0% found this document useful (0 votes)
45 views17 pages

Australian Productivity Trends and The Effect of Structural Change

This document analyzes trends in Australia's productivity performance and how structural changes have affected productivity growth. It finds that labor productivity, not terms of trade fluctuations, will be the main driver of future growth in living standards. While Australia's recent productivity growth is in line with historical averages, sustained growth of around 2.5% will be needed to maintain income growth. The document examines sources of productivity growth, finding capital deepening has contributed more than multifactor productivity growth, unlike in other nations. It analyzes how shifts between high- and low-productivity sectors, especially mining, have impacted aggregate productivity.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
45 views17 pages

Australian Productivity Trends and The Effect of Structural Change

This document analyzes trends in Australia's productivity performance and how structural changes have affected productivity growth. It finds that labor productivity, not terms of trade fluctuations, will be the main driver of future growth in living standards. While Australia's recent productivity growth is in line with historical averages, sustained growth of around 2.5% will be needed to maintain income growth. The document examines sources of productivity growth, finding capital deepening has contributed more than multifactor productivity growth, unlike in other nations. It analyzes how shifts between high- and low-productivity sectors, especially mining, have impacted aggregate productivity.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 17

Australian productivity trends and the effect of

structural change
Simon Campbell and Harry Withers

For a small open economy like Australia, which specialises in commodity exports, fluctuations in the
terms of trade and productivity growth are the primary drivers of per capita income growth. Because
the global mining sector responds to higher commodity prices by expanding capacity, the terms of
trade are unlikely to provide sustained boosts to Australia’s living standards. As such, labour
productivity is likely to be the main driver of future growth in living standards. This paper analyses
trends in Australia’s productivity performance and disaggregates productivity growth into industry
contributions to evaluate how structural change is affecting productivity growth.

1
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Introduction
Labour productivity growth is, and is expected to continue to be, the key determinant of growth in
Australian living standards. In terms of the size of the economy, economic growth is determined by
growth in labour utilisation 1 and growth in labour productivity. 2 At an individual level, the primary
drivers of per capita income growth are fluctuations in the terms of trade and labour productivity
growth.

Because the global mining sector responds to higher commodity prices by expanding capacity, the
terms of trade are unlikely to provide sustained boosts to Australia’s living standards. As such,
labour productivity is likely to be the main driver of future growth in living standards.

Despite concerns, Australia’s labour productivity growth over recent years is in line with its
longer-term performance. In the five years to 2015-16, labour productivity in the whole economy has
grown at an average annual rate of 1.8 per cent. This compares to an average annual rate of
1.4 per cent over the past 15 years and 1.6 per cent over the past 30 years. 3

Given the importance of labour productivity growth in improving living standards, an understanding
of trends in Australia’s productivity performance and the impact of structural change on productivity
growth can help reveal where we stand and implications for the future. This paper discusses sources
of productivity growth in the Australian context, followed by an examination of sectoral productivity
growth to highlight how within-sector productivity growth and across-sector productivity growth (or
the effects of structural change on productivity) contribute to aggregate productivity growth.

In analysing sources of labour productivity growth, we address the tension between labour
productivity growth and multifactor productivity (MFP) metrics. Commentators who view labour
productivity growth through the lens of a closed economy neoclassical growth framework have
voiced concerns about the slow growth of MFP (Garnaut, 2015). This concern, in large part, stems
from the belief that sustainable long-run economic growth must be balanced with output and capital
growing at the same rate and that this common growth rate is determined solely by the growth of
MFP. Our analysis shows that Australia’s labour productivity growth has not been limited by
balanced growth or the growth rate of MFP. Australia’s labour productivity growth has largely been
driven by capital deepening (that is, higher capital per worker) rather than MFP growth.

Sectoral analysis reveals how aggregate productivity growth can be affected by structural change in
the economy. In Australia, most sectors have broadly similar productivity levels with the exception of
the Mining and Utilities sectors, which have relatively high productivity levels. The movement of
workers into and out of the Mining sector is the dominant factor behind the effect of structural change
on aggregate productivity growth.

1 Labour utilisation is a function of the ratio of the working age population to the total population; the labour
force participation rate; the employment (unemployment) rate; and average hours worked.
2 Labour productivity growth — the key measure of productivity growth — measures growth in output per
worker (typically defined on an hours worked basis). Labour productivity growth is driven by increases in
the ratio of capital to labour (capital deepening), as well as improvements in the efficiency with which labour
and capital inputs are utilised (multifactor productivity).
3 This is not a reason for complacency, however. Mechanically, there would need to be a sustained lift in
average annual productivity growth to around 2½ per cent to allow living standards (measured as per capita
income) to continue to improve at the long-run historical rate (represented by 30-year average growth in real
gross national income per capita) of around 2 per cent per annum.

