Teodor Shanin - The Awkward Class. Political Sociology of Peasantry in A Developing Society - Russia 1910-1925-At The Clarendon Press (1972)
Teodor Shanin - The Awkward Class. Political Sociology of Peasantry in A Developing Society - Russia 1910-1925-At The Clarendon Press (1972)
AWKWARD CLASS
POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY OF
PEASANTRY
IN A DEVELOPING SOCIETY:
RUSSIA 1910-1925
OXFORD
AT TH E C L A R E N D O N PRESS
1 97 2
Oxford University Press, Ely House, London W. /
GLASGOW NEW YORK TORONTO MELBOURNE WELLINGTON
CAPE TOWN IBADAN NAIROBI DAR ES SALAAM LUSAKA ADDIS ABABA
DELHI BOMBAY CALCUTTA MADRAS KARACHI LAHORE DACCA
KUALA LUMPUR SINGAPORE HONG KONG TOKYO
\
j
i
i ■^Ya 'z
PRINTED IN GREAT B R IT A IN
AT T H E U N I V E R S I T Y PRESS, OXFORD
BY VIVIAN RIDLER
PRINTER TO T H E U N I V E R S I T Y
TO
ISAAC D E U T SC H E R
A GENTLE REVOLUTIONARY
AND TO
AN A R G U M E N T L EF T U N F I N I S H E D
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
LIST OF F IG U R E S xvii
R U S S IA N A B B R E V IA T IO N S U SE D xix
IN T R O D U C T IO N I
PART I
R U SSIA A N D ITS PE A SA N T R Y
AT THE T U R N OF THE C E N T U R Y
I. R U SSIA AS A D E V E L O PIN G SOCIETY 9
(a) The Turn of the Century 9
(b) A ‘Developing Society’? 13
(c) The Peasant Sector 19
(<d) Social Dualism and Russian Society 24
2. P E A SA N T H O U SE H O LD A N D PEASANT SOCIETY 28
(a) The Peasant Household 28
(b) The Peasant Commune 32
(c) Peasant Society and Culture 38
P A R T 11
CYCLICAL M OBILITY
3. THE D IF F E R E N T IA T IO N DEBATE 45
(a) The Roots of the Debate 45
0b) Census Evidence 47
(c) The Unfinished Debate 58
id) The Heritage of the Debate: Towards New Answers 61
4. PO L A R IZ A T IO N A N D CYCLICAL M OBILITY 63
(a) The Correlation of Wealth and Size 63
(b) Budget Studies and Polarization 66
(c) Dynamic Studies and the Mobility of Peasant Households 71
(d) The Mobility of Peasant Households and the Mobility of Peasant
Society 76
X CONTENTS
5. ‘SUBSTANTIVE CH A N G E S’ 81
(a) The Levelling Mechanism 81
(b) Partitioning and Newly Created Households 85
(c) Merger and Extinction 88
(d ) Migration 92
6. M U LT ID IR E C T IO N A L A N D CYCLICAL M O BILITY:
TOW ARDS AN E X PLANATO RY MODEL 96
(a) The Residual Component of Peasant Household Mobility 96
(b) Biological Determinism 101
(c) Economic Determinism and Multifactorial Analysis 109
(d) The Peculiarities of a Smallholding Economy 112
(e) The Mobility of Peasant Households: a Multifactorial Model 115
7. M U LT ID IR E C T IO N A L A N D CYCLICAL M O BILITY:
V ALIDITY A N D RELEVANCE 122
(a) Validity: Regional Differences 122
(b) Validity: Historical Trends 126
(c) Validity: Operational Definitions 131
(d) Social Differentiation and the Political Significance of
Multidirectional and Cyclical Mobility 137
P A R T III
THE PR E D O M IN A N T CO NFLICT (1917-1925)
8. THE A G R A R IA N R EVO LUTIO N A N D L EV ELLIN G
AM ONG THE R U SSIA N PE A SA N T R Y 145
(a) In Search of Kulak Counter-Revolution 145
(b) Land Redivision, 1917-1919 147
(c) The Results of the Agrarian Revolution 153
id) Mobility of Peasant Households and the Agrarian Revolution 156
(e) Peasant Solidarity and Agrarian Revolution, 1917-1920 160
9. THE R UR AL SOCIETY IN THE PERIO D OF THE N.E.P.:
POWER, DIVERSITY, A N D CO NFLICT 163
(a) The Local Authority in Rural Russia: the de jure situation 163
(b) The Commune Gathering and the Rural Soviet 166
(c) The Socio-Economic Strata 169
(d) The Traditional Division of Roles by Sex and Age 175
(e) Vertical Segmentation and the Outsiders 177
10. THE R U R A L SOCIETY IN THE PERIO D OF THE N.E.P.:
THE P R E D O M IN A N T CO NFLICT 180
(a) The Rural Salariat (Sluzhashchie) 180
(b) The Party Members (Partiitsy) 185
CONTENTS xi
(c) The Ex-Servicemen (Armeitsy) 190
(d) The Plenipotentiary Outsiders and the Volost' Power Caucus 192
(e) The Rural Power Structure and the Future Development of the
Countryside 197
A PPE N D IC ES
A. THE P E A SA N T R Y AS A PO LITICAL FACTOR 203
(a) The Peasantry: An Analytical Definition 204
(b) The Peasantry: The Historical Context 207
(c) The Peasantry and Society 211
(1d) The Peasantry in Political Action 214
B. R U S S IA N PE A SA N T LAW A N D THE IN H E R IT A N C E
OF PRO PERTY 219
(a) Peasant Law 219
(b) Family Property 220
(c) Peasant Inheritance and Partitioning, 1883-1905 222
(d) Peasant Law, 1905-1929 224
B IB L IO G R A PH Y 228
G LO SSA R Y 239
IN D E X 245
LIST OF TABLES
CHAPTER I
chapter 3
CHAPTER 4
chapter 5
chapter 6
chapter 7
chapter 8
chapter 9
CHAPTER 10
i. Salaried Staff employed by the State in Rural Areas of the U.S.S.R., 1926 181
11. Communists in Rural Administration 184
h i. Bolshevik Party Membership by Social Class, 1905, 1917-1924 186
iv. Officials of Soviet Local Authorities by Type, 1924-1926 194
LIST OF FIGURES
i. Types of Mobility in Peasant Society (Graphs of Socio-Economic
Change) 51
11. Types of Household Mobility 76
Peasant Socio-Economic Mobility: Peasant Society and Peasant
Households 78
iv. Households undergoing ‘Substantive Changes’ by Wealth (Hypothetical 118
Graph)
v. Multidirectional and Cyclical Mobility: The Determinants of Centri
fugal and Centripetal Mobilityamong PeasantHouseholds 118
vi. The ‘Statistical Optical Illusion’ inGraphic Form 136
RUSSIAN ABBREVIATIONS USED
des. Desyatina, which was the standard Russian land measure, (i des. =
1-09 hectares = 2-7 acres.)
gub. Guberniya, a province—the main administrative division of the
Russian state in the period discussed.
Komsomol Kommunisticheskii Soyuz Molodezhi: the youth organization of the
Bolshevik party.
N.E.P. Novaya ekonomicheskaya politika; the economic policy introduced
by the Soviet government during the period 1921-8; also the period
of its implementation.
R.S.F.S.R. Rossiiskaya Sovetskaya Federativnaya Sotsialisticheskaya Respublika:
the Russian republic in the Soviet period.
Rub. RubV—the basic unit of Russian currency.
Ts.S.U. Tsentralnoe statisticheskoe upravlenie: the central statistical board
created by the Soviet government after the revolution.
8214986 B
INTRODUCTION
T he conception o f the basic dynamics of a peasant society accepted by
Russian policy-makers and, indeed, by the majority of educated Russians at
the beginning o f this century can be outlined in a few sentences. It was
believed that, in the process o f inevitable economic advance, every human
society necessarily headed towards an increasing division of labour,1 the
establishment o f market relations, the accumulation o f capital, and social
diversification. It was also believed that these processes were centred in towns
but inevitably spread into the countryside. Rich peasant farms, which were
larger and better equipped and had a higher capital/worker ratio, found
themselves in an advantageous position as far as the optimal use o f the factors
o f production and their further accumulation were concerned. For precisely
opposite reasons, poor peasant farms were at a disadvantage in any attempt
to improve their economic position. Continuing cumulation o f economic
advantages and disadvantages led to a polarization o f peasant society into
rich farmers, who increasingly acquired the characteristics o f capitalist entre
preneurs, and poor farmers, who lost their farms and became landless wage-
labourers in the employ o f rich farmers, estate owners, or urban entrepreneurs.
Some o f the typical characteristics o f a traditional peasant family farm could
still be seen in the middle strata of the peasantry, but these would disintegrate
or change in the inevitable process of economic advance. With them would
disappear the survivals of the traditional peasant society. A new social struc
ture based on capitalist farming would finally come to be established in the
countryside.
This general picture of the dynamics o f a peasant society was firmly
established as a piece o f self-evident knowledge—it had become part o f the
prevailing ideology, not only in the normative but also in the cognitive sense.2
It was, in turn, taken as given and constituted the basic assumption under
lying the rural policies of all the rulers of the Russian state during the politically
crucial quarter o f a century which followed the 1905-6 revolution.3 The
political perspective was that the peasantry would break down into new rural
1 In the broad sense advanced by Adam Smith in The Wealth o f Nations (1806).
2 Ideological images o f reality may act merely as justifications and canonizations of
political decisions taken but also as ‘lenses . . . through which men see, a medium by which
they interpret and report what they see’ (C. Wright Mills, Power, Politics and People (1963),
p. 406). For a recent discussion see P. Berger and T. Luckman, The Social Construction o f
Reality (1967).
3 The Russian populism expressed in the Social Revolutionary party was ideologically
‘odd man out’ in its acceptance of and reliance on the cohesion o f the peasantry as one
class. The populists were not, however, given the opportunity to carry out any real policy
towards the countryside, and are not, therefore, significant for our discussion.
2 INTRODUCTION
classes typical of capitalist society (i.e. capitalist farmers, wage-workers, etc.)
which would demonstrate increasing self-awareness, cohesion, and tendencies
to political action in support of their own interests. This expected development
was in fact a precondition for the success of the policies pursued by successive
Russian governments.
The major fact o f Russian rural history in the first quarter o f the century
is that the predicted development both of the class structure and o f the politi
cal response of the peasants did not happen. The richer farmers and the rural
wage-earners (and/or poor peasants) on the whole failed to act as independent
factions. In spite o f the apparent differentiation and of polarization-processes,
the villages o f the Russian peasantry went on showing remarkable political
cohesiveness and unity of action. The results of Stolypin’s attempt to estab
lish, from 1906 onwards, a stratum of independent, well-to-do, and con
servative peasant yeomen settled on enclosed farms (khutora) disappeared
practically overnight, without a trace of any rallying to its defence, in 1917-
18.1 In 1918, new rural policies attempting to socialize the countryside by
mobilization of the rural poor for a second revolution against the wealthy
peasants had to be abandoned, and the ‘Committees o f the Poor’ ( Kombedy)
which had been set up, disbanded.1 Similar results occurred with the various
attempts made to organize the rural poor during the period o f the New
Economic Policy (1921-8).1 Efforts to socialize the countryside reached a new
climax in imposed collectivization which, instead o f being the looked-for
socialist revolution of the rural poor (supported by their urban allies) against
their exploiters, turned into ‘a battle . . . more perilous and formidable . . .
than the battle of Stalingrad’2 between the forces of the Soviet state and the
Russian peasantry acting virtually as a united whole.3 This basic discrepancy
between the acknowledged aims and the manifest results o f rural policies
constitutes the crux of the political history of rural Russia during a decisive
period and forms the focal point of this study.
The apparent failure of accepted theories to accord with the crucial evidence
o f Russian rural history can be approached in three ways: (i) by denying
the very existence of a problem; (ii) by claiming that delays intervened in the
processes expected; or (iii) by introducing new factors into the analysis. The
first approach could be made by denying either the very fact of an unexpectedly
high political cohesion of the Russian peasantry4 or denying the existence of
peasant differentiation and polarization during the period. An alternative
form of the first approach could be to dispose of the very premiss o f class
analysis by putting in doubt the correlation between socio-economic position
1 See Chapter 8, section (b).
2 Stalin’s description of collectivization (as reported by Churchill) in F. Maclean, Eastern
Approaches (1951), p. 360.
3 For a discussion of the background see Chapters 9 and 10.
4 This was, in fact, the attitude adopted by many scholars o f the Soviet establishment,
especially after collectivization.
INTRODUCTION 3
and political attitude and action. But neither the Russian evidence available
nor the indications of comparative studies would seem to make any such
solutions appear reasonable. In the case of the second approach, the initial
theory would be sustained, and the claim would be made that the changes
predicted had not had time to take place fully. Interest and further research
promoted by this attitude would therefore be focused on the factors of social
inertia as the reasons behind the delay in the fulfilment o f the changes pre
dicted—i.e., on the static factors which reinforce stability. Research on these
lines has, in fact, been done and has produced illuminating results in the form
o f studies o f Russian peasant culture, of the structure of the peasant commune
and so on.1 Finally, the accepted basic model of the dynamics o f peasant
societies can be challenged by re-analysing the nature of the factors accepted
as relevant and their interaction. It will be apparent that this study is based
on the last approach—namely, the admission of major additional factors as
necessary for the understanding o f the problems analysed. Particular attention
is given to the processes reinforcing the stability o f the social system—an aspect
which tends to be overlooked by many of the theories o f social change.
The argument o f the present work is, firstly, that the patterns of socio
economic mobility2 peculiar to and characteristic of peasant society led to
significant changes in the way actual differentiation and polarization-processes
impinged on the political consciousness and action of the Russian peasantry.
The focus o f investigation o f mobility will here turn from the changes in
peasant society as a whole to the social impact of the mobility of individual
households and their multidirectional and cyclical nature.3 Secondly, it is
argued that analysis of conflict-relations between the social groups in the
Russian countryside points to a crucial division between the members o f
peasant communities and the rural representatives of the town-centred ap
paratus o f the party and the state, which overshadowed the other divisions
within peasant society. Finally, it shows the relationship between patterns of
socio-economic mobility and the conflict-relations in rural society and indi
cates the significance of these for explanation o f the basic processes of Russian
rural history with a number of possible inferences relevant to the general
analysis o f peasantry in the contemporary world.
Before turning to the relevance of our analysis it may prove useful to say
what it does not attempt to do. The analysis and concepts introduced are not
intended to provide a master key to the understanding of peasant societies in
general, regardless o f space, time, and political and cultural framework. Yet
it may prove relevant to analysis at some levels of generalization. In the first
1 For example, the contemporary studies by Luzhin and Rezunov and the recent studies
by Taniuchi and Male referred to in Chapters 9 and 10.
2 The term ‘mobility’ is used in the sense of vertical mobility as defined by The Encyclo
paedia o f the Social Sciences (1st edition), vol. ii, p. 554, but is limited to the socio-economic
dimension only.
3 For a discussion o f the relationships between types of mobility see Chapter 4, section (d).
4 INTRODUCTION
place, it may shed further light on the history of Russia and, in particular,
contribute to clarification o f the course of events in that major period of
Russian rural history which lies between the 1917 revolution and mass
collectivization in 1929. Secondly, it may prove significant for more general
studies o f the peasantry as a social entity and suggest important directions for
future empirical investigations. It seems highly unlikely that the processes
discussed were confined to the Russian peasantry alone. Indeed, recent studies
have indicated possible similar tendencies in Turkey, Iran, China, and Japan.1
Such evidence, if true, would lead to readjustments in our interpretations o f
contemporary peasantries—particularly in so far as the persistence o f tradi
tional rural social patterns is concerned. It may therefore prove relevant also
to evolving strategies for rural development in contemporary developing
societies. Thirdly, it may contribute to sociological theory at a more general
level. The discussion of ‘non-economic’ determinants o f the economy, the
elaboration of analytical concepts like cyclical mobility or vertical diversity, and
the confrontation of major theories and models o f society with challenging
new evidence, may provide an additional perspective to the general study of
social structures and their dynamics.
The importance o f the study of Russian peasant society is very much
increased by the unusually high quality and the extensive nature o f the data
gathered in rural Russia in the last decades of the nineteenth and first quarter
o f the twentieth centuries—the result of an historically extraordinary en
counter between a highly sophisticated and deeply committed intelligentsia
and a massive traditional peasantry.1 These studies by Russian rural econo
mists, sociologists, and ethnographers were, in their day, the leading works
in this field in the world. The studies were followed up and developed on a
national scale up to 1928 by the Central Statistical Board (Ts.S.U.) o f the
Soviet government and by various Soviet planning departments. In fact, the
Russian data collected half a century ago are in many ways superior to those
of recent studies of peasant societies and, indeed, still unique. This is not
to deny that there are enormous difficulties involved in using these Russian
materials today. With primary sources lost, authors dead, and explanations
obscure, some of them are incomprehensible, Russian impatience with detail
plus frequent technical faults in printing and presentation exacerbate the
problem. Last but not least, the steps involved in assembling the Russian
sources after half a century of war, purge, and revolution would, if described,
read like a detective story. Yet the extraordinary quality and range o f the
Russian data on peasant society make its study an illuminating and worth
while exercise, for all the difficulties involved.
1 See Chapter 6, section (e).
2 In fact many of the research workers of the local authorities (zemstvos) embarked on
their studies as a direct result of being banned, because of revolutionary activities, from
living in big cities and from holding university posts. Others volunteered for this work
out of commitment to the populist or the socialist causes.
INTRODUCTION 5
The limits o f the period and of the geographical area of this study were
determined, at least in part, by the data available.1 This choice, nevertheless,
does cover a most significant period of Russian rural history (1910-25 and,
in particular, the years 1917-25) and broadly corresponds with that likely to
be chosen on the merits of subject-matter alone. The geographical area con
centrated on covers the main rural regions o f European Russia, which con
tained more than three-quarters of all Russian peasants and can be considered
as representative o f the Russian peasantry as a whole. The delimitation of
data in terms o f both time and space has not, however, been approached with
rigidity. Consequently, some data deriving from other periods and regions
have been presented when they seemed to be illuminating. On the other hand,
the generalizations reached should prove to some extent valid for other
periods and areas, and, particularly, for the whole o f the first three decades
o f this century and for all rural Russia, the Ukraine, and Belorussia.
The present study consists of three main parts plus Appendices. Part I
serves to provide the introduction necessary by examining what were the
major problems, strains, and alternatives facing Russia and the position of
the peasantry in Russian society. It then presents the social structure o f the
Russian peasantry, focusing on its specific characteristics. This part may be
omitted if the general background is already known without affecting the
cohesion o f the further argument. Part II attempts a systematic examination
o f socio-economic differentiation and of the mobility of the peasant households.
It concentrates on the phenomena o f multidirectional and cyclical mobility
among peasant households, their causes and their significance for the power
relations and political sociology o f Russian rural society. Part III then analyses
Russian rural society in terms of classical political sociology, i.e. in terms o f
conflict and power relations between the major social groupings of the village.
It does so by examining aspects of the agrarian revolution o f 1917-19, and by
analysing the major groups and group relationships within Soviet rural society
prior to collectivization. The discussion is summed up in Chapters 6-7 and
9-10 concluding Parts II and III respectively. The various parts o f the study
are, to some extent, independent and, at times, touch on issues broader
than the specific topic o f this book. It is hoped, however, that a unity will be
seen to emerge—the basic theme o f sociological investigation o f Russian
agrarian history which may contribute to the more general analysis of the way
a peasant social structure actually operates.
Before the present study could proceed, preparatory work had to be done
in order to fill numerous gaps. Two of these ‘pre-studies’ have been included
as Appendices. Appendix A makes explicit the author’s general framework of
analysis o f peasant social structure and political action. Appendix B provides
an exposition o f the inheritance customs of the Russian peasantry, expand
ing what is discussed in Chapter 2, and providing additional explanations
1 See Chapter 4, sections (a), (b), and (c).
6 INTRODUCTION
o f the evidence examined in Chapters 5 and 6. The Bibliography lists the
sources used.
The limits to our knowledge of peasant social structure are evident in the
way current concepts are often underdeveloped and ambiguous. On the
whole, the concepts which have been used in this field have been transferred
uncritically from the analysis of a qualitatively different urban capitalist
society and, time and time again, they have acted as blinkers rather than
sources of illumination. The English language (unlike the Russian) adjusted
long ago to an urban setting and a market economy and has therefore often
proved recalcitrant. In an attempt to break free from ‘bewitchment by our
own language* terms have had to be invented, modified, and at times adapted
from the Russian; these may sound unconventional, at least to the English
reader. In so far as additional clarity has been gained by these inelegancies,
such a procedure has seemed justified, for ‘although the invention o f new
language symbols by itself would achieve little, it is certain that, without
it, no headway could be made at all’.1 To try to offset some o f the conse
quent inconveniences a number o f figures have been introduced, and a short
Glossary o f terms used has been added.
The conclusions reached in this study are necessarily o f a tentative nature.
During research, the need to investigate a number of additional issues became
particularly evident. A study of the dynamics of peasant wealth, including
such elements as enrichment, capital-formation, etc., badly needs to be under
taken. The external economic relations of the peasantry (as expressed in
taxation, rent, terms of trade, etc.) and the social significance o f these also
need to be studied. The peasant budgets described in Chapter 4 would provide
illuminating basic material for such investigations. Large-scale studies o f the
political activity and consciousness of peasantries are also needed; again,
existing data are a potentially rich source o f information. Most important,
comparative studies of peasant socio-economic mobility on the lines suggested
by the Russian scholars should be urgently taken up in contemporary
‘developing societies’ in which the issues involved are crucial for the realistic
planning of socio-economic change and growth. When these have been done,
the issues raised in the present study will need to be re-examined in a widened
framework of evidence and in the light of the analytical insights o f our
generation.
1 W. Baldamus, ‘Notes on Stratification Theory’, Discussion Papers, University o f Bir
mingham, Faculty o f Commerce and Social Science (1967), no. 5, p. 23; for discussion see
also pp. 22 and 24.
PART I
T able i -i
(abs.) (% o f 1900)
Lyashchenko (and presented in part in Table I •I above) form the basis o f the
majority o f contemporary studies of Russian economic growth. Yet Lya-
shchenko’s key summary table1 fails to reveal the full extent o f the problem of
relations between agriculture and industry. He presented the 46 per cent rise
in grain production 1899-1913 as his only index of agricultural growth, dis
regarding the fact that the year 1913 was marked by an untypical bumper
harvest, and without relating, in his crucial table, economic growth to the rise
in population. Furthermore, the increase in grain production was due to a
great extent to the ploughing-up of grazing land; this, in fact, led in turn to an
increasing shortage o f fodder. Livestock production, which was estimated by
Goldsmith to account for a quarter of the total production of Russian agri
culture, actually decreased in per capita terms during the period.2 The over-all
results could not be much influenced by agricultural production other than
that o f grain and livestock which accounted for nine-tenths of the total value
of agricultural production.3 During the years 1900-13, the increase in the
production o f Russian industry was estimated at about 5 per cent per capita
per annum, while the increase in agricultural production was only slightly
ahead o f the rise in population.4 ‘The gap between the development of agri
culture and o f industry’, mentioned by Lyashchenko, the ‘discrepancy between
the industrial segment o f the economy which was forging ahead and the
relatively stagnant agricultural segment’, pointed out by Gershchenkron,5
was a crucial characteristic o f Russian economic development.
Analysis o f Russian economic history seems highly relevant to the recent
debates on contemporary ‘developing societies’. Social systems and economic
conditions never exactly repeat themselves—but identity is not, o f course,
a condition o f valid comparative analysis. During the period we are talking
about, Russia was a country with an overwhelmingly peasant population, less
than $100 per capita annual income, and a government pursuing industrial
izing policies in a world increasingly dominated by powerful industrial
societies. Does not all this sound familiar to every student o f the contemporary
world?
(b) A ‘Developing Society'?
In 1946 Timasheff published in London an extensive treatment of Russia
as a developing society.6 In a ‘mental experiment’, to use a Weberian term, he
examined and extrapolated forward the major trends in Russian development
between the 1890s and 1913. He concluded that, ‘if undisturbed’, Russia
would by 1940 have reached levels of industrialization, income, and education
1 Ibid., p. 395. r ,
2 Ibid., pp. 278-9. Khromov has estimated livestock as responsible for only 10 per cent
of the total agricultural production, which seems, however, a gross understatement.
P. Khromov, Ekonomicheskoe razvitie Rossii (1967), P* 513- Goldsmith, op. cit., p. 451.
3 Ibid., p. 453. 4 Ibid., p. 442.
5 Lyashchenko, op. cit., p. 408; C. Black (ed.), The Transformation o f Russian Society
(i960), pp. 50-1. 6 Timasheff, op. cit., p. 386.
i4 RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY
similar to if not higher than those reached under Soviet rule, a rule which also
‘threw back Russian philosophy and arts at least a century’.1 Far from being
a necessary breakthrough and a removal o f obstacles to development, ‘the
communist revolution has been a dangerous illness, but the Russians possess
enough vital energy to overcome it’.2 Rapid economic growth at the rates
achieved at the turn of the century he assumed to be self-perpetuating into the
future. The 1909-13 economic boom, clearly related to the extension o f the
internal market, has been treated as the turning-point to a ‘take-off’.
The time which has passed has not diminished the appeal of Timasheff’s
way o f thinking for some writers; in fact, a number of recent studies echo his
argument without, however, either referring to him or enriching his analysis.3
Yet the growth-prospects offered by Timasheff do seem surprisingly far-
removed from those o f the so-called ‘developing societies’ in the contemporary
world. During the last decade, both official reports and explanatory theories
concerning the socio-economic development of these societies have grown
increasingly alarming. Myrdal’s notion of the cumulation o f advantages and
disadvantages seems to put it in a nutshell.4 In an unrestricted market economy,
accumulated capital tends to produce further accumulation o f capital;
accumulated ability to produce makes for increases in productivity; the better
the educational facilities, the better the conditions for the growth o f new
educational facilities. And vice versa. Shortage o f capital, low productivity,
limited access to educational facilities, as well as political feebleness, will tend
to cumulate at the underprivileged pole of society, creating unending ‘vicious
circles’. Nor is all this the result o f some objective or natural economic laws;
the tendency towards cumulation rests on the power structure and existing
differences of interest in the world society. The ‘developing societies’ find
themselves in the position of feeble newcomers in a world very much divided
among crafty partners. Their infant industries are strangled as much by the
cheap mass-production of well-established industrial complexes as by the
conscious policies of the big powers. Both the rapid development o f substi
tutes and monopolistic controls drag down the prices o f the products tradition
ally exported by the developing societies. The catching-up process becomes
increasingly difficult as time goes by.5 It is the very existence o f the ‘advanced
world’ with its accumulated and accumulating advantages and bullying power
which stands in the way of the ‘developing societies’. A slow process of
economic growth and an increasing lag behind the ‘advanced’ industrial
countries results.
Was the Russian development at the turn of the century different in kind
1 Timasheff, op. cit., pp. 394-5.
N. Timasheff, ‘The Russian Revolution’, The Review o f Politicst 5 (1943), no. 4, p. 440.
3 See for example, V. Treml (ed.), The Development o f the Soviet Economy: Plan and
Performance (1968), and in particular G. Warren Nutter’s contribution (pp. 290-6).
4 G. Myrdal, Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions (1957).
5 C. Furtado, Development and Underdevelopment (1967).
RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY 15
from the contemporary experience o f the ‘developing societies’? How far are
Timasheff’s projections into the future valid and what can we learn from
Russia’s actual economic growth? Does pre-revolutionary Russian develop
ment offer a key to the most significant o f contemporary problems? The
answers can possibly be found, on the one hand, in the contemporary analysis
undertaken by some o f the development economists (in particular, by Baran,
Furtado, and Frank1) and, on the other hand, in the history o f Russia’s
western neighbour, Germany. The historic performance of the entrepreneurial
middle classes, the early capitalists o f Western Europe, does not seem to be
repeated in other conditions; if ‘undisturbed’, ‘developing societies’ gravitate
towards backwardness and poverty, regularly associated with parasitic elites
and military regimes.2 However, between on the one hand the lucky first-
comers—those nations and societies which benefited from the early develop
ment o f capitalism and the exploitation of colonies—and, on the other hand,
the colonized peoples, who form the mass o f today’s ‘developing societies’,
a third intermediate group can be distinguished. This third group seems to
consist o f those countries which reached the threshold of industrialization and
capitalism somewhat later than the first-comers, yet did not have their econ
omies distorted by conquest and colonization. They could benefit from the
industrial experience already gathered, learning from their predecessors’
mistakes and even avoiding some of the limitations imposed by pioneer
development, while as the world market had not yet been fully established,
the intervention o f the more advanced economies could be kept in check. The
U.S.A. would head this list, though it is not wholly typical since placed in
particularly favourable conditions. In fact the spectacular advance o f England
at its peak repeated itself in the U.S.A. at a higher level o f capital accumulation
and technological advancement. It lacked established pre-capitalist social
structures and traditions, had large ‘empty’ territories (i.e. scarcely populated
or populated by peoples who could be exterminated), was far enough away to
eschew Europe’s political tensions, and yet was close enough to benefit from
its market and experience. Such conditions made the U.S.A., as early as the
First World War, into a creditor o f Western Europe, now outstripped.
The other members o f the third group seem to be Germany, Japan, and
Russia, with the latter at the bottom of this list in terms o f achievement and
dynamism.3 In spite o f the differences in conditions and history in these three
countries, all show marked similarities as far as the basic issues and aims
o f government policies are concerned.
Nineteenth-century Germany managed to escape the road o f cumulation
o f disadvantages by virtue of the powerful interventions o f the Bismarckian
1 Ibid.; P. Baran, The Political Economy o f Growth (1957); A. Frank, Capitalism and
Underdevelopment in Latin America (1967).
2 For examples see S. Andreski, Parasitism and Subversion (1966), or R. Dumont, False
Start in Africa (1966).
3 See for comparison Goldsmith, op. cit., pp. 474- 5-
8214936 C
16 RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY
state which ensured rapid industrialization.1 Such development there neces
sitated a government powerful and aggressive enough to link radical develop
ment policies with an at least partial removal of internal social obstacles and
a degree o f control over foreign pressures and the impacts of the world market.
In this period, the Russian government consciously attempted to follow ‘the
German path’. Bunge, Mendeleev, Witte, Stolypin, Kokovtsov—a succes
sion o f brilliant finance ministers and prime ministers—professed policies of
directed economic development, government intervention, and thorough
going support of native industrialists.12 The whole of the economy was power
fully influenced by the Russian State Bank—which ‘differed from European
banks by being financed mainly by government resources’.3 The policy of
increasing the national debt figures as the source o f the ‘financial well-being
at the roots o f the development of industrial capitalism’.4 Government
policies facilitated high profit margins in industry, low wages, and the skim
ming o f agricultural returns for the sake of urban capital formation.
Russia’s opportunities for rapid economic development were better than
those of today’s' developing societies’ in several ways. Firstly, the rise in world
prices of foodstuffs and, in particular, of grain, Russia’s main export product,
had ensured a constantly positive balance of payments and favoured increases
in agricultural production.4 Secondly, Russia had not just recently emerged
from a colonial past; the powerful and highly centralized Russian state was
able both to mobilize resources and—at least to some extent—to check
foreign political and economic pressures. Two further factors (which seem,
however, less decisive) relate to Russia’s extensive territory: first, the Asiatic
parts o f the country played, at least to a limited extent, the role o f an amalgam
o f British India and the American Wild West, i.e. o f an exploited colony and
o f an ‘open frontier’;5 second, the very size and potential wealth o f Russia
could be considered as an additional preferential factor (one should, though,
recall Indonesia or Brazil of today, which are large and potentially rich yet
actually immensely poor and slow in economic growth).
Yet, the chances o f conditions favourable to the socio-economic develop
ment of Russia persisting were anything but good. In economic terms, Russian
growth was very much dependent on a positive balance o f payments, while
more than 50 per cent of the value of exports, in 1913, was made up o f food
stuffs and only 5 per cent of manufactured goods.6 Yet from the early 1920s
the terms o f trade were increasingly unfavourable to primary products and
1 For a discussion see, for example, F. F. Clairmonte, Economic Liberalism and Under
development (i960), chapter 10.
2 Lyashchenko, op. cit., pp. 387-93, 408, 414-17. Black, op. cit., pp. 47-61, 211-23.
3 Khromov, Ocherki, pp. 94-5.
4 Lyashchenko, op. cit., pp. 386-8.
5 In fact Russia has also tried to imitate ‘Western’ economic imperialism in its relations
with its southern and eastern neighbours (Persia, China, etc.). Khromov, Ocherki, pp. 230-1.
6 Bolshakov and Rozhkov, op. cit., vol. iii, pp. 13-15.
RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY 17
specifically to foodstuffs.1 The period of war seems to have provided the only
substantial exception and, in our century, as Atallah puts it, ‘except under
specific conditions, the long-term movement of the terms of trade between in
dustrial and agricultural products will be against agricultural products’.12 This
will also hold good for the more broadly defined primary products/secondary
products division. The basic determinant of Russia’s positive balance of pay
ments and the ‘booster’ o f the internal market and of production was, there
fore, on the point o f an extended downward turn.3
At the same time Russian economic development was very much conditioned
by the policy o f encouraging foreign investment and by the increasing foreign
debts o f the government. Indeed, it was said that ‘without the influx of foreign
capital the development o f Russian industry would be impossible’.4 Lya-
shchenko estimated foreign investments during the period 1898-1913 at 4,225
million roubles (of which 2,000 million roubles consisted of state loans).5 By
1914, the total foreign capital invested in Russia was said to be 8,000 million
roubles, which included foreign ownership o f up to two-thirds o f Russian
banking, extensive foreign ownership of mines and other enterprises, large
state and municipal debts, and so on.6 The costs of the war more than doubled
foreign debts.7 In post-First World War conditions, Russia would have had to
face an inevitable crisis o f payments abroad with the necessity of contracting
further loans just to pay off the old ones and foreign dividends. Foreign
investments and exports would probably be increasingly insufficient to meet
the growing obligations and needs of economic development and to secure
self-perpetuating and rapid economic growth.8
Furthermore, the prospects for Russia’s economic development must be
viewed in the broader framework of the interaction between state policies
and the economy. The ability o f the Russian state to outweigh the effects of
cumulated economic backwardness was very much the crux of the matter and
determined future possibilities. Yet the power o f the Tsarist state was clearly
diminishing. From a first-class power in the first half o f the nineteenth century,
Russia had deteriorated, by the turn of the century, into a second-class force
1 M. Atallah, The Long-Term Movement o f the Terms o f Trade between Agricultural and
Industrial Products (1958), pp. 3-4, 7-9, 12-13, 72-9. P. Lamartine Yates, Forty Years o f
Foreign Trade (1959), pp. 38-45, 62-72. 2 Atallah, op. cit., p. 79.
3 For the unfavourable impact o f such change in the terms of trade on the economic
position o f the contemporary ‘developing societies’ see the letter of the leading British
economists in The Times, 29 October 1957, and estimates, ibid., pp. 3-4.
4 Evaluation by the prominent Russian economist Tugan-Baranovskii as quoted by
Gordon, op. cit., p. 353. 5 Lyashchenko, op. cit., p. 385.
6 Khromov, Ocherki, pp. 134, 144. Half of the foreign debt is said to consist of the state
loans, 1,200 million roubles of the guaranteed railway loans, 700 million roubles of muni
cipal debts, and the rest in private investments (ibid., pp. 147-8).
7 Khromov, Ocherki, p. 148; Lyashchenko, op. cit., p. 644.
8 For elaboration o f possible negative results o f such economic trends and dependences
see, for example, proceedings o f the Delhi Conference o f the seventy-seven poorer members
o f the U .N . reported in the Observer, 28 January 1968.
18 RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY
both politically and militarily. Externally, military defeats in the war against
Japan in 1904-5 and against Germany during the First World War both signalled
and contributed to this growing weakness. Internal contradictions and revolu
tionary pressures operated in a similar way. Far from being ‘undisturbed’
the political, the economic, and every other aspect of life in Russian society
oscillated violently under the impact o f external turbulences and internal
contradictions. The First World War tended to strengthen these processes and
led both to increasing dependence on foreign capital and to increasing politi
cal and military influence on the part o f the senior members o f the Entente
over Russia. Given a build-up o f post-war crises and an increasingly doubtful
ability on the part o f the Russian government to dominate, control, exploit,
and mobilize resources, predictions by extrapolation o f the trend o f socio
economic development between 1900 and 1913 seem anything but prudent.
