his own hedging volatility σth. We
allow the flexibility that the hedger may not choose the implied
volatility σti from the market option price. The hedger computes
Vth = V (St, t; σth) based on the choice of the volatility parameter
value σth in the Black-Scholes option price formula and use Vth to
h ∂Vth
compute the hedge ratio ∆t = ∂S . The various Greek parameters
h ∂Vth h ∂Vth h ∂ 2 Vth
Θt = ∂t , ∆t = ∂S and Γt = ∂S 2 are related by (based on the
Black-Scholes equation)
h Γh St2 h 2
Θt = − t (σt ) + rVth − (r − q)∆h
t St . (2a)
2
By applying Itô’s lemma to the price function Vth = V (St, t; σth), we
have
h h h 1 ∂ 2Vth 2
dVt = Θt dt + ∆t dSt + 2
(dS t )
( 2 ∂S )
h 2
= ∆h dS + Θh + Γt St σ 2 dt, (2b)
t t t t
2
where dSt2 = σt2St2dt. The diffusion term in (2b) involves σt2 instead
of (σth)2 since St follows the dynamics as specified in (1).
73
Substituting Θh
t in (2a) into (2b), we obtain
h h Γh St2 2
dVt = ∆t dSt + t [σt − (σth)2]dt + r(Vth − ∆h h
t St )dt + q∆t St dt.
2
(2c)
Let Πt denote the time-t value of the P&L, then dΠt over [t, t + dt]
is given by the sum of the three components:
dΠt = ∆h i h i
t (dSt + qSt dt) + r(Vt − ∆t St )dt − dVt .
We eliminate the hedge ratio term by substituting (2c) into the
above equation to obtain
h i h i Γh St2 2
dΠt = (dVt − dVt ) − r(Vt − Vt )dt − t [σt − (σth)2]dt
2
−r(T −t) d [ r(T −t) h ] Γh S 2
=e e (Vt − Vt ) dt − t t [σt2 − (σth)2]dt.
i
dt 2
74
The total P&L at maturity T is given by the accumulated sum of
the forward value of the differential P&L, where
∫ T
ΠT = er(T −t) dΠt
0
∫ T
−t) Γh St2 2
= (VTh − VTi ) − erT (V0h − V0i) − er(T t [σt − (σth)2] dt.
0 2
At maturity T , the option price is independent of the volatility pa-
rameter yielding
VTh = VTi = V (ST ).
The total P&L at maturity T is
∫ T
−t) Γh S 2
ΠT = erT [V (S0, 0; σ0i ) − V (S0, 0; σ0h)] + e r(T t t [(σ h )2 − σ 2 ] dt.
t t
0 2
Since the factor Γh 2
t St appears as cash term in ΠT , it is commonly
called the cash gamma or dollar gamma since it is expressible in
dollar value.
75
Remarks
76
2. Suppose the trader is delta hedging the option at the implied
volatility, where σth = σti, then the total P&L becomes
∫ T iS2
Γ
ΠT = er(T −t) t t [(σti)2 − σt2] dt.
0 2
In this case, the total P&L is equal to the future value of the
weighted sum of the difference between the implied variance and
realized variance, where the weight factor is half of the cash
Γit St2
gamma, 2 . Usually, options are over priced, which means
σti > σt. As most options observe the property Γit > 0, we then
deduce that delta hedging strategy generates positive P&L.
Note that the variance exposure associated with the delta hedged
option is also dependent on the realized path of St. It is still
possible to obtain
∫ T
[(σti)2 − σt2] dt > 0,
0
while the P&L can be negative due to the path dependent factor
Γit St2
2 .
77
4.6 VIX and timer options
78
Mathematical derivation of VIX
σt2
The drift term − dt in d ln Ft arises from the Ito lemma, where
2
1 2 2 2 ∂2 σt2
σt Ft (dWt) 2
ln Ft = − dt.
2 ∂Ft 2
79
Subtracting the two equations, we obtain the cumulative variance
over [0, T ] under continuous time model as follows:
∫ T [∫ ]
dFt σ 2 T dFt F
− d ln Ft = t dt, so σt2 dt = 2 − ln T .
Ft 2 0 0 Ft F0
[∫ ]
T
Our goal is to find the mathematical formula for EQ 0 σt2 dt , visu-
alized as the forward price of the realized cumulative variance over
[0, T ]. Recall that the T -maturity forward price of a risky asset St
is given by EQ[ST ]. In the current context, the underlying is the
∫
random cumulative variance 0T σt2 dt.
Note that
[∫ ] [∫ ]
T dFt T
E = EQ σt dWt = 0
0 Ft 0
so that
[∫ ] [ ]
T F
EQ σt2 dt = −2EQ ln T .