2
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Outside a Mining boom, where the structural change effect supplements within-sector productivity
growth, aggregate productivity growth is driven overwhelmingly by within-sector productivity
growth. While within-sector Mining productivity growth is expected to contribute strongly to
aggregate productivity growth for the next few years, the large and growing services sectors will
remain responsible for growth prospects in the longer term. Efforts to increase productivity in the
services sectors will grow in importance into the future.

Sources of aggregate labour productivity growth


Labour productivity growth can be calculated as the sum of capital deepening and MFP growth.
Capital deepening is the change in the ratio of capital to labour 4 multiplied by capital’s share of factor
income. MFP, which is also known as total factor productivity, reflects the overall efficiency with
which labour and capital inputs are used together in the production process. In simplified terms,
labour productivity growth can therefore be thought of as the sum of: (i) increases in the amount of
capital per worker; and (ii) how much better labour and capital work together.

MFP growth can arise for many reasons, including new management practices that allow capital and
labour to be combined more effectively or a more efficient allocation of labour and capital across the
economy. But unlike output, labour or capital, MFP is not directly observed. Rather, it is calculated as
a residual (meaning mismeasurement of labour or capital inputs will be reflected in mismeasured
MFP). 5

Internationally, G7 countries have experienced a slowdown in MFP growth relative to capital


deepening over recent decades. Up until around the late 1990s, the contribution of MFP growth to
labour productivity in G7 countries was generally at least as important as the contribution of capital
deepening. Since then, most of the slowdown in labour productivity growth has been driven by lower
MFP growth (OECD, 2015).

The contribution to labour productivity growth in Australia from capital deepening has been higher
than the contribution from MFP growth. Of the 30-year average of 1.6 per cent whole-of-economy
labour productivity growth, capital deepening contributed 0.9 percentage points and MFP
0.7 percentage points (Chart 1). This is at odds with the balanced growth/MFP growth framework,
which implies a contribution from capital deepening equal to capital’s share of factor incomes. After
rising slowly over the past 30 years, capital’s share of factor income in Australia’s market sector is
currently around 41 per cent (coming off its peak of 44 per cent in 2011-12). 6

4 Labour being hours worked in our analysis.


5 For example, it can be difficult to accurately measure the volume of capital services.
6 Labour’s share of income is therefore currently around 59 per cent. (ABS cat. no. 5260.0.55.002, Table 14).

3
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

7
Chart 1: Labour productivity growth decomposition
Per cent Per cent
2.5 2.5

2.0 2.0

1.5 1.5

1.0 1.0

0.5 0.5

0.0 0.0

-0.5 -0.5
1981-82 to 1984-85 to 1988-89 to 1993-94 to 1998-99 to 2003-04 to 2007-08 to
1984-85 1988-89 1993-94 1998-99 2003-04 2007-08 2015-16
MFP Capital deepening Labour productivity

Source: ABS cat. no. 5260.0.55.002 and Treasury calculations.

As a source of labour productivity growth, MFP growth is considered to have an important


advantage over capital deepening. Neoclassical growth theory implicitly assumes that, unlike capital
deepening, MFP growth does not necessarily require an economy to forgo consumption. As such,
growth in MFP is generally considered a highly desirable — and sustainable — source of labour
productivity growth. That said, improvements in MFP do not come for free, given they usually
require the use of other factors of production.

However, Australia has largely avoided the downside to capital deepening-led labour productivity
growth. Productivity improvements in the rest of the world have caused a persistent fall in the price
of capital goods relative to consumption goods. This has allowed Australia to sustain its high rate of
capital deepening without forgoing ever higher levels of consumption.

It is important to note that the relative contribution of capital deepening and MFP may be skewed if
new capital takes some time to boost output. For example, during an investment boom the
contribution of capital deepening to labour productivity growth may be overstated and the
contribution of MFP growth understated for capital with a long-time-to-build. Such a delay in
productivity associated with capital investment has been particularly evident in the Mining sector
over the past decade — with flow-on effects to whole of economy estimates of capital deepening and
MFP growth. With the ending of the Mining investment boom and Mining output continuing to grow
over coming years, MFP growth is expected to recover (although potentially be overstated).

