Learning Curves
Learning Curves
Curves in Factories
by Creating and
Transferring Knowledge
Michael A. Lapré
Luk N. Van Wassenhove
T
he learning curve phenomenon is widely known. As organizations
gain experience with production, productivity and quality improve
at a decreasing rate. Early empirical studies showed that the loga-
rithm of unit cost decreased with the logarithm of cumulative num-
ber of units produced at a uniform rate—the learning rate.1 The disappointing
managerial implication of most learning curve studies is that the only way to
accelerate cost reduction is to accelerate cumulative production volume, which
may not always be desirable or feasible. Yet, experts such as CEO Ray Stata of
Analog Devices have argued that “the rate at which individuals and organiza-
tions learn may become the only sustainable competitive advantage.”2 The
importance of managing learning rates becomes all the more apparent when
we consider variation in learning rates. Learning rates exhibit considerable vari-
ation across industries, within industries, within firms, and even across workers
within a factory. Some factories reduce unit cost by 50% after doubling cumula-
tive production volume, others do not learn at all.3 Consequently, there is an
opportunity to manage learning rates.
Managing learning rates is by no means an easy task. Barriers to learning
in factories include the following:
▪ Separation of cause-and-effect in time and space (dynamic complexity).
▪ Presence of too many variables, which makes it difficult to comprehend
a system in its entirety (detail complexity).
Factory
Floor
Note: Rectangles and squares represent machines. Actual numbers of machines per step are disguised.Whereas upstream departments consist
of a handful to a few dozen machines, downstream departments have hundreds. In reality several steps are repeated.
Low High
Operational Learning
Note: Percentages denote the impact of one additional quality improvement project on the initial learning rate. For example, one
additional operationally validated theory would speed up the rate of waste reduction by 3.6%. On the other hand, one additional
non-validated theory would slow down the rate of waste reduction by 3.2%.
1 None
2 Specify Direction
3 Specify Impact of Local Changes
4 Empirical Equation
5 Scientific Model
Note: Adapted from R.E. Bohn,“Measuring and Managing Technological Knowledge,” Sloan Management Review, 36/1 (Fall 1994):
61-73.
projects that routinely reached levels 4 and 5. Regression output from natural
and controlled experiments yielded empirical equations that quantified the
impact of several variables at the same time for broad ranges (level 4). Several
projects yielded complete scientific models (level 5).
In 1993, Bekaert transferred production of the MLA product to a new
U.S. plant. The process control knowledge derived from level 4 and level 5 tech-
nological knowledge allowed the new U.S. plant to become the Bekaert plant
with the highest productivity and quality performance.
largely driven by existing culture in a plant, and the creativity or research skills of
[model line personnel].”
FIGURE 3. Logarithm of Total Factor Productivity for the Four Model Lines
MLC2
MLB
MLC1
MLA
Model Line A B C1 C2
Note: Productivity improvement is measured by percentage change in Total Factor Productivity (TFP) compared to the MLA. To protect
Bekaert’s proprietary information, we defined TFP improvement on the original Model Line A (MLA) as 100%. We expressed TFP
improvements on the other model lines as a percentage compared to the TFP improvement on the MLA. For example, 25% productivity
improvement on MLC1 means that TFP improvement on MLC1 was only 25% compared to the TFP improvement on the MLA.
Notes: The dependent variable is Log(TFP). R2 of the model was 0.98.We allowed for autocorrelation.The autocorrelation coefficient was not
significant.Total number of observations: 149. * indicates statistically significant at 0.05. ** indicates statistically significant at 0.01. n.s. means not
statistically significant. n.a. means not applicable (for MLA and MLB there were no back-and-forth changes in raw material suppliers, so for MLA
and MLB no coefficient was estimated for %supplier change).
FIGURE 4. The Impact of Changing Suppliers on Total Factor Productivity: Model Line C1
Note: Open squares (▫) indicate months during which (i) more than 50% of raw materials was provided by back-up suppliers, and/or (ii) more
than 15% of raw materials was provided by a different back-up supplier compared to the previous month.
FIGURE 5A. Management Buy-in for Projects Conducted on the Model Lines
100%
Model-line projects
80% defined by model-line
team
60% Model-line projects
defined by plant
40% management
Department-wide
20% projects defined by
plant management
0%
MLA MLB MLC1 MLC2
100%
Projects spanning
80% at least three
departments
60% Projects between
two neighboring
40% departments
Intra-departmental
20% projects
0%
MLA MLB MLC1 MLC2
high). The MLA team found that wire-related variables determined in preceding
production stages (such as copper content) did affect drawability. In addition, the
team learned in an experiment that the temperature of the soap solution was
significant—dipping the wire into a warm soap solution improved drawability by
73%. The installation of a “hot lubricant rinse” in the production stage preced-
ing wet wire drawing achieved the same drawability improvements in full-scale
manufacturing (i.e., operational learning was high). The hot lubricant rinse and
controlling specific wire properties in preceding production stages led to a sharp
increase in productivity. Moreover, faced with the combination of conceptual
and operational learning, the Aalter plant adopted the findings for all products.
