Theories of Social Conflict
Theories of Social Conflict
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Annual Reviews is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Annual
Review of Sociology
Anthony Oberschall
INTRODUCTION
This review is mainly concerned with describing and evaluating the two
principal approaches to conflict theory: the breakdown-deprivation ap-
proach and the solidarity-mobilization approach. The older classics and the
well-known theories based on them like Dahrendorf (1959) and Coser
(1956) are not reviewed here, because their contributions have become part
of the shared fund of sociological knowledge. However, I indicate in a short
example how the classics might be more tightly incorporated into current
conflict theories.1
This review also omits evaluations of the conflict perspective in sociologi-
cal thinking, because a perspective or orientation is not a theory of conflict
defined by the three broad topics. For instance, Randall Collins' Conflict
Sociology, Towards an Explanatory Science (1975), does not contain the
statement of a theory of social conflict. It is rather a work of general
sociology written from a conflict perspective. Collins writes little about
overt conflict, such as strikes, rebellion, and collective violence. He does not
discuss the forms of conflict, the formation of conflict groups, mobilization,
recruitment, and leadership, nor outcomes and conflict resolution. And he
deals only briefly with major and common group conflicts such as ethnic,
racial, and communal conflicts. He seeks instead to explain how structures
of domination based on social class, gender, and age differences have come
'A comprehensive review of the literature on social conflict is provided by Kriesberg (1973).
This essay is primarily concerned with modes of theorizing and theory construction.
about and how they are maintained. These structures of domination have
a potential for conflict, but the link between these structures and overt
conflict is not explicitly spelled out.
However, I am concerned with two issues of theory construction that are
particularly salient in theorizing about social conflict. The first is levels of
analysis. Some theorists treat a conflict group as a single collective actor.
Their theories consist of statements about groups and the relations between
groups. Other theorists start with individual behavior as the unit of theoriz-
ing, and derive group behavior from a summation of individual tendencies
and behaviors. Still other theorists handle the problem of levels of analysis
and of moving from the individual to the group level in more complicated
ways. Does the mode of theorizing lead to different insights and different
kinds of conflict theory?
The second issue is the use of different assumptions about human behav-
ior. Some theorists utilize the rational-choice model derived from economic
analysis; others incorporate complex psychological and social psychological
assumptions into models. Are these approaches mutually exclusive or com-
plementary? Do their conclusions differ?
Theories of group conflict will have to pay special attention to group struc-
ture and the emergent properties of group. Group behavior should not
simply be assumed to be analogous to individual behavior. Social psycholog-
ical knowledge will help locate emergent group properties for conflict theo-
rists.
2The social change and modernization literature that incorporates breakdown ideas is im-
mense. Two sophisticated exponents of breakdown views are Huntington (1968) and Smelser
(1968).
and what they are actually getting. As deprivation increases, frustration and
anger will ensue. These psychological states will produce aggression. At the
level of aggregates, many aggressive acts and tendencies will produce civil
strife.
The relationship between discontent and strife is mediated, however, by
a number of intervening conditions either facilitating or inhibiting overt
conflict. Just as punishment, actual or threatened, will inhibit individual
aggression, increased size and use of social control agents against regime
opponents can be expected to have a deterrent and depressing effect on
group conflict. Gurr refers to such inhibiting conditions simply as the
"coercive potential" of the regime.
A second inhibiting condition, called "institutionalization" refers to the
existence of stable, enduring and strong associations and solidarities beyond
the primary group level (Gurr 1968:1105). For Gurr, such groups provide
members with an opportunity to obtain what they think they are entitled
to. Their presence will thus lower deprivation, or else provide nonviolent
means of voicing discontent. In either case, institutionalization will inhibit
civil strife.
Other facilitating conditions identified by Gurr are inaccessibility of
regime opponents due to poor transportation in rugged terrain, the strength
of subversive groups such as the Communist party, external support for the
initiators of civil strife, and past levels of strife, which create a climate of
opinion tolerant of violent responses to discontent (Gurr 1968:1106,1114,
1115). Finally, legitimacy of the regime is assumed to have an inhibiting
effect on civil strife.
Many problems of operationalizing and measuring these variables and
processes are admitted by Gurr. There are also difficulties of interpreting
the result of multivariate analyses based on cross-national, static compari-
sons. Here I comment only on the theoretical issues raised by Gurr's model
as an example of conflict theory. The most completely spelled out parts of
the model are those concerned with relative deprivation and institutionali-
zation. Both together make Gurr's model a variant of the breakdown-
frustration explanation of social conflict. The other inhibiting and
facilitating variables in the model come from empirical generalizations in
past studies of civil strife, or from widely accepted notions about conflict,
rather than from theory.