In fact, both unreserved acceptance and total rejection o f Timasheff’s
extrapolation would seem to oversimplify a highly complex situation. The
socio-economic development of Russia in this period was very much a race
against time with the results very much in the balance. The possibilities lay
between rapid industrial development and recovery o f political momentum,
before the growing power of the world’s leading states made this less probable,
and further deterioration. Consequently, the future could be either a German-
style rapid economic advance to join the club of the dominant ‘advanced’
societies, or a cumulative political and economic decline to the status of
‘another China or India’, a society shaken by increasing internal contra
dictions and, at least temporarily, an easy prey to powerful foreign imperial
ists.1 Yet the economic gap between Russia and the industrial societies was
increasing. Between 1861 and 1913, the economic growth o f Russia in per
capita terms was somewhat below the average for Europe; about half the
figure for Germany, two-fifths of that for the U.S.A., and one-third o f that
for Japan. The economic position o f Russia by 1913 in comparison with those
countries had actually become more unfavourable than in 1861.12 Even a
revolution could not, ipso facto, force Russia out o f this set o f alternatives
created by the development of the world society.
The race against time imposed by world socio-economic processes made
crucial the potential stumbling-blocks and delaying factors in the process of
catching up with the West. The conservative character o f the Tsarist political
regime and state machinery time and time again was charged with such a
negative influence. Foreign economic domination was probably developing
into another such factor. A major obstacle to rapid socio-economic change
and political reform was, moreover, built into the very fabric o f Russian
society—in the single fact that more than four-fifths o f the population were
peasants.
1 D obb’s comparison between Russia and India may be of interest here (op. cit., p. 11).
2 Goldsmith, op. cit., pp. 442-3, 474-5; also Khromov, Ocherki, p. 398.
RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY 19
1 The first article of the Russian General Statute of Emancipation. See G. T. Robinson,
Rural Russia under the Old Regime (1949), PP- 65, 80-9.
2 In the 1858 census 107 million mature males were listed as ‘private serfs’ and 12-8
million as ‘state serfs’ (including direct serfs o f the Imperial family), ibid., p. 63. Gerschen-
kron, however, has estimated the ‘private’ serfs to be 53 per cent of the total in the time of
emancipation; A. Gerschenkron, Continuity in History (1968), pp. 153, 198-206.
3 See Chapter 2 and Appendix A below.
4 Entsiklopedicheskii s l o v a r op. cit., add. vol. iv/D, p. xix.
5 Ibid., p. 1. For a discussion o f the non-peasant rural population see Chapters 2, 9,
and 10. 6 S. Dubrovskii, Stolypinskaya zemel'naya reforma (1963), p. 410.
7 Narodnoe khozyaistvo SSSR v tsifrakh (1925), p. 105.
8 Even some of the traditionally peasant land (otrezki, etc.), was taken over by nobility
in this process Robinson, op. cit., chapter v.
20 RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY
exists in some o f the developing societies today) did not result in Russia. The
nobility owned hardly any land in northern and Asian Russia and only a
limited amount in the south east. More important, the Russian nobility failed,
on the whole, to take up the challenge of modern capitalist production. By
1913, about half o f the land belonging to the nobility at the time o f the
emancipation had been sold, mainly to peasants.1 Half the remainder was
rented out, once more to the peasants.12 In 1914-15, only about a tenth of all
the land sown in Russia belonged to the estates, some o f which were still being
run as traditional manors with lands worked by peasant labour (otrabotka),
on the basis of various share-cropping arrangements and as part o f the
essentially peasant economy. The nobility, moreover, owned only 5 per cent
o f the livestock.3 The big landowners participated in the rural economy
through peasant payments of rent, etc., rather than by large-scale production.4
The Stolypin reforms of 1906-10 attempted to create a powerful new
stratum o f wealthy peasants engaged in capitalist farming.5 ‘Private’ peasant
land (i.e., not the commune holdings) was bought to a very large extent by
this group, which also benefited from enclosures and showed, at least in some
areas, higher yields per acre and higher incomes.6 Yet, by 1913, the number
of Russian peasant households which were not only wealthier but had evolved
into agricultural enterprises run on capitalist lines was still very small.7 Russia’s
agriculture operated mainly in the framework of traditional family farms
typical of peasant agriculture, with some islands of modernized estates and
capitalist farms, relatively small yet somewhat more important as producers
for the market.8 The growth of the production for export o f butter in Western
Siberia seems the only case of a regional break-through to a full-scale market
and money economy within the Russian peasant agriculture.9
The poverty o f Russia was very much the poverty o f the Russian peasant.
In 1913 only half o f Russia’s national income was produced by her agriculture,
which engaged more than two-thirds o f the national labour force.10 Low as
the income per capita was in towns, it was still more than double the figure for
the countryside. Exclusion of the estates and of the thin upper crust of peasant
farmers who had done particularly well would, no doubt, reveal even lower
standards of per capita income for the peasant majority o f the Russians.
Furthermore, a three times greater annual variation in yields than that
1 Robinson, op. cit., pp. 131, 262; see also A. Anfimov, Rossiiskaya derevnya v gody
pervoi mirovoi voiny (1962), p. 37; see also Chapter 3, section (b), below.
2 Anfimov, op. cit., p. 44.
3 Ibid., p. 280, also see A. Chelintsev, Russkoe sel'skoe khozyaistvo pered revolyutsiei
(1928), pp. io- i i . 4 Anfimov, op. cit., pp. 152-5.
5 For elaboration of the Stolypin reforms see Chapter 2, section (b); Chapter 3, sections
(a), (b), and (c).
6 See further discussion in Chapters 2, 3, 4, and 8. Also Dubrovskii, op. cit.
7 Ibid., p. 469. Robinson, op. cit., pp. 238-42.
8 Dubrovskii, op. cit., p. 469. Robinson, op. cit., pp. 238-42, 260-1.
9 Yates, op. cit., p. 84. 10 Khromov, Ekonomicheskoe, p. 498. The figures are for 1913.
RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY 21
observed in Germany and the United Kingdom revealed itself in the course of
frequent years o f famine, which were particularly disastrous for smallholders.1
The socio-economic differentiation of the countryside had introduced a
variety o f conditions and incomes among peasant households—a process
which will be discussed below. Even so, the peasantry was more remarkable
for the depth o f its general poverty than for the extent of its differentiation.
‘The basic reason for the lowness of the average standard of life in Tsarist
Russia was the low production of agriculture, which constituted the livelihood
o f four-fifths o f the population’.12 Dobb’s remark stresses one o f the major
determinants o f the poverty of the peasant majority and consequently o f the
people o f Russia. For example, Russia’s yield o f wheat per acre during the
period 1909-12 was less than one-third of that in Britain and less than two-
fifths o f that in Germany.3 Other branches o f agriculture showed similar
weaknesses. Moreover, yields on peasant allotments were even lower than
those reported on ‘privately-owned land’.4 Supplementary incomes from
peasant crafts and trades (promysly) were relatively low and home crafts are
said to have declined under the pressure of cheap industrial goods.5 Low
productivity and income in peasant agriculture led to numerous ‘vicious
circles’ in which poverty bred poverty; low incomes and limited credit blocked
capital formation and serious chances of improvement via rises in produc
tivity. For example, Russian farmers used, per acre, about five per cent of the
chemical fertilizer used in Germany and one-twelfth of that used in Britain.6
Complex agricultural machinery barely existed. The 1910 census reported a
lack o f basic equipment in 34 per cent of peasant households and a total lack
o f horses in 30 per cent of peasant households.7 ‘In this grain-growing country’,
comments Robinson, ‘the existence of millions of farms without work-animals
is a fact which assaults the imagination with suggestions of every sort of hard
ship’.8
Contrary to widely held beliefs, the average size o f peasant allotments in
Russia was not much lower than the typical size o f farms in Germany or
France.9 It was rather the ‘prescientific and premechanical level of agriculture’
which led to an ‘acute sense o f population- and land-hunger’.10 ‘Russian
agriculture . . . combined in many parts of the country and in several of its
most important branches, the disadvantages of small-scale operation and
large-scale, and often absentee ownership; and showed at the same time the
becoming somewhat more diversified, 92*3 per cent of the area sown was
accounted for by grain.1 At the same time livestock increased at a much
smaller rate and actually decreased in per capita terms. In such circumstances
even a modest increase in income per capita could be doubted as far as the
majority o f Russian peasantry are concerned.
Secondly, agricultural exports were increasing considerably, partly on
account o f the production of estates and capitalist farms but probably mainly
as a result o f the traditional Russian policy of ‘we shall undereat but we will
export’—which under the Russian conditions of taxation and grain marketing
meant undereating by peasants and exporting by profiteers.2 In spite of the
expanding external trade money exchange was still fairly limited among the
Russian peasants. In 1913, the trade turnover per capita in Russian towns was
twenty times higher than that in the villages.3
Thirdly, between the emancipation of the peasants and the First World
War, the land held by the peasants was considerably extended. The additional
land was brought into cultivation by ploughing up grasslands, by colonizing
new land, and, even more, by buying and renting land which had belonged
to the nobility. Simultaneously, peasant emigration to the towns, and
colonization in the east o f Russia, was removing from the countryside about
a third o f the natural increase of the peasant population.4 Yet peasant
population growth was outrunning the growth of land in peasant hands: the
average size o f peasant holdings dwindled.5
Fourthly, capital accumulation in agriculture and investment in equipment
and agricultural improvements were limited, and their influence on production
could not have been substantial. The percentage rates of increase in the use of
chemical fertilizers and agricultural machines, and in the spread o f more
sophisticated types o f agricultural techniques, etc., were spectacular, yet the
very low absolute figures revealed the reason for this—barely existent take-off
points.6 At the same time livestock, the traditional form o f accumulation of
peasant wealth, decreased in per capita terms. Capital formation in agriculture
was kept in check by the general poverty o f the peasantry, was diluted by
population growth, and was skimmed off by those at the top o f the power
structure o f Russia. The peasantry carried a heavy burden o f state expenditures
and o f forced capitalist development in the towns, while participating to a
very limited extent in the benefits of the Russian ‘economic miracle’. The
Russian peasantry not only was poor but also constituted the major exploited
1 Ibid., Sbornik statistiko-ekonomicheskikh svedenii po seVskomu khozyaistvu, p. 59.
2 Ibid., pp. 321, 336. Lyashchenko, op. cit., pp. 283-5. The quotation taken from a speech
by a Russian minister of state, Vishnogradskii, in the late nineteenth century (Lyashchenko,
op. cit., p. 282). See also P. Lyashchenko, Russkoe zernovoe khozyaistvo (1927), pp. 274,
291, 320-1.
3 Khromov, Ekonomicheskoe, p. 218.
4 See Chapter 5, section (d), below.
5 Dubrovskii, op. cit., pp. 29-30, 415; Robinson, op. cit., p. 194.
6 See, for example, Anfimov, op. cit., pp. 60-9.
24 RUSSIA AS A DEVELOPING SOCIETY
class which, to a great extent, paid the bill for the spectacular development
o f the urban economy.
Finally, the national processes of economic growth described above resulted
in a variety of changes in which the mass of the peasant households found
themselves involved. A rapid process of socio-economic mobility was
going on; it will be discussed in detail later. There was large-scale migration.1
An increasing penetration of market and money relations into the villages,
a growing national educational system, army service, and village-to-town
migration were producing an increasing urban impact on peasant life. At the
same time, peasant immigrants formed urban enclaves o f worker-peasants
in every city o f Russia; they transferred to the towns both elements
o f peasant social structure (e.g. the artel'—the typical commune-type gang
o f peasant artisans and temporary workers) and peasant poverty (by increas
ing unemployment and keeping down wages, standards o f housing, and the
level o f literacy).
The national indices of socio-economic growth and the projects o f develop
ment in Russia have to be set against the fact of an overwhelmingly peasant
population. Even doubling the wages of industrial workers would have
influenced national income and the major pockets o f poverty but little. Even
total literacy in towns could have left three-quarters o f the nation illiterate.
And so on. The impact o f even the most spectacular achievements o f the urban
economy was diluted at times to the extent of one-sixth by rural backwardness.
For example, Goldsmith points to the fact that the 3 5 per cent rate o f per
capita growth of Russian industry was very high by international standards—
yet, in spite of it, Russia fell behind the Western countries simply because
of the high proportion of agriculture in its economy ‘which, in virtually every
other country, grew much less rapidly than the rest o f the economy’.2 On the
eve of the First World War the peasant majority o f the population was grow
ing into a major bottleneck for Russia’s economic and social development.
Further industrialization in towns called for an expanding internal market,
skilled mobile labour, increasing capital investment and productivity;3 the
Russian peasantry emerged as a braking factor on all o f these. However, the
peasantry was not only the poorest, the most exploited, and the most oppressed
part of the Russian population; it also lived within distinctive structures of
social interaction.
1 For discussion of the generic features o f the peasantry in different countries and periods
see, for example, R. Redfield, Peasant Society and Culture (1956).
2 V. Mukhin, Obychnyi poryadok nasledovaniya krest'yan (1888), p. 151.
3 Novyi entsiklopedicheskii slovar\ Brokgauz and Efron, 2nd edition (1913), vol. xviii,
p. 519.
4 Quoted from A. Chayanov, The Theory o f Peasant Economy (1966), p. 54.
P E A S A N T H O U S E H O L D A N D P E A S A N T S O C IE T Y 29
family lines, and basic identification of the member with the household.1
Consequently, one who joined the household through marriage or adoption
(primaka, viazen) was considered a member with full rights, while a son of
the family who set up a household on his own was viewed as an outsider.
The peasant household operated as a highly cohesive unit of social organ
ization, with basic divisions of labour, authority, and prestige on prescribed
family lines. Generally, the head of the household was the father o f the family
or the oldest kin-member. His authority over other members and over house
hold affairs implied by peasant custom both autocratic rights and extensive
duties o f care and protection. The household was the basic unit of production,
consumption, property holding, socialization, sociability, moral support, and
mutual economic help. Both the social prestige and the self-esteem o f a peasant
were defined by the household he belonged to and his position in it, as were
his loyalties and self-identification.
Women, in spite o f their heavy burden of labour (both housework and
fieldwork),2 and their functional importance in a peasant household, were
considered second-class members of the community, and nearly always placed
under the authority o f a male.3 However, even the equality o f male members,
accepted in principle, should be considered in the framework o f a patriarchal
structure, involving extensive rights o f the head over his household. The strong
cohesion o f the family and the family property meant submission and lack of
any tangible property for junior male members.4
‘The life o f a family is the life o f a farm.’5 A typical peasant farm in Russia
in the period under consideration was a small agricultural enterprise (2-6
desyatinas or approximately 5-15 acres o f sown land),6 based on centuries-old
agricultural techniques and types o f equipment.7 Grain-growing dominated
both peasant field production and diet.8 The Russian peasant economy
1 The word ‘traditional’ is used here in the wide sense adopted by M. Weber, The Theory
o f Social and Economic Organisation (1947), pp. 324-423, as the conceptual opposite of
‘rational-legal’. See also N. Birnbaum, ‘Conflicting interpretation o f the rise of capitalism:
Marx and Weber*, British Journal o f Sociology (1953), PP- 125-41.
2 For example, a study o f a typical peasant timetable in the 1920s has shown that a
peasant woman spent nearly as much time on ‘productive work’ as the male peasant (1,905
versus 1,935 hours per annum) but at the same time spent much more time on housework
(2,229 versus 622), which led to as much as one-third more work, in terms of time spent, by
a woman than by a man. See A. Bolshakov, Sovremennaya derevnya v tsifrakh (1925), p. 100.
3 As expressed in the peasant saying, ‘A crab isn’t a fish and a woman isn’t a person’ (Rak
ne rybay baba ne chelovek). There were, however, some exceptions as far as widows were
concerned. For a discussion see Appendix B, section (c), below.
4 For a discussion of family property see further parts o f this section; also Appendix B,
section (b). 5 N . Makarov, Krest'yanskoe khozyaistvo i ego interesy (1917), p. 71.
6 The average area o f sown land per household rose moving from the north to the south o f
Russia. The average for the south was more than 6 des. per farm and the production o f grain
for the market was also much more advanced. For further discussion see Chapter 7 below.
7 Mainly variations o f the three-field system o f land use, dependent on a traditional
communal crop rotation and in the majority o f cases on the horse-drawn sokha. See
V. Aleksandrov (ed.), Russkie (1967), pp. 17-99.
8 V. Den, Kurs ekonomicheskoi geografii (1925), pp. 188, 211.
3o PEASANT HOUSEHOLD AND PEASANT SOCIETY
displayed strong tendencies towards autarky characteristic of* pre~industrial
rural societies. The scope o f market relations was limited by largely consump
tion-determined production objectives, low rates of surplus, limited use o f
money, and a low level of professional specialization among and diversification
o f the rural population.
The household’s production activities primarily consisted o f strenuous
efforts by its members to make ends meet—i.e. to feed the family and to meet
dues and taxes. Serious rural underemployment (both total and seasonal) was
partly tempered by peasants’ supplementary employment in crafts and trades
(promysly); competition with growing urban industry was made possible by
natural exchange and desperately low earnings. ‘When the brief agricultural
season did not yield a living for the peasant family, the work for less than
subsistence through the long winter months was better than to be altogether
idle—and perhaps to be buried in the spring.’1 However, the main occupation
o f Russian peasants consisted of performing a wide variety o f rather non
specific tasks combined to make up what may be called traditional farming.2
Peasant family life was the main form of occupational training for the younger
generation, while tradition acted as the main occupational guide. The con
sumption-determined aims, the traditional methods o f production, the use
o f family labour, the low marketability of the product, and the lack o f check
ing and control in money terms by systematic book-keeping made the peasant
household a production unit very different from a ‘rational’ capitalist enter
prise. Nature was, in addition, a major determinant o f peasant economic life.
The smallness o f peasant resources magnified its impact. The difference
between a good agricultural year and a very bad one was the difference be
tween prosperity and famine, if not death. If it was family history which
determined, to a great extent, the development of a farm, it was the modes and
seasons o f traditional farming which prescribed the pattern o f everyday life
of the peasant family. The nature and development o f the family made for
a peculiarly deep-rooted cyclical rhythm o f life on the peasant family farm.
Family property was the major legal reflection o f the character o f the
Russian peasant household. Unlike private property, family property limited
the rights o f the formal owner (khozyain); he acted as the head administrator
o f the property (bol'shak) rather than as a property-owner in the sense current
outside peasant society.3 An extreme expression of this feature was the legal
possibility and actual practice of removing the head o f a household from his
1 G. T. Robinson, Rural Russia under the Old Regime (1932), p. 104. The meaning of
‘subsistence’ was, of course, far from absolute and varied between areas, households, and
periods.
2 For example, as late as the census of 1926, 95*3 per cent of the working population of
the Russian countryside named ‘farming’ as their only or main occupation. Statistiche-
skii spravodmik za 1928 g . (1929), p. 44- For an analysis of the peasant’s occupation see
B. Galeski, Chlopi i zawdd rolnika (1963).
3 For example, in the contemporary Russian Civil Code, which was, however, limited
to the non-peasant minority o f population. See Appendix B, section (a).
PEASANT HOUSEHOLD AND PEASANT SOCIETY 3i
position in some cases o f ‘mismanagement’ or ‘wastefulness’ and appointing
another member o f the household instead. On the other hand, unlike in cases
o f group property, participation in family property did not assume any
definable shares o f the property or the profits except in terms of rights to share
in collective consumption.
The peasant proceeded through certain prescribed stages; childhood, pre
marital adolescence, marriage, becoming a head o f one’s own household, and,
eventually, retirement and death. Only by becoming a head o f a household
was it possible to rise to the full status of a man within the peasant com
munity. The only alternative road to self-emancipation for the peasant
involved his leaving the peasant community altogether by emigration.1
Marriage became, in these conditions, ‘an absolute postulate’2—a crucial pre
condition o f social maturity necessitated by the character o f the farming.3 The
very existence o f a peasant household necessitated the existence of a farm, i.e.
some property expressed in holdings o f land and equipment. The passing of
property from one generation to another was therefore a major issue of every
day peasant life and peasant customary law.4
Within the framework o f family property, the very notion of inheritance as
developed in non-peasant societies failed by definition to appear. The passing
o f property from generation to generation did not necessarily involve the
death o f a parent and was approached legally as a partitioning o f family
property between its members. Partitioning (or apportionment to set up a
junior male) was, in fact, frequently carried out before the death of the head
o f the household—corresponding closely with the growth of nuclear families5
and their requests for independence. The head o f the household took the
decision (partly established by custom) as to when to partition his farm, when
to make apportionment to a son, and when to retire. Partitioning led, on the
whole, to an equal division o f household property between all its male
members.6 In cases o f the death o f all male members o f the household, the
property was generally taken over by the peasant commune.7
A typical new household would therefore begin as a young couple with a
few young children, on a small farm. The farm would consist of a limited
1 For a discussion see Chapter 5, section (d), below.
2 An expression taken from a classic study o f another peasant society; W. Thomas and
F. Znaniecki, The Polish Peasant in Europe and America (1958), vol. i, p. 107.
3 This explains the early age o f marriage typical of the Russian peasantry. See I. Pisarev,
Narodonaselenie SSSR (1962), p. 178.
4 For a full discussion of inheritance under Russian peasant customary law see Appendix
B, sections (a), (c), and (d), below.
5 i.e. a family consisting of parents and their children.
6 Russian peasant law made an exception for an individual female’s property, which
could include cutlery, cloth, etc. This ‘female property* was, in fact, the only private property
in the peasant household and could consequently be left by will and/or unequally divided.
For an elaboration see Appendix B, sections (b) and (c), below.
7 In some areas a blood-relation or a woman could inherit household property if no
male members of a household remained alive. See Appendix B, section (c), below.
8214936 D
32 PEASANT HOUSEHOLD AND PEASANT SOCIETY
amount o f land, one or two horses, and a little equipment shared out from or
by a ‘maternal’ unit in the process o f partitioning.
The growth o f the family created additional consumption pressures. The
head o f the new household tried to expand his farm and income by buying or
renting additional land and equipment and, at times, employing his family’s
labour in crafts and trades (promysly). The growing-up o f children gave
additional labour to the farm but also created new consumption needs and
problems o f employment. It also posed the problem of providing a dowry for
daughters and equipment for setting up new farms for sons, which required
apportionment. After each such apportionment or sometimes upon a partition
ing following the death of the head o f the household, the same cycle started
over again on a new small farm managed by a new young couple.
The Russian state’s policy before 1906 supported the stability and cohesion
o f the peasant household by imposing on it collective responsibility for the
payment o f taxes and dues and for the ‘good behaviour’ o f its members, in
addition to its many other functions. The state also legally confirmed the
head o f the household’s wide disciplinary powers over its members.1 Stolypin’s
policy, after 1906, greatly reduced the legal powers of heads o f households over
their members12 while, at the same time, in many cases making heads o f house
holds into unlimited owners of household property. From the turn o f the
century, moreover, the impact o f the capitalist developments in urban Russia
had been felt increasingly in the countryside. However, a decade o f Stolypin
policy had failed to produce a decisive change in the social character o f the
Russian countryside—at least as far as peasant households went. Capitalist
farms (or even farms well integrated into the market economy) remained, on
the whole, exceptional.3 The revolution and civil war o f 1917-21 swept away
the Stolypin reforms and re-established the essentials o f nineteenth-century
peasant customary law. Yet even the impact of the revolution on the character
o f peasant households was modest.4 The Russian peasant household retained
its basic characteristics during the whole o f the period under review.
1 Robinson, op. cit., p. 66. Until 1906 the head o f the household could, on the whole,
have a member o f his household arrested, sent back to his village under escort, or flogged,
by simple application to the peasant court.
2 For a further discussion see Appendix B, section (d), below.
3 This broad generalization would not hold true for some regions— in particular for the
less densely populated south and some of the guberniyas o f the north-west, though it did
remain valid for the majority o f the Russian peasant population.
4 For a further discussion see Appendix B, section (d), as well as Chapters 5, 8, and 10
below.
PEASANT HOUSEHOLD AND PEASANT SOCIETY 33
system o f accepted norms and values, and by the consciousness o f being
distinct from other groups delineated on similar lines.1 High self-sufficiency
should be added as a major characteristic of a traditional peasant community.12
Pitt-Rivers’s description o f a ‘closed community’ as based on habitual per
sonal contact, wide endogamy, homogeneity o f values, emphasis on strict
conformity, intense group solidarity, marked ideological egalitarianism, etc.,
is a fair generalization o f the cultural traits of peasant communities.3 Com
munity o f descent and relatively low territorial mobility, primary personal
contact and lack o f anonymity, low division o f labour and simple co-operation
seem to underlie the high cultural cohesion of rural communities. Common
political and economic interests find their expression in at least some rudi
mentary elements o f local authority, administering common affairs and
representing the community to outside authorities.
Yet actual village life is far from being a rustic haven o f equality, stability,
and brotherly love. Redfield’s classical descriptions o f a conflict-free rural
community o f Tepoztlan4 were disproved by Lewis’s study5 and further de
mystifications have followed.6 The village community is highly cohesive but,
at the same time, it is diversified into different and conflicting groups and
factions. These diversities and conflicts in no sense express some temporary
social pathology; rather, they play a vital part in village life and are decisive
for understanding its social structure and dynamism.7 Furthermore, the rural
community has to be treated in its historical setting. The relative stability of
the entity does not preclude change and development as the results of both
internal and external forces. The development o f a market society has been,
on the whole, the most crucial determinant o f structural changes in rural
communities.
Rural communities seem to display differences in specific national character
istics to an extent which far exceeds the differences between peasant house
holds in different cultures. In fact, the heated argument about the peasant
commune (obshchina or mir) made it into the best-known feature o f the pre
revolutionary Russian countryside. A typical peasant commune o f the main
1 The share of commune land turned into the private property o f heads o f households
after 1906 was 14 per cent of the total in 40 gub. of European Russia in 1915, but ranged from
less than 5 per cent in the north and south-east to more than 50 per cent in the Ukraine and
Belorussia. See Dubrovskii, op. cit., pp. 574-6.
2 This law abolished commune land property in all peasant communes which had not
undergone a full-scale land-redistribution since the emancipation. About 2 million house
holds would have been affected.
3 A. Anfimov, Rossiiskaya derevnya v gody pervoi mirovoi voiny (1962), p. 71.
4 Or, as R. Redfield has put it, describing the peasantry as a phenomenon: it is ‘a type
without localisation—not a typical anthropological community’. See his Peasant Society
and Culture, p. 25. 5 ibid., p.169.
PEASANT HOUSEHOLD AND PEASANT SOCIETY 39
and countries. The major dualism conceptualized by social scholars in notions
o f ‘mechanical’ versus ‘organic’ solidarity (Durkheim) community versus
society (Tonnies), brotherhood versus competition (Meine), etc., expresses, in
fact, a basic typological difference between peasant and urban societies.1 The
specific character o f peasant social structure is determined by the peculiarities
o f its basic constituent units: the household and the rural community. The
peasantry can be defined as small producers on land who, with the help of
simple equipment, their own labour, and that of their families, produce
mainly for their own consumption and for meeting obligations to the holders
o f political and economic power, and reach nearly total social self-sufficiency
within the framework o f a village community. A wider definition would have
to include analysis o f specific features: traditional agriculture as the main
occupation, the social characteristics of the family production unit, the impact
o f life in small, relatively stable, and ‘closed’ communities, relative stability of
pre-industrial cultural traits, the underdog political position in society, and
a distinctive typology o f change.12 The peasantry entered the contemporary
world as the major representative of pre-industrial social formations in a world
differently structured and increasingly dominated by urbanites. The spread of
the market and o f money relations, growing specialization in performance of
occupational tasks, the improvement of communications, state-sponsored
education, etc., led, in Europe, to structural changes in the character of
the main rural social units and to their closer integration into national urban-
centred societies. By all these yardsticks, the Russian peasantry remained,
during the period under discussion, at a relatively low level o f advancement.
Specific characteristics o f peasant society can be seen in all the major
spheres o f social interaction. The relatively high self-sufficiency of peasant
households and communities results in a general tendency in peasant societies
towards segmentation into units o f high similarity and low mutual interaction.
In the economic sphere, traditional values, consumption-oriented aims in
production, and the use o f family labour grossly restricted the impact o f the
drive to maximize money profits as the determinant of production. The major
concepts o f classical economics throw relatively little light where traditional
peasant economies are concerned.3 In fact, peasant economic action can at
1 For a discussion of the significance o f this major dualism o f sociological concepts see
P. Sorokin and C. Zimmerman, Principles o f Rural-Urban Sociology (1929), chap. 2. Also
see Appendix A , section (c), below.
2 For an attempt in this direction see Appendix A, sections (a) and (b), below. For further
discussion of the subject see T. Shanin, Peasants and Peasant Societies (1971), Intro
duction.
3 For example, the division of peasant incomes into wages, rent, and profit seems to have
little real or analytical value. For a discussion see Chayanov, op. cit. Even Marx remarked
that ‘with parcellated farming and small-scale landed property . . . production to a very
great extent satisfies own needs and is carried out independently o f control by the general
rate o f profit* (Chayanov, op. cit., p. 222). The edition o f Capital published by Kerr seems
to obscure the issue. See K. Marx, Capital (1909), vol. iii, p. 943.
4o PEASANT HOUSEHOLD AND PEASANT SOCIETY
times be better understood in terms o f economic ‘constraints’ rather than in
terms o f a market-oriented tendency towards an economic optimum. Yet all
that did not mean lack of drive for betterment on the peasants’ part. The
‘irrational’ peasant behaviour was logical in a qualitatively different system of
social organization and values. For example, partitioning which could lead
to a decrease in productivity in the newly created households made sense in so
far as higher value was placed on the independence and prestige gained by the
head o f the new household than on economic success and profits. The specific
characteristics o f peasant economy should of course, be seen historically, i.e.
in relation to increasing penetration o f market economy into the rural society.
To take an example from another sphere, peasant political activity was marked
also by specific characteristics such as tendencies towards vertical segmenta
tion, localization, spontaneity, and so on.1
Peasant communities showed also clearly distinguishable cultural patterns—
both results and determinants o f characteristically peasant peculiarities. These
cultural patterns2 determined a way o f life and coloured the peasants’ basic
attitudes, their perception of the world, their values and the meanings they
attached to social reality.3 Deep traditionalism (i.e. justification o f action in
terms o f the past), conformism (i.e. justification o f action in terms o f the will
o f the community), basic egalitarianism, particularistic and diffuse human
relationships, and on the whole, the setting o f a high value on landholding and
the inviolability o f the patriarchal family have been expressed in peasants’
customs and rules all over the world both as rationalizations and justifications
o f the present and in dreams o f a better future.4
The Russian peasantry showed the basic generic features o f a peasant
culture described in this section. The prevalent system o f values derived from
similar roots and is to be understood in terms o f the characteristics o f basic
units o f peasant social structure and their development as discussed in the
sections (a) and (b) o f this chapter. The so-called ‘non-rationality’ o f peasant
economic action (i.e. its not being geared to the sole aim o f maximizing
money income) was closely related to the character of the peasant household.
The communal cohesion, the powerful conformity and tendency to justify any
action in terms o f the communal will (po vole mira), was reinforced by the
specifically Russian forms of the communes’ organization. The attitude to
land— as serving essentially consumption purposes (kormitel)—meant that it
1 The concept o f vertical segmentation will be elaborated in Chapter 9 below. See also
Appendix A.
2 The term ‘cultural patterns’ is used in the sense defined by C. Wright Mills in Power,
Politics and People (1962), p. 406: ‘the lens of mankind through which men see; the medium
by which they interpret and report what they see*. For a discussion see P. Berger and
T. Luckman, Social Construction o f Reality (1967).
3 See the discussion by H. T. Fei in R. Bendix and S. Lipset, Class, Status and Power
( 1953), P. 32.
4 i.e. both ‘ideology’ and ‘utopia* in the terms o f K. Mannheim, Ideology and Utopia
( 1949).
PEASANT HOUSEHOLD AND PEASANT SOCIETY 41
should not be approached as property in the usual sense. The basic attitudes
to justice, as expressed by legal customs and the decisions of peasant courts,
were marked by their subjectivism1 and egalitarianism; they were determined
by overriding concern for the interest o f communal cohesion; the satisfaction
o f the minimum needs of every family and the maintenance of good neighbour
hood relations were valued more highly than impartiality.2 The image o f the
peasant millennium o f the just society frequently appeared as ‘Vselenskii M ir\
i.e. as a grandiose peasant commune which would include all the people of
Russia, or o f the entire universe. However, the increasing impact of market
relations resulted in growing conflict between traditional society and the new
values and patterns o f social organization of an urban society and its competi
tive economy.
The studies o f Russian scholars provided for extensive if uneven know
ledge o f rural Russia, some of which is summarized above. Yet an analysis of
the basic characteristics o f the social structure and dynamics o f the Russian
peasantry in the period under discussion is a very different thing from a
comprehensive collection o f generally accepted ‘facts’. On many o f the major
issues, the most essential evidence was either dubious or simply lacking.
Furthermore, much o f the collection, selection, and interpretation of evidence
was inseparably linked with the major ideological and political issues o f con
temporary Russia and can be understood only in such a context. The most
important controversy which, for a period o f as long as half a century,
divided Russian scholars and politicians, related to the socio-economic
differentiation o f the Russian peasantry, and its implications for the future of
Russia.
1 Expressed in the tendency o f the peasant court to pass judgement either ‘according to
the man’ (po cheloveku) or ‘according to conscience* (po sovesti), by which the personality
o f those involved and the social implications o f the judgement carried more weight than
objective circumstances or legal precedent. See Mukhin, op. cit., p. 311.
2 Which would account for the typical tendency o f the peasant court ‘to divide the sin by
half’ (delit' grekh popolam)— to resolve by division o f property rather than to pass judge
ments totally in favour o f one side, ibid., p. 311.
PART II
CYCLICAL MOBILITY
3
THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE
One feature of the history o f old Russia was the continual beatings she
suffered for falling behind, for her backwardness. She was beaten by the
Mongol khans. She was beaten by the Turkish beys. She was beaten by the
Swedish feudal lords. She was beaten by the Polish and Lithuanian gentry.
She was beaten by the Japanese barons. All beat her— for her backward
ness; for military backwardness, for cultural backwardness, for political
backwardness, for industrial backwardness, for agricultural backwardness.
She was beaten because to do so was profitable and could be done with
impunity . . .
That is why we must no longer lag behind . . . We are fifty or a hundred
years behind the advanced countries. We must make good this distance in
ten years. Either we do it, or they crush us.
j. s t a l i n , Speech t o Managers o f Industry
1 ‘Majority’ is, if anything, too weak a word for a group which still amounted in 1913
to as much as 84 per cent o f the total population. See Chapter 1 above.
2 Entsiklopedicheskii slovar\ Brokgauz and Efron (isted n ., 1907), vol. xxx, pp. 911—13.
3 Novyi entsiklopedicheskii slovar', Brokgauz and Efron (2nd edn., 1913), vol. xiv,
pp. 4° 4“ I2‘ Members were elected on the basis o f a discriminatory electoral law. For
example, in the election to the third Duma in 1907 one member was elected for every 230
landowners (mainly noblemen), for every 60,000 peasants, and for every 125,000 workers.
BoYshaya sovetskaya entsiklopediya (2nd edn.), vol. xii, p. 287.
THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE 47
as social groups with a broad unity of major political and economic interests,
shaped by conflict relations with other classes and expressed in the growth of
specific sub-cultures, self-consciousness, and tendencies to common action.
‘The history o f hitherto existing societies’, moreover, ‘had been the history of
class struggle.’1 The character of Russian society, as well as the mechanism
and agencies of change, were to be defined accordingly and related to assumed
social ends. Stolypin decided ‘to place the wager not on the needy and drunken
but on the sturdy and strong’—on the emerging capitalist farmers— ‘called
upon to play a part in the reconstructing of our Tsardom on strong monarchi
cal foundations’.2 The Liberals took capitalist development and the rise in
strength o f the urban middle classes for granted as the path o f constitutional
evolution. To the Marxists, the inevitable Western-like rise o f capitalism
would lead, through increasing social polarization, to the once more inevitable
proletarian revolution and a better civilization. To all three schools of thought,
the differentiation o f the peasantry was vital for their most sacred plans. The
process o f differentiation was to produce the class which would be called upon
to dominate and ensure a better future, be it the protective wall of monarchist
farmers, the camp o f middle-class respectability, or the proletarian revo
lutionary army. On the other hand, the Populist faith in peasant revolution
presupposed the ability o f peasant cohesiveness to withstand capitalist dif
ferentiation. Consequently, the future of Russia was seen as dominated by the
peasantry—the class representing the majority o f the nation. The features of
Marxism and Populism discussed above formed, together with varying degrees
o f revolutionary voluntarism,3the hard core o f Russian revolutionary ideology.
Far from being limited to purely academic considerations, therefore, the
peasant differentiation debate was reflected in the central questions o f political
evaluation, prediction, and action. The socio-economic differentiation of the
peasantry—i.e. the extent of diversity in wealth o f peasant households and the
consequent stratification by wealth o f the Russian peasant population—was
held to provide the main explanations for peasant political consciousness and
action. Judgements about the extent of the differentiation process were crucial
for the basic political decision-making of both the government and its enemies.