Products are primarily defined by the number of filaments and the diame-
ters of the filaments. In addition, products can be customized in terms of proper-
ties such as adhesion (ability to adhere to rubber) and tensile strength of the
wire. The MLA focus on a single product for a single customer kept characteris-
tics such as adhesion and tensile strength constant, thus creating a more stable
environment for conducting controlled experiments. Once new technological
knowledge was created on the MLA such as “a hot lubricant rinse improves
drawability,” the Aalter plant could assess how such principles could be trans-
ferred to other products. The Aalter plant found that installing a hot lubricant
rinse before the wet wire drawing stage improved drawability for all products.
The products produced in plants B and C fell in the same range as the Aalter
products in terms of number of filaments, filament diameters, adhesion, and
tensile strength. Therefore, new technological knowledge created on any model
line with high conceptual and high operational learning could be applicable to
all three plants. Bekaert’s replication efforts of the MLA demonstrate how the
organizational context limited formal learning and transfer of formal learning.
Replication Efforts
effort to influence what those pieces really do, even how they relate to each
other in any but the most superficial ways.”21 Consequently, plant managers did
not have an incentive to transfer authority over production from department
managers to model line managers.
tions (see Sidebar “Ruling out Alternative Explanations”). These robustness tests
increase our confidence in concluding that organizational factors significantly
impeded successful replication of the original model line concept.
Conclusion
Managing learning curves in factories is not an easy task. Many produc-
tion processes like Bekaert’s are shrouded in dynamic complexity, detail com-
plexity, ambiguity, and incomplete technological knowledge. Faced with such
barriers to learning, production personnel should engage in both conceptual and
operational learning. Knowledge created locally with both conceptual and oper-
ational learning can spread globally, thereby accelerating a factory’s global learn-
ing curve.
Organizational constructs such as Bekaert’s first model line should be run
as a learning laboratory to consistently produce both conceptual and operational
learning. Faced with dynamic complexity, separation of cause-and-effect in time
and space, a model line needs to cut across production departments. To success-
fully create new technological knowledge on a model line cutting across produc-
tion departments, management buy-in is required. Without authority to commit
different production departments to action, experiments are likely to fail.
Authority over production is critical, because learning needs to take place on the
factory floor. Note that we are not saying that every model line manager has to
report to the CEO. However, “thick management”—a deep understanding of the
required conditions to run a model line—is needed.
Running a learning laboratory in a factory requires controlling the pro-
duction environment as much as possible. A stable production environment will
reduce noise such that experiments yield better significance results. At Bekaert,
examples of noise reduction included stability in raw material suppliers as well
as focusing on a single product. However, in any specific case, factors that reduce
noise could be different things. Management should figure out which factors
reduce noise in order to maintain laboratory conditions. Running a learning
laboratory in a factory also requires knowledge diversity: different skills from
different production departments and disciplines, as well as a broad and diverse
knowledge base.
Given the managerial opportunity presented by the large variation in
learning rates, firms would be well advised to search for the required conditions
for learning and transfer of learning. Given the resources spent on quality and
productivity improvement efforts in firms and the often disappointing results,
learning to learn requires a concerted and dedicated effort.
Notes
1. For references on early learning curve studies, see Robert H. Hayes, and Steven C. Wheel-
wright, Restoring our Competitive Edge (New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons, 1984), chapter 8;
Linda Argote and Dennis Epple, “Learning Curves in Manufacturing,” Science, 247 (1990):
920-924.
2. Ray Stata, “Organizational Learning: The Key to Management Innovation,” Sloan Manage-
ment Review, 30/3 (Spring 1989): 63-74. For the importance of managing learning rates, see
Ramachandran Jaikumar and Roger E. Bohn, “A Dynamic Approach to Operations Manage-
ment: An Alternative to Static Optimization,” International Journal of Production Economics, 27
(1992): 265-282.
3. For variation in learning rates, see Ferdinand K. Levy, “Adaptation in the Production
Process,” Management Science, 11 (1965): B136-B154; John M. Dutton, and Annie Thomas,
“Treating Progress Functions as a Managerial Opportunity,” Academy of Management Review,
9/2 (April 1984): 245-247; Robert H. Hayes and Kim B. Clark, “Why Some Factories are
More Productive than Others,” Harvard Business Review, 64/5 (September/October 1986): 66-
73; Argote and Epple, op. cit.
4. For dynamic and detail complexity, see Peter M. Senge, “The Leader’s New Work: Building
Learning Organizations,” Sloan Management Review, 32/1 (Fall 1990): 7-23. For ambiguity,
see James G. March and Johan P. Olsen, “The Uncertainty of the Past: Organizational Learn-
ing under Ambiguity,” European Journal of Political Research, 3 (1975): 147-171. For incom-
plete technological knowledge, see Roger E. Bohn, “Measuring and Managing Technological
Knowledge,” Sloan Management Review, 36/1 (Fall 1994): 61-73. For misperception of feed-
back and poor inquiry skills, see John D. Sterman, “Learning in and about Complex Sys-
tems,” System Dynamics Review, 10 (1994): 291-330. For creation of myths, see March and
Olsen, op. cit.; Bo L.T. Hedberg, “How Organizations Learn and Unlearn,” in P.C. Nystrom
and W.H. Starbuck, eds., Handbook of Organizational Design (New York, NY: Oxford University
Press, 1981), pp. 3-27; Daniel H. Kim, “The Link between Individual and Organizational
Learning,” Sloan Management Review, 35/1 (Fall 1993): 37-50.