0 F0
The log contract with terminal payoff ln F T
F0 appears naturally. How
to relate the log contract with the usual call and put options?
80
Technical result For any twice-differentiable function f : R → R,
and any non-negative S∗, we have
∫ S
∗
f (ST ) = f (S∗) + f ′(S∗)(ST − S∗) + f ′′(K)(K − ST )+ dK
∫ ∞ 0
+ f ′′(K)(ST − K)+ dK.
S∗
The sum of the two integrals is the integral representation of the
remainder term in the Taylor expansion of f (ST ) up to the first
power term.
Proof
82
Rearranging the terms and rewriting FT and F0 for ST and S ∗, re-
spectively, we have
∫ F
f (FT ) − f (F0) = f ′(F0)(FT − F0) + f ′′(K)(K − FT )+dK
0
∫ ∞ 0
+ f ′′(K)(FT − K)+dK.
F0
Here, F0 is the time-0 forward price of the S&P index, an observable
known quantity. Taking f (FT ) = ln FT , we have
∫ ∫
∞ (FT − K)+
FT FT − F0 F0 (K − FT )+
ln = − 2
dK − 2
dK.
F0 F0 0 K F0 K
[ ]
FT
Recall EQ[FT ] = F0 so that EQ − 1 = 0. We then have
F0
[∫ ] [∫ ∫ ∞ ]
T F0 (K − FT )+ (FT − K)+
EQ σt2 dt = 2EQ 2
dK + 2
dK .
0 0 K F0 K
83
Note that
EQ[(K − FT )+] = erT putK ,
where putK is the time-0 price of a put on the S&P index with strike
K. At T , forward price and the underlying index coincide in value.
We then obtain
[∫ ] [∫ ∫ ∞ ]
T F0 putK callK
EQ 2
σt dt = 2erT dK + dK .
0 0 K 2 F0 K 2
The two terms represent continuum of puts whose strikes are below
F0 and calls whose strikes are above F0, respectively. They represent
out-of-the-money options with respect to the current forward price
F0. The CBOE’s choice is sensible since out-of-the-money options
tend to be more liquid contracts.
84
Actual implementation of VIX formula
Recall
∫ ∫
∞ (FT − K)+
FT FT − K0 K0 (K − FT )+
ln = − 2
dK − 2
dK
K0 K0 0 K K0 K
so that
[ ] [ ]
FT FT F0
EQ ln = EQ ln + ln
K0 F0 K0
∫ K rT ∫ ∞ rT
F0 0 e putK e callK
= −1− 2
dK − 2
dK
K0 0 K K0 K
85
We use the approximation
( ) ( )2
F0 F0 1 F0
ln ≈ −1 − −1 ,
K0 K0 2 K0
so that
{[∫ ∫ ∞ ] [∫ ∫ ∞ ]}
F0 putK callK K 0 putK callK
2erT 2
dK + 2
dK − 2
dK + 2
dK
0 K F0 K 0 K K0 K
[ ( )] ( )2
rT F0 F0 F0
= −2e ln − −1 ≈− −1 .
K0 K0 K0
Finally, we obtain
[∫ ]
T
EQ σt2 dt
0
[∫ ∫ ∞ ] ( )2
K0 putK callK F0
= 2erT 2
dK + 2
dK − −1 .
0 K K0 K K0
86
Finally, we multiply the above expected realized cumulative vari-
365
ance by the product of the annualization conversion factor and
30
percentage point factor 100 to obtain
V IXt2
( )2
2 ∑ ∆Ki 1 F0
= 1002 e r(30/365) Q(K ) −
i −1 .
30/365 2 30/365 K0
i Ki
Here, K0 is the first strike below the forward index level F0, Q(Ki)
is the time-t out-of-the-money option price with strike Ki.
87
Summary: Sources of errors
1. Truncation error
We choose a bounded truncation interval [KL, KU ] of strikes in-
stead of the theoretical interval [0, ∞]. Note that the CBOE may
add new strikes as the underlying S&P 500 index moves. The
added strikes expand the truncation interval. During the period
of frequent spikes, the expansion of interval can be frequent and
significant.
2. Discretization error
The continuous integration of option prices with respect to con-
tinuum of strikes is approximated by the sum of weighted out-
of-the-money option prices.
88
3. Approximation error arising from replacing F0 by K0
F0
The logarithm term ln K is approximated by the Taylor expan-
0
F0
sion in powers of K − 1 up to the quadratic term.
0
89
Plot of VIX for the past two decades
90
Plot of VIX in 2018
S&P 500 index and VIX are negatively correlated. Growth of SPX
over the last 10 years since 2008 financial tsunami with low level of
VIX.