As used by Gurr, the relative deprivation notion lacks explanatory
power. Relative deprivation is the discrepancy between what people think
they are entitled to, and what they actually get. Relative deprivation, by
definition, involves social comparison. One develops notions about what one
is entitled to relative to what some other group is getting, or relative to some
norm of equity. Gurr's theory is silent on the choice of the comparison
recent urban migrants. They are members of solidary groups in villages and
small towns, but remain unorganized for a time in the city milieu.
Urbanization, industrialization, and centralization of government stimu-
late political conflict, because the authorities make claims on the resources
of groups that retain a viable social organization and hence are capable of
defensive mobilization. Typical collective actions of the earlier 19th century
in which participants resisted the claims of national structures were the food
riot, the tax rebellion, and resistance to conscription. The sites of collective
action were the natural gathering places of rural folk: markets, church
services, festivals. As traditional groups weakened and new solidarities,
associations, and trade unions came into being, collective action shifted
from the defense of existing rights and resources to a claim for more rights
and a greater share of societal resources. The demonstration, strike, and the
deliberate assembly in an urban setting became the typical form of collective
action.
Other critics of breakdown-frustration theory find it deficient in explain-
ing internal war and rebellion in the contemporary world. Laqueur (1976)
is profoundly skeptical of social science theories and generalizations about
internal war and collective violence. He is even skeptical of the comparative
approach employed in civil strife studies: "The guerrilla phenomenon
presents endless variety ... a comparison between China and Vietnam or
between Angola and Mozambique, or even between the IRA and Basques
may be of value and of interest. Moving further afield in time or space,
generalizations can be made only with the greatest of caution" (1976:386)
Laqueur's Guerrilla, a Historical and Critical Study (1976) is an exhaus-
tive examination of secondary sources on partisans, guerrillas, and wars of
national liberation, ranging widely in geography and time. Rich in detail,
the book stresses the great diversity of such movements. Laqueur debunks
the notion that guerrilla war is a recent historical phenomenon, a rare event,
and an effective weapon. He holds that recent doctrines of revolutionary
warfare are neither original nor able to account for success and failure.
According to Laqueur, nationalism, patriotism, and separatist ethnic senti-
ment have been the most important driving force of guerrilla wars. He
doubts the usefulness of the breakdown-frustration explanation of popular
uprising in traditional societies undergoing rapid change. He questions the
assumptions that insurgency is deviant behavior, "as if acceptance of for-
eign occupations and domestic tyrants is the norm, and the decision to
oppose them a deviation" (Laqueur 1976:386). He notes that a consistent
bias of theorists of internal war has been to analyze "the forces which propel
societies towards violence rather than those which inhibit it" (1976:389). He
suggests that more attention be paid to incumbents, the targets of the
insurgents.
People may harbor intense grievances; yet they may possess few resources
and may be vulnerable so that they can provide but negligible inputs to
challengers. Others with but mild grievances, yet plentiful resources, might
make substantial contributions even if they provide but a fraction of their
resources to challengers. Societal breakdown is, to be sure, associated with
the generation of discontent, but its main impact on conflict is by way of
the costs of mobilization and collective action. Mobilizing the resources of
disorganized collectivities is far costlier than doing it within solidary
groups, because the latter already possess well-defined leadership and orga-
nization that can be enlisted on behalf of the challenger.
forget that groups high on solidarity, and therefore also on catnet, have a
better chance of identifying free riders and pressuring them to conform to
group norms. For both these sets of reasons then, the mobilization capabil-
ity of high-solidarity groups are greater than that of groups low on
solidarity.
Though mobilization theory is relatively well developed, much work
remains to be done to increase its explanatory power. In particular, it
appears useful to differentiate several categories of participants in conflict
groups, because their recruitment into a conflict group and their commit-
ment to a collective movement will be generated and sustained by a different
mix of selective incentives, psychological gratifications, and ideological ap-
peals. Useful work along these lines has been done by McCarthy & Zald
(1973) who distinguish constituents (those who provide resources to a
conflict group), adherents (those who value the collective good), bystander
publics, and opponents. Constituents may further be divided into a leader-
ship cadre or full-time activists, and transitory teams of part-timers. Finally,
all these categories may differ according to the direct benefits they expect
to derive from the realization of the conflict group's goals. These distinc-
tions have allowed McCarthy & Zald to identify the important categories
of conscience adherents and conscience constituents, i.e. participants and
supporters who are not direct beneficiaries of the collective good. Strategies
of mobilization can then be analyzed from the point of view of the different
resources each of these categories contributes to the struggle and the differ-
ing selective incentives and appeals necessary to ensure resource delivery.