Factors driving historical aggregate labour productivity growth


During the 1990s, there was strong growth in aggregate labour productivity (Chart 1). This can
largely be attributed to more investment by firms in information and communications technology
(ICT) and important microeconomic and macroeconomic reforms introduced since the mid-1980s. The
former contributed not only to productivity growth through ICT production but also the use of ICT

7 The time periods on the x-axis are productivity cycles as calculated by the ABS. Productivity growth cycle
peaks are determined by comparing the annual MFP estimates with their corresponding long-term trend
estimates. The peak deviations between these two series are the primary indicators of a growth cycle peak,
although general economic conditions at the time are also considered.

4
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

(Gretton, Gali and Parham, 2004). The latter included changes in monetary and fiscal policies, capital
markets, industry assistance, taxation, government enterprises, regulation, labour markets and
industrial relations, competition policy, innovation and training (Productivity Commission, 1999
and 2004).

These reforms have been shown to have increased competition, promoted more efficient allocation of
resources and improved international competitiveness. Some have argued that they also created a
competitive environment that has led to permanently higher levels of innovation as businesses
anticipated global changes in technology, international competition and tastes (Dolman, 2009).

The resurgence of economy-wide labour productivity growth during the 1990s was led by the
services sector. Industries like wholesale trade and financial services seized on new advances in ICT
to transform the way they did business. And following the corporatisation and privatisation of their
operations, industries like telecommunications and utilities achieved continued productivity growth
by scaling back investment levels and substantially reducing their workforces. Productivity levels in
these industries rose towards the international technological frontier (Dolman and Gruen, 2012).

However, aggregate labour productivity growth slowed during the 2000s. Several factors contributed
to this decline. The Agriculture sector was hit by drought and the Mining and Utilities sectors
experienced a fall in productivity as it pursued an ‘unrequited acceleration in input use’ without a
corresponding change in output (Parham, 2012). At a broader level, a reduction of productivity
growth in most developed countries would suggest a possible decline in the pace of technological
change (Gordon, 2014).

In the end, policy settings that seek to support both capital deepening (by lowering the cost of capital)
and MFP improvements (through greater efficiency, innovation and reallocation within existing
resource constraints) will support future growth in labour productivity in Australia.

Sectoral analysis
The drivers of aggregate labour productivity growth can be better understood by examining the issue
from a sectoral perspective. In particular, doing so provides insights into the role that structural
change plays on aggregate productivity growth.

Labour productivity, capital deepening and MFP can each be measured at the sectoral level. 8 In the
analysis that follows, the paper disaggregates the economy into six sectors: Agriculture, Forestry and
Fishing; Mining; Manufacturing; Utilities; Construction and Services, where Services is an aggregate
of all remaining sectors in the Australian economy. 9

For this analysis, aggregate labour productivity growth comprises two components: a within-sector
contribution; and an across-sector contribution, also known as a structural change effect. The former

8 Although data is unfortunately only available from 1988-89 to 2015-16.


9 The ‘services sectors’ are the combination of the following sectors: Wholesale trade; Retail trade;
Accommodation and food services; Transport, postal and warehousing; Information media and
telecommunications; Financial and insurance services; Arts and recreation services; Rental, hiring and real
estate services; Professional, scientific and technical services; Administrative and support services; Other
services; Public administration and safety; Education and training; and Health care and social assistance.

5
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

is the sum of sectoral productivity growth weighted by sectoral GDP share. The latter is the change in
productivity from sectoral reallocation of workers (see Appendix B for methodology). 10

Within-sector labour productivity growth


In the absence of workers moving between sectors, it is the productivity growth within sectors that
determines growth in aggregate labour productivity. Chart 2 shows how labour productivity has
grown in different sectors.

Chart 2: Sectoral labour productivity (indexed to 1988-89)


Index Index
300 300

275 275

250 250

225 225

200 200

175 175

150 150

125 125

100 100

75 75
1988-89 1991-92 1994-95 1997-98 2000-01 2003-04 2006-07 2009-10 2012-13 2015-16
Agriculture, forestry and fishing Mining Manufacturing
Utilities Construction Services
Source: ABS cat. no. 5204.0 (Table 5, Table 15), ABS cat. no. 5260.0.55.002 (Table 6), ABS cat. no. 6291.0.55.003 (Table 11,
supplemented with unpublished ABS data) and Treasury calculations.

A few initial observations can be made from Chart 2:

• Labour productivity has grown strongly in the Agriculture, Forestry and Fishing sector, with
productivity in the sector now over 2½ times its 1988-89 level.