T able 31
Peasant Households in European Russia by Size o f
Average Land-Allotment, 1905 a
Households
Land-allotment per
household (des.) (000) (%>
T able 311
Peasant Households in European Russia by
Horse-Ownership, 79/2°
See Svavitskii, op. cit., pp. 185-327, and V. Knipovich: K voprosu o differentsiatsii
russkogo krest'yanstva (1912).
2 V. Den, Istochniki vazhneishikh otraslei khozyaistvennoi statistiki SSSR (1929), p. 22.
THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE 51
the countryside made itself felt. In 1916, a national rural census was carried
out for the first time since the end o f the previous century. It was repeated in
19 17 —already in the midst o f revolution.
1 The Ts.S.U. was formally established by the Soviet Government on 25 June 1918.
A department specifically for rural statistics was established in the Ts.S.U. only in 1920
(Volkov, op. cit., pp. 275-6).
2 Den, op. cit., pp. 32-9.
52 THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE
standardization in methods of collecting and analysing statistical data made
valid comparisons possible. The repeated large-scale censuses for the first time
made it possible to draw reliable conclusions about mobility in a peasant
society.
T able 3*111
The Estimated Differentiation o f the Russian Peasantry, 1913 a
Stratum % o f households
Poor peasants 65
Middle peasants 20
Kulaks^ 15
All strata 100
The October 1917 revolution and the civil war which followed led to almost
total state control of the urban economy and to the redistribution o f land in
the countryside. The severe politico-economic crises o f the civil war resulted
in a rapid decline in production, the disintegration o f rural urban market
exchange, and the flight o f townsmen to the countryside. Only the end of
the civil war and the introduction of the New Economic Policy in 1921 led to
a gradual recovery o f the economy.1
The development of differentiation-processes in peasant society during
revolution and civil war was made apparent in Ts.S.U. studies, comparing
the differentiation o f peasant households in the census o f 1917 with that in
similar samples for 1919 and 1920. Sown area and horses per household were
adopted as the main indicators of peasant wealth.2The data for 1917 and later
years are compared in Tables 3*iv and 3*v.
These figures show a steep rise in number of households and an actual
decline in total land sown and in number o f horses. A powerful aggregate
shift downwards had consequently been taking place accompanied by a
strong levelling process, which seems to have been a manifestation o f agrarian
revolution. Yet, as revealed in Table 3.VI the degree of inequality still
remained high in the newly created Russian Republic (R.S.F.S.R.), and
especially in the agricultural south and in Siberia.
1 For an outline of this see Chapter 8 below.
2 For a discussion of indicators of peasant wealth see Chapter 7, section (c), below.
THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE 53
The introduction o f the New Economic Policy (N.E.P.) in 1921 marked the
beginning o f the recovery o f agriculture, though this did coincide with
a serious famine in some o f the important agricultural areas. Both these
phenomena found reflection in the pattern of socio-economic mobility as
presented on p. 56.
T a b l e 3*iv
A. By land sown
horses owned
Source. Ekonomicheskoe rassloenie krest'yanstva v J917 i 1919 gg. (1922), Tables on pp. 10-
11, 20-1.
Note. a The tables are based on a study o f the same villages in the two years. The villages
were selected from 25 gubemiyas and were considered to constitute a representative sample
of the peasantry of European Russia. For names of gubemiyas studied see Source, p. 2.
54 th e d iffe r e n tia tio n d e b a te
The figures reveal a slow aggregate upward shift in all the major regions
except those hit by famine, in which a sharp aggregate downward shift,
T a b l e 3*v
A. By land sown
% o f households
Land sown per
household (des.) 1920
1917
None io *6 4*7
Not more than 2 30*4 47*9
2* 1-4*0 30* 1 31*6
4*1-10*0 25-2 15*3
More than 10 0 37 0*5
B. By horses owned
% of households
Horses per
household 1917 1920
coupled with levelling, took place at the same time. The famine of 1920-2 had
a particularly marked effect in the areas which, as late as 1920, had displayed
a high degree of differentiation; this made the subsequent levelling all the more
spectacular.
c/> «
■O o
0 £° "S ■&
£
f " co oo on co o
Io o
O<- 8
•G C
O n co O VO co CO OO OO
O p £
*N ,9 «o3
CO
Os
s: 4> Cd Tt o o c-i (s r - 00 o
•S o o
go J>
<< c
& la On 00 o co co f
c
cd
2> 3
o
a
i iCd|o
pq ctf
On 9
r* <
r^
S- C
9 C °°P r* 'P
-itO00
—« co 6 6 o6
C* 9
w .a
-3
OQ 1 p H p h O nVO O n CO 9
< NOVONt^wcciOO 6
H
■*«»»
ed
NO 90 Nj- On VO
o £W
h b
>—
.o u< g
1** "cd
•2
On f" 9 7* co
I C^ obob 6 c» 6
u £ 11
4
<u *o 10 VI? N C">-> o
JZ
o oSn ob vo « co 6 6 6
£ (t>
(PA £ *J
o
JZ
<4-1 T f ON ~ lio -
o
I I
jo t>
o.;§
is
o x;
o
Z «d
v) £ souo^S
T3 2! o S yQ 2 T V 9 *p
C- I I I 5
S§ y ^ r T<<*
r voo N~ o~ ^< p
-J .C a a n H
56 THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE
T a b l e 3*v i i
Households in
Land
sown grain-deficient grain-surplus zone grain-surplus zone
per with no famine hit by famine
zone
household
ides.) 1920 1922 1920 1922 1920 1922
Development proved to be much slower in terms of horses per household (even a decline
was noted in one year— 1925) but the direction of development was very much the same as
that recorded in terms of sown area.
THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE 57
followed what had been the stormiest period of Russian rural history plus a
fully fledged agrarian revolution.1 Though lack of fully comparable data does
not permit detailed comparisons to be made, the 1925-6 stratification of the
peasantry would not, after all, seem to have been very different from that in
1917, in spite o f the generally acclaimed immense levelling during the period
o f the agrarian revolution.
T a b l e 3* v i i i
Households
Land sown per
household (des.)
1922(A) 1923(A) 1924(B) 1925(C) 1 9 2 6 (0
B. zstock ownedb
Households
Workstock
per household 1922(A) 1923(A) 1924(D) 1 9 2 5 (0 1926(C)
T able 31X
Lenin's Stratification o f the Rural Population o f European Russia, 1905
Land per
holding (des.) Holdings
Social stratum
Range Average (Min.) (%)
At the opposite extreme, Oganovskii, a decade later, was still to doubt the
very existence o f differentiation among the Russian peasantry, if measured
in per capita terms.3 In his view, the available figures on differences in the
1 For example, Puti seVskogo khozyaistva, no. 8, p. 116, or A. Gaister, ibid., p. 128, and
again in Na agrarnom fronte (1927), no. 11-12, p. 11.
2 For example, N . Sukhanov, Puti sel'skogo khozyaistva, no. 6-7, p. 140.
3 For example, the studies by A. Gaister of stratification estimated on the basis of budget
studies, Rassloenie sovetskoi derevnii (1928); or V. Nemchinov’s study o f incomes from
entrepreneurial activity in the Urals region, lzbrannye proizvedeniya (1967), vol. i, pp. 44-120
(first published in 1927).
4 See Trudy pervoi vsesoyuztioi konferentsii agramikov-marksistov.
62 THE DIFFERENTIATION DEBATE
While heated political debates and world-shattering revolutionary events
went on, important conceptual developments were taking place, laying the
foundations for new answers to old and new questions. An increasing number
o f Russian scholars departed both from the essentially deductive and specula
tive attitude o f the ‘Grand Theories’ and from orthodox empirical or de
scriptive methods. An attempt was made to approach the issues involved by
reconceptualization at a lower level of abstraction, and to adopt new methods
o f investigation—in a way which would have been classified by today’s
sociologists as the development of ‘theories of middle range’. As a result, new
types o f evidence were amassed. Far from bearing only on the Russian past,
these methods may well prove to be of contemporary value, for the major
issues o f the Russian differentiation-debate arise for the majority o f mankind
in the so-called ‘developing societies’ of today.
The most important of the conceptual and methodological developments
discussed was, no doubt, the focusing of research on the peasant household
as the main unit for statistical study.1 It was this increasing interest in peasant
households which led to new methods o f study, new questions being asked,
and essentially new types of data being sought.
This promising development in methods of research and analysis was
initiated by the statistical departments of some o f the more advanced
zemstvos. The revolution brought with it the appointment o f some o f the best
zemstvo statisticians to senior positions in the Ts.S.U. The research methods
developed in the zemstvos were now transferred into the Ts.S.U. and used on
a national scale. As a result, these Ts.S.U. studies supplemented the census
evidence with an additional body of data of a character and a scale still unique
throughout the world. After a short description of the findings related to
correlations characteristic of the Russia peasantry, of family size and eco
nomic positions, we shall proceed to examine the two major methodological
novelties developed by zemstvos and subsequently adopted by Ts.S.U.— ‘budget
studies’ and ‘dynamic studies’.
1 It was the 1887 Conference o f Russian Statisticians which declared that the peasant
household (dvor) was the major unit o f peasant society and that consequently future
statistical surveys should be focused on it (see Volkov, op. cit., p. 80). The slowness with
which this new attitude penetrated actual statistical studies is well worth specific investiga
tion in terms of relations between realities o f peasant life and of the consciousness o f ‘the
educated*.
4
POLARIZATION AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
From the point of view of the science of statistics, the zemstvo statisticians
achieved far more than the whole Russian statistical establishment. New
paths have been broken through by the work of the zemstvo statisticians
. . . substantially diverging in almost every respect from West European
models. The zemstvo statisticians constructed a tool, unique of its kind,
for studying the life of the peasantry, such as no other country has at its
disposal.
Russian encyclopaedic dictionary on the eve o f the First World War
T able 4-1
Size o f Households by Amount o f Land Sown
Kaluga Gub., 1897a
T able 4*11
Size o f Households and Number o f Horses Owned by Amount
o f Land Sown (Ts.S.U. Census, 1925)a
Less than
0*1 30 0*0
0*1-20 4*0 1*2 0*3 o *5
2* 1-4*0 5*4 2*7 0*5 o*8
4* i-6*o 6*6 46 o *7 ro
6 * i-io o 8*o 7*2 o *9 1*2
101-16*0 9*5 12*4 i *3 L5
16*1-25*0 99 18*8 i *9 i*8
More than
25» 9*8 33*3 34 2*5
Total 5-3 3*2 o*6 o*7
T able 4-111
Socio-Economic Differentiation o f the Peasantry in Saratov Gub.,
1927
T a b l e 4 * iv
Source. F. Shcherbina, Krest'yanskie byudzhety (1900), pp. 112, 115, 190, 198-9.
Notes. a The table is based on a study o f peasant budgets carried out by Shcherbina and
his assistants. The main part o f the budgets were taken during the 1893-6 period. The
methodology of this study was generally adopted as a model in later studies carried out in
various zemstvos. The sample covered 230 households.
6 N o information about land sown is available. Voronezh gub. in this period had a
relative abundance of land under extensive cultivation.
c The average number of workers per household was closely correlated with the average
number of members per household (see Source, p. 216).
d Property was defined as buildings, livestock, agricultural and domestic equipment,
furniture, and items o f dress.
e Income in kind was estimated as 54 8 per cent total, ranging from 19*3 per cent for the
landless, to 58-4 per cent for the wealthiest stratum (see Source, p. 216).
could account for considerable push for ‘rapid development’. (For a dis
cussion on this see Chapters 5 and 6 below.) In fact, the possibility that the
majority o f peasant households would have shown closely similar levels of
income during some periods o f post-revolutionary Russian history cannot be
excluded. Progressive taxation would reinforce such a tendency. In the
conditions o f the increased pressure of anti-kulak measures after 1927, some
studies even reported the lowest (or even negative) accumulation in the biggest
households.1 However, such a situation was exceptional. On the whole, the
post-revolutionary budget-study results, as exemplified in Table 4-v, fol
lowed the pre-revolutionary correlation patterns, i.e. they showed a clear
tendency towards the cumulation of economic advantages and disadvantages
in peasant households.
In the light o f the evidence of the budget studies, the social mechan
ism underlying the differentiation-processes among the Russian peasantry
could be, and by numerous scholars was, viewed within the framework of
1 See, for example, M. Sulkovskii, Klassovye gruppyi proizvodstvennye tipy krest'yan-
skikh khozyaistv (1930), pp. 169-70.
to
1 O-S.
■ o c
oo p n
6 cn
ttoo
on
u,
O
G
o 8J
TO
3 o & H
£ ■s
p ^ N ' f N O 00
o
o w I c
I
c The value of capital, income, and accumulation was estimated in pre-revolutionary gold roubles.
< &£ p
P
k~
u
Co W P
? <4_ o
s: O 40
3
p Q <5 2
o •G m r - Tf so tj- !-• 00
So 6
r> so so r - TT
£ 8 Tf Tf so so so vn
o>
s: •S
•S o
«- £
•S 9. r - r - p O so
a u. _§ 6 n Co 6 f" N
0 *5 c r^ o o os m OS £
£ a 2 p TO 2
I G W
*N k. p C4 N d - 6 rn r - WO C
§ <N
U
O 0) O
C .4 3
O 0 0 0 0 m Os tj-
<s is m m vn m
Os f .§ 5 *
r—
T3 u * s § !
§ a" £ '£ 00 G o S
• <L> .c 2
^ r r 9 ^ 'f
i^ .§<5j
15 S On vn r f ro On so
m osvo n Tj- & §5
•^r § s &i
uO
W O w
»nvo os ~ so oo —
~
TJ*
C ^
o
l
•J
•- *5
«s
OS TO~ ncd
-r *** 73
o y
w O X3 m
5 * J5
e
O on
43 .C | •&■§ a
5 “
2 2
G O 3§ m -rj- in m i2 5 . £ p
? > ! !
^ » a 2
^ T3
oo c5 2c/5
1 g g P £ G
c 43 O m <s o
X) 4/5 O
> *-> . O O
Os Os oo Os OO S3 c £H S3
£ < 8 . r f Co so r - oo to
o . £
o OVD O
8
IS
*»»
00
2 c o Os o s o oo s o <-.
a ^*2
■° d g
£ * ^ 5 o s o s oo sn 1 </5 „ >
»-> rn -<T SO Tf
■*«* < 8 S^ 0 8 2
Co on . c> 1 I H
00 TD 8 •§
« w 2
.£ g 00
00 s £ 8 3
- § ° | «s 8 8 8 i= ‘*5
I h <« (d
u. r t 3 *. s' ^
o8c s r r S l O r- ^
o cd § p
. — >> o fto o o ° =s o
C/3 43 So c* Tfsb 2 00 Z o
POLARIZATION AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY 71
textbook economic theory and the doctrines o f economic determinism.1
The differentiation-processes could be explained simply in terms o f the
advantages o f the bigger and wealthier households over the smaller and
poorer ones, resulting in cumulative polarization. After the reversal due to the
extra-economic factor of agrarian revolution in the years 1917-19, the cumu
lative polarization should once more have resumed its pace, even if tempered
by the generally low level o f capital-accumulation in agriculture and the
egalitarian policies o f the Soviet regime. However, such a simple explanation
is shaken by the results of what were called ‘dynamic studies’ of peasant
households.
(c) Dynamic Studies and the Mobility o f Peasant Households
Statistical data published by the Russian government before the revolution
tended to present the peasantry and the agriculture of the country (or o f any
region) as wholes.2 The introduction o f the use o f categories representing
various socio-economic strata revealed illuminating correlations between the
socio-economic differentiation o f peasant households and some basic aspects
o f peasant life.3 Furthermore, it permitted the identification of socio-economic
mobility within peasant societies by comparing peasant differentiation in
consecutive years.4
However, the recorded changes in the differentiation of peasant society did
not fully express the extent o f the socio-economic mobility of peasant house
holds; for instance, the economic rise of a thousand households counteracted
by the decline o f another 800 may be recorded merely as a rise o f 200, while,
in fact, 1,800 units have experienced socio-economic mobility. It was the
attempt to reach behind the gross data on peasant societies and/or socio
economic strata and to analyse the mobility o f individual peasant households
which brought ‘dynamic studies’ into being. This development of statistical
methodology clearly reflected a conceptual change related to the increasing
interest in peasant socio-economic differentiation as well as to increasing
awareness o f the importance of households as the basic units o f peasant
society. Dynamic studies involved tracing the individual histories o f peasant
households and analysing them statistically as mass data. The essential features
o f this method may be illustrated by the hypothetical example given in the
following Table 4*vi.
The basic data analysed by a dynamic study included information about the
socio-economic position of each household at the beginning and at the end of
1 See Chapter 3, section (c), above.
2 For example, the highly instructive Sbornik statistiko-ekonomicheskikh svedenii po
sel'skomu khozyaistvu Rossii, published annually from 1908 to 1917.
3 See, for example, the peasant censuses and budget studies introduced by the zemstvo
statisticians and after 1916 adopted by the government (Tables 4*1,4-11,4-111,41V, 4*v above).
4 See Tables 31V, 3-v, 3-vn, and 3-viii above. As a matter of fact, in many cases, Russian
scholars embarked on the obviously erroneous path o f assuming differentiation-processes
from the existence o f differentiation per se. For a discussion see N. Chernenkov, K kharak-
teristike krest'yanskogo khozyaistva (1905), p. 101.
72 POLARIZATION AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
the period studied, and some further information about changes which had
taken place in their internal structure during the same period.1The households
were classified by socio-economic stratum at the beginning o f the study. At
the next stage, every stratum was treated as a unit and the socio-economic
position o f each o f its households at the end of the period was recorded in
figures or percentages in the appropriate columns ( A A i . A B l , A C i ; B A i ,
B Bi, B C i ; etc.). The figures in squares A A i, B B i, C Ci (25, 265, and 15)
indicate, therefore, the households which had not changed their socio
economic position in terms of the strata as defined. The other figures represent
households in various degrees of ascending or descending mobility.
T ABLE 4- vi
Simplified Hypothetical Dynamic Study o f a Community,
1900-1910a
Number o f households
Socio-economic 1910
stratum
Ai Bi Ci
1900 Poor Middle Rich
T a b l e 4 - vi i
(d) The Mobility o f Peasant Households and the Mobility o f Peasant Society
Before proceeding to analyse the various factors influencing the mobility
of peasant households and to try to draw conclusions in the form o f an
1 Similar processes were observed in other peasant societies— see, for example, M. Yang,
A Chinese Village (1945), p. I32,P. Stirling, Turkish Village (1965), chap. 7, and I. Ajiami,
‘Social Classes, Family Demographic Characteristics and M obility’, in Iranian Villages,
Sociologia Ruralis, ix (1969). See also for centripetal trends M. Nash, ‘Indian Eco
nomies’, Social Anthropology (1967), pp. 93-101.
POLARIZATION AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY 77
explanatory model, let us recapitulate, in a more formalized and general way,
the essential relationship between the mobility of peasant households and the
mobility of peasant society (see Figure iii ). Such a summing-up, self-evident as
it may seem, may help us to clarify the problems arising from trying to under
stand differentiation-processes in peasant societies. It will also pinpoint the
issue o f the causes o f mobility among peasant households.
The mobility recorded for a peasant society as a whole is a net balance of
the oscillations o f its component peasant households. The forms of mobility
of peasant households display a practically unlimited heterogeneity and can
be analysed in a variety o f ways, two o f which are presented here as the most
important for our discussion. Those studying regularities in the mobility of
peasant households have tended to stress ascending and descending trends—
i.e. the enrichment and impoverishment of peasant households—those trends
o f which the informed public was most conscious. An analysis in terms of
centrifugal and centripetal movements is more appropriate to a study
o f differentiation-processes. These different analytical approaches do not, o f
course, express a different reality; the extent of the mobility of peasant house
holds will not change whatever method of analysis is adopted (£ = a + b =
c + d in the following Figure).
Figure in. Peasant Socio-economic Mobility: Peasant
Society and Peasant Households a
A. The M obility o f Peasant Societies and Peasant Households b
ir
w 60
to
.a
a
a
•3
c s .a
o <o 8
< Q Q
a <3
V Y
The aggregate shift upwards o f the peasant The aggregate shift downwards o f the
society (a l-f) = a —b peasant society (a l—) = b —a
The total number o f peasant households in The total number o f peasant households in
which mobility occurs j8 = a + b which mobility occurs P = a + b
The number o f households affected by The number o f households affected by
mutually cancelling mobility (a + b )—(a —b) mutually cancelling mobility ( a + b ) —(b —a)
= 2b = 2a
ji
cd cd
60 3 cd
a o. 3
a
U U O U
c *X3 0
V Y
The polarization of a peasant society (a ll-f ) The levelling o f a peasant society ( a l l—) =
= c —d d -c
The total number of peasant households in The total number o f peasant households in
which mobility occurs p — c + d which mobility occurs p = c + d
The number of households affected by The number of households affected by
mutually cancelling mobility ( c + d ) —(c—d) mutually cancelling mobility ( c + d ) —(d—c)
— 2d = 2C
POLARIZATION AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY 79
The general exposition of the interrelationships between mobility o f peasant
society and mobility o f peasant households contained in Figure h i , Part A
is expressed diagrammatically and in a quantifiable form by Parts B and C.
Knowledge o f the ascending and descending mobility of peasant households
enables conclusions to be drawn about the character and size o f the aggregate
shift in a peasant society and about the gross mobility of peasant households.
The knowledge o f centrifugal and centripetal tendencies away from and
towards the median (which can be envisaged as the middle household in terms
o f wealth in the given society) enables us to draw conclusions about the
character and the extent of the differentiation-processes in the peasant society,
as well as about the gross mobility of the peasant households in it.
The analysis in Part C of Figure in enables us therefore to identify the
two basic trends underlying the differentiation-processes in the peasantry.
Differentiation-processes are the resultants of the operation o f two major
tendencies—opposite in direction, different in strength, and generated by
what seem to have been different sets o f factors. Economic theory and the
empirical evidence o f the ‘budget studies’ lead us to accept, at least tenta
tively, the cumulation o f economic advantages and disadvantages as a major
generator of the centrifugal tendencies in the mobility o f peasant households.1
However, the centripetal tendencies evident in dynamic studies cannot be
explained in these terms. For this very reason, the evidence o f the dynamic
studies did not make sense to many economists, and tended to be dismissed
as doubtful, or, at least, as reflecting only a temporary and abnormal situation.
For example, Kondratev simply declared that the centripetal and cyclical
peculiarities o f peasant mobility reported ‘could not be a usual occurrence’.2
However, the increasing amount and reliability o f data made this ‘criticism
by shoulder-shrugging’ clearly unsatisfactory.
The focus o f the following discussion will turn, therefore, to the causes o f
centripetal mobility and the possible reasons for which peasant households
would move from being under the determining influence o f centrifugal forces
to being under the influence o f centripetal ones and vice versa. Such analysis
must go beyond the boundaries o f Neo-Classical economics and consider
broad issues o f the social structure and dynamics of peasant society.
To begin with, the land-redistribution practised by the Russian peasants
seems to have provided a manifest egalitarian wealth-redivision mechanism.
The extent of land-redistribution by the Russian peasant communes was never
fully recorded and may well have to remain for ever in the realm o f guess
work.3 The extent and frequency of land-redivision varied between regions and
even between different communes in the same locality.4 N o doubt, in some
1 Only further studies of a peasant economy and, in particular, of the problems of enrich
ment and capital formation could make it conclusive.
2 Puti sel'skogo khozyaistva (1927), no. 5, pp. 131-2.
3 G. Robinson, Rural Russia under the Old Regime (1949), PP- 121-2.
4 See Chapter 2, section (b), above and Chapter 8, section (b), below.
8214036 G
8o POLARIZATION AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
cases, land-redivision by communes would have accounted for a considerable
share of the centripetal mobility o f peasant households, or would even have
been the major factor responsible for it. Yet, for several reasons, it fails
to account for a major part of the centripetal (levelling) trend evident from
the dynamic studies.
Firstly, land-redivision by communes would have an egalitarian (centripetal)
effect on holdings o f commune land-allotments, though not, o f course, on
those peasant lands which were held as private property—which were particu
larly important in the case o f the wealthier households. The influence of land-
redivision on other categories of peasant wealth (ownership o f horses, capital
or equipment) could be only secondary. Yet powerful centripetal mobility was
observable in strata which held extensive private lands and in dynamic studies
stratifying on the basis of all the categories of peasant wealth (horses, capital,
etc.).1
Secondly, although, as has already been stated, the actual extent of land-
redivision by communes is far from clear, if we accept as realistic the legal
provisions about land-redivision (i.e. not to be carried out more frequently
than once every twelve years—this was at the end of the nineteenth century),12
or even allow for a shorter period, then the rates of centripetal mobility found
seem far too high to be accounted for by conceivable processes o f land-
redivision by commune.3
Lastly, and most importantly, large-scale centripetal trends were reported
in Belorussia where land-redivision by commune was practically non-existent.4
Land-redivision by commune could therefore be classified as only one o f
the possible determinants o f peasant households’ centripetal mobility, rooted
in the peculiarities of the social structure of the Russian peasantry. However,
yet another set o f factors affecting the centripetal mobility o f peasant house
holds and the levelling tendencies in peasant societies can be seen, also arising
out of the peculiarities of the peasant social structure and specifically o f the
internal dynamics o f peasant households. The Russian scholars working on
the dynamic studies identified them under the umbrella term ‘substantive
changes’ (organicheskie izmeneniya).
1 See, for example, Table 6*n below, or Nemchinov’s studies referred to in Chapter 6,
section (c).
2 See Chapter 2, section (b), and Appendix B, sections (a) and (b).
3 See Chapters 6 and 7. 4 See Table 71 below.
5
‘SUBSTANTIVE CHANGES’
In peasant life . . . family and farm appear as almost synonymous.
V. M U K H IN
T able 5-1
‘Substantive Changes’, Epifan' Uezd, 1899-1911
A. By Arable Land per Household
N o. o f Percentage o f households
Source. A. Khryashcheva, Krest'yanskie khozyaistva po perepisyam 1899-1911 gg. (1916), vol. ii, p. 38.
N otes, a This term covered both households which became extinct and those which emigrated with no intention
o f returning. O ther pre-revolutionary studies provided specific figures for extinction (see, for example, Table
5 'V in ).
b Included households which left the village to set up their own enclosed farm {khutor).
T able 5-11
‘Substantive Changes' in the Grain-Deficient Zone, 1924-1925?
T able 5-111
Households involved in ‘Substantive Changes', Surazh Uezd,
Chernigov Gub., 1882-1911
Households In 1882
which between
1882 and 1911: Av. no. of Av. no. o f Av. arable A v.n o. o f Females
members labour land per livestock per
per units'* household per males
household (des.) household6 (%)
T a b l e 5 - iv
Widows, old couples, and men without any family {bobyVs) were frequently
mentioned in descriptions of the poor households with high extinction or
merger rates. Indeed, study of the correlations o f various factors in peasant
economic life with rates o f ‘substantive changes’ led Prokopovich to conclude
that ‘The number o f male workers proves the strongest determinant of the
ability o f peasant households to survive’.1 Households without an adult male
lacked both the male labour crucial to traditional Russian farming and the
central figure o f husband and father of the patriarchal family. On the other
hand, a high number of adult male workers also meant the existence o f a large
number of nuclear families within the household, and this increased the proba
bility o f partitioning. Stratification by the number of mature male workers
per household proved particularly significant as exemplified in Table 5-v
on the next page.
T able 5*v
‘Substantive Changes' by Number o f Male Workers, Epifari Uezd,
Tula Gub., 1899-1911“
Source. A. K hryashcheva, Krest'yanskie khozyaistva po perepisyam 1899-1911 gg. (1916), vol. ii, p. 41.
N ote, a The strong influence o f the num ber o f male workers per household on the rates o f ‘substantive changes’
was already pointed out in the first dynamic study in 1897. N . C hem enkov, K kharakteristike krest'yanskogo
khozyaistva (1905), p. 35.
Official records o f the reasons for partitioning were vague and analysing
them would not lead us far; family quarrels between couples within the
extended family (in particular, amongst the women) were the major declared
reason for partitioning.5 In general, partitioning seems to have been accepted
by heads o f households as a necessary and natural course o f events. The
pecularities o f peasant social structure—in particular, the establishment of
1 For example, amounts of savings were withheld for long periods from use and invest
ment ‘in case of partitioning’ and, at times, two weak horses were kept by a household
instead of the economically preferable alternative o f one o f better quality (see N . Rosnitskii,
Litso derevni (1926), p. 11).
2 The relationship between the size o f a farm and its productivity and income has been
discussed in Chapter 4, section (b), above.
3 Na agrarnom fronte (1927), no. 5, p. 14: the reason for increasing rates o f partitioning
was described there as ‘petty-bourgeois fanaticism’.
4 See Chapter 2, section (c), above.
5 See, for example, the study by the Communist Academy reported in M. Kubanin,
Klassovaya sushchnost* protsesa drobleniya krest'yanskikh khozyaistv (1929), pp. 72-5. ‘Ne
uzhilis’— ‘We did not get on well’— was the phrase frequently used when declaring reasons
for partitioning.
‘SUBSTANTIVE CHANGES’ 87
one’s own household as a mark of maturity and independence—seem to have
been the main determining factors in the process.1
Social explanations of partitioning advanced in Chapter 2 are consistent
with the close correlation of the partitioning-rate with the average size of
household.12 Consequently, no partitioning whatsoever took place in large
numbers o f peasant households in the lower strata.3 However, the very high
rate o f partitioning observed in the wealthier strata had a considerable effect
on the peasant society as a whole. For example, from the early 1920s onwards,
no less than one-third of all households in the richer stratum underwent
partitioning during each consecutive period of three years (one formal crop-
rotation).4 It would mean also that as many as a quarter of all the households in
peasant communities were involved in partitioning during thepreceding decade.5
Information about newly created households is scarce and scattered. A
number o f studies were carried out by A. Khryashcheva and her assistants
but they were extremely limited in scope.6 The insights gained were summed
up as follows by Khryashcheva: ‘As far as the total number of newly-created
households is concerned we may generally observe, now as well as in the past,
an increase in land sown as well as in the means of production. It seems
that the moment o f partitioning coincides with the moment of greatest strain
in the original household which strives to equip the new ones—i.e. to provide
the necessary horses, equipment, and so on. The original household not only
divides existing equipment but at times buys horses and equipment or gives
money to new households for this purpose.’7 This seems also to be true o f the
immovable part o f wealth (e.g. the house, barns, etc.).
The mobilization of resources and effort called forth in the period of
partitioning could, in the short run, counterbalance the undesirable economic
effects o f pulverization of farms on over-all production. In per capita terms,
this could give a fair margin to the new households created within the richest
stratum. However, the majority of even these households started their exis
tence as smallholders, much exposed to the harsh vicissitudes and accidents of
T a b l e 5 - vi
Sparse data collected after the revolution seem to offer some additional
indications o f the causes o f merger.
T able 5 -vii
Clear economic gains were achieved as a result o f merger, and these were
expressed in increases in the sown area per capita—a major index o f peasant
well-being. Economic adjustment and better use of resources lay at the root
90 ‘SUBSTANTIVE CHANGES’
o f the decrease in the number o f horses.1 It seems fair to assume that the
perceived advantages of a more economic organization or expectations of
economic recovery were major reasons underlying the merger o f peasant
households. However, the crucial importance of the family structure o f the
household in an actual merger involves a variety of human factors and calls
for a frame o f reference much wider than the purely economic one. Merger
meant not only unification of resources but also things as personal as common
family life and acceptance of a new patriarchal authority. A solution o f the
crisis o f deterioration by merger might well be blocked, therefore, by personal
and social considerations, or merely by lack o f interested potential partners,
especially when consumption-needs exceeded the possible rise in production.
The final disappearance o f a household through extinction might well then
have followed.
The process o f extinction involved the disappearance o f a peasant house
hold through the deaths of all its members.12 The household was legally
declared extinct (vymorochnyi), its property taken over by the village com
mune,3 and the household struck off the rolls. The force o f extinction in pre-
industrial societies has been generally underrated by both laymen and scholars
in our generation. Its role remained well hidden, on the whole, behind the data
on over-all population growth. Yet mortality trends proved strong and erratic,
bringing about the extinction o f numerous households. Some indications of
its magnitude may, perhaps, be gained from the recorded genealogies o f the
nobility. During 900 years, the royal family o f Rurik expanded into 187 family
lineages, o f which 148—i.e. 79 per cent—became extinct. Over approximately
six centuries, 69 per cent of the family lineages o f the Russian descendants of
the Lithuanian prince, Gedymin, became extinct.4 Similar records are lacking
for the peasantry, but extinction would presumably have occurred even more
frequently.
On the present topic, it is the differentiation o f extinction rates which has
had even greater significance. The pre-revolutionary studies reported a re
markably strong inverse correlation between wealth and rate o f extinction
of the Russian peasant households. For example, in the dynamic survey quoted
in Table 5 •viii, the figures for extinction over a period of 29 years ranged from
T able 5 -viii
households among the lower strata, lay at the root o f the inverse correla
tion between wealth and extinction. Studies made o f this subject are few,
but a survey by Shcherbina at the turn of the century was widely accepted
as typical for the country in general in the first quarter of the twentieth cen
tury.1 Birth-rates rose, to a certain extent, with a rise in peasant wealth,
though death-rates showed a much closer inverse correlation. As a result,
rates o f natural increase were closely related to the wealth o f peasant
households. The rates of natural increase in the wealthiest households in
Shcherbina’s study (see Table 5-ix) were nearly twice as high as those in
the poorest ones.
In the post-revolutionary period, the term ‘liquidation of household’
adopted by Ts.S.U. combined both extinction and emigration by persons
declaring a decision not to return. N o exact evaluation of post-revolutionary
extinction-rates is therefore possible. However, extinction seemed to remain
a frequent occurrence in peasant life and a major component o f ‘substantive
changes’.
1 The data were, in fact, republished as typical in a summary o f the big debate on
differentiation (see Chapter 3, section (c)) in Pud sel'skogo khozyaistva (1927), no. 5,
pp. 121—2.
92 ‘SUBSTANTIVE CHANGES*
T a b l e 5*ix
Annual Rates o f Natural Increase in Voronezh Gub. by
Land Held per Household (per i,ooo)a
Source. F. Shcherbina, Svodnyi sbornik po 12 uezdam voronezhskoi gub. (1897), pp. 353-5,
392.
Notes. a This study is based on records drawn from 6 uezds, Voronezh Gub.
b A similar pattern was reported by N. Semenov, Statistika po zemel'noi sobstvemiosti
(1880), Appendix; also A. Shingarev, Vymirayushchaya derevnya, 1907.
(d) Migration
Rural migration consists of a variety o f distinct and interconnected processes
o f which the emigration of family units is the most relevant to our issue.
Emigration is defined as spatial mobility, i.e. movement o f residence for a
substantial period taking the emigrants out o f the community to which they
originally belonged.1 Its main relevant categories would be (i) emigration
abroad, (ii) country-to-town migration, and (iii) colonization o f new lands,
mainly over the Urals. Emigration abroad was virtually non-existent for
Russian peasants. Country-to-town migration in Russia accounted for about
300,000 villagers annually before the revolution.12The net result o f colonization
in the Asiatic parts o f Russia (i.e. the emigration less the re-immigration)
amounted to about 2 \ million peasants during the period 1905-17.3 After the
exodus of townsmen in the years 1918-21, the numbers o f villagers settling
in towns during the period o f the N.E.P. was recorded as about 400,000 per
annum,4 while colonization practically stopped. Net rural migration must have
1 Our rough estimate is based on a reported annual growth o f the urban population o f
2*7 per cent from 1897 to 1917 and, after the decline during the civil war, o f as much as
5 per cent during the period 1923-6 (Pisarev, op. cit., pp. 94-5). We have taken into account
the net colonization east of the Urals and assumed urban natural growth to be 1-2 per cent
before and 1-5 per cent after the revolution (this is based on figures given by A. N . Tatarchuk,
TsentraVno-chemozemnaya oblast' (1929), p. 10, and F. Lorimer, The Population o f the
Soviet Union (1946), pp. 31-3).
2 ‘Relative shortage o f land’ as used by Kaufman would possibly express this concept
better. For a fuller discussion o f the problems see D . Warriner, Economics o f Peasant Farm
ing (1964).
3 Lubny-Gertsykh, op. cit., pp. 6-7. The First World War seems to have validated these
somewhat arbitrary estimates. N o significant drop in land sown or production was reported
until 1916 and 1916-17 respectively— in spite o f the large-scale mobilization o f men and
horses carried out in rural areas.