5. For a scholarly development of the ideas in this article, see Amit S. Mukherjee, Michael A.
Lapré, and Luk N. Van Wassenhove, “Knowledge Driven Quality Improvement,” [Part 2 of
2], Management Science, 44/11 (November 1998): S35-S49; Michael A. Lapré, Amit S.
Mukherjee, and Luk N. Van Wassenhove, “Behind the Learning Curve: Linking Learning
Activities to Waste Reduction,” Management Science, 46/5 (May 2000): 597-611; Michael A.
Lapré and Luk N. Van Wassenhove, “Creating and Transferring Knowledge for Productivity
Improvement in Factories,” Management Science, 47/10 (October 2001): 1311-1325. For
further information on Bekaert, see Amit S. Mukherjee, Michael A. Lapré, and Luk N. Van
Wassenhove, “Bekaert: Beyond the Quality Prizes,” INSEAD-CEDEP case 01/94-4253.
6. Mukherjee, Lapré, and Van Wassenhove (1998), op. cit.
7. Lapré, Mukherjee, and Van Wassenhove, op. cit.
8. Lapré and Van Wassenhove (2001), op. cit.
9. Kim, op. cit.
10. Ibid., for similar definitions.
11. For the methodology behind the classification, statistical analyses, and robustness tests, see
Lapré, Mukherjee, and Van Wassenhove, op. cit. For examples of projects for each category,
see Michael A. Lapré and Luk N. Van Wassenhove, “Learning across Lines: The Secret to
More Efficient Factories,” Harvard Business Review, 80/10 (October 2002): 107-111.
12. W. Bruce Chew, Dorothy Leonard-Barton, and Roger E. Bohn, “Beating Murphy’s Law,”
Sloan Management Review, 32/3 (Spring 1991): 5-16; Gary P. Pisano, The Development Factory:
Unlocking the Potential of Process Innovation (Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press,
1997).
13. For natural and controlled experiments, see Roger E. Bohn, “Learning by Experimentation
in Manufacturing,” working paper 88-001, Harvard Business School, Boston, MA, 1987. For
statistical process control, see Harrison M. Wadsworth, Kenneth S. Stephens, and A. Blanton
Godfrey, Modern Methods for Quality Control and Improvement (New York, NY: John Wiley &
Sons, 1986). For similar approaches to learning in factories, see Dorothy Leonard-Barton,
“The Factory as a Learning Laboratory,” Sloan Management Review, 34/1 (Fall 1992): 23-38;
Chew et al., op. cit.
14. See Mukherjee, Lapré, and Van Wassenhove (1998), op. cit.
15. For persistence of productivity differences, see W. Bruce Chew, Timothy F. Bresnahan, and
Kim B. Clark, “Measurement, Coordination, and Learning in a Multiplant Network,” in R.S.
Kaplan, ed., Measures for Manufacturing Excellence (Boston, MA: Harvard Business School
Press, 1990); Michael van Biema and Bruce Greenwald, “Managing Our Way to Higher
Service-Sector Productivity,” Harvard Business Review, 75/4 (July/August 1997): 87-95. For
failure to replicate best practice, see Carla O’Dell and C. Jackson Grayson, “If Only We Knew
What We Know: Identification and Transfer of Internal Best Practices,” California Management
Review, 40/3 (Spring 1998): 154-174; Gabriel Szulanski and Sidney Winter, “Getting It Right
the Second Time,” Harvard Business Review, 80/1 (January 2002): 62-69.
16. For details on our TFP measure, see Lapré and Van Wassenhove (2001), op. cit. For a gen-
eral description of TFP, see Hayes and Clark, op. cit.
17. For improving supplier relationships, see Charles J. Corbett, Joseph D. Blackburn, and Luk
N. Van Wassenhove, “Partnerships to Improve Supply Chains,” Sloan Management Review,
40/4 (Summer 1999): 71-82.
18. Part of this example draws on Amit S. Mukherjee, “The Effective Management of Organiza-
tional Learning and Process Control in the Factory,” unpublished doctoral dissertation,
Harvard Business School, Boston, MA, 1992.
19. Sidney G. Winter, “Organizing for Continuous Improvement: Evolutionary Theory Meets
the Quality Revolution,” in J.A.C. Baum and J.V. Singh, eds., Evolutionary Dynamics of Organi-
zations (New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 1994), pp. 90-108.
20. For thick versus thin management, see Henry Mintzberg, Mintzberg on Management: Inside Our
Strange World of Organizations (New York, NY: The Free Press, 1989).
21. Ibid.