• The Mining and Utilities sectors showed strong labour productivity growth until the early 2000s
before steadily declining through to 2011-12. 11 In fact, Mining sector productivity fell so far over
the period that in 2011-12 it was below its 1988-89 levels. 12

10 The shift share-analysis considered in this article can be used to shed light on whether resource reallocations
between industries are producing efficiency gains through higher productivity outcomes or whether
developments within industries are driving aggregate productivity outcomes. The analysis is primarily
concerned with describing where, on an industry basis, productivity growth is coming from. The analysis
says nothing about the underlying factors driving resource allocation between industries or the nature of
developments within industries.
11 The productivity decline in the Utilities sector from 1997-98 was due to its own unique set of factors. The
construction of new facilities for the provision of water services, the higher levels of investment to replace
ageing network infrastructure, the move from large coal to gas-fired power stations and renewable energy
sources which require higher inputs per unit of output and the drought affecting output levels in water in the
early 2000s all detracted from productivity growth in the sector (Productivity Commission, 2012a and 2012b).
12 The reduction in the level of labour productivity in the Mining industry during the 2000s can be explained by
the lead times between capital investment and the corresponding increase in output, the employment of less
skilled workers at the outset of the mining boom and the depletion of high quality natural resources. In
interpreting Mining sector productivity it should be noted the dramatic fall in Mining productivity in the
2000s may also reflect some Construction sector labour being misclassified as Mining sector labour.

6
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

– Recent data show that with the shift of the mining boom to the production phase, Mining
sector labour productivity growth has improved. Despite more subdued productivity
growth in Mining during 2015-16, the sector’s productivity growth is expected to continue
its recovery in coming years as output increases (the payoff to the capital deepening from
2003-04 seen in Chart 1).

• Productivity in the Manufacturing and Construction sectors has shown growth consistent with
that of the broader economy.

• Similarly, labour productivity in Australia’s services sectors over the past 25 years has grown at
an average annual rate of 1.7 per cent — broadly in line with long-run labour productivity
growth for the whole economy.

– This result is not surprising, given the services sectors we define collectively account for
almost 70 per cent of Australia’s economic output (sector shares of output are shown below
in Chart 3 — note that the services sectors are plotted against the right-hand-side axis). 13

Chart 3: Sector shares of total economic output (gross value added)


16 Per cent Per cent 80

14 70
Services (RHS)
12 60
Manufacturing (LHS) Construction (LHS)
10 50

8 40

Mining (LHS)
6 30
Utilities (LHS)
4 20

Agriculture, forestry and fishing (LHS)


2 10
1988-89 1991-92 1994-95 1997-98 2000-01 2003-04 2006-07 2009-10 2012-13 2015-16
Source: ABS cat. no. 5204.0 (Table 5).

Chart 3 demonstrates that despite the attention given to Mining as a determinant of Australia’s
productivity performance, it is the services sectors that will continue to play a key role in driving
future aggregate productivity growth. Mining’s share of output is certainly significant — now over
8 per cent of the economy, rising sharply from just over 5½ per cent in 2003-04. But over the last five
years over half of Australia’s annual aggregate labour productivity growth was attributable to growth
within the services sectors, compared with around one-quarter attributable to Mining. This
underlines the importance of policy settings in the services sectors.

Meanwhile, Manufacturing and Agriculture (often referred to as key drivers of Australia’s


productivity) continue to shrink. The two industries now contribute less than 10 per cent of

13 It should also be noted that within the services sector composite the individual productivity levels and
growth rates of individual services sectors differ greatly; some suggest this makes them inappropriate to
consider in aggregate (Inklaar, Timmer and van Ark, 2007). While analysis of individual services sectors is
beyond the scope of this paper (perceptions about poor productivity performance in the services sectors
could relate to individual sectors) they have been aggregated to demonstrate their size and historical
contribution to aggregate growth.

7
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Australia’s output combined (around 7 per cent and 2½ per cent respectively). Their contribution to
aggregate productivity growth over the last five years has been negligible.

Structural change
Structural change involves the shift of resources from one industry to another. As workers shift in this
way, the contribution to aggregate labour productivity growth will depend on the relative
productivity between sectors. For instance, workers moving from relatively high productivity sectors
to relatively low productivity sectors will detract from aggregate productivity growth (and
vice versa).

In this respect, the key sector is Mining. Although the level of productivity in the Mining sector over
recent decades has been far from consistent, it has remained the highest in the Australian economy.
Among the sectors featured in Chart 4, only the productivity levels of the Utilities sector have come
close to the levels of the Mining sector in this period. The Mining sector is currently recording
productivity that is over three times the economy wide average in 2015-16 (after peaking at almost
six times the economy wide average in 2000-01).