92
VIX derivatives
93
Trading volumes of VIX futures
95
VVIX and modeling of dynamics of VIX
Every asset class deserves its own volatility index, including VIX
itself. The VVIX Index is an indicator of the expected volatility of
the 30-day forward price of the VIX. This volatility drives nearby
VIX option prices.
96
Timer options
A standard timer call option can be viewed as a call option with ran-
dom maturity which depends on the time needed for a pre-specified
variance budget to be fully consumed. A variance budget is calculat-
ed as the target volatility squared, multiplied by the target maturity.
97
The realized variance over time period [0, T ] is
n−1 ( )2
∑ Si+1
bT
VT = n∆tσ 2 ≈ ln .
i=0 Si
The investor specifies a variance budget
B = σ02T0,
where T0 is the estimated investment horizon and σ0 is the forecast
volatility during the investing period.
Suppose the variance budget is never met within [0, T ], the timer
call option expires at the mandated maximum expiration date T
with terminal payoff max(ST − X, 0).
98
Option strategy without paying the volatility risk premium
99
The first trade was in April 2007 on HSBC with a June expiry.
• The implied volatility on the plain vanilla call was slightly above
15%, but the client sets a target volatility level of 12%, a little
higher than the prevailing realized volatility level of around 10%.
• The realized volatility has been around 9.5% since the inception
of the trade. The maturity of the timer call is 60% longer than
the original vanilla call.
100
Hedge against stock price drop at a lower cost
• Suppose the stock price goes down, the timer put expires earlier
since the realized volatility increases. The compensation of the
stock price loss arrives sooner and more timely.
• Suppose the stock price goes up, the realized volatility decreases
giving longer life of the timer put. The insurance protection
provided by the timer put lasts longer. Hence, the hedging cost
is lower.
101
How to gain from the bullish view of the market?
Long a timer call and short a vanilla call, both with the same strike
K. Usually, stock price and volatility are negatively correlated. The
implied volatility in the market is too high currently, and subsequent
realized volatility will be less than that implied in the market.
If the stock shifts higher over the period, the tenor of the timer
option would be longer. The timer call will expire later than the
plain vanilla call. The value of the timer call at expiry of the vanilla
call is the sum of the intrinsic value ST − K and time value.
102
Pricing of discretely monitored finite-maturity timer options
Define the
∫
continuous integrated variance (quadratic variation) to
t
be It = Vs ds.
We use It as a proxy of the discrete realized
0
variance for the monitoring of the first hitting time and let ∆t be
the uniform time interval between successive monitoring dates. We
define τB to be
τB = min j Itj ≥ B ∆t.
103
Decomposition into a portfolio of timerlets
The event {τB > t} is equivalent to {It < B}. Note that τB = tj+1
if and only if Itj < B and Itj+1 ≥ B. Therefore, we have
−1
N∪
{τB ≤ T } = {Itj < B, Itj+1 ≥ B}.
j=0
Product Nature
105
Numerical example
• Let the initial fund value be $100, 000 and the withdrawal rate
be fixed at 7% per annum. Suppose the investment account
earns 10% in the first two years but earns returns of −60% in
each of the next three years.
• At the end of year five before any withdrawal, the fund value
$2, 883 is not enough to cover the annual withdrawal payment
of $7, 000.
106
The guarantee kicks in when the fund is non-performing
If the market does well, then there will be funds left at policy’s
maturity.
107
Numerical example revisited
• After the first year, the rate of return is 10% so each unit is
$1, 100. The annual guaranteed withdrawal of $7, 000 represents
$7, 000/$1, 100 = 6.364 units. The remaining number of units
of the mutual fund is 100 − 6.364 = 93.636 units.
108
• There is a negative rate of return of 60% in the third year, so
each unit of the mutual fund worths $484. The withdrawal of
$7, 000 represents $7, 000/$484 = 14.463 units, so the remain-
ing number of units = 73.388.
109
How is the benefit funded?
110
Static withdrawal model – continuous version
111
Surrogate unrestricted process
f , we obtain
Solving for Wt
( ∫ t )
f =X w −G 1
W t t 0 du
0 Xu
where
( 2
)
σ
r−α+ 2 t+σBt
Xt = e .
The solution is the unit exponential Brownian motion Xt multiplied
by the number of units remaining after depletion by withdrawals.
112
Financial interpretation
Take the initial value of one unit of the fund to be unity for con-
venience. Here, Xt represents the corresponding fund value process
with X0 = 1.
113
f > 0 for t ≤ T or W
Either W f remains negative once W reaches
t T t
the negative region at some earlier time prior to T .