4 Lubny-Gertsykh, op. cit., p. 549.
* L. Mints, Otkhod krest'yanskogo naseleniya na zarabotki v SSSR (1925), P- 13-
94 ‘SUBSTANTIVE CHANGES’
and the destruction o f the means o f recovery, followed by emigration of the
survivors.1
The peculiarities o f peasant social structure and, in particular, o f the peasant
family, strongly influenced the character o f peasant emigration. A quest for
independence and prestige in the situation o f a typical peasant family led to
emigration o f the young in particular.2 Data are lacking to prove this point
conclusively but impressionistic evidence and comparative considerations
seem to suggest that young peasants were the major group o f migrants. The
magnitude o f the problem is indicated by the size o f the rural population
between the ages o f seventeen and twenty-four; in Russia during the early
period o f the N.E.P. these amounted to about six million.3 On the other hand,
the peasant social structure provided powerful ties which were opposed to and
at times reversed migratory trends. The cultural peculiarities o f the peasants’
values and traditional way o f life joined forces, for its weaker members, with
the advantages o f living in a peasant household and a commune. Egalitarian
inheritance and family property limited migration4 and provided ties which
lasted long after some had left their villages. A survey o f printers in Moscow,
conducted on the eve o f the First World War, showed that 46 per cent o f them
were still engaged in some form o f farm work—generally seasonal work in
their original households.5 This proportion would surely be higher in less
skilled trades and smaller townships.
In the case o f emigration, the impact of factors external to the peasant com
munity is more manifest than with other ‘substantive changes’. The strength
o f factors external to village life can be seen by the impact o f wage levels,
unemployment, and the availability o f land for colonization on the directions
and rates o f migration from the villages.6 Yet, over most o f the period, the
impact o f internal factors on the emigration o f peasant families seems to have
been decisive. This is reflected in a close inverse correlation between wealth
and rates o f emigration. Here it is the differential rates rather than the total
figures which are significant. Rates o f emigration correlate inversely with the
wealth of peasant households. Basic social and economic indices relating to
migrating households show them as ranking between households which merged
1 For example, the famine o f 1921 led to a decline o f 21 per cent in the rural population
of the areas affected, and a decline o f between 31 and 37 per cent in sown areas in the
following year (V. Den, Kurs ekonomicheskoigeografii (1925), p. 209). Declining population
here includes both deaths by starvation and large-scale emigration.
2 Accompanied partly, no doubt, by dreams of saving enough ultimately to come back
to their own communities as proper heads of households.
3 Estimated on the basis o f data in Sbornik statisticheskikh svedenii po SSSR 1918-
1923 gg • (1924), PP- 6-17, 41-2.
4 See Appendix A below and H. Habakkuk in the Journal of Economic History, vol. xv,
no. 1, p. 7.
5 Quoted from G. T. Robinson, Rural Russia under the Old Regime (1932),
p. 249.
6 Robinson, op. cit., p. 250; Sbornik statistiko-ekonomicheskikh svedenii po seVskomu
khozyaistvu Rossii (1914), pp. 500-11; Mints, op. cit., pp. 40-2.
‘SUBSTANTIVE CHANGES’ 95
or became extinct and those which did not undergo substantive changes (see
Tables 5-111 and 5-iv).
One possible exception, limited to the richest households, was revealed by
the dynamic studies. In some cases, the correlation between wealth and rates
o f emigration were positive in the richest stratum, in a way similar to that
already described in the discussion of merger. This phenomenon was inter
preted as country-to-town emigration of capital and entrepreneurs. How
ever, this correlation did not always appear and seems to have reflected at
times an indiscriminate lumping together of actual rich emigrants with house
holds which were moving to consolidated farms (khutora) o f their own in
near-by neighbourhoods.1 When apparent, this phenomenon would reinforce
the levelling impact o f ‘substantive changes’.
Data are lacking to permit us to evaluate fully the impact of immigration
on socio-economic mobility. However, what evidence there is, points to marked
similarities between emigrants and immigrants in terms o f the indices of
peasant wealth.2 This would seem to justify, in discussion o f our issue,
standardized treatment of migration as surplus of emigration over immigration
(whether positive or negative).
1 For a discussion see A. Khryashcheva, Gruppy i klassy v krest'yanstve (1926), p. 77.
2 For example. Table 5*iv above.
6
MULTIDIRECTIONAL AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY:
TOWARDS AN EXPLANATORY MODEL
60 3 S
c •-i »n n n
cd 2 |o
JZ ■C
*-O
> O o\
O N fOOO
c H H
£
t/5
Os £>
I
fN
s 9 cnVOCO N
~ Cn cb cn
60^
°0 .s ^
o^ ^tvo cn t^vo
60 M do 6 cn 6 os
U
-S 3\
c ~ r^> tj- Tf n
p -p
^ C os ^ docb 6'
o 0 tt «—
> 0i
I <= « « jz • t
|h o in;
■3S 1 00 tJ- rn N S «H » I
K 2u
M H OOSj- H
os 2
5 o ‘
jD
« 8
O
VO 5 8 s 15
+z *o-* Os os r^-oo so
Z J3 H is
2 * R
W *o X $
O <£
HO C* C
in* bs
d- O
d*n cn <3
« s Oo
p 00 §
-C
H
•5 O cn o
2 to
C
H*n C
1-h^
co
3 8 S 2
60 _
os vo « H OO o cd
C ~ ■s iO ■8
O *C/3 2^
60 $ •"» §Q> to
N
*7"
v-, CtO—, «9 N
•« o s-o C
G O cn «-i
'PO
l l N§ R
*>
cd
I « 41 50 -P j3
^3
cd ^ os 9
Ah * 2n OS
^
o js o
5 C
I w 1
r-
Cn Cn
N N
« Mf rz >* 13
2o > 3 + O N N Tt to toj
I »2 3 oo o 7T do p
f K i° H 3 m do 6 rmvo
rt in t'b R
O
O
.P
^3
cnsp
VO
55 G
o-h cn
1 Cf do
cn cn
*o 2 C O
c o
cd R 60
cd
P
cd cd
I e5 0 50^
w 00 O n o
><
j 2*
C JO
*“’ uj
go u, cn qj
o Po~ £ VO OO N
i co
e *§
cujo .S 3 a I r
m .
r-'- i| 35
Q
io H cn 6 cn
Ah
ft V3
<*>
g cd
u,
g Ui N »-•
OO >-i
75 <«U Q W pci >
s 00 os
CO
T3 o 2
JO
C 5 0 «
o •g cd
S) B 1
- o\° O
< 45 O 8 8 8 8 8 M •
co Ov
C <o 1 8^
cd .
v>> a
O 2"o
CO i/I
2c l <0g -§
cd CS
■£ pS ge3 «c (o
c
h M O OS
N fOTf :* g ^ £ x>
- OS g § ■§
V 00 ~ H «0 •B*2 >v
<N a t3 3c £t= ki
Os o00 gw cd
m ? - «co v^ ofc
ft o 9 9 9 O o U
<-nm <s 6 CL
Pi g, c E
Os 1 - > S
o § 2 fr B - g *2
tj- moo m m “ o
G -C
co % o co .2
? 5
Co 2 ,2
o .
•g o 8
g * 3
•S 3
35 60 1 1 ^2 & o
r/v co
Co o § rj- tj- co m m
-S i • 2 £ o
o 6s moo <s >•!/) ~
H r^oo vo moo
Pi 1£ 1.<3 .5
-s:
•*«* 0) y-S Os co 'o
O 73o
> NO CO
co T3
•g o g .S s: ; £
.§> x: 1 1
w Ico Os
S’ n n \o o\ tr o
hJ X> ~ e 2 n n « 6 in o
« Jo 5> ^
' 005 w
W o
T3
<L>
Pi
Os »-! co
1 1
p
5 -
H c o 60 C/3 N
Sis' o 00 00 Tj-OO
Vh
o g 2 cn cS rs« :§
*o 5 0
%
•S si T3
1>
VO cs VOM
■s
2 ! cn 6 00 m 6v
§ O t-i
0r * *CO PSk -3
I <s m <s
OO
-o 1 8) C i ; 6 6
<o SOso N cn m s *5
.0 I 0<s ill
COr- £
o
1 co
2 a) <21 2
I ( h 5
0 8 !
O Tv
c
o
£ 6 § w s©
Z is.S
G
cd §
£ ■g
£ g J 2 2 + I
5W o* S Oe
o.j:.S = O <S
Z h n 2 A
CD
cd g ois TT
cd
u a 3 8 N
OS OS
< « U Q < to m >
•8
•o
3
2
J3 + 2 .8 1
-§ ? S
< is i +
888888888 1£ I
I
| vsno ON « P ' ON vs n n
si
to o
On PS
n - n ps n
t" vs r*» ^
Tf PS PS
0 0 0 0 0 P) Nf O
X 6 6 6 6 6 6 vs vs 0
* 9
ON O n •8
0 0 0 0 n
3
0 6 6 6 6 6 vs CTNCO 6
ps n
8
os - 0 O ^NO NO r»oo n
(JU 6 6 0 0 NO * n vs
£i
* PS ~
<N
Os n « PS VS N n *-t ys
w 6 6 NO «
H Vfi « I
00 t" •Nf 0 NO r~ 00 0 On 8-8
I Q 6 6
£
vs 6 6 ■Nf s »
vs
6 6
« r* M f >9 NO 00 no
n1 I00
ps r~* M S ’ *** ** O O '0-
U PS
§ x A*>
NO
n n 5*»
s3 6 6
PS 00 n 0 ■NT K
§■ 3^ m nO *^
on 0 6 6 6 6 PS
PS (m
0 NO
3
a
A < 00 6 0 6 0 0 0 n
§
c3
1
X «s
2-$
n ps ■V)o
0
vs
a •Q
*>a X *
cd s
0 1
O
i 0
w >s 3 S'
O vo ^ 9 “ 9 vsno no On 00 r 2 9 ~ A
n vs 6 no irs n PS t^ob
s.s :< 00 On Os on 00 00 00 On .S NO *XS
rt <N A
oj o
< .83 Os NO
PS P ' p* J> g
*-1 ■b- vs
H S rfi vi « £
o ^3 O
? * .S
<3 ■s . o
§ |1 2 r . O n00 £ a ao Subdivided in the source into ‘temporarily absent’ and ‘liquidated’.
<u 0
A r 5 ■b-NO •3
11 <N n -^s PS PS
§
vs ON f n 0O N
H X S< vs p s « ~ - 6 >"
Os O
U 5v O n
CO
.5 5 2
c
00 l •
r 5
0
ys ^t
O n VS
PS PS ft
n ps r 1 n no 8 •S
00 T f
«66 0 666 ^■S n n *5
S? 1 A %'S Is
k^v at -8
I •0 J®
a £>
3 vs mm^Pnpti^r' •w*
§
>* <*>
4>
On On •S a
5> o
■* *0
i
;3& O —n ^ r ^ n n p - n
S'
2T £* ^2 o
*v. *5 jT I 3 3
-* * A
CO S
o S'
y \p o 9s « ys Tj- 9
I irs irs ^ O n ps r»>6
X
0 S.E &
* §: ^2 •o
1 ,-Sr _« §
O «o .§
- i 0
■2-S^
o' !- og x(1 ^ . so 0 'S . I ^df
£) f * S'
0O VQ
0 a-2
v T T1 :
o o n ^vo o no
.
*g ^
•O n I i %l %
00
£
J &
<U *<^i
g g 1 iW
< «UQ WU,OE3 s ir 1
CYCLICAL MOBILITY: EXPLANATORY MODEL ioi
Q *4 so p** r*
o — «-i <<S
s rO
wfnrO
n o'O
n « «-<vooooo Tf
NOVOOOOO OnNON^ON
oO
oo0^o fN
» o tn
on
OO
U •
*
%■%
-1
I t i ooooooooooooooooooooooqooooo T* T* V* C* T* T
s; f-1.9
E
I p«
0 OOO ONhO o o
6 6 6 6 6 6
O >>
h
.§
•*-N
» •2'i
1-2 oo Os >-h p* Tf-rj-w^g\ONO 7* T T r10?0? ^ C"
*•
* H.S
a
o O 00 os vn po ph
T3 U n 6 6 6 66 6
I I W‘.C
f" o I I I I I I I I I I I 1I I I I 1I I
y
I I'- 5
—i pomm m
I I I I 1 I I I I I I II I I I 6 6 6 6 6
> * £ O I « Pi
oooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo ■^* C
8O
§ 666666666666666666666 * g
t
p*
1*
p 999990990909990999009 * s
X > 2 I
o
•S 8
1rt ~& d
o.
O8
rt «
jo *t §
i'i
>* 09
e< !* I
O J
6 ci c n ^ in N O p^oo os o p^ w Nf r-o o
*
£«
, ph vnno ono
Ss
CYCLICAL MOBILITY: EXPLANATORY MODEL 105
by any movement away from the point o f stability. Such a conception has
implicit in it a tendency to anticipate levelling and a high degree o f stability
in the system. That assumptions of a tendency towards social equilibrium and
levelling in peasant societies were associated with the doctrines o f biological
determinism was made explicit, as early as the beginning o f the century, by
A. Peshekhonov: ‘On the one hand, in every peasant household, there appears
a tendency to balance the production forces and the consumption needs o f its
membership with the size and organization o f the economic enterprise; on the
other hand, all peasant households tend to some mean or average family
size. This is typical o f the pattern o f social relationships known as the
peasantry.’*1
Chayanov’s general theory o f peasant economy and mobility was empirically
validated— or at least illustrated—by intensive budget studies of 101 peasant
households in Starobel'sk uezd published in 1915.
T a b le 6 -v
S tra tu m S ow n a rea % o f young Av. no. o f Av. no. o f Av. no. o f C o n su m er/
p e r h o u se fam ilies in m em bers per ‘consum ing ‘w orking w o rker ra tio
h o ld {d es.) stratum ® household u n its’ u n its’
1 The landless are treated as a qualitatively different group from the various farming
strata.
2 S. Prokopovich, Krest'yanskoe khozyaistvo (1924), pp. 32-3. These studies were based
on (i) 1907: Vel'sk uezd, Vologda gub.\ (ii) 1910: Kadnikov uezdy Vologda gub. \ (iii) 1909-
12: Novgorod gub.\ (iv) 1910: Tambov gub. \ (v) 1910: Starobel'sk uezd, Khar'kov gub.
3 See ibid., p. 36.
4 See ibid., p. 34. We shall not discuss here the more general methodological issue o f the
use o f correlations as proofs of causality.
TOWARDS AN EXPLANATORY MODEL 107
peasant households. The use of an index of income per household (and not
per capita) casts further doubts, in view of the correlation o f household size
and wealth which we have seen. Finally, Prokopovich, in his study, eliminated
the effects in terms o f adjustments in holdings of land and equipment made
by peasants (podtyazhka) which, in Chayanov’s view, would necessarily have
correlated with increases in ‘self-exploitation’, given increasing consumption-
pressure in peasant households.1
Another attempt to disprove Chayanov’s views empirically was made by
G. Raevich in a series of articles published in 1925 and 1926.2 Raevich analysed
elements o f a number o f pre-revolutionary budget studies relevant to Chaya
nov’s theory and pointed out that, firstly, contrary to Chayanov’s beliefs,
large differences are to be found in the consumption-levels of different peasant
strata as recorded in studies o f Volokolamsk and Vologda uezds.3 He proved,
furthermore that, even in Chayanov’s study o f Starobel'sk uezd, large
differences in consumption-levels appear if the households are classified as
‘capitalist’, ‘independent’, and ‘proletarian’, using a dual index o f land sown
and wage-work hired or offered.4 Secondly, he showed that the alleged ten
dency for total sown area and area o f land rented to be adjusted to family size
was far from clear in the budget studies of Fergana gub. and Tambov gub.5
Thirdly, Raevich pointed out that, in the thorough budget-studies made of
Penza gub., no proof of a correlation between the consumer/worker ratio and
the level o f ‘self-exploitation’ o f peasant labour had been found at all.6 This
criticism o f Raevich’s was far from totally demolishing Chayanov’s theory,
but the doubts he cast were serious—and were never answered by Chayanov
or his friends. As a matter o f fact, during the decade and a half following 1912,
which was marked by intensive debate and new evidence becoming available,
Chayanov’s own views underwent change. He came to stress increasingly, the
importance o f family labour (rather than consumption-needs) as the major
determinant o f peasant economic action and to accept the autonomous
significance o f capital on both the micro- and macro-economic levels in actual
analysis o f the peasant economy.7 However, Chayanov seems to have retained
the essence o f his views about the crucial influence o f ‘biological’ factors on
the Russian peasant economy o f this period and, more important, for us here,
fully restated in his later studies his initial explanation o f peasant socio
economic mobility.8
The empirical evidence gathered in the pre-revolutionary budget studies
1 For a discussion o f this point see G. Raevich in Na agrarnom fronte (1925), nos. 11-12,
p. 26.
2 Na agrarnom fronte (1925), nos. 11-12; (1926), nos 1 and 3.
3 Ibid. (1926), no. 3, PP- 6-7. 4 Ibid. (1926), no. 3, p. 7.
5 Ibid. (1926), no. 1, pp. 12-14 and 17-19.
6 Ibid. (1925), nos. 11-12, pp. 27-9.
7 A. Chayanov, The Theory o f Peasant Economy (1966) (originally published in German
and then in Russian in the mid 1920s).
8 Ibid., pp. 53- 69.
108 MULTIDIRECTIONAL AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
remains far from conclusive as far as validation or invalidation o f Chayanov’s
theory o f mobility is concerned. The majority o f budget studies—as well as
the extensive data collected in the countryside for purposes other than budget
studies (e.g. censuses and dynamic studies)—gathered since 1916 did not offer
adequate information for drawing conclusions about the problem. The few
post-revolutionary budget studies which did attempt to highlight this problem
seemed to support Prokopovich’s and Raevich’s criticisms, in that no con
sistent relationships were discovered between consumer/worker ratios and
estimated incomes, labour intensities, etc.1 However, these post-revolutionary
studies were few in number and all were carried out by scholars politically
opposed to Chayanov in the in-fighting over the rural policies, which could
have influenced the results. Only further studies and further sophistication o f
methods could establish the validity o f Chayanov’s theory. Yet by the time
o f collectivization, even, no practical statistical method for validation, accept
able to all the major participants in the debate, had been arrived at.
The ambiguity o f the available empirical evidence is particularly serious in
view o f the seriousness o f the analytical misgivings raised by Chayanov’s
basic conceptual framework. To begin with, ‘biological determinism’ was
severely criticized at the time by many Russian economists, who claimed that
the penetration o f market relations into peasant life which had taken place
made even the use o f the concept o f an ‘ideal type’ of a peasant household,
free from market influences, unrealistic and misleading.12 We may add to this,
methodological doubts (even stronger in our generation) about equilibrium
models3which have proved, on the whole, to be o f doubtful value for analysing
structural change. Equilibrium models seem to have particular drawbacks for
analysing peasant societies developing under the pressure o f alien and town-
centred economic and political influences.4
An important attempt to overcome what seemed to be inherent weaknesses
o f biological determinism for analysing both structural change in a peasant
society and the changing impact on it o f a market economy was made by
N. Makarov, one o f the outstanding members o f the Neo-Populist group.
The analysis developed by him in fact departs from strict biological determin
ism in the direction o f a broader multifactorial and historical analysis o f
peasant society.5 Makarov saw the history o f peasant societies as a struggle
desyatina or more. The yields for localities would no doubt have fluctuated
even more sharply. To the tale of natural fluctuations in yields one can add
the ‘natural disasters’ of flood and fire. The extent and impact o f such disasters,
which a townsman today would tend to treat as extraordinary and rare, can
be gauged by a remark in a 1929 issue of Pravda to the effect that, in the whole
country, there was not a single peasant house which had not been burnt out
at least once.1
The terms o f trade between the rural and urban sectors (reflected in the
relative prices of major agricultural and non-agricultural products on the open
market) strongly influenced peasant households’ economies. Practically every
peasant household was involved in some exchange operations; at the mini
mum, it had to sell its produce at least to pay taxes and to buy some industrial
goods, including equipment. At the same time, peasant wage-labour came to
the market. In fact, peasant market operations were, of course, much more
complex than this and varied from period to period, decreasing during the
years 1917-19 and increasing afterwards. The extent of the involvement in a
money economy o f peasant households was subject to heated controversy at
the time and has not since become clear. However, the fact of the involvement
o f households in market exchanges cannot be denied. For example, the 1924-5
annual budget studies—based on representative samples drawn from the main
agricultural regions o f (i) the Grain-Deficient Zone, (ii) the Grain-Surplus
Zone, and (iii) the North Caucasus—showed 19, 25, and 26 per cent re
spectively o f Conventional Net Income spent as cash on purchases on the
general market.12 The market prices significant for a peasant economy fluctu
ated widely and their determination was, of course, outside the scope o f the
peasant smallholder’s economy. The changes taking place in the relative prices
o f industrial and agricultural products can be seen in their extreme form in
the so-called ‘scissors crisis’, in which the movement of the exchange rate
against agricultural products reached in 1923 a rate of 1:3 (taking the 1913
price levels as 1: i).3
The policy o f the highly centralized Russian and Soviet states strongly influ
enced Russian agriculture. The economic intervention of the state involved
the imposition o f taxes and the granting o f credits but also went further in the
form o f attempts at securing total control over the market through price
fixing (e.g. under the ‘grain monopoly’ after 1915), at imposing a ban on
the distilling o f home-made vodka (samogon), at confiscating all agricultural
surpluses (under ‘War Communism’, 1918-21), and even at total planning of
1 Pravda, 18 May 1929; quoted after M. Lewin, Russian Peasants and Soviet Power
(1968), p. 28. Every year about 400,000 farmhouses caught fire (ibid., p. 28).
2 Itogi desyatiletiya sovetskoi vlasti v tsifrakh 1917-1927 (1928 (?)), pp. 200-1. For
the discussion o f regional division of Russia see Chapter 7.
3 M. Dobb, Soviet Economic Development since 1917 (i960), pp. 162-9; also Klepikov,
op. cit., Table XXXI.
114 MULTIDIRECTIONAL AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
the production o f rural smallholders (in 1920). One can also include the
legislation on land-reform in 1917-19 and the ban and later limitation on land-
renting and the employment o f wage-labour in the years 1917-28.1 The real
ability o f the state to impose its will on the peasant communities varied over
time, but the fact o f its influence on the peasant economy cannot, once again,
be doubted.12
Our specific knowledge o f the impingement o f these factors on the peasant
economy is still extremely thin, and demands further work. However we may
already draw some conclusions about certain o f the general characteristics of
the interaction between the external factors discussed and the economy of
Russian peasant households.
The economy o f Russian peasant households was typified by limited
resources o f labour, land, and equipment and by extremely limited money
savings and access to credit. The impact of the major external forces on the
peasant economy would have varied widely in extent and character by period
and by area. Yet the way these forces acted tended, on the whole, to be
uniform, at least in that: firstly, the impact o f these external forces was over
whelmingly powerful compared to the resources of the peasant household;
secondly, they appeared to the peasants as almost totally unpredictable and
certainly quite uncontrollable; lastly, they tended, by their very nature, to
fluctuate widely—whether in the form o f sequences o f ‘good’ and ‘bad’ years,
o f fluctuations in prices, or of seemingly arbitrary twists and turns in the state’s
policies and its officials’ applications o f them.
The massive economic vicissitudes of peasant households resulting from
the impact o f these external factors were expressed in two ways: (i) aggregate
shifts, or changes in the prosperity of the peasantry en masse; (ii) changes in
the relative positions of peasant households. The general economic effects of
external factors on peasant society has been discussed above. These aggregate
shifts were, it seems clear, coupled with large fluctuations in the relative socio
economic positions of peasant households. Each peasant farm was strongly
influenced by individual chance factors in its specific history and present
family structure. The relative position depended on very small economic
differentials; chance could therefore play an exaggerated role. A successful
contract, a hard-working son, a useful merger, or, conversely, the illness or
death o f a working member, a fire, the death of a horse, the obligation to
provide a dowry, or even a family quarrel culminating in partitioning, could
lead to a complete change in the socio-economic position of a household.
Peasants were well aware of the influence o f chance factors on their life. For
example, a local survey reports: ‘The middle peasants say “Today I am a
middle peasant (,serednyak), tomorrow I become a poor peasant (bednyak). If
/(c4) Emigration of
\ \ the wealthiest
\ \
// ' //
(c2) Merger \ \
Time
K e y to P a r t B T re n d s o f M o b i l i t y
R e fe r e n c e s to th e c o m p o n e n ts (Parts B and C)
a. For a discussion o f this see Chapter 4, sections (b)and (d).
b. For a discussion of this see Chapter2, section (b) and Chapter 4, section (d).
c. For a discussion o f this see Chapter 5. (For the differences between the centripetal trend
o f Ci and C2 and the semi-centripetal effects of C3 and C4 see Chapter 5, section (a).)
d. For a discussion of this see Chapter 6, section (b).
e. For a discussion of this see Chapter 6, section (c).
a The Figure aims only to show the m a in te n d e n c ie s o f the determinants and does not
exclude differing results in the cases o f individual peasant households (e.g. the partitioning
o f an impoverished household).
b Centrifugal mobility may lead, in some cases, to structural changes (e.g. final prole-
tarization or alternatively the development o f a peasant household into a commodity-
producing enterprise typical of a market economy) with subsequent disappearance o f mobility
typical o f peasant societies.
c A centripetal statistical bias will result from the form of presentation usually adopted in
the dynamic studies (discussed in Chapter 6, section (a)).
4 Land-redivision administered by communes did not occur in some areas— in particular,
in Belorussia and the north-west.
* For a discussion of the specific ‘semi-centripetal* characteristics o f the process o f ex
tinction and emigration o f peasant households see Chapter 5, section (a).
For the benefit o f the reader the basic patterns of mobility of peasant house
holds described in Figure 11 are repeated in essence in Figure v, Part A. The
causality o f these patterns is analysed in Figure v, Parts B and C.
Figure v, Part B looks at the specific influence o f each o f the analytically
delineated major types o f factor involved in the mobility found among peasant
households, and relates the predominant direction of mobility to the socio
economic strata affected. The character of each of the major components of
the mobility o f peasant households (and the elements o f the proposed model)
has been already discussed at some length and will not be repeated here. The
arrows indicate the most probable directions of each type of socio-economic
movement o f peasant households and the semi-centripetal levelling effect of
differential emigration and extinction on the peasant society. In peasant com
munities and peasant society the tendency towards the cumulation of econo
mic advantages and disadvantages (a) leads to a polarizing tendency which is
at least partly counteracted by commune-administrated land-redivision (b).
120 MULTIDIRECTIONAL AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
Differential ‘substantive changes’ (c)—the existence of a correlation between
the rates o f ‘substantive changes’ and the wealth o f peasant households— has,
on the whole, an additional levelling effect on peasant society, through both
centripetal trends o f partitioning and merger (ci and C2) and the ‘semi-
centripetal effect’ o f disproportionately high disappearance o f poor households
as the result o f extinction and emigration (c3 and C4). A particularly intensive
emigration o f the richest could, at times, have a similar effect. The powerful re
sidual centripetal mobility in the dynamic studies which cannot be ascribed to
factors (b) and (c) indicates the existence of additional components o f mobility.
These are explained here in terms of random oscillation (e) and the possible
influence o f the biological cycle (d). The centripetal tendency would have been
somewhat magnified in the dynamic studies as the result o f a statistical bias,
created mainly by the elimination of ‘substantive changes’ from the records;
this has been pointed out by the use o f a double arrow. The operation o f such
u set o f simultaneously acting factors in a peasant community would neces
sarily lead to and account for the powerful multidirectional mobility of
peasant households revealed in the dynamic studies. It will also, in all prob
ability, generate strong cyclical forces—tendencies for peasant households
to be caught up successively in ascending and descending phases o f socio
economic movement.
The differentiation-processes in a peasant society are the net sum o f centri
fugal and centripetal trends of peasant households’ mobility. Figure v. Part
C sums up the five major components o f the multidirectional mobility of
peasant households and relates them to the centripetal and centrifugal
tendencies discussed. Projection of the resulting processes in time explains the
multidirectional and cyclical mobility described in the preceding diagram—
Figure v. Part A.
The figure presented helps to clarify yet another point: the cyclical mobility
displayed by many households does not presuppose the operation o f any
mystic equilibrium mechanism or necessary averaging o f the prosperity of
peasant households over time. Indeed acceptance o f the relative autonomy
o f the factors involved leaves open (and subject to further investigation) the
possibility that a number of peasant households will ascend or descend rapidly,
to establish a new type of market-oriented enterprise or, alternatively, to
turn into wage-worker units (marked by A ▼). Such developments, if wide
enough spread, could, at some stage, bring about the disintegration o f the
specifically peasant social structure, with the consequent disappearance of
the types o f mobility which are characteristic o f peasant society.1
1 The actual attempt by some Russian scholars during the period o f N.E.P. empirically
to trace such a development did not, on the whole succeed— possibly because o f the gener
ally low level of capital accumulation obtaining. The only success in this direction was the
discovery of a low partitioning-rate among wealthy households o f an entrepreneurial nature
in a small sample of 571 households in the Urals: see Khryashcheva, op. cit., pp. 99-105,
and V. Nemchinov, Izbranrtye proizvedeniya (1967), vol. i, pp. 46-62.
TOWARDS AN EXPLANATORY MODEL 121
The analysis o f peasant mobility calls for investigation beyond and above
the stage reached in the Russian dynamic studies. The major components of
peasant households’ mobility need to be isolated, subjected to further investi
gation and related to specific areas and periods.
Some reasonably secure quantitative conclusions can no doubt be drawn
at this stage. For example, the fact that multidirectional mobility greatly
exceeded net mobility in terms o f peasant communities (by about five times in
the studies presented above). However, the most significant conclusion to be
drawn from the Russian dynamic studies is the establishment of the very
fact that massive multidirectional and, in all probability, cyclical types of
household mobility were taking place among the Russian peasantry at this
time; this must be accepted, whatever interpretation is adopted.
The value of identifying the various types of mobility and of interpreting
them in the way done here is to be judged by the validity and usefulness of the
concepts proposed for analysing the basic problems of Russian rural history
and peasant social structure. The chapter which follows will examine, firstly,
the validity o f this model, which has been constructed on the basis of data
drawn mainly from the central regions o f Russia, for different areas of the
country; secondly, changes in the forms of the socio-economic mobility of
Russian peasant households over time; and, thirdly, the limitations of the
operational definitions used. To conclude, we shall consider the significance
for the political sociology of Russian peasant society of the facts we have
culled and o f the interpretations we have advanced.
7
MULTIDIRECTIONAL AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY:
VALIDITY AND RELEVANCE
1 For a fuller discussion o f the regional divisions o f rural Russia see, for example, A. Che-
lintsev, R u s s k o e s e l's k o e k h o z y a is tv o p e r e d r e v o ly u ts ie i (1928). For the post-revolutionary
period see, for example, S. Klepikov, S e l's k o e k h o z y a is tv o R o s s ii v ts ifr a k h (1923).
2 Other samples (presented in S ta tis tic h e s k ii s p r a v o c h n ik 9 2 7 g . (1927). PP- 70-3) include
figures for Siberia and the Ukraine, while Khryashcheva, op. cit., pp. 146-9, gives figures
for the region of Volga in R.S.F.S.R.
3 For example, S h o r n ik s ta tis tic h e s k ik h s v e d e n ii p o S S S R (1924). PP- IQ8 and i n
showed that the percentage o f peasant households involved in crafts and trades ( p r o m y s ly )
has been:
1917 1922
<1
2 ’s a
u-S-gg
O 3
*3
cj « MNW»0\">nOf< «-O 83 *5 g*2
«3 yi 9 \ oo r>N mo
6 -too 3* -I3 -2
v©© O*5
S.C ? -G
O—« N n r t6n r t »nt O
ooo
" boob 6 i© r4\©cb m
m m n rs es m
6 isb-
O« 2 3 Sip
25 = I I S -s£ l l l l l l l
i o^ ■-. 1-1 «o o o r o
s© in O
'g ??a I I I | ° * 3 S,6
~?_ n »<h r °^ ■n<Nm r^oo
<3 o«C O I© U,
I ° *£> I 16
1° ^ m Ovo \o oo o
I 1 6 i?v i * T* o« U
© 3J 6 6 h M S6no I | inII
o ? A_S i^ 6 6 1 11 1 1
13 Os
jf <d o PC
w i O~
\ C\« t « m O O t
h -i*in m 6 r t ir> O ^
3 Si
O 2 2 « ^O s« m ^ m n
I OSCs Os Os Os P* O Os O t " r - © m <s m m
m
<u
•R x a £< xa £< 0\ Os On Ov Os 00 0\00
<
o*2
H 3c to
2
\o » f< r*oo
&
wKWEw ? fOri « 6 6 X*2 /T' m Tfso m
w S £• 6" 6 6 6 « i
to £>
•JJ 3
jw
m f* rt to V^ «noo moo
*5 a \? s S " 6 66 6 5S 66 66 6« I
m ,
5
R Co
.5 9
§~ TJ
k: So t ©
• co
Co ■38 S'
2 e £
3 <*
n *n y'G r ^ 9
1 2 .S 6 « m inoo © ?no | 2.S
o~
6« in in © s© i-»
r
r *r 2© Si
g
08 o®
§! « « a « » t' o 3«
o S oo s© >- O i «n © os
qj
R
t3 2 o 2 v
p» r*- •- m O -sJ-oo i t« ^ s*
-0»>c
•§1 tj- o «n <s os os
—OO Os'© O « o ©B
I so ea
dga
H i z ^ .s
Q
.R
5 •S
£
<3 o?« Sk.
2 o p o ? ^ t 2 « ? 9I
o O ? 9 6 s® 2
r0 «i i -* i ~i ?• o
2h« £
K
2 ta r u = 1 r r ; : 6 '® 5 “
O o M ^VO •" ^ ^ — g -o ’o u « . "
62 o <it* . ■"
^ ^ ^
r 6 ^ 5
A l l h<
A ll he
h olds
•S«
ho ld s
•3 §
Ids
Ids
c V rt o *3 c
X it c
bousel
chang<
stratu i
w h ich
% o f
in NO
g 2 (S M Cl-) ~ CO ^ r t NO CO
O o 5 c
S 3 * 1 1 1 1 1 ° ^ C!, ° S 3 * 1 I 1
j. ix O H">NO > « « O ^ m o r t no r * v p o ^ o
I | 6 6 6 h f n n o vb ' o n O O O O r to O N r tn
3 S B I I > M N rt V
~<A
8 v 1
to ~ 9 rt o rt f " ° o tj - oo r~- to r
o NO ^
9 ^ f i (S 00 O NO OO r t N f ' t
6 vo u ; O O O O O O N f 'r tr t i 6 6 6 Tf NO > VO 00
Xi > <s « > <s
o o
it it
_> t " co co vo N n r t r t w 1 ° ^ ON NO oo - N t o «S r n r - O
1 9 >
T 6 uj 6 6 f i c i b N » i i n H n -a 6 « c b ob r s s r v o 6 ob
\o « w £ 2 w rt l o r t m
I 1
(A
JS oo oo »s **» r » t n on •*■ <rt JO i CO r - o o s o rtp
1 « ^
M « o o N r - T f 6 o « 3 r t no ^ 6 no ro « 6 no
g ; i e « «o « <s M ^ N g e
00 to
i vOO 0 v O O O t} - t} - O c 00 On On Ci O r o lO OO
o 1 o ^
r 9 y v n ^ V r - c o ^ O O ^ o N o f 'N r tr - N f « 6 6 w
<s T t J i , r t« H rn to Ies Z o
w «s > ~ -
V it
c i . oo «o o on ^ rt rt *"» c 1 ____
2'C i o > r t on« « ir t m «
3 3
(B]
2-0
(B )
6 6 - r t « 6 o b ' b
01
jn g 0 ,0 o o o | -
O I
fS NO « IX
I o-o
0 - 0 -I
. 2c ?
)
4 pC ^
& Is X s «
15 0 *3 o o r» o *s x. r - vo co ■*■
3 S' ON O « Is ^ VO fH M 3 O'
o 6 <s C o s t — r* i n i n o M - r t ^ ^ n o b "
s . g S i 00 a a O N O n00 00 00 On DC.5 00 Ov On On on On 00 00 O'
W
-J 2? !?
« O C3
< 4> 11 O NO r t NO r t O i r n OO O n o • S s> t * o n c « *" r - t}- o no
H •a ■ais r* st-N -* -> 6 -» 6 * <
> X c ^
W V w
v b ^ ro rH x ^ riv ri'b -
§
S
I
Xt r< T3 « s
3 Wl 3 U)
V r-v •x NO OO NO *0 On On 9 9 - u ^ t ^ r t OOO r tNO « r t O
oo_. r t « 6 6 o 6 6 r t M 60 2 5 - - - 6 6 6 6 6 "
2 5
fid •S s ?
o O
•S Q
o O
co £ ?^
V 1
•o
it
£? «
O 1
•a
v
co
•to s r
■g S ’ I c n
321
co 5 S'
•g Tt o o NO NO 00 N O O n ON <S 00 ON w n r t O
2 .2
o 1
(« ^
a* 5
6 « r« CON© 6 ri ei ei 2 -S
o .