Chart 4: Sectoral labour productivity levels (relative to economy-wide average)


Ratio Ratio
6.0 6.0
5.5 5.5
5.0 5.0
4.5 4.5
4.0 4.0
3.5 3.5
3.0 3.0
2.5 2.5
2.0 2.0
1.5 1.5
1.0 1.0
0.5 0.5
0.0 0.0
1988-89 1991-92 1994-95 1997-98 2000-01 2003-04 2006-07 2009-10 2012-13 2015-16
Agriculture, forestry and fishing Mining Manufacturing
Utilities Construction Services
Source: ABS cat. no. 5204.0 (Table 5), ABS cat. no. 6291.0.55.003 (Table 11, supplemented with unpublished ABS data) and
Treasury calculations.

As such, structural change will only have a significant effect on aggregate labour productivity growth
when labour moves in and out of the Mining sector (and to a slightly lesser extent, the Utilities
sector). As Chart 4 shows, there is little gain or cost to aggregate labour productivity growth when
labour moves between sectors with similar productivity levels, such as Manufacturing, Construction
and Services.

In some sectors, there has been an inverse relationship between productivity growth and labour
share. Chart 5 below shows how each sector’s share of hours worked has changed since 1988-89,
thereby highlighting the movement of labour across sectors (again, note that the services sectors are
plotted against the right-hand-side axis). The strong labour productivity growth in Agriculture over
recent decades shown in Chart 2 is explained by the sector experiencing reduced hours worked
(Chart 5) for the production of broadly the same output (Chart 3).

8
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Chart 5: Hours worked share


18 Per cent Per cent 90

16 80
Manufacturing (LHS) Services (RHS)
14 70

12 60

10 50
Construction (LHS)
8 40

6 30
Agriculture, forestry and fishing (LHS)
4 20

2 Mining (LHS) 10
Utilities (LHS)
0 0
1988-89 1991-92 1994-95 1997-98 2000-01 2003-04 2006-07 2009-10 2012-13 2015-16
Source: ABS cat. no. 6291.0.55.003 (Table 11, supplemented with unpublished ABS data) and Treasury calculations.

The same inverse relationship is evident in the Mining sector — with significant ramifications for
aggregate productivity growth. The decline in the share of hours worked in the Mining and Utilities
sectors from 1988-89 to the early 2000s is associated with rising productivity levels illustrated in
Chart 2 and Chart 4. This inverse relationship, particularly in Mining, then continued albeit in the
other direction as the Mining boom attracted labour while productivity fell sharply (due to a
combination of a significant increase in labour with a modest increase in output). This is now
beginning to turn around again. These movements of labour into and out of Mining have been the
key driver behind the fluctuations in both the within and across sector contributions to aggregate
labour productivity growth.

Overall contributions to aggregate productivity growth


To understand the relative contributions of each to aggregate productivity growth, Chart 6 below
decomposes it into contributions from within-sector growth and the reallocation of workers across
sectors. In doing so, it illustrates distinct periods where sector reallocation has detracted from
aggregate labour productivity growth and where it has contributed to it. 14

The chart shows that productivity growth is largely driven by the within-sector contribution. Looking
across the whole sample, just over 90 per cent of the economy’s aggregate labour productivity growth
has come from within-sector productivity growth. In other words, the effects of structural change,
including the ups and downs of the Mining boom, has contributed less than 10 per cent of the
economy’s aggregate labour productivity growth since 1988-89.

14 The red bars of Chart 6 are closely related to movements of the Mining sector’s share of hours worked in the
economy in Chart 5. That is, when Mining’s share of hours worked falls (such as during the period from the
early 1990s up until the turn of the century), we see large blue bars (strong within-sector productivity growth,
largely driven by Mining’s productivity performance) and smaller negative red bars (the offsetting effect on
aggregate labour productivity growth of losing labour to less productive sectors). When the Mining sector’s
share of hours worked rise (such as from the early 2000s until recently), we see smaller blue bars combining
with positive red bars as reduced productivity growth within Mining is supplemented by the positive effect
of the sector attracting labour from lower productivity sectors like Agriculture and Manufacturing.

9
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Chart 6: Labour productivity growth decomposed into within and across sector effects
Per cent Per cent
5 5

4 4

3 3

2 2

1 1

0 0

-1 -1

-2 -2

Productivity growth within industries Movements of hours worked between industries


Productivity growth*
Source: ABS cat. no. 5204.0 (Table 5), ABS cat. no. 6291.0.55.003 (Table 11, supplemented with unpublished ABS data) and
Treasury calculations.
*There are slight differences in labour productivity aggregated growth rates using hours worked data in this figure and the
indexed hours worked data reported in National Accounts.