Internal splits and factionalism within conflict groups may also be usefully
understood by looking at the internal heterogeneity of conflict groups.
Most "twentieth century Americans" know how to demonstrate. They know that a
group that has a claim to make assembles at a public place, identifies itself and its
demands or complaints in a visible way, orients its common action to the persons,
property, or symbols of some other group that is seeking to influence. Within those
general rules, most Americans know how to carry on several different forms of demon-
stration: the mass march, the assembly with speechmaking, the temporary occupation
of premises (Tilly 1978:Ch. 5).
CONCLUSION
Literature Cited
Boulding, K. 1963. Conflict and Defense. Janis, I. 1972. Victims of Groupthink. Bos-
New York: Harper Torchbooks. 349 pp. ton: Houghton Mifflin. 277 pp.
Coleman, J. S. 1957. Community Conflict. Kriesberg, L. 1973. The Sociology of Social
New York: Free Press. 28 pp. Conflicts. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Pren-
Collins, R. 1975. Conflict Sociology, Towards tice-Hall. 300 pp.
an Explanatory Science. New York: Laqueur, W. 1976. Guerrilla, A Historical
Academic 584 pp. and Critical Study. Boston: Little,
Coser, L. 1956. The Functions of Social Con- Brown. 462 pp.
flict. New York: Free Press. 188 pp. Leites, N., Wolf, C. J. 1970 Rebellion and
Coser, L. 1967. Continuities in the Study of Authority. Chicago: Markham. 174 pp.
Social Conflict. New York: Free Press. McCarthy, J., Zald, M. 1973. The Trendof
272 pp. Social Movements in America. Morris-
Dahrendorf, R. 1959. Class and Class Con- town, NJ: General Learning. 30 pp.
flict in Industrial Society. Stanford Oberschall, A. 1973. Social Conflict and So-
Univ. Press, Calif. 336 pp. cial Movements. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Deutsch, M. 1973. The Resolution of Conflict. Prentice-Hall. 371 pp.
New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press. Oberschall, A. 1978a. The decline of the
420 pp. 1960s social movements. In Research in
Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J., Young, O. Social Movements, Conflict, and
1971. Political Leadership and Collec- Change, ed. L. Kriesberg. Johnson As-
tive Goods. Princeton Univ. Press, NJ. soc. In press
161 pp. Oberschall, A. 1978b. Protracted conflict. See
Gamson, W. 1975. The Strategy ofSocial Pro- Gamson & Fireman 1978
test. Homewood, Ill.: Dorsey. 217 pp. Olson, M. Jr. 1968. The Logic of Collective
Gamson, W., Fireman, B. 1978. Utilitarian Action. New York: Schocken. 176 pp.
logic in the resource mobilization per- Paige, J. 1975. Agrarian Revolution. New
spective. In The Dynamics of Social York: Free Press. 435 pp.
Movements: Resource Mobilization, Salert, B. Revolutions and Revolutionaries.
Tactics, and Social Control, ed. M. New York: Elsevier. 161 pp.
Zald, J. McCarthy. Beverley Hills, CA: Schelling, T. 1963. The Strategy of Conflict.
Sage. In press New York: Oxford Univ. Press. 309 pp.
Gurr, T. R. 1968. A causal model of civil Smelser, N. 1968. Toward a theory of mod-
strife. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 62,4:1104-24 ernization. In Essays in Sociological Ex-
Gurr, T. 1969. A comparative study of civil planation, ed. N. Smelser, pp. 125-46.
strife. Violence in America, ed. H. Gra- Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall
ham, T. Gurr, pp. 544-605. New York: Spilerman, S. 1970. The causes of racial dis-
New American Library turbance: A comparison of alternate ex-
Gurr, T. 1970. Why Men Rebel. Princeton planations. Am. Sociol. Rev. 35:627-49
Univ. Press, NJ: 421 pp. Tilly, C. 1978. From Mobilization to Revolu-
Hechter, M. Internal Colonialism: The Celtic tion. Reeding, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.
Fringe in British National Development, In press
1536-1966. Berkeley: Univ. Calif. Tilly, C., Tilly, L., Tilly, R. 1975. The Rebel-
Press. 361 pp lious Century, 1830 to 1930. Cam-
Heirich, M. 1971. The Spiral of Conflict: bridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press.
Berkeley 1964. Columbia Univ. Press, 354 pp.
NY. 462 pp. Tilly, C. 1975. Revolutions and collective vi-
Huntington, J. 1968. Political Order in olence. In Handbook of Political
Changing Society. New Haven, CT: Science, ed. F. Greenstein, N. Polsby,
Yale Univ. Press. 488 pp. Vol. 3. New York: Addison Wesley