114
f > 0.
Lemma τ0 > T if and only if WT
115
Intuition of the dynamics
f
Relation between WT and WT
116
∫
G t 1
Defining Ut = du, we obtain
w0 0 Xu
EQ[e−rT W
f +] = w E [e−rT X (1 − U )+].
T 0 Q T T
The pricing issue is to find the fair value for the participating fee
rate α such that the initial policy value equals the lump sum paid
upfront by the policyholder so that the policy contract is fair to
both counterparties.
117
4.8 Transaction costs models
How to construct the hedging strategy that best replicates the pay-
off of a derivative security in the presence of transaction costs?
118
Let k denote the round trip transaction cost per unit dollar of trans-
action. Suppose α units of assets are bought (α > 0) or sold (α < 0)
k
at the price S, then the transaction cost is given by |α|S in either
2
buying or selling.
119
After the small time interval δt, the change in value of the portfolio
is
k
δΠ = −δV + ∆ δS − |δ∆|S,
2
where δS is the change in asset price and δ∆ is the change in the
number of units of asset held in the portfolio.
120
By Ito’s lemma, the change in option value in time δt to leading
orders is given by
( )
∂V ∂V σ2 ∂ 2V
δV ≈ δS + + S2 2 δt.
∂S ∂t 2 ∂S
∂V
In order to cancel the stochastic terms, one chooses ∆ = . The
∂S
change in the number of units of asset in time δt is given by
∂V ∂V
δ∆ = (S + δS, t + δt) − (S, t).
∂S ∂S
From the dynamics of St, we observe δS ≈ ρSδt + σSδZ. Note that
√
δZ ≈ O( δt) is dominant over ρSδt, so the leading order of |δ∆| is
found to be
∂ 2V 2 V
∂
|δ∆| ≈ 2 |δS| ≈ σS 2 |δZ|.
∂S ∂S
121
√
Formally, we may treat δZ as xe δt, where x
e is the standard normal
variable. The expectation of the reflected Brownian motion |δZ| is
given by
(∫ )
∞1 −t 2 /2 √
E(|δZ|) = 2 t√ e dt δt
0 2π
(∫ )
∞ 1
−u
√
= 2 √ e du δt, u = t2/2,
0 2π
√
2√
= δt.
π
The risk of loss associated with transaction costs is investor-specific,
so it should not be compensated. By the Capital Asset Pricing
Model, the hedged portfolio should earn an expected rate of return
same as that of a riskless asset. This gives
( ) √
∂V σ2 ∂ 2V k 2 ∂ V √
2
E[δΠ] = −
− S2 2 δt − σS 2 δt
∂t 2 ∂S 2 π ∂S
2
( )
∂V
= r −V + S δt.
∂S
122
By putting all the above results together, the above equation can
be rewritten as
√ ( )
−
∂V σ 2
2 ∂ 2V σ 2
2 2 k ∂ 2V ∂V
− S − S √ δt = r −V + S δt.
∂t 2 ∂S 2 2
π σ δt ∂S 2 ∂S
√ ( )
2 k
If we define the Leland number to be Le = √ , we obtain
π σ δt
2 V
∂V σ 2 2 ∂ 2V σ2
2 ∂ + rS
∂V
+ S 2
+ Le S 2 − rV = 0.
∂t 2 ∂S 2 ∂S ∂S
123
σ2 ∂ 2V
In the proportional transaction costs model, the term Le S 2 2
2 ∂S
is in general non-linear, except when the comparative static Γ =
∂ 2V
2
does not change sign for all S. The transaction cost term
∂S
∂∆
is dependent on Γ, where Γ = measures the sensitivity of the
∂S
hedge ratio ∆ to the underlying asset price S.
One may rewrite the equation into the form that resembles the
Black-Scholes equation
∂V e 2 2 ∂ 2V
σ ∂V
+ S 2
+ rS − rV = 0,
∂t 2 ∂S ∂S
where the modified volatility under transaction costs is given by
e 2 = σ 2[1 + Le sign(Γ)].
σ
e2
The governing equation becomes mathematically ill-posed when σ
becomes negative. This occurs when Γ < 0 and Le > 1.
124
Modified volatility
The governing equation then becomes linear under the above as-
sumption so that the Black-Scholes formulas become applicable
e is now used as the volatility
except that the modified volatility σ
parameter.
125
e ) and V (S, t; σ) denote the option values obtained from
Let V (S, t; σ
the Black-Scholes formula with volatility values σ e and σ, respectively.
The total transaction costs associated with the replicating strategy
is then given by
T = V (S, t; σ
e ) − V (S, t; σ).
126