A few episodes highlighted in Chart 6 are worth highlighting:

• The 1988-89 to 1999-00 period, represented by strong within-sector labour productivity growth
partially offset by the loss of labour from high-productivity sectors (Mining and Utilities), bares
similarities with 2014-15.

• The 1999-00 to 2013-14 period, represented by generally lower within-sector labour productivity
growth supplemented by the addition of labour to high-productivity sectors, looks more like
2015-16. 15

• The last two years, when taken together, reflect the recent declining trend in the share of
Australia’s labour force attached to the Mining sector while the services sector’s labour share
continues to grow, detracting from aggregate labour productivity growth. 16

The above observations suggest likely future developments in Australia’s productivity growth.
Notwithstanding the slight return of labour to Mining in 2015-16 due to the relatively labour intensive
LNG projects in Western Australia and Queensland, Mining’s share of the labour force is expected to
continue to fall across the following decade and provide a drag on aggregate labour productivity
growth. But as output in the Mining sector continues to rise during the continuing production phase
(see Chart 3) and labour moves elsewhere, we expect within-sector Mining productivity growth to
more than offset the detraction to aggregate productivity growth from labour moving to less
productive sectors (like services).

15 2015-16 saw a slight return of labour towards Mining.


16 It is worth noting that this reallocation of labour coincided with the end of the construction phase of the
mining boom, so the combination of less labour needed and greater output from the production phase means
that productivity within the sector is beginning to recover (Chart 4).

10
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Chart 7 provides further insights into the relationship between labour movements into and out of the
Mining sector and productivity growth within that sector. It reproduces Chart 6 but separates the
years where movements of labour detract from aggregate productivity growth and where they add to
it; and separately identifies the contribution to aggregate labour productivity growth of the Mining
and services sectors.

Chart 7: Labour productivity for selected periods decomposed into


within (by sector) and across sector effects
Per cent Per cent
3.0 3.0

2.5 2.5

2.0 2.0

1.5 1.5

1.0 1.0

0.5 0.5

0.0 0.0

-0.5 -0.5

-1.0 -1.0
Years where labour Years where labour 2013-14 to 2014-15 2014-15 to 2015-16
movements detract from movements add to
productivity growth productivity growth
Movements of hours worked between industries Productivity growth within Mining
Productivity growth within Services Productivity growth within other sectors
Productivity growth*
Source: ABS cat. no. 5204.0 (Table 5), ABS cat. no. 6291.0.55.003 (Table 11, supplemented with unpublished ABS data) and
Treasury calculations.
*There are slight differences in labour productivity aggregated growth rates using hours worked data in this figure and the
indexed hours worked data reported in National Accounts.

A striking feature of Chart 7 is that when labour movements have detracted from aggregate
productivity growth (the first and third columns), aggregate productivity growth in those years (the
black marker) has been higher than years where labour movements have made a positive
contribution (the second and fourth columns). This means, essentially, that the within-sector effect
from Mining when labour leaves the sector dominates the across-sector effect. When labour moves
towards Mining, within-sector productivity growth in Mining is significantly weaker.

The longer-term samples of the first two columns of Chart 7 also highlight the significant role that the
services sectors have played in underpinning aggregate labour productivity growth over almost three
decades.

While no clear pattern emerges from recent years to help predict what the next few years may look
like, we expect the foreseeable future to look more like the first and third columns, with quite strong
aggregate labour productivity growth. A risk to this prediction, which is evident in 2015-16, is the
possibility that additional labour will be used to take advantage of the temporary spikes in resources
prices in the shorter term, which would lead to more columns like the fourth column. 17

17 At the 2017-18 Budget, the assumed price for Australia’s key commodities exports were: iron ore at
US$66/tonne; metallurgical coal at US$200/tonne; thermal coal at US$85/tonne.

11
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Regardless, the Mining sector is expected to continue to be a significant contributor to aggregate


labour productivity growth in coming years. For example, despite the Mining sector actually adding
labour in 2015-16 — which contributed to labour productivity growth in the sector falling from
29.5 per cent in 2014-15 to 3.4 per cent in 2015-16 — within sector Mining productivity growth still
contributed around a quarter of the economy’s aggregate labour productivity growth (column 4 of
Chart 7).

Conclusion
Despite concerns about Australia’s labour productivity and MFP growth in light of the lower terms of
trade and an ageing population, recent labour productivity growth (driven by capital deepening) is in
line with its longer-term averages.