« ^8
Pk w
6 - - r t ^ f ' O r t r t ei-I
J3 2
•g I % »
B S no « o r " co vo s f oo oo 3 C 9 cn o oo o \ rn r f r^No
*r +
o g o t + On r* in i n b b <s s* s * n o O' no in no O N f n p - c b
DC ’S H sSax DC o H 5 +
v>
2 «
N !§ a
O Tv sj- vo no ^ nono no 5 s?n § . o a
<« 43 c <S OO NO — — O N t ^ , 3\2 NOh VOh O O O O O N
o « q r - O' no j " onoo «s s t •»!■
.§ C/3 cj rrt MOO
no h o
O' 00 Ort
a » vn
'£>
ȣ
1s J ®ii a n - in ^ t r ;
NO 00 ' t rt jy no’" o’ o’ oo’ Crt ^ M
& l l . s 3
3 I K
u
*5
NO nt»
<s fS
2 2
o
•a
"5 0 9 S o o ? |
per househ
per househ
<u
land sown
p o o ^ ^ r t
land sown
r 7 sj-no 2 i i S 3
Stratum
Stratum
£ o • 1 i
i J , " 2
1 M " o t £ q ,!, 1 J , i - M o
• T1 • T o ' O 5
i
s «o
ides.)
1 w
ides.)
T able 7-11
‘Substantive Changes’, Chernigov Gub. {percentage)
T able 7-111
4Substantive Changes', Moscow Gub. (percentage)
More detailed studies of the modern agrarian history of Russia are clearly
necessary. However, to recapitulate, the evidence available over time and
space points to the validity of the concept used and the universality o f the
processes discussed. Moreover, some additional, though tentative, quantitative
conclusions can be added: firstly, for both pre-revolutionary and post-
revolutionary periods (though not for the gap between those two periods),
Khryashcheva’s statement may be accepted :‘the rate o f “substantive changes”
in different regions and periods varies, but the difference is so small that it
indicates a similarity—i.e. a rate of change fairly typical for all the different
areas, with variability mainly due to lengths of the period of observation.’1
This evaluation can, in fact, be extended to cover all the components of
peasant households’ mobility.
Secondly, the assumption of general similarities does not exclude—indeed
it assumes—specific differences in the rates of mobility in different areas and
at different periods. These variations may be classified into three major types:
(a) relatively stable differences between rates of mobility in different regions—
in particular, lower rates of mobility further north; (b) long-term trends of
which the increase in the rate of ‘substantive changes’ claimed by Prokopo
vich for the period 1897-1911 remains the main example; (c) major breaks in
continuity brought about by the crises of famine, war, and revolution. The
period o f war and revolution seems to have had a particularly large and lasting
effect in the form o f a large-scale increase in the rates o f multidirectional
mobility in all its forms.
Thirdly, with no exceptions, multidirectional mobility involved substantial
parts o f the peasant community. The strength of the mobility of peasant
households appears particularly great when compared with the differentiation-
processes in the same samples and when analysed in terms of similar
operational definitions. The typical relationship between parts A and B of
Tables 6 •1-6 •in in Chapter 6 (both in general and specifically for each stratum)
recurred in all the studies of different areas and periods known to us.
1 See, for example, L. Kritsman (ed.), Materialy po istorii agrarnoi revolyutsii v Rossii
(1928), vol. i. Introduction.
2 Statisticheskii spravochnik SSSR za 1928 g. (1929), and A. Gaister, Rassloenie sovet-
skoi derevni (1928).
3 N. Jasny, The Socialised Agriculture o f the U.S.S.R. ( 1949), P- 162. For examples of a
number of simple and complex indices proposed and used see Kritsman, op. cit., tables.
4 Gaister, op. cit., pp. 105-6. Fifty days of wage-labour could be easily accounted for by
the temporary illness of a farmer, the drafting of a son, or the need for a couple o f dozen
pickers for a day or two days in the peak season. It could stand, moreover, in as little as
a 1:10 proportion to the family labour used.
5 See, for example, B. Knipovich, K voprosu o differentsiatsii russkogo krest'yanstva
(1912), p. 10; also Gaister, op. cit., pp. 108-9, xxxi-
134 MULTIDIRECTIONAL AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
solution could not lie in some brilliant discovery o f the ‘correct’ and final index
o f wealth but rather in the clarification o f the uses and the limitations o f those
already in existence.
There were, indeed, drawbacks to the usefulness of land sown or horses per
household as the main index o f socio-economic stratification as used by
Ts.S.U., but the possible distortions related mainly to two opposed groups—
the richest and the poorest, who departed most from the pattern o f earnings
usual for the great majority o f Russian peasants. The numbers o f these were
always relatively small and even smaller in the N.E.P. period. Moreover,
objections raised to operational definitions o f peasant stratification by land
sown and/or horses owned per household could be met on two additional
grounds.
Firstly, close correlations were regularly reported between the relative
socio-economic positions o f peasant households defined in terms o f all the
major indices o f peasant well-being: land sown, livestock held, capital, in
come, household size, percentage o f mature males, and so on.1 In fact, even
Gaister’s major attack on Khryashcheva was supported by tables which
registered the strength of the correlation between strata as defined by capital
per household and strata as defined by land held or horses owned.12 In these
conditions, conclusions based on different indices of peasant wealth would,
broadly speaking, correspond at least as far as the large majority o f peasant
households was concerned.3
Secondly, turning from statics to dynamics, consistent use o f any o f the
indices o f peasant wealth would correctly reflect major trends in mobility,
assuming that no deliberate selection o f misleading samples had taken place
and that their randomness had been safeguarded. A change in the indices
used would lead to quantitative changes, but the direction and character of
trends would remain the same.4
The results and conclusions would, therefore, be basically similar, whatever
index o f peasant wealth was used. With none o f the major single indices
1 Examples may be found in every statistical study o f the Russian countryside: for
example, A. Khryashcheva, Krest'yanskie khozyaistva po perepisyam 1899-1911 gg. (1916).
The study of correlations between income and various factors o f production based on
five major budget studies gave strong support to this view. See Prokopovich, op. cit.,
pp. 32-3.
2 Gaister, op. cit., pp. 120-40. Gaister acted as the main spokesman for the agrarian
section o f the Communist Academy, which claimed that the methods introduced by
Khryashcheva underestimated the amount o f differentiation among the Russian peasantry.
3 The validity of the analysis could, moreover, be increased by the simultaneous use o f
more than one major index o f wealth, e.g. both land sown and horses per household. See
the operational definitions used by Ts.S.U., as recorded in Chapter 3, Tables 31V and 3*v
above.
4 A recent work on methodology in fact advanced an even more extreme proposition—
that, in so far as the sample is not purposefully biased, even samples selected not in a repre
sentative way would prove sufficient to validate or invalidate hypotheses: see H. Zetterberg,
On Theory and Verification in Sociology (1965), pp. 129-30.
VALIDITY AND RELEVANCE 135
postulated as being o f ultimate validity, each could validly be used (and, if
possible, be checked on by employing others), differences between theoretical
concepts and empirical evidence needing, however, to be kept constantly in
mind.
Three further distortions resulting from the operational definitions used
by Russian rural statisticians in presenting data should be pointed out as being
relevant here. Firstly, the formally three-field system o f agriculture prevalent
in large parts o f rural Russia at this period necessarily resulted in fluctuations
in the land sown per household recorded in different years.1It could be claimed
that it was this which determined the residual component of mobility in
dynamic studies based on stratification by land sown. In reply, it should be
pointed out that the land of a peasant household was usually split into
numerous strips situated in different parts of the commune’s land, and that
this limited the impact of three-field rotation on the proportion of its land
sown each year by a household. (The land of the commune sown each year
was probably roughly similar.) Moreover, the persistence and universal
appearance o f residual centripetal mobility in dynamic studies where strati
fication by horses per household—or income from entrepreneurial activities
per household—were used,2 means that the possibility of such a phenomenon’s
being due only to the agricultural techniques of a formally three-field system
can be discounted.
Secondly, a general decrease in size of peasant families, correlating with a
proportional decrease in the stock of basic means of production per household
(land, horses, and equipment held), might, it was argued, mistakenly be
recorded as an aggregate downward shift for the peasant community. No
doubt such developments did take place on a national scale during the period.
However, the relatively slow nature o f decreases in size of peasant households3
would not be sufficient to make necessary recasting the whole o f the discussion
o f mobility.
Thirdly, a major distortion of differentiation, observable in samples drawn
from diverse areas, was pointed out by N. Chernenkov and dubbed ‘The
statistical optical illusion’ by N. Oganovskii.4 By combining several com
munities o f differing wealth as one report-unit when presenting the data, an
image o f a highly polarized society results. For example, in the situation
represented by Figure vi,the samples from both the villages A and B show low
1 In the usual crop cycle of this type, in each of the strips a winter crop would be followed
by a spring crop and after that the land would be fallow for one year.
2 See the study by V. Nemchinov, Izbrannye proizvedeniya (1967), vol. i, pp. 44-62. See
also Table 611 above.
3 The average membership of peasant households in Russia decreased between 1897 and
1917 from 6*3 to 6 0 (Yu. Larin, Ekonomika dosovetskoi derevni (1926), p. 197). For the
Soviet period see Table 8*i. For discussion of the decrease in size and wealth o f peasant
households during the 1917 period see Chapter 8.
4 See Brokgauz and Efron (eds.), Novyi entsiklopedicheskii slovar' (2nd edn.) (19 13)
vol. xviii, p. 522.
136 MULTIDIRECTIONAL AND CYCLICAL MOBILITY
Wealth
THE PREDOMINANT
CONFLICT
(1917-1925)
8
THE AGRARIAN REVOLUTION AND
LEVELLING AMONG THE RUSSIAN PEASANTRY
E k h , t y d a y u b lo c h k o
D a ts v e ta y a s n o g o
B e i s le v a b e lo g o
D a sp ra va k ra sn o g o
said to have been expropriated from this group by the second revolution.1 Of
12.455.000 des. of land held by the ‘peasant bourgeoisie’ in the Ukraine,
7.087.000 des. is said to have been taken away.2 One would have expected a
tremendous civil war, an inter-peasant Armageddon, a clash in comparison
with which even the collectivization o f 1929-32 would pale.
Soviet scholars have been well aware of the necessary conceptual results
of their stand. Widespread kulak rebellion against the proletarian dictatorship
and against the ‘second revolution’ was claimed time and time again, but solid
evidence is lacking. The intensive search for proofs produced many stories of
clashes, mainly over grain requisitioning. No doubt cases of peasant rioting
were numerous in the Russian countryside of that time,3 but there is practi
cally no record o f uprisings of wealthy peasants against land-redivision. For
example, the large-scale study of the Committees of the Poor (Kombedy)4 by
Aver'ev alleged kulak rebellions at the end of 1918, but adduced only one
example—an uprising in Sosnovka uezd, Tambov gub.,5 which was described,
however, on the very next page of his book, as a general peasant revolt against
extensive taxation and poor supplies. When more carefully examined, the
so-called kulak rebellions seem nearly always to have been general peasant
uprisings, in which no class distinction can be traced.6 In fact, the countryside
in the period o f this supposed ‘second revolution’ (1918-19) proves to have
been relatively peaceful when compared with 1906, 1917, or 1920. Moreover,
in the major peasant rebellions of 1919-21 (those of Makhno and Antonov,
those in West Siberia and the Far East and Turkestan, that of the ‘Green Army
o f the Black Sea Area’, and so on), which were against both the ‘Whites’ and
the ‘Reds’, all strata of the peasantry seem to have risen by localities with
remarkable unity and with no trace of internal class division. Such unity
would seem startling had a major internal class struggle and inter-class
expropriations taken place just a year earlier.
We are, therefore, left with a major problem. What was it that made the
powerful kulaks, the ‘sturdy and strong’7 of the Russian countryside, accept
meekly what would have amounted to robbery in their eyes? Alternatively,
what is wrong with the ‘two stages’ theory of the agrarian revolution in Russia?
the failure o f these measures as well as the disappearance o f hope that the
state farms ‘would in a short time become meat and grain factories’1 which
led to the final change of policy expressed in the introduction o f the N.E.P.
and in the Land Code of 1922.2
How far did all that legislation passed by national bodies influence actual
happenings in the Russian countryside? Agricultural revolt had preceded the
Decree on Land. In the autumn o f 1917, peasant revolution had spread like
wildfire. The causal roots o f the rebellion seem to be indicated by the close
correlation to be found between the extent o f local ‘surplus agrarian popula
tion’ (or, more exactly, relative land shortage) and the spread o f rebellion.3
Its organization was remarkable. Village assemblies decided how to divide
the non-peasant property in each locality. Then action was taken, all house
holds being compelled to participate in order to ensure success—and equal
responsibility in the event of possible subsequent reprisals.4 These features
displayed in the rebellion of 1917 dominated developments in 1918. The weak
ness o f the central town-based authorities in the villages left the real power in
the hands o f local organizations. The new government legislated but the local
bodies had the final say.5
A study carried out by Narkomzem showed what were the local by-laws
and instructions relating to agriculture in force in the Russia o f 1918.6 N on
peasant farmland had been taken over and divided between peasant house
holds, but the legal provisions for the establishment o f state farms on the
exemplary estates had remained on the whole disregarded. Generally, this
land-redistribution had been declared ‘temporary’, ‘until the final implemen
tation o f the Basic Law’. Practice had varied greatly over methods o f dividing
up land between peasants. In some areas, all the land (including peasant
allotments o f communal land) had been pooled and then equally divided in
accordance with the number o f consumers per household—in the language
o f Russian peasant millenarianism, a ‘black redistribution’ (chernyi peredel).
In other areas, peasant holdings had remained untouched and only non
peasant land had been divided up, special attention being given to landless
families. As an intermediate measure, the ‘cutting off o f strips’ (prirezka,
otrezka) had been applied; in these cases, ‘surplus land’ had been transferred
from the richest to the poorest, the intermediate strata not participating in
the reform. Peasants’ privately owned land had sometimes been expropriated
in the same way as non-peasant land, but in other cases such land had been
1 O tc h e t N a r k o m z e m a , pp. 7, 34-55.
2 See Appendix B, section (d). 5 See the map in O z e m le , p. 20.
4 V. Milyutin, A g r a r n a y a r e v o ly u ts iy a (1928), vol. ii. s ibid., p. 179.
6 The study, edited by P. Pershin, covered 33 g u b . o f the R.S.F.S.R. and analysed the
decisions of the g u b e r n iy a and of about one-third o f the u e z d authorities: R a s p r e d e le n ie
z e m li v 1 9 1 8 g . (1919)- The conclusions o f this study, recapitulated in the following para
graph, find full support in recent publications by Yakovtsevskii (op. cit., pp. 68, 72) and
Sharapov (op. cit., pp. 136-7). See also Z e m li o s o b y k h s u b 'e k to v v la d e n iy a p r i o tc h u z h d e n ii
( 1919).
AMONG THE RUSSIAN PEASANTRY 151
treated in the same way as allotments of commune land and, possibly, left
in the possession o f its owners. The study made clear that ‘black redistribu
tion’ had been exceptional and had generally been carried out on local initia
tive and against the will of the higher authorities. ‘Cutting off strips’ with
consequent or allocation o f land to the poor, was found to have been the
most common type of land-redistribution. Many instances in which the
richest peasant households had benefited, and sometimes benefited most,
from this land-redistribution, were reported in some later studies. The
land-redistribution involved only fields; peasant house-plots remained, on the
whole, untouched.1
The most remarkable change which seems to have occurred was a change
in the role of the peasant communes. In the words of contemporaries, ‘The
land commune, coming alive with quite exceptional force, was undoubtedly
the basic ideological kernel of the social mechanism which in fact carried out
the agrarian revolution within the peasantry itself.’2 This revival of the peasant
commune was related to two major developments. In the first place, the old
custom o f land-redistribution by communes developed into the main mech
anism by which the land-redistribution of the revolution was carried out.
Consequently, the communes, the volost', and even the uezd (district) author
ities tended to clash in attempting to secure the maximum amount of land for
‘their’ peasants and, in the process, consolidated their identities. Claims to land
based on the property rights of serf-owners in the nineteenth century (‘ours
was the lord— ours is the land’) seemed to prove time and time again stronger
than requests for equality between districts, voiced by the central authorities.3
Secondly, a new situation had emerged in central Russia concerning
peasants with enclosed types of farms (uchastkovye form y khozyaistva) who
had mostly left peasant communes after 1906 as a result of the Stolypin re
forms.4 In the new conditions, with power shifting to the hands of peasant
communities, tension between the members of communes and the ‘splitters’
exploded in the form of a general tendency to force the enclosed types o f
farms back into the communes.5 Newcomers who had settled on enclosed
farms were usually forced out of the region.6 This action could not be
1 See, for example, G. Gordeev, S e l's k o e k h o z y a is tv o v v o in e i r e v o ly u ts ii (1925), p. 107;
see also Rubach, op. cit., p. 234. Some cases o f levelling house-plots were reported by
V. Keller and I. Romanenko, P e r v y e ito g i a g r a r n o i r e fo r m y (1922), p. 105.
2 Keller and Romanenko, op. cit., p. 21.
3 Milyutin, op. cit., p. 230.
4 See G. T. Robinson, R u r a l R u s s ia u n d e r th e O l d R e g im e (1949), chaps, xi, xii.
5 Milyutin, op. cit., pp. 177 and 223-4; S. Dubrovskii, K r e s t'y a n s tv o v 1 9 1 7 g . (1927),
pp. 69 and 70. In some cases the owners o f enclosed farms rejoined communes by their own
free will, believing that they would gain more this way from the redistribution of non-peasant
lands. See L. Kritsman, K la s s o v o e ra s s lo e n ie v s o v e ts k o i d e r e v n e (1926), p. 9.
6 The tension between the members o f traditional peasant communes and the owners
of independent farms engaged in enclosures o f various kinds is by no means specific to
Russia. See, for example, M. Bloch and G. Lefebvre in Charles K. Warner (ed.). A g r a ria n
C o n d itio n s in M o d e r n E u r o p e a n H is to r y (1966), pp. 79-98.
152 AGRARIAN REVOLUTION AND LEVELLING
T able 8 1
Indicators o f Peasant Economic Activity, R.S.F.S.R., Agricultural Censuses
o f 1917, 1920, and 1922
T a b l e 8* i i
Peasant Households by Size o f Membership, i g i j and i g i g a
T able 8111
Annual Rales o f Partitioning o f Peasant Households, 1911-1922
% o f households
Period partitioned per annum
1911-14 i -7
1914-17 03
1917-20 3‘3
1920-22 2*3
The steep rise in the general rate o f partitioning during the revolution must
have been particularly evident in the richer strata. National figures are lacking,
but partial records published for three guberniyas o f European Russia fully
support this conclusion.
Table 8-iv
It seems safe to assume, for the period o f 1917-20, something like a 50 per
cent rate o f partitioning among peasant households in the richest strata of
the Russian peasantry. To this should be added the levelling impact o f the
AMONG THE RUSSIAN PEASANTRY 159
general aggregate shift downwards.1 In the conditions of land shortage and
aggregate downward shift, a marked process of partitioning among the rich
est necessarily found reflection in the form of considerable levelling among
peasant households.
Even partial and indirect data on household disappearance is lacking for
this period. Given civil war and hardship, the rate of extinction must neces
sarily have risen. On the other hand, we may assume a decrease in emigration
o f peasant families, with some certainty; conditions were deteriorating in the
towns, resettlement o f peasants in the east had lapsed, and new rights to land-
allotment on the spot had been proclaimed by the revolution. The migratory
cycle, in fact, led to unusual results. Large-scale rural re-immigration out
stepped emigration during the years 1918-20. On the whole, the immigrants
seemed to join the poorer strata of peasant households and this would partly
account for the numerical rise of the latter.2The impact of immigration on rural
socio-economic mobility would therefore be differential. By swelling the ranks
o f the lower strata, the immigrants seem to have cancelled out the generally
noted levelling effect o f the high extinction rates among the poorest households.3
During the period 1917-20 ‘substantive changes’ seem, therefore, to have
undergone a basic transformation. A sharp increase in partitioning and, in
particular, partitioning o f the biggest households, took place. Simultaneously,
the ‘purge’ o f poorer households was partly arrested and possibly even reversed
by a change in the direction o f rural migration. A trend towards both an
aggregate shift downwards and levelling would follow.
Data for estimating the residual component of peasant households’mobility
from 1917 to 1920 are lacking. However, the intensification of external pres
sures and an inevitable decrease in stability during the civil war must have led
to an increase in mobility via the operation of chance factors o f all kinds.
The agrarian revolution was mainly carried out through the channel of
commune land-redistributions. In the years 1917-20, some peasant com
munes carried out as many as four land-redivisions.4 Fully egalitarian land-
redistribution, however, was limited to a minority of peasant communities
and o f households. Nor did commune-operated redistribution become uni
versal even in 1918.5 Commune redistributions reached their peak in 1918
and then quickly subsided.
To recapitulate, the agrarian revolution, taking the form of requisitioning
o f the non-peasant land and its commune-based redistribution, had a power
ful levelling effect in 1918. Its impact would have been particularly strong on
the position o f the poor and the landless—the major beneficiaries of the
expropriation o f non-peasant land. However, the sharp drop in the commune
1 See Chapter 3, section (b).
2 See Chapter 5, section (d).
3 For rough estimates o f ‘substantive changes’ during the World War, 1914-17, [see
Khryashcheva, op. cit., pp. 14-20.
4 Keller and Romanenko, op. cit., p. 100. 5 Ibid., pp. 23-6.
8214036 M
i6o AGRARIAN REVOLUTION AND LEVELLING
land-redistribution after 1918 did not bring levelling trends to an abrupt end.
A levelling effect o f the centripetal mobility unrelated to agrarian reform1 on
land-redistribution became evident during the aggregate shift downwards of
the years 1919-20. Furthermore, though the expropriation during the revolu
tion o f horses and equipment seems to have had a limited effect on peasant
economy, the process o f differentiation in terms o f horses and equipment per
household closely followed the levelling observed in terms o f land sown per
household.2 Extensive centripetal mobility of the ‘usual’ kind must have been
operating as a major trend alongside the revolutionary distribution o f prop
erty in the Russian village and was especially important as far as the richer
strata were concerned. Moreover, the traditional form in which revolutionary
redistribution o f land took place gave a very specific flavour to the political
character o f the Russian agrarian revolution.
In quantitative terms, the centripetal and levelling effect o f multidirectional
and cyclical mobility during any consecutive five years o f the twenties was
comparable in strength to such mobility during the agrarian revolution o f
1917-18. This is not to say that the impact o f agrarian revolution was non
existent or insignificant. It is to say that multidirectional and cyclical mobility,
determined by the peculiarities of the Russian peasant social structure, were
extremely strong and cannot be disregarded in any analysis. It is to suggest,
furthermore, that, though the landless and the poorest strata were strongly
influenced by division o f non-peasant lands, the levelling effect recorded
both among the bulk o f the middle peasants and the richer strata derived
mainly from the aggregate downward shift, from differential rates o f ‘substan
tive changes’, and from powerful random oscillation o f peasant households.
1 The term ‘Rural Soviet’ has been used for the Russian expression sel'sovet. The term
‘Village Soviet’ is sometimes used, but it seems misleading, for a sel'sovet might cover a
rural area with a number of settlements having anything from 300 to ‘over 10,000’ in
habitants; see E. H. Carr, A History o f the Russian Revolution (1950), vol. i, p. 126.
2 Carr, op. cit., vol. i, p. 126; also vol. vi, p. 322. The first Soviet Constitution o f 1918
provided for a 5 to 1 ratio in terms of representatives per unit of population, in favour o
City Soviets as against Rural Soviets, thus scaling down the possible impact o f the peasant
majority. However, this was o f no internal significance for the rural and volost' organizations
themselves.
3 This feature was derived, in fact, from the Paris Commune; see ibid., vol. i, pp. 144-5.
4 For a full treatment, ibid., vol. vi, chaps. 20, 21, and 22.
5 See the Land Code o f 1922, Zemel'nyi kodeks RSFSR (1924)-
164 RURAL SOCIETY IN PERIOD OF N.E.P.
narrowly restricted to the problems of land-redistribution. The volost' Execu
tive Committees (V.I.K.) were to guide and control the activities o f ‘land
communes’ on their territories. In addition, a ‘rural gathering’ (sel'skii skhod)
was to be established in parallel with the ‘land gathering’.1 The ‘rural gather
ing’ would consist o f all the inhabitants with Soviet electoral rights within the
area o f a Rural Soviet. The ‘rural gathering’ was to exercise a democratic,
grass-roots control over those whom it elected to the Rural Soviet.
This was the structure o f local authorities which the new regime legislated
for the Russian countryside during the revolution and the subsequent process
o f establishment. However, to turn once more from laws and intentions to
reality, what were the actual relations o f power and authority in the Russian
village? What were the major diversities and group conflicts in the contem
porary Russian countryside? Finally, what were to be the implications o f the
power-structure, diversity o f interests, and conflict-relations for the next stage
o f the rural history o f Russia?
1 The decision to set up both rural and land gatherings was taken by a considerable
number o f regional authorities, proclaimed as necessary by a conference on the work of
Soviets held in 1925, and finally legislated on a national scale at the beginning o f 1927. See
M. Rezunov, Sel'skie sovety i zemel'nye obshchestva (1928), p. 23.
2 P. Pershin, Zemel'noe ustroistvo dorevolyutsionnoi derevni (1928), pp. 77-147, 207-81,
329-438. This spontaneous process had, o f course, been greatly accelerated by the Stolypin
reforms (see Chapter 2).
3 Novyi entsiklopedicheski slovar', Brokgauz and Efron (2nd ed n .), vol. xviii, p. 489.
4 See, for example, a report on the Russian colony in Lower California established in
1905: N. L. Whetton, Rural Mexico (1948), p. 164.
POWER, DIVERSITY, AND CONFLICT 165
of the N.E.P. more than 20,000,00c1 peasant households were organized in
300,000-400,000 peasant communes all over rural Russia.12 In many cases,
a commune corresponded to a settlement but, in a considerable number of
cases, a commune spread over several settlements—though, alternatively,
settlements with more than one commune were also reported.3 Some of these
communes (in particular in the west) were not repartitional, i.e. they did
not engage in periodical blanket distribution of fields between member-
households though otherwise displaying all the typical characteristics o f a
peasant commune. Some ‘super-communes’ were also reported. These ‘super-
communes’ united several peasant communes through common property in
meadows, forests, etc., and were headed by meetings of representatives of the
commune gatherings involved.4
As we have seen, Soviet law provided for two types of democratic assembly
to include most o f the adult inhabitants of a rural area; on the one hand, the
‘rural gathering’ and, on the other hand, the ‘land gathering’. This intention
o f the legislators never came to fruition, however. ‘The facts of life were
stronger than these principles of our law— Until now, in the decisive majority
o f the villages o f the R.S.F.S.R. the rural and the land gatherings are not dis
tinct and peasants who have lost their political rights actually participate in
the meetings’, sums up a major study in this period.5 Furthermore this report
stated that ‘The gathering consists o f the heads of households which are mem
bers o f the land commune. . . . Other members of peasant households are
present only accidentally.’6 The study described what amounted, in fact, to
the well-known features of the traditional peasant commune and its gathering,
with not much evidence of impact of a decade of Soviet rule and legislation.
The traditional peasant commune was possibly even strengthened by a de
crease in the importance o f extra-commune land holders and by some weak
ening o f external controls.
A peasant household had to recognize at least two types o f local authority
in the village, therefore; the formally established rural Soviet and the com
mune gathering with its somewhat dubious legal standing.7 However, a
number o f large-scale studies of the Russian countryside made during the
1 For example, S. Ossowski, Class Structure in the Social Consciousness (1963); J. Rex,
K ey Problems o f Sociological Theory (1961); R. Dahrendorf, Class and Class Conflict in
Industrial Society (1959).
2 For example, the six ‘classes’ in the classical studies o f ‘Yankee City’ by W. Lloyd
Warner and P. S. Lunt, The Status System o f a Modern Community (1942).
3 See Chapter 7, section (d).
4 Ibid.; also Chapter 4, sections (b) and (c). 5 See Chapter 7, section (c).
I70 R U R A L S O C IE T Y IN P E R IO D O F N .E .P .
T able 9 1
The social analysis underlying the policy o f the Soviet Government was
based on the assumption o f a necessary evolution o f the rural proletariat
(or, alternatively, o f the rural poor) into a ‘class for itse lf—a socialist
driving force against the rich peasants. The number o f wage-workers in the
rural areas was, therefore, anxiously studied.
The number o f rural wage-workers in Russia/U.S.S.R. (i.e. those to whom
wage-work was the main source o f livelihood) was recorded as 1,616,000 in
1917; their number had fallen to less than 1,000,000 in 1920 but had subse
quently increased to about 2,000,000 by 1926.1 O f rural wage-workers in
1926, nearly 25 per cent were as a matter of fact said to work on state farms
and 35 per cent as shepherds—mainly for the peasant communes. About
1.000. 000 rural wage-workers would therefore have been employed by
U.S.S.R. peasant households by 1926; this would account for about 2 per
1 For the results o f the agricultural census o f 1917 see M2 agrarnom froute (1925), nos.
7-8, pp. 72-3, for those o f the agricultural census o f 1920, see ibid., p. 72; for 1926 figures,
see Statisticheskii spravochnik SSSR 1927 g. (1927), pp. 307-8. The same sources are used
hereafter if not otherwise stated.
POWER, DIVERSITY, AND CONFLICT 171
cent o f the total labour force in the countryside. Furthermore, about one-
third o f the rural wage-workers consisted of temporarily engaged youngsters
below the age of seventeen.1The percentage of peasant households employing
permanent wage-labour was recorded as 3 3 per cent in 1917, 1 per cent (its
lowest) in 1920,2 and 17 per cent in 1924.3 This would have risen later, but a
majority o f the employing households were probably those short of manpower
in the poorer and middle strata rather than bigger or richer households.4
The discrepant figures given by different sources make any estimate o f Rus
sian rural wage-work, and in particular seasonal ones, somewhat dubious.
However, not much doubt remains that the numerical strength of the rural
proletariat was extremely low. So was capitalist exploitation, as defined in
classical Marxist terms.
The image o f a barely existent rural counterpart to the revolutionary urban
proletariat was quite unacceptable to the Bolsheviks. It could be avoided
however, were a wider concept of the ‘poor peasant’ (bednyak) employed. Any
operational definition o f the rural poor had necessarily to be arbitrary, but
substantial numbers of Russian peasant households would be included what
ever the precise definition used. The rural proletarians could then be seen and
treated as a more advanced section o f the rural poor. What was the character
o f the poorest strata of the Russian peasantry and how far could they be
treated as semi-proletarians in the process of class crystallization?
The study carried out by the Bolshevik Party organization in Penza gub.
during 1924 and 1925 is a unique source of data for the character of the rural
poor and on the causes of rural pauperization. The large sample and the
‘average’ character o f this guberniya (in relation to other regions of European
Russia) point to the general validity of the study.5 The survey presented in
Table 9-11 attempted to clarify, on the basis of the views expressed both by
the peasants and by an independent investigation, the question of the causes
o f poverty for peasant households described as poor.6
Shortage o f physically and mentally fit family manpower and, in particular,
o f mature and able-bodied males, had led to economic deterioration in up to
half of the poor households.7 N o doubt the same reason at least partly ex
plained the limited ability of this group to exercise political influence in the
1 Na agrarnom fronte (1925), nos. 1-2, pp. 4-8 and nos. 7-8, pp. 65, 77.
2 Ts.S.U. estimate (see ibid., no. 4, p. 71).
3 A. Khryashcheva, Gruppy i klassy v krest'yanstve (1926), p. 54.
4 Statisticheskii spravochnik 1927, pp. 86-9. For regional division see Itogi desyatiletiya
sovetskoi vlasti (1928), p. 162.
s In the sense of lacking exceptional characteristics and displaying indices of agricultural
production and rural social organization which closely followed those average for peasant
households of European Russia.
6 From 25-9 to 43*4 per cent o f Russian peasant households were defined as poor in the
districts under investigation. Rosnitskii, op. cit., pp. 22, 26.
7 For a classical study which demonstrated the high percentages of physically and
mentally handicapped, aged, lonely (,bobyli), widows, etc., within the poor strata, see
F. Shcherbina, Svodnyi sbornik po 12 uezdam voronezhskoi gub. (1897), p. 356.
172 RURAL SOCIETY IN PERIOD OF N.E.P.
community. The second major sub-group consisted o f households moving
downwards as a result o f partition or o f chance factors within the general frame
work o f multidirectional and cyclical mobility. Only a small part o f the poor
stratum consisted o f households with fit adult male workers and still remain
ing over a long period at the bottom o f peasant society. Despite the widespread
poverty in the Russian countryside, the chance o f a hard core o f poor peasants
showing lasting cohesion and ability for political action emerging was very
limited, therefore, because o f the group’s social composition. The key im
pressions conveyed by this survey are corroborated by less systematic in
formation from other sources, as well as suggested by the continued failure
o f party and governmental attempts to organize the rural poor.1
T able 9*11
The Causes o f Rural Poverty, Penza Gub., 1924-1923°
Percentage o f all
Causes^ the rural poor*
1 L. Kritsman et al.y op. cit., p. 318; see also Luzhin, op. cit., pp. 83-6.
POWER, DIVERSITY, AND CONFLICT 173
The word kulak (‘fist’ in Russian) was used to imply a mixture of social
definition, political evaluation, and plain abuse, if not slander. Commonly
the term was used in Soviet Russia in several different ways: either synonym
ously with: ‘member of the rural bourgeoisie’ exploiting fellow members
o f the peasant community, or for the head of a rich household, or also as a
description o f a political enemy of the Soviet regime,1 or even as a description
o f a mean personality. Estimates of the number of kulaks varied accordingly.
The Ts.S.U. studies in 1925 estimated kulak households as about 3 per cent
o f the total, with little change during the years o f N.E.P. However, at the same
time, the number o f villagers deprived of voting rights (lishentsy)—nominally
including all the kulaks as well as some other groups (ex-policemen, etc.)—
was reported to amount to only about 1 per cent of the adult rural population
in 1925.12 Kulaks, defined as those deriving substantial income from employing
wage-workers or engaging in usury or trade (a definition said to be widely
accepted by the peasants and used in the majority of contemporary local
studies—except those carried out by Ts.S.U.) would therefore have amounted
to even less than the 3 per cent estimated by Ts.S.U.3 The extremely small
numbers o f kulaks traced in villages led some Soviet scholars to unite this
stratum conceptually with the wider group of well-to-do (zazhitochnye). True
enough, the well-to-do and the majority of so-called kulaks did constitute
qualitatively indistinguishable strata; both showed higher incomes and
productivity.4 However, it is rather the smallness o f the differences between
their average per capita incomes and the incomes o f their less-successful
neighbours which is striking to us today in the studies of peasant budgets.
Moreover, the wealthier households were distinguished by being bigger and
more intensive in terms o f capital per unit o f land and per worker, by higher
productivity and income per capita in money terms, rather than by being
based on capitalist farming and the exploitation of wage-workers.5 The
wealthier households were particularly important in marketing and formed the
backbone o f the majority o f peasant co-operatives; they included a major part
o f the more competent and articulate farmers and potential political leaders.6
1 A special term, ‘kulaks’ stooges’ (podkulachniki), was invented for those political
opponents who could not by any stretch o f the imagination be regarded as members o f
the rural bourgeoisie.
2 For 1925 see Perevybory v sovety RSFSR v 1925)26 g. (1926), p. 6; the figure for 1924
was i*3 per cent (ibid., p. 6).
3 For example, Rosnitskii, op. cit., pp. 16-22; or I. Voronov, Gruppovoi sostav
voronezhskoi gub. 1925. 4 See Chapter 3, section (b).
5 See Chapter 4, section (b). Further investigation o f this matter is no doubt called for. As
already mentioned (Chapter 3, section (c)), Kritsman and his followers claimed that it was
the renting of equipment and horses which developed into a new and major channel of
capitalist exploitation in rural Russia. The volume o f income derived in this way was never
clearly established and the significance of the phenomenon in peasant communities remains
ambiguous.
6 See, for example, A. Bol'shakov, Derevnya, 1917-1927 gg. (1927), chapter on Co
operation. See also Rosnitskii, op. cit., Chapter 4.
174 RURAL SOCIETY IN PERIOD OF N.E.P.
Hubbard summarized as follows: ‘The Kulak was a Kulak because he
was more intelligent and enterprising. . . . N o doubt he generally made a
good bargain for himself but there was always a great deal o f mutual assis
tance and give and take among all classes in the village community.’1Even the
spokesmen o f the Soviet establishment were bound to declare that the mem
bers o f ‘the well-to-do stratum—i.e. the capitalists or those developing into
capitalists in the villages—are (together with the producers’ co-operatives)
the standard-bearers of agricultural progress. They use to a greater extent
advanced techniques, agricultural co-operation, school education, etc. This
stratum tends to become influential in the Rural Soviet as well as other local
authorities and its members to appear as representatives o f the peasantry
as a whole.’12
It was fully accepted by both scholars and politicians at the time that the
middle peasants formed a large majority of Russian peasant households.
Delineation o f this stratum was generally in negative terms:3 households
which neither hired nor provided wage-labour, which neither hired for use
nor rented out land, equipment, horses, etc. Defined in positive terms, this
would comprise small producers who, with the help of their families and
simple equipment, produced just enough to meet the basic consumption-needs
o f their families and the obligations imposed on them from outside. The
middle peasant was declared by official Soviet spokesmen ‘the major figure
o f the Soviet countryside’.4 N o doubt this declaration was true. However,
the fact o f the matter was that, in these terms, the middle peasants had always
(at least until 1930) constituted a decisive majority o f the Russian peasantry.
The Soviet Revolution o f 1917-18 had only exaggerated middle-peasant
dominance in the Russian countryside.
This description o f the composition of the main socio-economic strata goes,
therefore, to reinforce the conclusions drawn in Part II o f this study.5 The
social character o f the poorest stratum made its unification into a self-
conscious class and independent political action by it highly improbable.
The absence o f a division in community into qualitatively different and
conflicting groups o f employees and employers blunted potential class con
flicts. The middle peasant formed an overwhelming majority o f the rural
population. Well-to-do peasant households tended to include the ablest
1 See, for example, Rozit, op. cit., p. 8; see also the evidence quoted in the discussion of
the commune gathering in section (b), above, especially pp. 166-9.
2 See Chapter 2, section (b), and Appendix B.
3 On the other hand, women had, o f course, their influence by influencing men through
both personal pressures and the formulation of village public opinion. There seem also to
have been regional differences: women’s position seems to have been notably higher in the
far north of Russia.
8214930 N
176 RURAL SOCIETY IN THE PERIOD OF N.E.P.
labour force in the Russian countryside.1 With many men away for years,
the commune’s affairs were increasingly influenced by women. Heavy war
casualties meant that large numbers of widows (many of them with young
children in their care) had to take charge of households and they could no
longer be treated on the same footing as dependent women under male
tutelage. Later on, Soviet law established legal equality for women: the right
to participate in communal gatherings, to share family property, etc. With
the end of the civil war, the position of women never quite returned to the
pre-war situation. In some cases, the appearance and pressure o f women at
commune gatherings influenced decisions. In other cases, Bolshevik Party
rural activists failed to influence the men but succeeded in organizing the
women, appealing to their underprivileged position.2 This emancipation also
found its expression in a reported wave of partitioning initiated by women,
in many cases as part of divorce settlements.3 Yet, in the big majority of
villages, men, reinforced by tradition, seem successfully to have withstood
female emancipation. On the whole, men remained the heads of peasant
households. Women were stopped by public scorn or by sheer force from
attending commune gatherings.4 Heavy pressure from the Soviet government
raised the proportion of female members of Rural Soviets from 1 per cent
in 1922 to about 10 per cent in 1925, but the more real positions of authority—
chairmanship o f Soviets and officership in the commune—remained in the
hands o f men.5
On the whole, this position of subordination held true, too, for the junior
male members of peasant households.6 Conflict of power and will between
generations and its accompanying frustrations found a partial outlet in violent
family clashes and intra-family crime as w'ell as in the cock-like showing-off
o f young peasants, w?hen away from family and village control (in the army,
in town, and so on). Both the weakening of the patriarchal family and Soviet
legislation strengthened the hand of juniors in conflicts with heads of house
holds and with the older generation as a whole. Furthermore, war and military
service added to the prestige and the real pow'er of young men in the peasant
communities. Greater adaptability to new ideas made the younger members
o f the community the channels by which urban culture and political influence
came to the village and made them potential challengers of village tradition.
However, both emigration and partition provided major safety-valves for
these pressures. The selective emigration of the ablest (to go into education,
1 Female rural labour during the world war has been estimated as 71-9 per cent o f the
total. A. Anfimov, Rossiiskiya derevnya v gody pervoi mirovoi voiny (1962), p. 192.
2 See Rozit, op. cit., p. 77.
3 M. Kubanin, Klassovaya sushchnost' protsesa drobleniya krest'yanskikh khozyaistv
(1929), PP- 7 i - 5.
4 Rosnitskii, op. cit., p. 112.
5 Perevybory v sovety RSFSR v 1925/26 g. (1926), pp. 16, 20.
6 At the beginning of the century, Gurvich had even put forward a theory of rural class
warfare between generations; see Chapter 3 above.
POWER, DIVERSITY, AND CONFLICT 177
administration, etc.) deprived the rural youth of its potential leaders. Other
rebels could be ‘married off’ and apportioned land. As new heads of house
holds, they were then brought under the heavy pressure of additional respon
sibilities and they lost, on the whole, what could be treated as ‘fantasies of
youth’.
The traditional peasant social structure and social mobility provided both
powerful levers of social control and major safety-valves against possible
rebellion. Generally the female and/or junior members of peasant society
were successfully checked and controlled in spite of their inherent conflict-
ridden position and potential strength.1 Only when allied with additional
powerful factors could this diversity assume major importance.
and blood-feuds between communes over land, meadows, forests, or just over
past grievances whose actual content had long been forgotten.1 Homogeneity
did not equal unity and segmentation (and consequent socio-political
weakness) o f the peasants on a national scale found ample expression in
relations with neighbouring villages within the Russian peasantry in the
post-revolutionary period. However, it was interaction with qualitatively
different groups and social structures which proved crucial for the Russian
peasant communities.
1 See, for example, the reports of clashes between communes in V. Kellar and I. Roma
nenko, Pervye itogi agrarnoi reformy (1922), and a description of post-revolutionary societies
by V. Tan-Bogobaz (ed.), Revolyutsiya v derevne (1925)—in particular vol. ii. pp. 55* 102.
10
THE RURAL SOCIETY IN THE PERIOD OF THE
N.E.P.: THE PREDOMINANT CONFLICT
T able i o -i
Two amendments to the Table should be made for our purposes. Firstly,
Rural Soviets employed on the average two full-time officials each2 (generally
a chairman and secretary).3 This would add about 100,000 persons to the
figures for rural civil servants. Secondly, persons working in the rural co
operative trade system and living in the village have not been included
1 A case can be made for the inclusion under the same rubric of agricultural wage
workers. In view, however, of the character of this group, it has been treated in Chapter 9,
section (c), as a specific socio-economic stratum of the peasantry. In terms of numbers
rural craftsmen outnumbered the salariat, but most of them were basically peasants utilizing
a secondary skill (see above).
2 L. Kritsman, P. Popov, and Ya. Yakovlev (eds.), SeVskoe khozyaistvo na putyakh
vostanovleniya (1925), p. 810.
3 See Y. Taniuchi, ‘A Note on the Territorial relationship between Rural Societies, Settle
ments and Communes’, Discussion Papers, University o f Birmingham, Centre for Russian and
East European Studies (1966), Series RC/D, no. 3, p. 13.
i «2 THE R U R A L SOCIETY IN THE PERIOD O F N.E.P.
because their numbers cannot be ascertained. The salariat in the rural areas
o f the U.S.S.R. in the mid 1920s would appear to have amounted, all told,
to not much more than 1 per cent of the rural labour force.1The percentage of
families involved would be higher, probably about 2 per cent o f the rural
families. Similar proportions would seem to have held good for the Russian
Republic (the R.S.F.S.R.), which accounted for two-thirds o f the total rural
population o f the U.S.S.R.
The occupational groups presented in the above table may be roughly
grouped into a few major categories. The so-called rural intelligentsia (i.e.
the teachers, medical staff, veterinary surgeons, land surveyors, etc.) made up
more than half o f all salaried employees (two-thirds o f those listed in Table
10 -i).2 The executives of local authorities accounted for somewhat less than a
third, including the officials of the volost' and village authorities, the police, and
part o f the judiciary (in Table 10 -I the share of local administrators drops to
about 16 per cent). The remaining salaried employees represent a rather mixed
bag o f ‘others’ o f which trade and forestry employees (mainly forest guards)
and postmen account for the greater part.3
The rural intelligentsia, therefore, constituted the largest single category of
rural employees, yet their number in the countryside was still extremely small.4
Furthermore, the cultural and social distance separating them from the
peasantry was so great that, in spite of numerous attempts ‘to go to the people’,
no close relationship ever developed. Social contact and cultural interaction
are more difficult to quantify or study and, once more, systematic and reliable
mass evidence on the matter is lacking. Yet some evidence is provided by
memoirs and literature and may be turned to, faute de mieux.s The rural
intelligentsia lived in an ‘island’ o f its own creation in the midst o f the peasant
population. They remained socially and culturally detached: they spoke their
own dialect,6 lived their own social and cultural life, kept to their own kind,
and crowded into the few bigger and less agricultural villages (especially
1 About 800,000 out of a working population of some 70 million in the U.S.S.R. living
in rural areas, Statisticlieskii spravochnik SSSR za 1928 g. (1929), p. 44.
2 We use this expression in the sense accepted in Russian society to identify as a social
group persons exhibiting a variety of characteristics, some of which will be discussed later.
Possibly the best single characteristic usable for delineating this group in the conditions we
have outlined would be an occupation whose performance necessitates more than primary
education and the subsequent pursuit of formal occupational training.
3 A number of those listed in the table as ‘others’ would, no doubt, have qualified either
as members of the rural intelligentsia or as rural administrators.
4 Less than half a million in the rural population of 120 million of the U.S.S.R. at that
time (Statisticheskii spravochnik SSSR za 1927 g. (1927), p. 1). Alternatively, about 70 (of
whom 40 were teachers) in an average district (volost') with a population of about 17,000
and containing about 60 settlements (see below).
5 For example, A. Oknanskii, Dva godasredi krest'yan (1924), and M. Gorkii, O russkom
krest'yanstve (1922).
6 The differences between the Russian literary language used by the intelligentsia and the
language of the semi-literate masses were great. See, for example, the writings of Artem,
who tried to put to literary use the language of soldiers and peasants.
THE PREDOMINANT CONFLICT 183
villages which were centres of volost's) in which ‘there was somebody to talk
to’. They, on the whole, also remained distinct from the local administrators
and party members.1This isolation greatly restricted, in practice, the potential
cultural and political influence of the rural intelligentsia on the surrounding
population.2
The biggest single group of salaried employees and the most promising
channel for the spread of non-traditional culture was that of the teachers.
However, their impact was considerably weakened by the opposing and
contradictory pressures o f the state administration and the village communes,
both claiming rights as employers. Economic hardship and the dependence
o f the majority o f teachers on the communal gathering (to which they did not
belong) for the provision of the resources necessary for teaching and even at
times o f their own salaries made their position if anything more precarious
than that o f other members of the rural intelligentsia.3
Those o f the employees of the local rural administration accounted for in
Table 101 consisted mainly of the staffs of Volost' Executive Committees
(V.I.K.). In 1925, an average volost' in the R.S.F.S.R. had roughly 17,000
inhabitants and a territory of about 4,000 square kilometres.4 An average
volost' consisted o f about sixty settlements and was subdivided into about
ten Rural Soviet areas:5 the actual figures varied considerably from place to
place, however.
A V.I.K. was legally supposed to consist of three members and two candidate
members. However, the actual figures show an average of seven members per
V.I.K. rising to as many as thirteen or even more in some of the guberniyas in
1925. On average, three members of the V.I.K. were on its payroll as full-time
employees,6 plus an additional staff of some six to eight executives and clerks.7
These V.I.K. officials, supported by the most rudimentary means of com
munication, were responsible for the various aspects o f volost' welfare, col
lecting taxes, controlling the Rural Soviets and land communes, carrying out
1 The number of ‘members of the intelligentsia* elected in the U.S.S.R. in 1924-5 to
serve on the volost' Executive Committee (V.I.K.) was 596—i.e. about o*i percent of the
whole rural intelligentsia or 4 per cent of the total number of members of V.I.K. See
D. Rozit, Proverka raboty nizovogo apparata v derevne (1926), pp. 88-9. Kritsman,
op. cit., p. 811, also pp. 847-8.
2 In this sense, the rural intelligentsia proved to have the least overlap of membership
with other groups of outsiders and may be treated as a nearly pure case of outsider strangers.
3 See Kritsman, op. cit., pp. 829, 847-8; also Y. Taniuchi, The Village Gathering in Russia
in the Mid-1920s (1968), p. 7. The average size of a volost' increased as a result of the ad
ministrative policy of the Soviet government: the average volost' consisted of 12,000
inhabitants in 1924 (Kritsman, op. cit., p. 793).
4 Narodnoe khozyaistvo SSSR v tsifrakh, pp. 1, 11.
5 Taniuchi, ‘A note on the territorial relationship’ loc. cit.y p. 13.
6 A. Luzhin and M. Rezunov, Nizovoi sovetskii apparat (1929), p. 168.
7 Eight randomly picked guberniyas in 1924-5 showed 5,626 paid staff for 327 V.I.K.s, i.e.
an average of eleven members of staff per V.I.K. See Kritsman, op. cit., pp. 810, 812. This
study estimated the average number of staff-members per V.I.K. in the R.S.F.S.R. as
‘about 10’.
184 THE RURAL SOCIETY IN THE PERIOD OF N.E.P.
numerous governmental orders and instructions, and answering a stream of
questions coming both from the higher authorities and from the peasant
population.1
The militia, tax collectors, and part o f the judiciary acted under the V.I.K.’s
authority and were counted as belonging to the same category as its im
mediate employees. The rural executives to a considerable extent overlapped
with the party members and the ex-servicemen o f the Red Army: the pro
portion o f party members on the staffs o f local authorities was reported, for
example, as shown in Table i o - i i . See also Table i o *i v below.
T a b l e i o -ii
take on himself the punishment meted out by the rulers—was, no doubt, frequently used.
5 Rezunov, op. cit., p. 49.
6 G. Sharapov, Razreshenie agrarnogo voprosa v Rossiiposlepobedy oktyabr' skoirevolyutsii
1961), p. 114. The author also states that the total number of peasants who had joined the
Bolshevik Party before the revolution was 494; 4,122 joined in 1917 and 14,792 in 1918.
186 THE RURAL SOCIETY IN THE. PERIOD OF N.E.P.
peak o f 28 2 per cent in 1921. However, this development did not solve the
problem o f the paucity o f party members and party organizations in the
villages. This was particularly difficult to overcome in a situation where
activists were lacking, resources were scarce, and party members were
frequently called up. The new problem o f mastering state power, of win
ning a civil war, and o f coping with the decentralizing tendencies o f localities
made the Bolshevik leadership urge the spread o f party organization into the
peasant countryside. Bolshevik Party branches were to act as rallying points
for Soviet loyalists, and as watch-dogs o f the local administrative machinery.
T able i o - i ii
Sources. (A) Vserossiiskaya perepis' chlenov R K P 1920 g. (1923), p. 37, Table 33.
(B) A. Bol'shakov, Sovremennaya derevnya v tsifrakh (1925), p. 100.
Notes. a Probably ‘by social origin’ defined in terms of parent’s occupation and not of the
actual occupation of the member.
b Figures published in 1931 gave as much as 28*8 per cent of members of peasant origin
for 1924 which, however, was said to have declined steadily and reached 25*9 per cent in
1926 (E. H. Carr, A History o f the Russian Revolution (1959), vol. vi, p. 180). Another source
shows members and candidates of the Bolshevik Party of peasant origin as 18-4 per cent
(only 13*5 per cent i f ‘candidates’ are excluded) of the total in January 1927 (Itogi desyatil-
etiya sovetskoi vlasti (1928), p. 20).
A department for rural work (Otdel raboty v derevne) o f the central com
mittee was created early in 1919 to organize and co-ordinate the attempt to
penetrate the peasant villages. However, during 1919, the department only
managed to enlist 55 party organizers in all, who were sent to 35 guberniyas
with a combined population of not less than 50 million peasants.1 Small
wonder that, at the end o f a year, the report o f the department concluded: ‘as
may be deduced from our data, party work in the villages does not exist’
(raboty v derevne net).1
1 Otchet otdela raboty v derevne TsKRKP (1920), p. 5.
THE PR E D O M IN A N T CONFLICT , i87
Party branches classified as rural did, however, exist and were, in fact,
increasing. These organizations consisted of the party members living outside
towns, and were estimated in 1920 to total 4,238 branches with 23,000
members in 22 guberniyas of European Russia, populated by 32 million
peasants.1 By 1924, half of the total of 26,000 party branches in R.S.F.S.R.
were classified as rural. The rural branches included, however, only 22 per
cent o f the total membership, i.e. about 100,000 full party members, and
50,000 candidate members.2 The 1922 census of party members reported the
Bolsheviks as constituting 1-3 per cent of the urban population, but only 013
per cent of the rural population.3 At the end of 1924, the percentage of Bolshe
viks in the adult rural population in the main 15 guberniyas of European
Russia still only ranged between o-io per cent and 0 26 per cent.4
The membership of the rural branches of the Bolshevik Party consisted
mainly o f salaried executives. Those farmers by occupation (ot sokhi) (repre
senting more than 80 per cent of the total population of Russia, and about
95 per cent o f the rural population) remained an insignificant part of party
membership. In 1927, after the biggest recruitment drive in the villages which
had lasted for three years (the so-called ‘face to the countryside’ campaign),
party members actually engaged in farming were less than 7 per cent of the
national membership.5 Furthermore, members o f peasant origin (in particular,
those actually farming) headed the lists o f those expelled in the party purges
(chistki).6 The number of villages per single rural party branch in the main 15
guberniyas o f European Russia ranged from 9 to 123.7 Furthermore, three-
fifths o f these branches existed in villages which were administrative centres
o f volost's leaving nearly all the others without any party organizations at all.
Indeed, ‘in relation to the huge mass of 100 million Russian peasants, they
made a small handful, dispersed over the vast territory of U.S.S.R.’.8
A typical rural party branch would be set in the centre of a volost', and
consist o f twelve to fifteen members, at least ten of whom would hold admin
istrative posts—e.g. the chairman and some members o f the V.I.K., the judge,
the head o f the militia, the heads o f the local departments o f education and
propaganda, tax inspectors, and so on. Of this group, not less than one-third
1 Ibid., p. 8. The estimated size of the peasant population in the guberniyas referred to
is based on Sbornik statisticheskikh svedenii po SSSR , 1918-23 gg. (1924)* P- 8.
2 Kritsman, op. cit., p. 169.
3 ‘In this way, the kinship of the town with the proletarian revolution proved ten times
stronger than the kinship of the village’ (D. Rozit, op. cit., p. 9).
4 Kritsman, op. cit., pp. 770-2.
s E. Statten, Sostav VKP (b) (1927), PP- 19-20. In 1925 the figure was 8 per cent. See
E. H. Carr, A History o f the Russian Revolution (1959), vol. vi, p. 181.
6 Of those expelled and resigning from the Bolshevik Party in 1924, half were peasants
by origin, of whom four-fifths belonged to rural party branches (M. Khataevich, ‘Partiya
v derevne’, Na agrarnom froute (1925)* no. 2, p. 112.
7 Kritsman, op. cit., pp. 770-2. In 1925, the average figures for Russia were reported as
twenty-five or thirty villages per party branch (see Carr, op. cit., p. 311).
8 Kritsman, op. cit., p. 770.
188 THE RURAL SOCIETY IN THE PERIOD OF N.E.P.
would be newcomers with no roots in the locality, sent in to carry out various
administrative duties.1 Only two to four o f the members o f such a typical
branch would be engaged, to any extent, in farming. Members of the party
engaged in farming as their only source o f income were estimated in 1924 at
‘less than 15 per cent’12 o f the actual membership o f rural party branches.3
The position could, if anything, be worse. In the only available monograph
o f a volost' the author (a party member o f peasant origin) describes the volost'
party branch as consisting, in 1923, o f four members.4 (There were eighteen
members in 1918.) The four members were: the chairman and the treasurer
o f the V.I.K., the judge, and the local head o f the militia, o f whom only one
was a ‘proper peasant’ (korennoi krest'yanin).
The second and smaller category o f rural branches would contain those
situated outside volost' centres. On the whole, such branches are said to
consist o f five or six members filling various full- and part-time offices who
would be drawn from three or four villages.5 They tended to keep contact with
the volost' centre rather than with fellow-members in neighbouring locali
ties; this tended to make the very existence o f the branch illusory.6 Non-
administrative political contact with the peasant population barely existed.
The peasant image o f the rural party organization was best expressed by
the answer repeatedly given by peasants to an investigation, carried out in
1924-5, as to why they did not join the Bolshevik Party. They answered: ‘How
could the Party find so many posts (dolzhnostei) for us?’7 On examination, the
Schweikian wit o f this remark turns out to reflect a realistic appraisal o f the
state o f affairs.
N ot surprisingly, the internal life o f the rural branches did not have much
in common with peasant everyday life and problems. Actual farming was on
the whole not even discussed. Instead, the subjects o f discussion reported
include anniversaries o f revolutionary events, collections for M.O.P.R.
(International Red Aid—the organization for helping revolutionaries in prison
abroad), and even lectures on sexual ethics.8 Meetings were dominated by
reports on the oscillations o f state policy and the administrative problems of
carrying them out. The vague boundary between the areas o f competence of
the organizations o f the Soviet authorities and Party led many party branches
to take over the administrative duties o f the local authorities. On the other
1 Ibid., p. 75. The author speaks of the ‘invisible party branch’ (yacheika-nevidimka).
2 Ya. Yakovlev, Derevnya kak ona est' (1923), p. 74.
3 Rosnitskii, op. cit., p. 73.
4 Yakovlev, op. cit., p. 84.
5 See the reports in Rozit, op. cit., pp. 64-7.
6 Kritsman, op. cit., pp. 784-5; Carr, op. cit., vol. vii, p. 89.
7 Kritsman, op. cit., pp. 785-6. The figures are doubtful, but seem to express correctly
the main trend.
T90 THE RURAL SOCIETY IN THE. P E R IO D OF N.E.P.
1 Kritsman, op. cit., p. 786. Some other sources claim somewhat higher figures: see
Carr, op. cit., vol. vi, p. 99.
2 There seem to have been about 20 million peasants of Komsomol age in the R.S.F.S.R.
in the mid 1920s.
3 Kritsman, op. cit., p. 787; Rozit, op. cit., pp. 81-3. 4 Rozit, op. cit., p. 83.
5 The tension between generations reappeared also in a struggle for control between
Komsomol and party branches, reported from a number of localities. It is possibly this
which is reflected in the remarkably low representation of Komsomol members among
executive officers, chairman of Rural Soviets, etc. See Table io-iv; see also Taniuchi, The
Village Gathering, p. 77.
6 Kritsman, op. cit., p. 785; Carr, op. cit., vol. vi, pp. 91, 106.
7 One has to keep in mind the early age of marriage amongst the Russian peasantry. See
I. Pisarev, Narodonaselenie SSSR (1962), p. 178. For a discussion of this see Chapter 3,
section (a), above. 8 Rozit, op. cit., pp. 66-7; Carr, op. cit., vol. vi, p, 314.
9 Narodnoe khozyaistvo SSSR v tsifrakh, pp. 108-9.
THE PREDOMINANT CONFLICT 191
‘self-demobilization’ (mass desertions) followed but, at the height of the civil
war, the Red Army consisted once again of 5^ million men, while not less than
2 million Russian subjects served in the various White armies.1 The total
numbers in the Red Army decreased rapidly at the end of the civil war; in
1921— 1£ million, in 1922—560,00c.1 During the mid 1920s, about 1,200,000
young men each year reached call-up age; about 800,000 were found fit for
service, and about 260,000 (i.e. only about one-fifth of the total age-group)
were actually drafted.2 About 70 per cent of those called up were classified as
being o f peasant origin.3
The army provided Russian peasants with a social schooling of extra
ordinary importance. The traditional one-village outlook broke down under
the pressures o f a new style of living. These young peasants learned about
formal organization, large-scale and complex forms of co-operation, and new
skills—ranging from simple literacy to the handling of complicated machinery
and weapons. New life-experiences and contacts with new people considerably
broadened the outlook of young peasants and made them aware of the nation,
its problems, and the powers o f modern administration. The hierarchical army
structure provided the framework for a training in leadership based on achieve
ment rather than ascription.
In the Red Army, the young peasants were introduced to a new political
atmosphere and to a coherent political ideology. Half of the army commanders
were reported as belonging to Bolshevik organizations in 1926 (46 per cent to
the Party and 4 per cent to the Komsomol).4 The proportion among privates
and non-commissioned officers was 19 per cent (5 per cent Party, 14 per cent
Komsomol). The Red Army made a systematic effort to educate and politically
indoctrinate its servicemen. Political education and the maintenance of morale
was the task o f political commissars specially attached to every unit. This new
politicized environment, the example and influence o f commanders, and
systematic political indoctrination made a deep impression. The draft brought
4,700 members o f the Bolshevik Party and about 20,000 members of the
Komsomol into the army in 1924. Yet the closely similar group of those dis
charged from the service in 1926 included as many as 19,400 members of the
Bolshevik Party, and 50,000 members of the Komsomol.5 N o doubt various
degrees of cultural and ideological influence would also have been felt far
beyond those peasant soldiers who actually joined Bolshevik organizations.
With the end o f civil war, wartime soldiers gradually adjusted to the every
day life o f the peasant communes, and disappeared as a special social entity.
1 G . G o rd e e v , SeVskoe khozyaistvo v voine i revolyutsii (1925), P- H 5 *
2 B. Tal', Istoriya krasnoi armii (1929), p. 190.
3 S t a tis tic h e s k ii sp r a v o c h n ik S S S R z a 1 9 2 7 8 . (1927), p. 45 - Twenty-nine per cent of the
commanders and 78 per cent of the privates and non-commissioned officers in the Red
Army were reported to be of peasant origin in 1926 (ibid., p. 45).
4 Ibid.: see also Carr, op. cit., vol. vi, p. 415.
5 Tal', op. cit., pp. 190-1: this would seem to amount to one-third of those drafted
annually during the mid 1920s.
8214936 O
192 THE RURAL SOCIETY IN THE PERIOD OF N.E.P.
Yet, with peace, the impact o f ex-servicemen on village life was far from
coming to an end. Some of the peasant soldiers—perhaps those influenced
most by the new experience—remained in the army or settled in the towns.
Others returned to the village after a couple o f years. Closely bound to the
peasant communities through their households, these ex-servicemen brought
with them the new skills, contacts, and views they had acquired; they acted
as a powerful channel for outside cultural influences to make their way into
the peasant communities.
Many returning ex-servicemen brought with them a desire for change,
rebellious views about the nature of social relationships, and new attitudes to
the Soviet regime.1 The freshly discharged ex-servicemen seemed to challenge
the traditional peasant establishment, time and time again, by setting up new
organizations (of the Bolshevik Party, the Komsomol, co-operatives, etc.).
They budded off and organized new villages (vyselki)— a peculiar kind of
rebellion by the younger generation against the heavy pressures o f village
tradition and their elders.2 Eventually the commune establishment usually
succeeded in bringing them under control.3 The ex-servicemen married,
created new households, and integrated into the peasant commune, gradually
losing the ‘outsider’ qualities they had acquired in the past. A significant group
o f returning ex-servicemen joined the rural administration and party organ
izations, however, and never became fully reintegrated into peasant society.
For example, in 1925-6, 54 per cent o f all the chairmen o f Rural Soviets and
70 per cent o f the chairmen o f V.I.K.s4 were Red Army ex-servicemen;
as many as 92 per cent of the chairmen o f V.I.K.s were ex-servicemen in
Stalingrad guberniya.5
T a b l e i o -i v
Chairmen of
Volost' Executive
Committees (A) 1925-6 86-0 85*2 o-8 707 48-3
Members of
Volost' Executive
Committees (B)a 1924 614 700
(A) 1 9 2 5 -6 50-5 467 3*8 67*3
Chairmen of
Rural Soviets (A) 1925-6 18*o 14-3 3-7 53*i 953
(C) 1925 5*9 36 2-3 937
The discrepancy between the aims and requests o f higher authority and the
resources o f the volost' leadership was stupendous. The Soviet local executive
lived under perpetual pressure from an everlasting string o f orders, requests,
instructions, and threats coming from the various branches o f the state and
party machinery. He was kept in an atmosphere o f perpetual involvement in
several simultaneously running campaigns, generally without the allocation
o f any additional resources.2 The Weberian model o f ideal-type bureaucracy
1 Luzhin, op. cit., p. 148. The ‘sections* o f the V.I.K.S intended to deal with the various
aspects o f local welfare simply did not work (ibid., p. 216).
2 Frequent complaints were voiced about the staff o f V.I.K.s being overworked. For
example, see ibid., p. 168.
THE PREDOMINANT CONFLICT 195
acting in an apolitical, rational, and objective manner would, no doubt, have
seemed ridiculous to this group. Not objectivity, but zealous devotion was
required by the higher authorities; personal failure had the smell of treason
and counter-revolution. Silent peasant defiance of orders added to the general
atmosphere reminiscent of a harassed besieged garrison.
An additional element of tension was that this heavily overworked group
was extremely badly paid. Salaries varied in different areas and periods but
in 1924, members o f V.I.K.s received an average monthly salary of less than
20 roubles; it amounted to as little as 12 roubles in many cases. Chairmen
o f Rural Soviets were reported as receiving less than 10 roubles a month.1
The average salary o f an urban state employee during the same period was
36 roubles per month whilst for those in Moscow the sum was 42 roubles
per month.12
The discrepancy between aims and resources, between personal power and
limited income, between the authority granted and the insecurity felt in
the position led to two opposite reactions. On the one hand, recourse to harsh
administrative methods, arrests,3 and beatings of the peasants by particularly
zealous devotees o f the Party were widely reported.4 This reflected the diffi
culties experienced in trying to carry out the orders of the higher authorities,
the common lack o f administrative experience, and the tension generated by
the feeling that peasant households ‘had it too good’. On the other hand,
cynicism and corruption spread; this is evidenced by the frequently reported
embezzlement o f public funds,5 bribes, and cases of gross drunkenness
indulged in company with the richer peasants.6
The heavy external pressures, the similarity of problems, and a way of life
far removed from the great majority of the rural population all tended to
produce small and exclusive groups o f ‘outsiders’, sharing a particular sub
culture, in the volost' centres. Their members lived in their own world of
problems, images, values, friendships, and sociability which centred around
the V.I.K. and the local party branch, and was vastly remote from the world
o f the surrounding peasant communes. Many of the plenipotentiary outsiders
5 See Table i o -i v . More than half o f the members o f the V.I.K.s (including the chairmen)
consisted o f party members and Red Army ex-servicemen.
THE PREDOMINANT CONFLICT 197
carious. The chairmen of Rural Soviets, as we have seen, were a good example
o f this. Both the members of the Komsomol and the Red Army ex-servicemen
constituted a group of potential party sympathizers but, under the pressure
o f this deep political and cultural polarization of rural society, they tended
either to join the administration or to dissolve into the peasant mass. The
members o f the Komsomol were prevented, what is more, by the older
generation, from making any real impression on the Volost' Executive.1 Party
reports o f this period complain endlessly about the lack of non-party peasant
sympathizers in rural areas, ready to shoulder the burden of political work.2
The Bolshevik Party did not fare much better with the rural intelligentsia,
which remained isolated.3
The power structure o f Russian rural society, was, therefore, characterized
by a profound dualism. Real power was held, on the one hand, by the peasant
commune gatherings and, on the other hand, by the plenipotentiaries o f the
state administration, embodied in the V.I.Ks and the party branches; the
Rural Soviets played a mainly subsidiary role. The members of the volost'
power caucus operated not as ‘power-brokers’, to use J. Steward’s and E.
W olf’s term (i.e. a buffer group typical of many rural societies, mediating
between the state power and the peasants, having resources of its own and a
reasonable field o f manoeuvre4), but was totally dependent on the national
leadership. Polarization was in fact reinforced by the weakness and lack of
stability o f what buffer groups there were5 and by the cultural diversity of the
members o f the major groups. The image of a dual society resembling the one
depicted by Boeke as typical of rural areas in the contemporary ‘developing
societies’6 was further complicated in our case, however. The essential dualism
o f the power structure was associated with an essentially threefold division in
the cultural sphere: the Russian rural intelligentsia constituted a third closed
group—that o f ‘stranger outsiders’, who lived alongside the peasant com
munes and the other distinct group o f ‘plenipotentiary outsiders’. Moreover,
once again the overlap between the three groups was very limited and the
groups which could possibly bridge the gulf were notably weak.
(e) The Rural Power Structure and the Future Development o f the Countryside
During the period discussed, the great majority of Russians lived within the
social framework o f peasant society. The revolution and civil war had dis
located the main pre-revolutionary classes and social groups of Russia—with
1 See Table io -iv. 2 Rozit, op. cit., pp. 66-7-
3 See Chapter 10, section (a), above.
4 See, for example, Fei Hsiu-Tung, ‘Peasantry and Gentry’, American Journal o f Sociology
(1946), and E. R. Wolf, ‘Aspects o f Group Relations in a Complex Society: Mexico’,
American Anthropologist (1956), no. 6, pp. 1075-6.
5 See, for example, the discussion of the position of the chairmen o f a Rural Soviet in
Chapter 10, section (a), above.
6 J. Boeke, Economics and Economic Policy o f Dual Societies, as Exemplified by Indonesia
( 1953).
198 THE RURAL SOCIETY IN THE PERIOD OF N.E.P.
the sole exception o f the peasants. At the same time, it gave rise to a new
power elite embodied in the urban-centred Bolshevik Party and the machinery
o f the Soviet state. During the N.E.P. period these two profoundly different
forces faced each other nationally in an uneasy truce.
On the local level, the revolution led to considerable changes in the patch-
work o f the socio-political groups in the Russian countryside. Some o f these
groups had disappeared completely (e.g. the landed nobility), the importance
o f others had increased (e.g. the ex-servicemen and the women), and significant
new groups had come into being (e.g. the Party members). The source-group
and the personality-type o f those recruited to man the local administration
had also changed, reflecting the needs and views o f a new and radical national
leadership. At the same time the socio-economic differentiation o f the
peasantry diminished, mobility went up, enclosed farms disappeared, and
the engagement in crafts and trades lessened, increasing the homogeneity of
the peasant communes and limiting chances o f a ‘Western’ path o f moderniza
tion by the growth o f the market economy. These changes made the politi
cal divisions o f the Russian rural society all the more significant for future
developments.
The political dynamics o f Russian rural society in this period were related
to a variety o f conflict relations at work, one o f which seems clearly to have
overshadowed the others and to have become predominant in the political
life o f the countryside. This conflict-relationship developed between peasant
communes and the plenipotentiary outsiders, reflecting on the local level the
relationship between the peasantry and the Soviet state.
The position and actions o f the plenipotentiaries were to a decisive extent
determined by the national organizations and leadership. The implementation
o f state rural policies was strongly influenced by the depth o f the gulf existing
between the members o f the peasant communes and the plenipotentiaries in
the Russian countryside. The possibility o f the latter’s influencing the Russian
peasant communities by political mobilization o f various groups o f the
peasantry was limited to an extreme; various exercises in pressure and coercion
were the main, if not the only, contact and in these the power o f the state
found its match in the silent stubbornness of the peasant communities.
On the other hand the political stand and the social impact o f the peasant
communes was a result of the peculiarities of the peasant social structure.
Defensive conservatism faced state pressures. The vertical segmentation
embodied both the strengths and the weaknesses o f the peasant groups: the
intense solidarity o f each village meant disunity between the villages; the
division into cohesive households and communes gave rise to the socio
political weakness shown by the peasantry as a whole. Without outside
organizers, peasant action and pressure remained, as a rule, localized; the
peasants lacked national organization, symbols, and leaders and stood little
chance in an open clash with the bureaucratic organization which the state
THE PREDOMINANT CONFLICT 199
and the ruling party constituted. Yet the ability of the state machine to break
peasant resistance by a full display of force did not mean that it had the ability
to shape the future in accordance with its untrammelled will. The choices open
were determined by the existing social structure, by the resources available,
and by the apprehension of reality by the major political ‘actors’.
During the N.E.P. period, the tremendous passive power of the Russian
peasant communities proved incapable of generating a political alternative
and uniting for political action. The Soviet state machinery and the Bolshevik
Party did have the power, but lacked a perception of the real social processes
going on in the Russian countryside. Worse still, the remoteness of the local
representatives of the Bolshevik Party and the state from the peasantry
blocked the very channels by which an adjustment of concepts and policies
to reality could have taken place. With the political leadership committed to
a misleading conception of rural society, with its local representatives out of
touch with the peasantry in nearly all contexts other than coercive admin
istrative force, with the power of the communes decisive in local affairs, yet
unable to dictate national policy and bound to be defeated in a full-scale
confrontation with a modern state, the stage was set already in the mid 1920s
for the drama o f collectivization.