In addition, there is little cause for alarm over the effect of structural change on productivity growth.
While the services sectors continue to attract more and more labour, their aggregate productivity level
is similar to all other sectors of the economy bar Mining and Utilities and their combined
within-sector productivity growth is tracking at similar speeds to that of the whole economy (in part
as they already represent over two-thirds of the economy). Indeed, it is labour productivity growth in
the services sectors that has been underpinning aggregate productivity growth in Australia over
recent decades, and will continue to do so, notwithstanding cyclical periods of weak and strong
productivity growth in the Mining sector (which is largely associated with inflows and outflows of
workers in the sector) or other sectors.

While the Mining sector is expected to continue to make a strong contribution to Australia’s
productivity growth in the next few years, the services sectors will remain responsible for growth
prospects in the longer term. With within-sector productivity growth the dominant force behind
aggregate productivity growth, both capital deepening and MFP improvements will be important to
support future growth in labour productivity in Australia.

12
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

References
Dolman, B., 2009, ‘What Happened to Australia’s Productivity Surge?’, Australian Economic Review,
vol 42, pp 243-263.

Dolman, B. and Gruen, D., 2012. ‘Productivity and structural change’, 41st Australian Conference of
Economists, 10 July 2012.

Eslake, S., 2011, ‘Productivity: The Lost Decade’, Paper presented to Reserve Bank of Australia
Conference on The Australian Economy in the 2000s, Sydney, 15 August 2011.

Garnaut, R., 2015, Addresses to the National Reform Summit (26 August 2015, Sydney) and Workforce
and Productivity Summit (8 December 2015, Melbourne).

Gordon, R.J., 2014. ‘The Demise of U.S. Economic Growth: Restatement, Rebuttal, and Reflections’,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 19895.

Gretton, P., Gali, J. and Parham, D., 2004, ‘The effects of ICTs and complementary innovations on
Australian productivity growth’, in The Economic Impact of ICT — Measurement, Evidence and
Implications, OECD, Paris.

Inklaar, R., Timmer, M., and van Ark, B., 2007. ‘Mind the Gap! International Comparisons of
Productivity in Services and Goods Production’, German Economic Review, vol 8, pp 281-307.

OECD, 2015. ‘OECD Compendium of Productivity Indicators 2015’, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Parham, D 2012, ‘Australia’s Productivity Growth Slump: Signs of Crisis, Adjustment or Both?’,
Visiting Researcher Paper, Productivity Commission, Canberra.

Productivity Commission, 1999. ‘Microcosmic reforms and Australian productivity: Exploring the
links’, Commission Research Paper, AusInfo, Canberra.

Productivity Commission, 2004. ‘ICT Use and Productivity: A Synthesis from Studies of Australian
Firms’, Commission Research Paper, Canberra.

Productivity Commission, 2012a. ‘Impacts of COAG reforms: Business regulation & VET, Supplement
to research report’, July 2012.

Productivity Commission, 2012b. ‘Productivity in Electricity, Gas and Water: Measurement and
Interpretation, March 2012.

13
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Appendix A
Data
This article uses two different sources of Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) hours worked data to
calculate labour input. Index data is sourced from the National Accounts (ABS cat. no. 5204.0) and
Multifactor Productivity (ABS cat. no. 5260.0.55.002) data releases and is typically used for official
productivity reporting. Levels data is sourced from the Labour Force Statistics (ABS cat. no.
6291.0.55.003) and is required for the analysis of movements of labour.

Using these sources, aggregate labour productivity estimates for the 12 industry market sector, the
16 industry market sector and the whole economy are available from 1973-74, 1994-95 and 1977-78
respectively.

Sectoral productivity analysis requires levels data from the ABS Labour Force Statistics. There are
slight differences between estimates of growth in hours worked using levels data and the index data
used elsewhere in the paper — particularly when comparing whole of economy and disaggregated
industry sector data — which lead to differences in labour productivity estimates for a given increase
in real GDP. 18

While improvements in labour quality, for example through education and training, can be a source
of productivity gains, for simplicity this article uses an hours worked basis when considering labour
input (as opposed to quality adjusted hours worked).

Industry classification
The economy comprises market and non-market industries, listed with their availabilities in Table 1
below. The market sector industries are broken up into the 12 industry market sector industries and
four ‘new’ services industries, included since 1994-95.

18 The levels data are stock data (referring to a particular week within the quarter) and will therefore not sum to
the ABS headline figures used in the National Accounts (which is based on flow data that covers the entire
quarter).