APPENDICES
APPENDIX A
THE PEASANTRY AS A POLITICAL FACTOR1
P e a s a n t s are the majority of mankind. For all but comparatively few countries,
‘the people’ (as opposed to ‘the nation’) still denotes ‘the peasants’; the specific
‘national culture’ closely corresponds to peasant culture; ‘the army’ means young
peasants in uniform, armed and officered by men different from themselves. And
yet one has to be reminded of this.
‘It is a commonplace to say that agrarian history, as such, is neglected—the fact
is too obvious to be denied’ :2 this holds true for many branches of social science
as far as the countryside is concerned. The dozen years which have elapsed since
this passage was written have not much improved the situation, apart from several
notable exceptions in the fields of anthropology and history in the last few years.
Indeed, in the growing flood of social science publications, the few existing rural
studies have almost been submerged.3 But reality seems to confute this solipsism
of the ‘civilized’ mind. Day by day, the peasants make the economists sigh, the
politicians sweat, and the strategists swear, defeating their plans and prophecies
all over the world—Moscow and Washington, Peking and Delhi, Cuba and Algeria,
the Congo and Vietnam.
Even more striking than the neglect of its study are the emotional undertones and
diversities of opinion which shroud this subject. Mitrany’s 400 pages4 bring together
but a fraction of the views expressed. Writers, scientists, and politicians have all
contributed to the discussion, in which the image of the peasant has swung from
that of an angelic rustic humanist to a greedy, pig-headed brute. For example, in
Russia, in one and the same period, the peasantry was held to be ‘the real autocrat
of Russia’5 and ‘non-existent, historically speaking’.6 This kind of verbal contest
did not make reality much clearer. The peasantry went its own way, quite oblivious
of being an intellectual nuisance.
The emotional tension underpinning ambiguous contempt or utopian praise, the
replacement of definition by allegory, as well as acute shortcomings in the conceptual
grasp of the peasantry, are only too strongly felt in the Western intellectual tradition.
The neglect of the subject is but a symptom of this. It calls for a serious study, in
the field of the sociology of knowledge, of the eidos of intellectual image-makers
when dealing with the ‘class that represents the barbarism within civilisation’.7 The
treatment of peasant action as an ‘undecipherable hieroglyphic to the understanding
of the civilised’7seemed to be determined by a conglomeration of factors, of which
1 First published in The Sociological Review, vol. xiv (1966), no. 1.
2 F. Dovring, Land and Labour in Europe, 1goo-1950 (1956)* P- 5-
3 The discussion was brought up to date inT. Shanin (ed.), Peasants and Peasant Societies
(1971). Also T. Shanin, ‘Peasantry, a Delineation of Concept and a Field of Study’,
European Journal o f Sociology (1971).
4 D . Mitrany, M arx against the Peasant (1951), dealing with Marxist as well as Populist
ideologies.
5 V. Chernov, as quoted by J. Maynard, The Russian Peasant (1967), p. 97.
6 G. Plekhanov on the Russian peasantry.
7 K. Marx and F. Engels, Selected Works (1950), vol. i, p. 159-
204 APPENDIX A
one stands out as crucial. The peasantry does not fit well into any of our general
concepts of contemporary society. This ‘maddening* peasant quality seems to lie
at the roots of the problems of research in this field.
In this paper we shall start by an attempt to define the differentia specifica of the
peasantry—the uniqueness by which the peasantry may be defined and selected.
This analytical definition1 will then be used as a reference-point in the historical
context. From here we shall proceed to the problem of the peasantry as a part of
society, and then to the patterns of political action of this entity. In dealing with
this subject, other approaches are feasible—and, indeed, needed. The translation
of rich, complex reality into a verbal form of fewer dimensions makes many ap
proaches possible and valid, subject to recognition of the limitations involved.
1 See, for example, on the influence of the stratification of the peasantry on political
action, H. Alavi, ‘Peasantry and Revolution’, The Socialist Register (1965).
2 Marx and Engels, Selected Works, vol. i, p. 303-
216 APPENDIX A
are acting temporarily as class entities though not bearing all the features of a class
and their place in political processes.
(iii) Fully spontaneous, amorphous political action . This pattern seems to be highly
typical of peasants’ impact on politics, and may take one of two forms:
(a) Local riots which ‘suddenly’ appear as short outbursts o f accumulated frus
tration and rebellious feeling. Generally easily repressed by the central authorities,
these riots may act as a check on central policy and stimulate change. When related
to crisis in other areas and spheres, they may develop into nation-wide movements
capable of determining major political development.
(b) Peasant passivity. The conceptual grasp o f passivity as a factor of the dynamics
poses some complex questions. Yet the spontaneous restriction of production by
the Russian peasantry in 1920 proved strong enough to frustrate the will of a govern
ment victorious in a war against powerful enemies. Enormous numbers of govern
ment decrees and orders have, all over the world, been voided of effect by the
peasantry’s spontaneous, stubborn, and silent non-fulfilment. The influence of
conservative peasant ‘apathy’ has also many times proved decisive for the victory
of ‘the establishment’ over revolutionaries. That passive resistance is actually a
specifically peasant contribution to politics with a long history, merely elabor
ated and sophisticated by Tolstoy and Gandhi, has been already suggested by
R. E. F. Smith. The existence of a relationship between the basic features of peasant
society and passive forms of resistance seems evident.
In the study o f the political life of societies, especially those which include
numerous peasants, armed action has a place of special importance. Clausewitz’s
remark that ‘war is an extension of politics by other means’ holds true not only for
the relations between states. This leads us to the need specially to consider the
army and guerrilla warfare as frameworks of peasant political action.
The modern conscript army is one of the few nation-wide organizations in which
the peasantry actively participates. The segmentation of the peasantry is thereby
broken. The cultural intercourse involved, even if there is no indoctrination, teaches
the peasant-soldier to think in national and not just village-limited terms. He is
taught organization, complex co-operative action, co-ordination, modem tech
niques, and military skills. The army provides him with a hierarchical institution
through which he may rise as a leader and be trained for this position. Even where
other national bodies have organizations represented in the rural level, it is generally
the army which has provided the peasant with the framework for the most active
participation.
This increase in the peasant’s ability to act politically is, while he is in the army,
on the whole successfully curbed by rigid discipline and by control exercised by non
peasant officers. Yet, in a time of crisis, this repression may disappear and the
attitudes, action, or refusal to act of a peasant army may become decisive. Moreover,
the experience gained in army service acts as an important influence later in the
villages. The ex-serviceman, because of his new experiences, tends to become a
leader and a channel through which outside influences reach other villagers. In
attempting to organize politically, peasants frequently refer back to their army ex
perience. The Russian Tamanskaya armiya and ‘Green Army of the Black Sea’, the
F.L.N., the Chinese ‘People’s Militia’, the Zapata and Villa armies in Mexico,
served not only as the military organizations but also as the main political organiza
tions—a kind o f party in arms.1
1 One such force is described by Marx in the Communist Manifesto when speaking of the
PEASANTRY AS A POLITICAL FACTOR 217
The army, as this kind of organization, may bear the marks of both the first and
second patterns of political action we have described—i.e. the peasantry as ‘a class
for itself’ and as a ‘guided’ socio-political entity.
During the last decade, guerrilla warfare , by its success, moved into the centre of
public attention. American strategists approach guerrilla warfare as a specific
military technique to be taught by smart sergeants along with saluting and target
practice. Their failures in both guerrilla and anti-guerrilla warfare in Vietnam is the
best comment on this approach.
Guerrilla warfare is the most suitable form for the expression of armed peasant
action. The record of it seems to be as old as the peasantry itself. Innumerable rebels
brigands, and outlaws appear in the myth, in the folk-memory of every people as well
as in its real history. The ability of the amorphous guerrilla ‘army’ to dissolve itself
in times of need into the sympathetic peasant mass and vanish into the expanses of
the countryside, its ability to utilize various degrees of peasant militancy and
friendly passivity, its ability to survive without outside supplies, and the adequacy
for this type of warfare of primitive weapons may make guerrillas unbeatable by
modern military methods.
Yet the essentially peasant character of guerilla warfare provides not only its
strength but also its weaknesses: segmentation, lack of crystallized ideology and
aims, lack of stable membership. These essential weaknesses may be overcome by
the injection of a hard core of professional rebels, making the revolt into guided
political action. The professional rebels’ nation-wide ideological and organizational
cohesion, their ability and zeal, and their ability to work out a long-term strategy
may enable them to unite the peasantry, sometimes transforming its revolt into a
successful revolution. Yet the main key to the understanding of guerrilla warfare
has to be sought not in the marvels of the rebels’ organization, but in their relation
ship with the peasantry; not only in the military techniques of the few, but in the
sociology of the mass.1
There are subjective determ inants o f m ilitary action—generally labelled ‘m orale'
whose resistance to quantification does not negate their importance in the shaping of
reality. Peasant revolts all over the world display common cultural features which
in all their complexity, seem to have been better caught in the synthetic expressions
of the arts than dissected by the analytical tools of the social sciences. The leader-
hero, the legends which surround him, his personal charisma—these to a large
extent take the place of ideology and organization as unifying factors. The pictur
esque image of the young peasant rebel challenges the mundane nature of everyday
peasant life. The childish display of exhibitionism, described by Znaniecki as typical
of the peasant’s attempts to establish his own personality when breaking out of
rigid family ties,2 explains much of the spirit of peasant fighters. All these features
influence the general character of peasant units as a fighting force, together with the
specific values and self-images of the leading Elites.
The main stream of contemporary sociology has bypassed the traditional peas
antry. Rural sociology has been localized in and financed by rich industrial societies
early stage of bourgeois class organization as ‘an armed and self-governing association in
the mediaeval commune’. Marx and Engels, Selected Works, vol. i, p. 34.
1 Inroads into research on this subject have been made by E. Hobsbawn in Primitive
Rebels (1959), and ‘Vietnam and the Dynamics of Guerilla Warfare’, in New Left Review
(1965), no. 33. See also Monthly Review , vol. xvii (1965) on guerrilla activities in Latin
America. 2 Thomas and Znaniecki, op. cit., p. 103.
218 APPENDIX A
and has consequently been centred upon the problem of how to promote members
of farming minorities into fully productive and prosperous members of ‘civilized
society’. Few sociologists have so far elevated the peasantry from the footnote to
the page. Yet, were historical and social significance the criteria for the choice of
objects of study, we should be almost overwhelmed by the flood of publications
on the peasantry. Innumerable problems of our world’s political and economic
development lead us back to the subject of the peasantry, to the understanding and
misunderstanding of it by policy-makers. To take but one example, the history of the
Soviet Union has time and time again (in 1918, 1920, 1927-9, etc., up to the 1960s)
largely been shaped by unexpected responses to the ruling party’s policies, based on
such evaluation and prediction. Countless other examples could be cited from
Africa, Asia, Latin America, etc.
Only a cross-disciplinary combination of both conceptual and factual studies may
overcome the shortcomings in our knowledge of the peasantry, in spite of the
methodological difficulties involved. Limping along main roads achieves more than
strolling along side roads.
APPENDIX B
RUSSIAN PEASANT LAW AND THE INHERITANCE OF PROPERTY
1 We here use the word ‘inheritance’ in its widest sense—i.e. the passing on of property
from generation to generation—and not only in the legal sense adopted by civil law of both
the Roman and the British varieties and related necessarily to death of the owner.
2 In 1906-14 and 1918-21. 3 Mukhin, op. cit., p. 109.
4 SeeSvod zakonov reprinted in V. Gsovski, Sov/e/ Civil (1949), vol. i,p. 621.
5 Ibid., p. 99; also Khauke, op. cit., p. 209.
6 Mukhin, op. cit., p. 90. A peasant proverb seems to express this attitude: ‘By keeping
my parents I pay my debts, by helping my sons I give a loan, by giving to my daughter I
chuck away (za okno brosayu).’ (Mukhin, op. cit., pp. 122-3.)
7 Ibid., pp. 243-4. The view that Russian peasant women enjoyed full equality of property-
rights expressed by Stepnyak in The Russian Peasantry (1888), p. 130, and requoted by M.
Hindus in The Russian Peasant and the Revolution (1920), was based on a misinterpretation,
as is clearly demonstrated in Mukhin’s authoritative exposition of all the sources from which
Stepnyak drew his conclusions.
RUSSIAN PEASANT LAW AND INHERITANCE OF PROPERTY 223
The customarily accepted property-rights of male members of the family, in cases
of partitioning, were characterized by a high degree of equality. The rights of an
adopted member were equal to those of descendants,1 as also were the rights of
minor males.12 A member who had benefited from apportionment relinquished his
rights to take part in any further sharing of the original household property.3 In
partitioning, or in the case of apportionment to a member, the division of the
property was left to the discretion of the head of the family, on the understanding
that all members (but only members) got their share.4 If challenged before a peasant
court or carried out on its order, sharing would tend to be fairly equal, though
influenced, to some extent, by judgements on the personal qualities of the members
—their industriousness, sobriety, and so on.5 Generally, awareness of public opinion
and the attitudes of the peasant magistrates would determine the decision of the
head of the household and tend to make division fairly egalitarian.6 The household
property was generally divided into fairly equal shares among all male members with
some additional portion for the member who accepted responsibility for the aged
and the females.7 Among the great majority of Russian peasantry inheritance by
a non-member of the household was practically unknown. Inheritance by will did
not exist as far as land and agricultural equipment were concerned and, in other
cases, was extremely limited and open to challenge as unjust before the peasant
courts. In cases where the members of a household did not want to part after the
death of the head, one of them (generally the eldest son) became, by common con
sent, the new head.
The partitioning of a peasant household was legally defined as ‘the division of
members and property into new peasant households’.8 Inheritance as a result of
the death of an ‘owning’ head of household was, therefore, treated as a special case
of partitioning. Where no male members of a household remained, the household
was declared escheated ( vymorochnyi). In a repartitional commune, the farm then
became the disposable property of the commune. In villages consisting of enclosed
farms the custom about escheated households varied, sometimes allowing for in
heritance by blood relations and, at other times, taking the same form as in the
repartitional communes.9
The Russian government repeatedly attempted to limit the partitioning of house
holds to cases where it was ‘economically justifiable’. However, they failed either to
convince or to force the Russian peasantry to act in an ‘economically rational’ way,
alien to peasant values and the social structure. This legislation only succeeded in
increasing the number of illegal yet customarily accepted partitions.10
Generally, partitions were carried out either at the wish of the head of the house
hold or immediately following his death. Both courses of events were accepted as
natural. The main reasons put forward for partitioning were the desires of members
1 Mukhin, op. cit., p. 20. 2 Ibid., pp. 15, 60. 3 Ibid., p. 79.
4 Ibid., pp. 66-7; Khauke, op. cit., p. 203.
5 Mukhin, op. cit., p. 59; Khauke, op. cit., p. 187.
6 The actual procedure of partitioning seems to have varied a great deal. For carrying out
partitioning in cases of disagreement, a peasant could resort to different agencies, e.g. the
peasant court, the peasant assembly, older or respected members of the community, etc.;
see Khauke, op. cit., p. 223.
7 Mukhin, op. cit., pp. 120-31, 155. An unmarried woman might sometimes present an
ill-defined claim for a dowry and clothes; in a few localities, she might even inherit land.
8 Khauke, op. cit., p. 219. 9 Ibid., p. 196.
10 Khauke, op. cit., pp. 202, 222; also Mukhin, op. cit., p. 155.
8214086 Q
224 APPENDIX B
for independence, and increased family tension. In cases where the head of the
household was unwilling to effect a partition, he might well be forced into it. The
law of 1886 allowed for partitioning by decision of the commune gathering ( skhod)
against the wish of the head of household in cases o f prodigality or immoral behav
iour; in practice, these justificatory circumstances were considerably widened to
include cases of family quarrels, disregard of other members* rights, and the like.1
Studies of peasant customs revealed wide diversity according to locality, a fact
which gave rise to considerable argument amongst scholars. Yet there was no
disagreement on the fact that, ‘granting diversity in detail, the basic principles of
partitioning have shown surprising uniformity*.2
1 Kubanin, op. cit., Part III, Na agrcrnom fronte (1928), no. 11, p. 11.
2 Ibid., p. 15. 3 Khauke, op. cit., pp. 201-2.
4 Kubanin, op. cit., Part III, Na agrarnom fronte (1928), no. II, p. 15.
5 Dekrety sovetskoi vlasti (1957), vol. i, pp. 17-20. ‘Land-workers’ amounted in fact 10
the members of peasant households. 6 Gsovski, op. cit., vol. i, p. 624.
7 ibid., p . 618. 8 Zemel'nyi kodeks RSFSR (1924)-
226 APPENDIX B
for it (paragraphs 68, 69). The legal possibility of renting land and hiring labour was
now reinstated (paragraphs 29, 39), but this was tempered by time-limits and the
requirement that an employer should work alongside his employees. Inheritance by
will or receipt o f household property by gift was forbidden, as was the buying or
selling o f land (paragraph 27). Partitioning, defined as the creation of new house
holds, had to be carried out on the basis of equal rights for all members of the house
hold (this was limited, however, by the degree o f labour-participation o f the adult
members—paragraphs 67, 74). Farms declared extinct became the property of the
village commune (paragraphs 18, 20).
In 1921 peasant property affairs were placed under the Land Departments of
local Soviets, and ‘taken out of the jurisdiction of the General Court’.1 By 1922, the
peasantry had been put under the civil jurisdiction of the Land Commissions here
acting specifically as courts, with the Chief Land Commission of the Peoples’ Com
missar (Minister) of Agriculture acting as the highest court of appeal.12 This was
reaffirmed in paragraph 80 of the Land Code.
In two respects the Land Code differed significantly from peasant customary law.
Firstly, women became equal members of the household, with all rights, including
equal shares on partitioning (paragraph 67). Secondly, much wider equality among
members of the household was asserted. This was expressed, for example, in the
provision that all adult members of the household (and not only its head) should be
members of the commune gathering (paragraph 75).
The only element of Stolypin-type legislation found in the 1922 Code was a legal
provision to limit partitioning by allowing the Peoples’ Commissar of Agriculture
to declare a minimum size of land-plot, into smaller units than which partitioning
would be forbidden (paragraph 88).3 However, this piece of legislation never, in
fact, became operative.
‘We have overcome the written law of the Imperial regime comparatively easily,
yet the old law is quite persistent in the form o f customary law. It is still dominant
among the peasants, though it is losing its power.’4 This evaluation by a prominent
spokesman of the People’s Commissariat of Justice, was if anything, over-optimistic.
The Code of 1922 proved this by being itself little more than a codification of
nineteenth-century peasant legal custom. Only in the field of female equality could
some substantial legal changes be discerned.
During the period 1906-28 legislative attempts of elites at extreme ends of the
political spectrum had failed to reshape basic peasant customs and social behaviour
regarding property. Persistent peasant passivity proved too much for even the most
vigorous legislators and administrators. Peasant inheritance and property customs
emerged from the storms o f revolution and counter-revolution almost untouched.5
1 By a Decree of the V.Ts.I.K. of 10 March 1921: see O zemle , p. 153.
2 See the Circular of 6 July 1922, issued by the People’s Commissariat of Agriculture,
O zemle , p. 153.
3 Kubanin, op. cit., Part III, Na agrarnom fronte (1928), no. 11, p. 15.
4 Gsovski, op. cit., vol. i, p. 660.
5 One is struck by the extent to which this still holds true even after collectivization. A
Soviet court still must begin civil proceedings in the countryside by establishing if the prop
erty is peasant property ‘because this is decisive in defining rights of members of a household
(family) and the type of law relevant in cases of partition’ (see B. Liskovetz, Razdely i vydely
v kolkhoznom dvore (1963), p. 5). Only cases of inheritance in extinct households came under
the ordinary property law. Otherwise the Land Code of 1922 seemed still to be in operation
as late as the 1960s (ibid., p. 9). All this, of course, excluded the property of the state and
of the kolkhoz.
R U SSIA N PEASANT LAW AND INHERITANCE OF PROPERTY 227
The spread of egalitarian inheritance has proved to be closely correlated with
specific features in rural social development all over Europe.1 The areas where
egalitarian inheritance (as opposed to inheritance by will or entail) prevailed were
typified by a rapid rise in the number and a decrease in the size of farms, by higher
rates of natural growth, by lower rates of accumulation of capital, by lagging in the
development of a money economy, and so on. Furthermore, egalitarian inheritance
seems to have limited rural emigration, to have increased agrarian overpopulation
and to have handicapped the integration of the countryside into the capitalist
industrializing society. All this was true also of rural Russia. However, the impact of
egalitarian inheritance in the Russian countryside can be fully perceived only when
it is related to a breakdown by family size, wealth, and social mobility of the various
peasant strata.
1 See H. J. Habakkuk, ‘Family Structure and Economic Change in Nineteenth Century
Europe’, Journal of Economic History, vol. xv (1955), no. 1.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
York, 1963.
A j a r n i , I., Social Classes, Family Demographic Characteristics and Mobility in
Three Iranian Villages’, Sociologia Ruralis, vol. ix, 1969* no* l
A l a v i , H., ‘Peasantry and Revolution’, The Socialist Register, 1965.
234 BIBLIOGRAPHY
A lth u sser, L., ‘Contradictions and Overdetermination’, New Left Review, 1967,
no. 41.
A n d r e s k i, S., Parasitism and Subversion, London, 1966.
A tallah, M . K .,The Long-term Movement of the Terms of Trade between Agri
cultural and Industrial Products, Rotterdam, 1958.
B a il e y , F. G., ‘The Peasant View of the Bad Life’, The Advancement of Science,
vol. xxiii, 1966.
B a l d a m u s , W ., ‘The Role of Discovery in Social Science’, Discussion Papers, Uni
versity of Birmingham, Faculty of Social Sciences, 1966, Series E, no. 2.
B a r a n , P., The Political Economy of Growth, New York, i960.
B e r g e r , P., and L u c k m a n n , T., The Social Construction of Reality, London, 1967.
B l a c k , C. (ed.), The Transformation o f Russian Society, Cambridge, i960.
B l o c h , M., Feudal Society, London, 1961.
B l u m , J., Lord and Peasant in Russia, Princeton, 1961.
B o ek e, J. H ., Economics and Economic Policy of Dual Societies, as exemplified by
Indonesia, New York, 1953.
B o t t o m o r e , T., Elites and Society, London, 1 9 6 4 .
B r a t b a n t i , R., and S p e n g l e r , J., Tradition, Values and Socio-Economic Development,
Durham, N.C., 1961.
C a h n m a n , W., and B o s k o f f , A. (eds.), Sociology and History, New York and
London, 1964.
C a r l s s o n , G., Social Mobility and Class Structure, Lund, 1958.
C a r r , E. H., ‘The Russian Revolution and the Peasant’, in Proceedings o f the British
Academy, vol. xlix, 1963.
----- A History o f the Russian Revolution, London, 1950-9, vols. i-vi.
C e n t e r s , R., The Psychology of Social Classes, Princeton, 1949.
C h a y a n o v , A., The Theory of Peasant Economy, Homewood, 111., 1966 (published
in Russian as Organizatsiya krest'yanskogo khozyaistva, 1925).
C h i l d e , V. G., Man Makes Himself, London, 1948.
C l a i r m o n t e , F. F., Economic Liberalism and Underdevelopment, London, i960.
C l a r k , C. G., The Conditions of Economic Progress, London, 1940.
C o h n , N., The Pursuit of the Millennium, London, 1957.
C o le , G ., Studies in Class Structure, L on d on , 1964.
C r o o k , D. J., Revolution in a Chinese Village: Ten Mile Inn, London, 1959.
D a h r e n d o r f , R., Class and Class Conflict in Industrial Society, London, 1959.
D a v is , K . , The Population of India and Pakistan, Princeton, 1951.
----- ‘Urbanisation and Development of Pre-Industrial Areas’, Economic Develop
ment and Cultural Change, vol. iii, 1954-5.
D o b b , M., Russian Economic Development since the Revolution, London, 1928.
----- Soviet Economic Development since 1917, London, i960.
D o v r i n g , F., Land and Labour in Europe, 1900-1950, The Hague, 1956.
D u m o n t , R., Lands Alive, London, 1965.
D u r k h e i m , E., The Division of Labour in Society, Glencoe, 111., 1947.
D z i e w i c k a , M., Chlopi-robotnicy, Warsaw, 1963.
BIBLIOGRAPHY 235
E C. K., and W i t t , L. W. (eds.), Agriculture in Economic Development, New
ic h e r ,
York, 1964.
E is e n s t a d t ,S. N., Essays on Sociological Aspects of Political and Economic Develop-
merit. The Hague, 1961.
----- The Political Systems of Empires, New York, 1963.
E l i a d e , M., The Myth of Eternal Return, New York, 1965.
Encyclopedia of Social Sciences, New York, 1930-5.
E t z i o n i , A. and E. (eds.), Social Change: Sources, Patterns and Consequences, New
York, 1964.
F a n o n , F., The Wretched of the Earth, London, 1965.
F e i H s ia o - T u n g , ‘Peasantry and Gentry’, American Journal of Sociology, vol. lii, 1946.
----- ‘Social Change in Modern China’, The Sociological Review, vol. xl, 1948.
F i n e r , S., The Man on Horseback, London, 1962.
F i r t h , R., Human Types, New York, 1963.
----- Malay Fishermen: their Peasant Economy, London, 1946.
F i r t h , R., and Y a m e y , B., Capital, Saving and Credit in Peasant Societies, London,
1964.
F o s t e r , G. M., ‘Interpersonal Relations in Peasant Society’, Human Organisation,
vol. xix, 1960-1, no. 4.
F r a n k l i n , S. H., ‘Reflections on the Peasantry’, Pacific Viewpoint, vol. iii (1962),
no. 1.
F u r t a d o , C., Development and Underdevelopment, Berkeley, 1967.
G a l e s k i , B., Chlopi i zawdd rolnika, Warsaw, 1963.
----- Socjologia wsi, Warsaw, 1966.
G e e r t z , C., ‘Studies in Peasant Life: Community and Society’, Biennial Review of
Anthropology, Stanford, 1961.
G e r s c h e n k r o n , A., Continuity in History, Cambridge, Mass., 1968.
G e r t h , H., and W r i g h t M i l l s , C., From Max Weber, New York, 1961.
G l a s s , D. (ed.), Social Mobility in Britain, London, 1966.
G o l d s m it h , R. W., ‘Economic Growth of Tsarist Russia 1860-1913’, Economic
Development and Cultural Change, vol. ix, 1961.
G o r d o n , M . , Workers Before and After Lenin, N e w Y o r k , 1 941.
G o u l d , F . , ‘The Language of Sociology’, British Journal of Sociology, vol. xiv, 1963.
G s o v s k i , V., Soviet Civil Law, Ann Arbor, 1948-9, vols. i, ii.
G u e v a r a , E . ( C h e ), Guerrilla Warfare, N e w Y o r k , 1961.
H a b a k k u k , H . J . , ‘Family Structure and Economic Change in Nineteenth Century
Europe’, Journal of Economic History, vol. xv, 1955, no. 1.
H i n d u s , M., The Russian Peasant and the Revolution, New York, 1920.
H o b s b a w n , E., Primitive Rebels, Manchester, 1959*
----- ‘Vietnam and the Dynamics of Guerrilla War’, New Left Review, 1965, no. 33.
H o s e li tz , B. F., Sociological Aspects of Economic Growth, Glencoe, 111., i960.
H u b b a r d , L. E ., The Economics of Soviet Agriculture, London, 1939*
J a s n y , N., The Socialised Agriculture of the U.S.S.R., Stanford, 1949 *
K e r r , C., Industrialism and Industrial Man, London, 1962.
236 BIBLIOGRAPHY
K ornhauser, R., ‘The Warner Approach to Social Stratification’, in Bendix, R.,
and Lipset, S. M. (eds.), Class, Status and Power, Glencoe, 111., 1953.
Kroeber, A. L., Anthropology, London, 1948.
K uhn, T. S., The Structure of Scientific Revolution, Chicago, 1968.
Laslett, P., ‘The Study of Social Structure from Listing of Inhabitants’, in Wrigley,
E. A. (ed.), An Introduction to English Historical Demography from the Sixteenth
to the Nineteenth Century, London, 1966.
Lefebvre, G., The Coming of the French Revolution, New York, 1957.
Lenski, G., Power and Privilege, New York, 1966.
Lewin, M., Russian Peasants and Soviet Power, London, 1968.
------‘Who Was the Soviet Kulak?’ Soviet Studies, vol. xviii, 1966, no. 2.
Lewis, O., Life in a Mexican Village: Tepoztlan, Restudied, Urbana, 1951.
----- Village Life in Northern India, New York, 1958.
Lipset, S. M., and Bendix, R., Social Mobility in Industrial Society, Berkeley, 1966.
Lorimer, F., The Population of the Soviet Union, Geneva, 1946.
Lowde, R. H., Social Organisation, London, 1950.
Luckman, T., and Berger, P., ‘Social Mobility and Personal Identity’, European
Journal o f Sociology, vol. v, 1964.
Luxemburg, R., The Russian Revolution, Ann Arbor, 1961.
Maclean, F., Eastern Approaches, London, 1951.
Maine, Sir H. J. S., Ancient Law, London, 1897.
Male, D. J., ‘The Village Community in the U.S.S.R., 1925-1930’, in Soviet Studies,
vol. xiv, 1963.
M andel, E., Marxist Economic Theory, New York, 1970.
Mannheim, K., Ideology and Utopia, London, i960.
Mao T s e - T u n g , Selected Works, Peking, 1 9 6 1 - 5 , vols. i-iv.
Marshall, T., Citizenship and Social Class, Cambridge, 1950.
----- (ed.), C/ow Conflict and Social Stratification, London, 1938.
Marx, K., Capital, Chicago, 1909, vol. iii.
------Pre-capitalist Economic Formations, London, 1964.
----- and Engels, F., Selected Works, Moscow, 1950, vols. i, ii.
Maynard, Sir H. J., The Russian Peasant and Other Studies, New York, 1962.
Merritt, R., and R okkan, S. (eds.), Comparing Nations, New Haven, 1966.
Mills, C. W., Power, Politics and People, New York, 1963.
Mitrany, D., Mar* against the Peasant, London, 1951.
Moore, B., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Harmondsworth, 1969.
----- Soviet Politics—the Dilemma of Power, Cambridge, Mass., 1950.
Myrdal, G., Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions, London, 1957.
N alson, J., Mobility o f Farm Families, Manchester, 1968.
N ash, M., ‘Indian Economies’, Handbook of Middle American Indian Series,
vol. 6, Social Anthropology, Dallas, 1967.
N urkse, R., Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries, Oxford,
1953 .
Ossowski, S., C/ow Structure in the Social Consciousness, London, 1963.
BIBLIOGRAPHY 237
Pitt-Rivers, J., The Closed Community and its Friends’, Kroeber Anthropological
Society Papers (1957), no. 16.
Pohoski, M., Migracja ze wsi do miast, Warsaw, 1963.
Polanyi, K., ‘The Belief in Economic Determinism’, The Sociological Review,
vol. xxxix, 1947.
----- Arensberg, C. M„ and Pearson, H. W. (eds.), Trade and Market in the Early
Empires, Glencoe, 111., 1957.
Preobrazhenski, E., The New Economics, Oxford, 1965.
R edfield, R., The Little Community, Uppsala, 1955.
----- Peasant Society and Culture, Chicago, 1956.
----- Tepoztlan: a Mexican Village, Chicago, 1946.
----- and Singer, M., ‘The Cultural Role of Cities’, in Economic Development and
Cultural Change, vol. iii, 1954-5.
R ex, J., Key Problems of Sociological Theory, London, 1961.
Robinson, G. T., Rural Russia under the Old Regime, New York, 1949.
R obinson, J. V., Economic Philosophy, London, 1962.
R ostow, W. W., The Stages of Economic Growth, Cambridge, i960.
Schumpeter, J. A., Imperialism and Social Classes, Oxford, 1951.
----- The Theory of Economic Development, Cambridge, Mass., 1961.
Shanin, T. (ed.), Peasants and Peasant Societies, Harmondsworth, 1971.
Smelser, N. (ed.), Readings on Economic Sociology, Englewood Cliffs, N.J., 1965.
Smelser, N., and Lipset, S. M. (eds.), Social Structure and Mobility in Economic
Development, London, 1966.
Smith, A., An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Edin
burgh, 1806.
Smith, R. E. F., ‘A Model of Production and Consumption on the Russian Farm’,
Discussion Papers, University of Birmingham, Centre for Russian and East European
Studies, 1964, Series RC/D, no. 1.
----- The Origins of Farming in Russia, Paris, 1959.
----- ‘Russian History and the Soviet Union’, Comparative Studies in Society and
History, 1962.
Sorel, G., Reflections on Violence, Glencoe, 111., 1950.
Sorokin, P., Social Mobility, New York, 1927.
----- and Zimmermann, C., Principles of Rural-Urban Sociology, New York,
1929.
Stepniak, The Russian Peasantry, London, 1888.
Stirling, P., Turkish Village, London, 1965.
Sweezy, P. (ed.). The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism, New York, 1954 *
Taniuchi, Y., ‘A Note on the Territorial Relations between Rural Societies,
Settlements and Communes’, Discussion Papers, University of Birmingham, Centre
for Russian and East European Studies, 1966, Series RC/D, no. 3.
----- The Village Gathering in Russia in the Mid-I920's, Birmingham, 1968.
Thomas, W. I., and Znanieckj, F., The Polish Peasant in Europe and America, New
York, 1958, vols. i, ii.
Timasheff, N., The Great Retreat, New York, 1946.
238 BIBLIOGRAPHY
T imasheff, N., ‘The Russian Revolution’, The Review o f Politics, vol. v (1943), no. 4.
Toennies, F., Community and Society, East Lansing, Mich., 1957.
Transactions of the Third World Congress of Sociology, London, 1956, vol. iii.
Treml, V. (ed.), The Development of the Soviet Economy: Plan and Performance,
New York, 1968.
Venturi, F., Roots of Revolution, London, i960.
Warner, C. (ed.), Agrarian Conditions in Modern European History, New York,
1966.
Warner, W., and Lunt, P. S., The Status System of a Modern Community, New
Haven, 1942.
Warner, W., Meeker, M., and Eells, K., Social Class in America, Chicago, 1949.
Warriner, D., Economics of Peasant Farming, London, 1964.
Weber, M., General Economic History, New York, 1961.
----- The Theory o f Social and Economic Organisation, London, 1947.
Whetton, N. L., Rural Mexico, Chicago, 1948.
Wittfogel, K., Oriental Despotism, New Haven, 1957.
Wolf, E. R., ‘Aspects of Group Relations in a Complex Society: Mexico’, American
Anthropologist, 1956.
----- Peasants, Englewood Cliffs, N.J., 1966.
Worsley, P., The Third World, London, 1964.
----- (ed.), Two Blades of Grass: Rural Cooperation in Developing Societies, Man
chester, 1971.
Wrong, D. H., Population and Society, New York, 1965.
Yang Ch’ing-K’un, A Chinese Village in Early Communist Transition, Cambridge,
Mass., 1959.
Yang, M., A Chinese Village, New York, 1945.
Yates, P. L., Forty Years of Foreign Trade, London, 1959.
Zetterberg, H., On Theory and Verification in Sociology, Totowa, N.J., 1965.
GLOSSARY
Aggregate shift (podvizhka). General bettering or worsening of the socio-economic
position of peasantry (a peasant local community or peasant society) as a whole
(See Chapter 3, section (b); Chapter 4, section (d).)
Apportionment (vydel). Creation of a new peasant household by the budding-off
from a family of a young couple to form a new nuclear family with its own
farm.
Budget studies of peasant households. Systematic study of the economic performance
of individual peasant households in terms of input/output analysis and the
statistical analysis of data so collected. (See Chapter 4, section (b).)
Committee o f Poor Peasants (Kombed). An organization of the rural poor created
by the Soviet government at the beginning of 1918 and dissolved at the end of the
same year. (See Chapter 8, section (b).)
Commune, peasant (1obshchina, mir). A territorially based Russian peasant com
munity, governed by a commune gathering (q.v.), in charge of a variety of tasks:
local services, welfare, fiscal duties, etc. The majority of communes (with the
exception of the western parts of European Russia) were repartitional, i.e. were
the formal owners of peasant land and practised periodical redivisions of land (q.v.)
between their constituent households (q.v.). (See Chapter 2, section (b); Chapter 9,
section (b).)
Commune gathering (skhod). The assembly of heads of peasant households which
embodies the authority of the peasant commune. (See Chapter 2, section (b);
Chapter 9, section (b).)