14
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Table 1: Australian and New Zealand Standard Industrial Classification 2006 (ANZSIC06)
‘12 industry market sector’ ‘New’ services industries Non-market industries
industries

Industry data from 1988-89 Industry data from 1994-95 19 Industry data from 1994-95 20

Agriculture, Forestry and Fishing Rental, Hiring and Real Estate Services Public Administration and Safety

Mining Professional, Scientific and Technical Services Education and Training

Manufacturing Administrative and Support Services Health Care and Social Assistance

Electricity, Gas, Water and Waste Other Services Ownership of Dwellings


Services

Construction

Wholesale Trade

Retail Trade

Accommodation and Food


Services

Transport, Postal and


Warehousing

Information, Media and


Telecommunications

Financial and Insurance Services

Arts and Recreation Services

19 While data from the ‘new’ services industries is available as part of the ‘16 industry market sector’ from
1994-95, output and employment data for these industries can be obtained from 1988-89 to create the
composite ‘services sectors’ series from 1988-89 used in this article.
20 MFP and capital deepening components are unavailable for these industries.

15
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Appendix B
We thank Michael Kouparitsas and Daniel Silva-Withmory for providing the following analysis.

Shift-share analysis
Aggregate labour productivity is the ratio of total gross value added to the number of hours worked
in the economy; equal to the sum of labour productivity levels in each sector weighted by the hours
worked in those sectors. Growth (or decline) in labour productivity can therefore be attributed to
either changes in productivity levels in individual sectors or changes in employment share in each
industry.

This decomposition of aggregate labour productivity growth is shown below, by letting 𝑌 be


aggregate output and 𝑌𝑖 be sectoral output, 𝑁 be aggregate hours worked and 𝑁𝑖 be sectoral hours
worked.

Output at time t is the sum of sectoral output 𝑌𝑖𝑖 :

𝑌𝑡 = � 𝑌𝑖𝑖
𝑖

Which we can divide through by hours worked for productivity:

𝑌𝑡 𝑌𝑡 𝑁𝑖𝑖
=�
𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑡
𝑖

Subtracting by previous period for the change in productivity;

𝑌𝑡 𝑌𝑡−1 𝑌𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1


− =� +�
𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑡−1
𝑖 𝑖

And rearranging:

𝑌𝑡 𝑌𝑡−1 𝑌𝑖𝑖 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1


− = �� − � + �� − �
𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡−1
𝑖 𝑖

Which we can divide through by lagged productivity the aggregate for growth rate:

𝑌𝑡 𝑌𝑡−1 𝑌 𝑌 𝑁 𝑁 𝑁 𝑌
� − � � 𝑖𝑖 − 𝑖𝑖−1 � 𝑖𝑖 � 𝑖𝑖 − 𝑖𝑖−1 � 𝑖𝑖−1
𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡−1
=� +�
𝑌𝑡−1 𝑌𝑡−1 𝑌𝑡−1
𝑖 𝑖
𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡−1

And rearranging to express the growth rate of productivity as its contributions from within industry
productivity improvements and reallocations of labour.

𝑌𝑖𝑖 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1


�� − � � 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1
𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1
=� + �� − �
𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑌𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑌𝑡−1
𝑖 𝑖
𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡−1

𝑌𝑖𝑖 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1


− � �
𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1
=� + �� − �
𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑌𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑌𝑡−1
𝑖 𝑖
𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑡−1

16
Australian productivity trends and the impact of structural change

Given that:

𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑡−1
≈1
𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1

It follows that:

𝑌 𝑌 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1
𝑌𝑡 𝑌𝑡−1 � 𝑖𝑖 − 𝑖𝑖−1 � 𝑌 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1
� − � 𝑁𝑖𝑖 𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑖𝑖−1
𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 � +�� − �
≈ 𝑌𝑖𝑖−1 𝑌𝑡−1 𝑁𝑡 𝑁𝑡−1 𝑌𝑡−1
𝑌𝑡−1 𝑖
𝑁𝑖𝑖−1 𝑖
𝑁𝑡−1
𝑁𝑡−1
(𝑊𝑊𝑊ℎ𝑖𝑖 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ) (𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖)

The first term in the decomposition is the weighted sum of productivity growth within individual
sectors, where weights are the share of output of each sector at the beginning of the time period — the
‘within industry’ component of productivity growth.

The second term captures the effect on aggregate productivity growth from the reallocation of labour
across different sectors. This is a weighted sum of the changes in sectoral employment shares, where
the weights are relative productivity levels at the beginning of the time period — the ‘across industry’
component of productivity growth.

17

You might also like