Conventional net income (uslovnyi chistyi dokhod). The gross income of a peasant
household—i.e. income in both kind and money—less all inputs but family
labour. (See Chapter 4, section (b).)
Crafts and trades (jpromysly). Gainful employment (often seasonal) of Russian
peasants not consisting of farming on own farm. (See Chapter 2, section (a).)
Sub-categories: (i) Non-farming activities on the farm (domestic industry);
(ii) Off-farm wage-work in agriculture; (iii) Off-farm non-agricultural wage-work
(C. and t. = (i)+(ii)+(iii)).
Cumulation of economic advantages and disadvantages. The tendency for rich house
holds to develop further economically because of the advantage they can take of
accumulated capital, etc., and for poor households to decline economically from
inability to take such advantages; a process tending towards polarization (q.v.).
(See Chapter 4, section (b).)
D esyatina (abbr. des.). The former standard Russian land area measure (1 des. =
1-09 ha. = 2*7 acres).
D ifferentiation, socio-economic. The diversity in wealth of peasant households. (See
Chapter 3, sections (b) and (c).)
8214036 R
240 GLOSSARY
Differentiation processes. Changes in the socio-economic differentiation (q.v.) of
a peasant community or peasant society. (See Chapter 3, sections (b) and (d).)
Sub-categories: (i) polarization (q.v.); (ii) levelling (q.v.) (D.p. = (i)+(ii)).
Dynamic study. A type of research analysing socio-economic mobility by tracing
the histories of individual peasant households and analysing statistically data so
collected. (See Chapter 4, section (c).)
Emigration. A form of spatial mobility, in which members leave a community and
move elsewhere either permanently or for a prolonged period. In the above
study, mainly emigration of peasant families leading to the disappearance of a
peasant household from its original community. (See Chapter 5, sections (a) and (d).)
Enclosed farm (khutor). A peasant household (q.v.) not belonging (in some cases
only partly belonging) to a repartitional commune (q.v.) and with consolidated
land outside the village, on which its house is placed. (See Chapter 2, section (b);
Chapter 8, sections (b), (c), and (d).)
Enclosed types o f farms (uchastkovye formy khozyaistva). Peasant households (q.v.)
whose land does not belong (in some cases only partly belongs) to a repartitional
commune (q.v.).
Sub-categories: (i) enclosed farms (khutor) (q.v.); (ii) farms with enclosed fields
(otrub) (q.v.) (E.t. of f. = (i)+(ii)).
Extinction. The disappearance of peasant household through the death of its mem
bers. (See Chapter 5, section (c).)
Farm with enclosed fields (otrub). A peasant household (q.v.) not belonging (in
some cases only partly belonging) to a repartitional commune (q.v.) but living
in a village and with land held in the form of strips scattered among other peasant
strip-holdings. (See Chapter 2, section (b); Chapter 8, sections (b), (c), and (d).)
Guberniya (abbr. gub.). Province: the former main administrative division of Russia,
composed of a number of uezds (q.v.).
Household, peasant (dvor). The basic social and economic unit of peasant society
consisting of a family (defined in terms typical of the Russian peasantry) and its
farm. (See Chapter 2, section (a); Appendix B.)
Immigration. Return of members (in this study, mainly families) to a commune after
a prolonged period of absence. (See Chapter 5, sections (a) and (d).)
Komsomol (abbr.). Communist League of Youth; for persons ged from afourteen to
twenty-six. (See Chapter 8, section (b).)
Kulak (Russ: ‘fist’). A rich peasant exploiting his peasant neighbours; in the Soviet
period identified with the enemies of the Soviet regime within the peasantry. (See
Chapter 9, section (c).)
Levelling. The process of decrease in the diversity of peasant households in terms
of wealth, leading to a concentration of households round the mean wealth of
a peasant community or peasant society. (See Chapter 3, section (b).)
Liquidation of peasant households. A term used by Ts.S.U. (q.v.) for the households
disappearing from dynamic study (q.v.) samples, including those extinct and those
allegedly not intending to return on departure. (See Chapter 5, section (c).)
Sub-categories: (i) extinction (q.v.); (ii) (permanent) emigration (q.v.) (L. of
p.h. = (i)-h(ii)).
GLOSSARY 241
Merger. The amalgamation of different households into one unit. (See Chapter 5
section (c).)
Migration. Spatial mobility involving a change of place of residence either per
manently or for a prolonged period. (See Chapter 5, sections (a) and (d).)
Sub-categories: (i) emigration (q.v.); (ii) immigration (q.v.) (M = (i)+(ii)).
Mobility (socio-economic, vertical). Changes in the wealth of the households in a
peasant community or peasant society. (See Chapter 4, section (d); on the opera
tional definitions see Chapter 7, section (c).)
Sub-categories: (i) M. of peasant households (q.v.); (ii) M. in terms of a
peasant community or peasant society (q.v.). (The categories reflect analytical
aspects relevant to the study, and cannot be added together to give the total M.)
Mobility, ascending. Increases in the wealth of peasant households. (See Chapter 4,
section (d).)
Mobility, biological cycle of. A possible component of socio-economic mobility due
to a peasant household’s passing through various phases in family life-history.
(See Chapter 6, section (b).)
Mobility, centrifugal Changes in the wealth of peasant households tending away
from the mean; further impoverishment of poorer families and/or further enrich
ment of richer families. (See Chapter 6, section (e).)
Mobility, centripetal. Changes in the wealth of peasant households tending towards
the mean; relative impoverishment of richer families and/or relative enrichment
of poorer families. (See Chapter 6, section (e).)
Mobility, cyclical. Socio-economic mobility in which a substantial number of house
holds participate successively in powerful and opposing trends of enrichment and
impoverishment, both continuously in operation within a peasant society. A specific
type of multidirectional mobility (q.v.). (See Chapter 4, section (c); Chapter 6,
section (e).)
Mobility, descending. Decreases in the wealth of peasant households. (See Chapter
4, section (d).)
Mobility (socio-economic) in terms of a peasant community or society. Changes in
the wealth or differentiation (q.v.) (socio-economic) of a peasant community or
society, resulting from changes in wealth of its constituent households. (See
Chapter 4, section (d).)
Sub-categories: (i) Aggregate shifts (q.v.); (ii) differentiation processes (q.v.).
(The categories reflect analytical aspects relevant to the study, and cannot be
added together to give the total M. of a peasant community or society.) See also
Mobility of peasant households.
Mobility, multidirectional. Simultaneous and opposing trends in the socio-economic
mobility of peasant households which at least partly cancel one another out when
analysis is confined to a peasant society. (See Chapter 4, section (c); Chapter 6
section (e).) Cyclical mobility (q.v.) is a type of a multidirectional M. but not the
sole form of it (e.g. another type would be random oscillation (q.v.)).
Mobility (socio-economic) of peasant households. Changes in the wealth of peasant
households. (See Chapter 4, section (d); Chapter 6 , section (e).)
Sub-categories: (i) ascending M. (q.v.); (ii) descending M. (q.v.); (iii)centrifugal
M. (q.v.); (iv) centripetal M. (q.v.); (v) multidirectional M. (q.v.); (vi) cyclical
242 GLOSSARY
M. (q.v.) (M. of p.h. = (i)-h(ii)=(iii)+(iv) = (v). Also see M. o f peasant house
holds, factors of; M . in terms of peasant community or society.
Mobility o f peasant households, factors o f Components of the explanatory model of
households* mobility advanced in this work. (See Chapter 6, section (e).)
Sub-categories: (i) cumulation of economic advantages and disadvantages (q.v.);
(ii) redivision of land by communes (q.v.); (iii) substantive changes (q.v.); (iv) the
biological cycle of M. (q.v.); (v) random oscillation (q.v.) (M. of p.h., f. of = (i)-f-
(ii) +(iii)+(iv)+(v)).
Mobility, residual component o f That part of the mobility of peasant households
revealed by dynamic studies (q.v.) after the households which had undergone
substantive changes (q.v.) had been statistically eliminated from the sample.
(See Chapter 6, section a.)
Narkomzem (Russ. abbr. for People's Commissariat for Agriculture). The Soviet
ministry of agriculture 1917-43.
N.E.P. (abbr. for Novaya Ekonomicheskaya Politika). The new economic policy of
the Soviet government after the civil war, based on a mixed economy; also the
period it was in force (1921-28).
Outsiders to a peasant community. Rural inhabitants interacting with a peasant
community without belonging to it. (See Chapter 9, section (e).)
Sub-categories: (i) neighbour outsiders (q.v.); (ii) stranger outsiders (q.v.);
(iii) plenipotentiary outsiders (q.v.).
Outsiders, neighbour. Peasants, not members of a given community, holding land
bordering on the community’s. (See Chapter 9, section (e).)
Outsiders, plenipotentiary. Non-members of a peasant community working in the
countryside as representatives of external centres of power influencing the com
munity. (See Chapter 8, section (e).)
Outsiders, stranger. Non-members of a peasant community culturally dissimilar to
the peasants, bringing into the countryside forms of social and cultural compe
tence alien to the peasant community. (See Chapter 9, section (e).)
Partitioning (razdel). The creation of two or more peasant households as a result
of a split in the membership and property of an original household; when the
process is limited to the budding-off of a young nuclear family, it is generally termed
apportionment (q.v.). (See Chapter 5, section (b); Appendix B, section (b).)
Polarization. The process of increase in the diversity of peasant households in terms
of wealth leading to concentration of households at the poles of wealth and
poverty of a peasant community or peasant society. (See Chapter 3, section b.)
Random oscillations. A form of multidirectional mobility (q.v.), generated by the
idiosyncratic impact of general economic trends and ‘chance’ factors on individual
peasant households. (See Chapter 6, section (c).)
Redivision o f land by communes (peredel). Redivision of commune (q.v.) land in
accordance with broadly egalitarian principles, e.g. the number of consumers or
of mature male workers per household. (See Chapter 2, section (b).)
R.S.F.S.R. (abbr. for Rossiiskaya Sovetskaya Federativnaya Sotsialisticheskaya
Respublika). The Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic; until 1923 in
GLOSSARY 243
alliance with other Soviet Republics, since 1923 a constituent republic of the then
created U.S.S.R.
Rural Soviet (Sel'skii sovet, abbr. Sel'sovet). The lowest-ranking local authority in
the Soviet countryside covering area an usually including several settlements, with
a population of from 300 to over 10,000 inhabitants. (See Chapter 9, section (a).)
Semi-centripetal effect. Levelling (q.v.) in a peasant community or peasant society
as a result of differential emigration or extinction (e.g. higher rates of disappear
ance in the poorer strata) without actual centripetal mobility (q.v.) of peasant
households taking place. (See Chapter 5, section (a).)
Statistical optical illusion. An exaggeration of the extent of differentiation within
a peasant community, resulting from use of a statistical technique which grouped
the households of several communities together. (See Chapter 7, section (c).)
‘Substantive changes' (organicheskie izmeneniya). Transmutations of peasant house
holds resulting in the appearance or disappearance of households within the
peasant community.
Sub-categories: (i) partitioning; (ii) merger; (iii) extinction; (iv) migration.
(See Chapter 5, section (a).) (S.c. = (i)+ (ii)H-(iii)+ (iv).)
Ts.S.U. (abbr. for Tsentral'noye Statisticheskoe Upravlenie). The Central Statistic
Board; a data-collecting and publishing agency created after the revolution as a
department of the Soviet government. (See Chapter 3, section (b).)
Uezd. A district; the former territorial-administrative units of which a guberniya
(q.v.) was composed.
Vertical segmentation. A form of social grouping cutting across the major socio
economic strata to reveal another division of society—into qualitatively similar,
highly self-sufficient, hierarchical, territorially based segments. (See Chapter 9,
section (e).)
V.I.K. (abbr. for Volostnoi IspolniteVnyi Komitet). The standing committee of the
volost' Congress of Soviets; the volost' local authority in the early Soviet period.
(See Chapter 9, sections (a) and (b).)
Volost'. The former administrative territorial units in rural Russia of which an uezd
(q.v.) was composed (in pre-revolutionary Russia, also a territorial unit of the
specifically peasant self-government); it embraced a number of peasant com
munes (q.v.) and after the revolution Rural Soviets (q.v.). (See Chapter 2, section
(b); Chapter 9, sections (a) and (b).)
Zemstvo. A pre-revolutionary Russian rural local council at guberniya (q.v.) or uezd
(q.v.) level, composed of representatives elected by the social estates, and usually
controlled by the gentry. (See Chapter 2, sections (b) and (d).)
INDEX
Adopted members of family, rights of, 223 Blood-feuds, 179
Age and sex, traditional division of roles by, Bol'shakov, on partitioning, 127
175-7 Bolshevik Party, 185
Agrarian revolution, 26, 57, 225 branches, functions, 186
and levelling, 145-61 department for rural work, object of,
and mobility of peasant households, 186
156-60 ex-servicemen in, 189
and peasant solidarity, 160-1 farmers in, 187-8
and war, 129 meetings, subjects discussed, 188
economic deterioration in peasantry membership, 185-90; by social class, 186;
after, 153 peasants’ image of, 196
land redistribution after, statistics, 153-4 organization in Penza, 171
legal history of, 148 peasant attitudes to, 189
results of, 153-6 peasant soldiers in, 185
stages, 145 power of, 185
Agricultural equipment, lack of, 21 rural branches and membership, 185,
Agricultural exports, 23 187; inspection-reports, 189
Agricultural improvements and investment, Bolsheviks and Left S.R. Party, split in, 148
23 Bondage, abolition of, 19
Agricultural industry, establishment of, 149 Budget studies, analysis of, 67
Agricultural prices, rise in, 12 and polarization, 66-71
Agricultural production, 16 post-revolutionary, 69, 108
diversification, 23 pre-revolutionary, 106
Agricultural revolution, 208 1887-96, 69
Agricultural system, peasant, 19 1922-3, 69
Agriculture and economy, effects of weather 1924-5, 113
on, 112
and industry, relations between, 13 Capital, accumulation, 15, 209, 211; and
capital accumulation in, 111 industrial growth, 12
economic control, 113 shortage of, effects, 68
industrialization of, 210 Capitalism, 46
legislation on, 149 at turn of century, 58
low production of, in Tsarist Russia, 21 Marxists’ attitudes to, 47
Marxist specialists in, 1929 congress, 61 Capitalist society, 2
polarization in, 103 Capitalists, 174
recovery of, 1922-5, 56; and socio Caucus, volost', power, 193, 196; members,
economic mobility, 53 success and advancement, 194
state-organized collectivization of, 211 Censuses, 97
three-field system, and wealth index, 135 analysis of data, 51
Allotments, average size, 21 evidence of socio-economic differentia
All-Russia Congress of Soviets, 163 tion, 47
All-Russia Executive Committee, 163 first modern national, statistics, 9
Army, peasantry in, 185, 216 local, 49, 50
national, after 1916, 60
Backwardness in Russia, 45 national rural, 1916 and 1917, 5i
Balance of payments, 16 of land holdings, 1905, 122
Banking, foreign ownership, 17 Chayanov, A., general theory of peasant eco
Biological deterioration of households, 103 nomy and mobility, 105; Prokopovich
Biological determinism, 101-9 attack on, 106; Raevich attack on, 107
criticism of, 108 multidirectional mobility, 102
246 INDEX
Chernenkov, N., introduction of dynamic Council of Peoples’ Commissars, 163
studies, 72 Countryside, socio-economic differentiation
on social class, 138 of, 21
Civil Code, 222, 224 Courts, peasant, 219
Civil war, 26, 52, 129 Crafts, peasant, income from, 21
Class analysis of society, validity of, 138 Crises, development of, 93
Class conflict within peasant household, Cultural patterns of peasant communities,
no 40
Class, definition, 212 Culture and peasant society, 38-41
Class division, rural, 169-75 Customary peasant law, 219
Class struggle and mobility, 139
Class theory, Marxist, 46, 145 Decree on Land, 148, 225
Collectivization, 2 Democratic centralism, establishment of,
Colonists, re-creation of communes, 164 162
Colonization, 92 Developing societies, 14
Committees of the Poor, 2, 147, 148, 149 Differentiation, and levelling, of peasantry,
Commune assembly and peasant courts, 50-2, 54, 56; by region, 55; Marxist
authority, 225 views on, 146
Commune dues, 35 socio-economic, intracommunity, 60; of
Commune gatherings, absorption of Rural peasantry in Saratov, 65
Soviets, 185 Differentiation debate, 45-62
and Rural Soviet, 164-9 Differentiation-processes, 77
procedures, 167 during revolution and civil war, 52
supremacy over Rural Soviets, 166 nature of, 79
Commune offices, compulsory, 34 Disappearance, rates of, 128
Communes, 32-8 Disasters, natural, 113
change in role, 151 Division of labour, 1, 180
expenditure, 167 Drunkenness, 195
formation of administrative parish, 35 Dualism, 25-6, 197
freedom from obligation to, 224 Dynamic censuses, Ts.S.U., 1920, 73
functions, 35, 37 Dynamic studies, and mobility of peasant
government efforts to destroy, 37 households, 71-6
land-redistribution by, 78, 151 introduction of, 72
land-redivision by, 103, 135, 159; legal of a community, 72
provisions, 80 of Vyazma and Smolensk, 75
membership, 34
officers’ responsibilities, 35 Economic boom in 1890s, 12
peasant households organized in, 165 Economic deterioration, i n , 153
recognition of, 34 Economic determinism and multifactorial
self-government of, 34 analysis, 109-12
self-imposed taxes, 166 Economic development, 16
social machinery of, 164 1900-13, indicators of, 11
state control of, 36 of peasant household, A. Chayanov, 102
structure and organization, 3, 165 Economic growth at turn of century, 10, 18
ultimate, 41 Economic position of household, rise in
Communist Party during N.E.P., rural factors affecting, 103
campaigns, 137 Economy and agriculture, effects of weather
Communists in local rural administration, on, 112
184 peasant, 39, 107, 114, 204, 209
Conflict situations, 168, 178 Educational facilities at turn of century,
Consumer/worker ratio, annual change in, 10
109 Egalitarian inheritance, spread of, 227
hypothetical family, 102 Emancipation, of serfs, law of, 219
in different strata, 106 of women, 176
Consumption pressure, 103 self, of peasant, 31
Conventional Net Income, definition of, 68 Emigration, and extinction of poor peasants,
Co-operative, 173, 174 129
INDEX
247
and merger, 82
and re-immigration, 159 Horses, 1912 military survey of, 48
definition, 92 Household. See Peasant household
Employment, salaried, in rural areas, 181-2
Equilibrium models, 108 Ideology and misinterpretations, 137
European Russia, geographical zones, 122-6 Illiteracy, 10, 22, 24
Executive Committees, 193 Income, annual, per capita, at turn of
Exports, agricultural, 23 century, 10, 13
in 1913, 16 Conventional Net, definition of, 68
Ex-servicemen, 180, 190-2 types of, 66
in Bolshevik Party, 189 Indexes of socio-economic differentiation
in peasant stratum, 146 132-4
in V.I.K.s, 192 Industrial development at turn of centurv
role in village life, 192 58
Industrial growth and capital accumulation,
Family, adopted members, rights of, 223 12
father of, authority of, 29 Industrialization in Germany, 15
peasant, social structure of, 175, 206 Industrialization policy in dualistic society
peasant, stages of, 31 27
Family household, farm, 28-32, 205 Industry and agriculture, relations between,
formal membership of, 221 13
Family labour, 106, 107 Inheritance, egalitarian, spread of, 227
Family member, rights of, 221 in peasant society, 31
Family patterns, variety of, 221 of property and peasant law, 219-27
Family property, 220-1 peasant, and partitioning, 222-4
framework of, 31 Intelligentsia, rural, social and cultural life
in peasant household, 30 of, 182
partitioning of, 31 Iron production, 10
Family size, and socio-economic status, 63
and wealth, correlation of, 63-6 Khryashcheva, A., analysis of cyclical
Famine 21, 22 mobility of peasant families, 111
and socio-economic mobility, 53 dynamic studies of peasant households,
economic effects, 110 97
social effects, 129 on peasant socio-economic mobility, 96
Farmers, in Bolshevik Party, 187-8 study of partitioning, 127
professional stratum of, 210 Kombedy, 147, 148
Farms, enclosed, 2, 151-2; abolition of, failure of, 149
224; destruction of, 178 Komsomol, members in Bolshevik Party,
family, 205 189
non-partitionable, 224 organization and membership, 189
peasant, typical, 29 social characteristics of members, 190
Father of family, authority of, 29 Kondratev, N., 60
Fire, 113 Kritsman, L., 60
Flood, 113 concept of peasantry, 211
Foreign debts after First World War, 17 discussion of wealth index, 132
Foreign investment at turn of century, 17 Kubanin, M., interpretation of partitioning,
no
Geographical area under survey, 5 Kulak, 132, 173-4
Germany, industrialization in, 15 counter-revolution, 145-7, 161
Grain, 113, 123, 148 defeat of, 146
Green Army, 147 households, definition, 133
Guerrilla warfare, 217 percentage of, 146
Gurvich, 58 rebellion against proletarian dictator
ship, 147
High Court of Appeal, Russian, 219 reprisals, 137
Historical trends, mobility, 126-31 use of term, 173
Horse ownership, 48 wealth of, 173
248 INDEX
Kushchenko, G., dynamic studies of peasant Livestock, decrease in, 23
households, 97 production, 13
Livestock-ownership, development of, 152
Local authority, in village, 165
Labour, division of, 180 officials, 194, 195
family, 106, 107 and peasant population, communication
intensity of, 103 between, 196
specialization, 180 rural, 162-4
surplus of, 93 communists in, 184
Labour force and consumption-needs of structure, 163
peasant family, 104 Lutskii on agrarian revolution, 146
Land, arable, acquisition by peasantry, 153
Decree on, 148, 225
demand for, by non-farming population, Magistrates, peasant, functions, 36
155 Makarov, N., analysis of structural change
holding of, 204 in peasant society, 108
Law on Socialization of, 148 Males, able-bodied, lack of, in poor house
nationalization of, 148, 225 holds, 171
non-peasant, expropriation of, 159 in peasant households, 85
ownership of, 205; communal character Market economy, growth of, 198
of, 36 Marriage, importance of, 206
privately owned, 36 Marx, K„ class analysis, 138, 212
property in, 205 Marxist specialists in agriculture, 1929
Land Code of 1922, 150, 225-6 congress, 61
Land Commissions, 226 Marxist views on peasant differentiation,
Land commune, authority, 163 59-61, 146
functions assigned to, 163 Men, young, prestige and power, 176
Land Departments of local Soviets, 226 responsibilities, 177
Land-division, 208 Mergers, economic gains, 89
Land gathering, 163, 165 of peasant households, 88-92
Land Measures, Socialist, Regulations on, personal and social considerations, 90
149 Middle peasants, 58, 114, 174
Land-redistribution, 65, 150, 151 Migration, 92-5
after agrarian revolution, statistics, 153-4 large-scale, effects of, 24
benefits to rich householders, 156 rural, pressures, 93
black, 150, 151 Mobility, and social structure, analysis of,
by communes, 78, 151 140
Land-redivision, 36, 147-52 basic types, 50, 117
by communes, 103, 135, 159; legal provi biological determinism, 101-9
sions, 80 centrifugal, 76, 96
in Belorussia, 97 centripetal, 74, 76, 78, 101, 120
Land-reform, legislation, 114 cyclical, 63-80, 96-141
Landholding, peasant, study of, 48 dynamic study 1924-5, 123-6
Law, of emancipation of serfs, 219 in sixteen guberniyas of European
of partitioning, 127 Russia, 100
on Socialization of Land, 148 in some regions of R.S.F.S.R., 99
peasant, 19, 219; and inheritance of in Surazh uezd, 98
property, 219-27 influence on political consciousness, 139
Leadership, volost', 193 multidirectional, 74, 76, 96-141; social
Lenin, 59 differentiation and political signifi
introduction of N.E.P., 27 cance, 137-41
on kulaks, 148 peasant households, 26-32, 76-80; ana
on Marxist class theory, 145 lysis of, 77; and agrarian revolution,
organization of rural poor, 149 156-60; and dynamic studies, 71-6;
Levelling, 50-1, 81-5, 156 determinants, 119; major trends, 118;
and agrarian revolution, 145-61 residual component, 115; towards
Liquidation of household, 91 multifactorial model, 115-21
INDEX 249
peasant society, 76-80; measurement of, initiated by women, 176
73 Kubanin interpretation of, no
regional comparison, 123 law of 1886, 127
social, in 1900, 10 of family property, 31
socio-economic, 3, 49, 53, 78 or rich households, 101
sociological studies of, contemporary, rates of, 128
139 rise during revolution, 158
Money economy of peasant households, Peasant(s), attitudes to Bolshevik Party,
113 189
Monism, 115 definition of, 213
Muscovy, princedom of, at turn of century, emigration to towns, 23
area, 9 image of, 203
image of party members, 196
National income, 20 middle, 58, 114, 174
Nationalization of land, 148, 225 poor, 1, 114, 171-2; emigration and
National Growth Rate, peasant, 91 extinction, 129
Neo-Populists, aims of, 46 prestige and position of, in society, 205
members, 102 proletarianization, 58
New Economic Policy (N.E.P.), 2, 27, 52, resettlement of, 159
53 rich. See Kulak
Communist Party during, rural cam state, emancipation of, 19
paigns, 137 support of kulaks, 137
migration during, 92 Peasant agricultural system, 19
operational definitions of peasant strati Peasant apathy, 216
fication and wealth, 131 Peasant bourgeoisie in Ukraine, land held
passive power of peasant communities, by, 147
199 Peasant communities, characteristics of, 32-
rural society, 162-79, 180-99 8, 140
Nobility, elimination of, 178 cultural patterns of, 40
lineages and extinction, 90 passive power during N.E.P., 199
sale of land, 20 underestimation of cohesiveness of, 137
Non-farming population, demand for land, see also Communes
155 Peasant co-operatives, 173
Peasant economy, 39, 107, 114, 204, 209
Occupational indexes, 139 Peasant estate, membership of, 219
Occupations, rural salaried, 182 Peasant household: and peasant society,
of peasant, 206 28-41, 117
October Revolution, 25, 52, 110 authority in, 29
Operational definitions, validity, 131-6 biological deterioration, 103
Organization and Production School, 46, by size of membership, 157
102 by sown area and horse-ownership, 53, 54
Outsiders, neighbour, definition, 178 characteristics, 28
plenipotentiary, and volost' power caucus, differentiation, 75; in R.S.F.S.R., 57
192-7; definition, 178 disappearance of, 81
rural, changes in make-up, 178 diversity of wealth between, 47
stranger, 197; definition, 178 economic determinants, 83
economy of, 102, 114
Parliament, consultative, 46 employing wage-labour, statistics, 171
Partitioning, 81 extinction, process of, 90
1861-82, 126-7 growth of, 32
1911-22, annual rates, 158 heads of, legal powers over members, 32;
1917-21, factors, affecting, 157 rights of, 221
and newly created households, 85-8 ideal type, 102
and peasant inheritance 1863-1905, 222-4 in European Russia, by horse-ownership,
definition, 223 48; by size of average land-allotment,
effect of 1914-17 war, 156 48
from early 1920s, 87 in zones of R.S.F.S.R. by sown area, 56
250 INDEX
Peasant household (cont.): independent class action, 215
independent, establishment of, 87 polarization of, 60, 132
kulak, definition, 133 political involvement of, 141
liquidation of, 91 political sociology of, 140
males in, 85 relationship to land, 204
membership, 28 social structure of, 24
merger and extinction, 88-92 stratification, 57
mobility, 76-80; analysis of, 77; and Peoples’ Commissar of Agriculture, 226
dynamic studies, 71-6; residual com Peoples’ Commissars, Councils of, 163
ponent of, 96-101 Plekhanov, G., concept of peasantry, 211
money economy of, 113 Podzol Zone, 122
newly created, and partitioning, 85-8 Polarization, and budget studies, 66-71
pattern of life, 30 and cyclical mobility, 63-80
poor, lack of able-bodied males in, 171 in agriculture, 103
random oscillation of, 115 of peasantry, 60, 132
size, and number of horses owned, 64; by Polarization-processes, 50
amount of land sown, 64 Political action, peasantry in, 214-18
socio-economic deterioration of, 88 Political consciousness, influence of mobil
statistical study, 62 ity on, 139
stratification by capital and income, 133 Political divisions of rural society, 198
structure of, 175 Political factor, peasantry as, 203-18
typical poor, 65 Political involvement of peasantry, 141
typical well-to-do, 65 Political significance and social differentia
wealth of, differences in, 59 tion of multidirectional and cyclical
wealthy, growth rates, Shcherbina’s mobility, 137-41
study, 91 Political sociology of Russian peasantry,
see also Family 140
Peasant land, private, 20 Poor, Committees of, 2, 147, 148, 149
Peasant law, 19, 219 Poor peasants, 1, 114, 171-2
and inheritance of property, 219-27 Population, rural, on eve of First World
Peasant passivity, 216 War, 19
Peasant population and local administra Poverty, in 1913, 20
tion, communication between, 196 in Tsarist Russia, 21
Peasant revolutions, 147, 150, 217 Power-brokers, 197
Peasant sector, 19-24 Power caucus, 196
Peasant social estate, 19 and plenipotentiary outsiders, 192-7
Peasant society, basic dynamics of, 1 Power structure, and its influence on future
polarization of, 1 developments, 197-9
Peasant Soviets, 148 of rural society, 197
Peasant stratification and wealth, opera Price fixing, 113
tional definitions during N.E.P., 131 Prices, ‘scissors crisis’, 113
Peasant wealth, indexes of, 132 Prokopovich, S., 60
Peasantry: attack on Chayanov’s theory of peasant
and society, 211-14 economy and mobility, 106
as political factor, 203-18 budget studies, 68
as pre-industrial social entity, 207 on partitioning, 127
cumulative pauperization of, 211 on social class, 138
definition of, 39, 204-7 studies of peasant households, 106
differentiation of. See Differentiation Proletarian dictatorship, kulak rebellion
duality in social character of, 213 against, 147
external conflicts, 141 Proletarianization of peasants, 58
external organization of, 215 Proletarians, 146
guerrilla warfare, 217 Property, family, 220-1
guided political action, 215 in land, 205
historical context, 207-11 inheritance of, and peasant law, 219-27
in army, 216 women’s rights to, 222
in political action, 214-18 Property-relations, 208
INDEX 251
Prosperity, downwards shift in, 155 powers of, 168
role of chairman, 184
Raevich, G., attack on Chayanov’s theory, women members of, 176
107 Rural stratification, operational definition,
Railway network, 10, 12 132
Red Army, 147 Rural wage-workers, statistics, 170
enrolment statistics, 191 Russia, as developing society, 9-27
ex-servicemen, 189 European, geographical zones, 122-6
peasants in, training, 191 territorial extent, 16
political, atmosphere, 191 Tsarist, 17, 21
Redemption fees, 22, 35 basic dualism in, 25
Regional authorities after 1864, 49 Russian Republic. See R.S.F.S.R.
Regional differences, validity, 122-6
Regulations on Socialist Land Measures, Salariat, rural 180-5
149 Salaried employment in rural areas, 181-2
Rents and taxes, 22 Schumpeter, J., 139
Revolutionary ideology, 47 Segmentation, vertical, 177-9
Revolutions, agrarian. See Agrarian revo Self-exploitation of family labour, 106
lution and wars, 129 Semenov, P., budget studies, 66
changes in socio-political groups after, Serfs, emancipation of, law of, 219
198 private, emancipation of, 19
1905-6, 26 Sex and age, traditional division of roles
October, 26, 52; economic effects, n o by, 175-7
peasant, 147, 150, 217 Share-cropping, 20
rise in partitioning during, 158 Shcherbina, F., budget studies, 66, 68
second, 145, 147, 149, 156 study of growth rates of wealthy house
two-stage, 1917-19, wishful theory, 160 holds, 91
Riots, local, 216 Sluzhashchie, 180-5
R.S.F.S.R., creation of, 52 Smallholding economy, peculiarities of,
European parts, substantive changes, 112-15
1920-4, 130 Social classes, 46
Land Code of, 225-6 analysis of, 212
mobility in 1920-4, 99 see also Class
Rural areas, salaried employment in, 181-2 Social differentiation and political signifi
Rural communities, patterns of, 162 cance of multidirectional and cyclical
structural changes, 33 mobility, 137-41
Rural gathering, 164, 165 Social diversification, 1
Rural groups, power-relationships, 193 Social dualism, 24-7
Rural history of Soviet Russia, 138 Social dynamics, equilibrium model, 103
Rural intelligentsia, social and cultural life, Social estate, peasants, by, 19
182 pre-revolutionary system of, 38
Rural population, of European Russia, status, 46
1905, stratification of, 59 Social structure, and mobility, analysis of,
on eve of First World War, 19 140
Rural salariat, 180-5 of peasantry, 24, 161
Rural society, during N.E.P., 162-99 Socialist Land Measures, Regulations 149
political divisions of, 198 Socialization of Land, Law on, 148
power-structure, 197 Society, and peasantry, 211-14
Rural Soviet, and commune gathering, class analysis of, validity of, 138
164-9, 185 peasant, and peasant household, 28-41,
area of, 185 117; differentiation-processes in, 120;
authority of, 163 mobility of, 76-80; structural change,
budgets, 166 analysis, 108; vertical segmentation
dependence of V.I.K., 185 and outsiders, 177-9
election of, 163 prestige and position of peasant in, 205
formal definition, 163 rural, during N.E.P., 162-99; political
officials employed by, 181 divisions of, 198; power-structure, 197
25 : INDEX
town-centred, development of peasant Ts.S.U., annual budget studies, 68
sector, 210 dynamic censuses, 73
Socio-economic changes within peasant dynamic studies, 109; of peasant house
social structure, 161 holds, 97; of peasant mobility, 123-6
Socio-economic deterioration of peasant establishment of, 51
households, 88 research and analysis methods, 62
Socio-economic differentiation, intracom study of substantive changes, 127
munity, 6o
of countryside, 21 Ukraine, peasant bourgeoisie in, land held
of peasantry, 65, 154 by, 147
Socio-economic mobility, 3, 24, 49, 53, 78 zones of, 123
Socio-economic status and family size, 63 Underemployment, 68
Socio-economic strata, 169-75 Urban economy, 24
Sociological studies of mobility, contem Urban growth at turn of century, 58
porary, 139
Socio-political groups, changes after revo
lution, 198 V.I.K.s, 183
Soldiers, mass desertions, 191 administration of peasant countryside,
peasant, in Bolshevik Party, 185 193
Sombart, W., 139 authority of, 184
Soviets, Congresses of, 163 ex-servicemen in, 192
Land Departments of, 226 members, salaries, 195
Spatial mobility, 92 Rural Soviet dependence on, 185
Stalin, J., concept of peasantry, 211 Village Soviet, use of term, 163
speech on backwardness, 45 Village social structure, 192, 207
State ownership, 12 Volost' , 35, 161, 163
State peasants, emancipation of, 19 Volost' areas and inhabitants, 183
Statistical optical illusion, 135 Volost' caucus, 193
Stolypin, P., 2 members, success and advancement, 194
policy on heads of households, 32 VolosV Executive Committees, 183
reforms, 20, 58, 221, 224, 225 Volost' leadership, 193
Stratification of peasant households by Voting rights, villagers deprived of, 173
capital and income, 133
Substantive changes, 81-95 Wage-labour, households employing, statis
categories, 81 tics, 171
European parts of R.S.F.S.R., 1920-4, Wage-workers, rural, statistics, 170
130 War, and agrarian revolution, 129
rates of, 127 economic effects 1914-21, n o
term and processes, 81 First World, effect on partitioning and
Ts.S.U. study of, 127 liquidation, 156; effect on peasant
Sverdlov, social differentiation in villages, women, 175
149 ‘War Communism’, 1918-21, 113
Wealth, and family size, correlation of, 63-6
Tariffs, 12 and number of horses owned, 88
Tax-collection, 167, 184, 194 and rate of extinction, inverse correla
Taxes, 85 tion, 90
and rents, 22 differentiation of, 49
payment of, 221 diversity between peasant households, 47
self-imposed, by communes, 166 indexes of, 132; validity of, 133
Teachers, economic hardship, 183 of households, differences in, 59
Town-centred society, development of pea strata among peasants, 173
sant sector, 210 Weather, effect on economy, 112
Trade terms between rural and urban Weber, M., on social class, 212
sectors, 113 Wheat yield, low, 21
Tsarist Russia, 17, 21 White Armies, 147, 191
Tsentralnoe Statisticheskoe* Upravlenie. See Women, emancipation of, 176
Ts.S.U. equality, 226
INDEX 253
First World War effect on, 175 Yakovlev, Ya, 189
legal equality for, 176 Young Communist League, 189
members of Rural Soviets, 176
partitioning initiated by, 176 Zemstvos, activities, 49, 50
rights to property, 222 Zones, geographical, 122-6
role in household, 29, 175 grain-deficient, 123
status in household, 29 grain-surplus, 123