The Korean Semiconductor Industry
The Korean Semiconductor Industry
THESIS
2000
1
TABLE OF CONTENTS
1. INTRODUCTION 1
8. CONCLUSION 44
Annexes 48
Annex I - Semiconductor Classification by Device 48
Annex II - Income and Technological Performance in OECD countries, 1995 49
Annex III - Average annual rates of growth of real GNP (selected years). 50
Annex IV - APEC Economies’ GDP figures (1989 – 1998) 51
References 52
List of Acronyms 54
2
1. INTRODUCTION
The semiconductor industry has been termed 'the crude oil of the information
industrial robots, from consumer durables to smart missiles, without their silicone
‘brains’ would be useless. This implies that in the future the semiconductor industry
will increasingly serve in a bed-rock capacity, being the basis for the development of
required to meet the demand for not just high-technology goods but also increasingly
semiconductors as well.
to overcome the high entrance barriers of the industry. South Korea has been
3
many American and European semiconductor manufacturers, since the 1970s, have
Starting from scratch, the Korean semiconductor industry was fostered in the
the United States of America and Japan. However, despite this rather inauspicious
Electronics and Hyundai Electronics) came to be ranked amongst the world’s fifteen
began in 1983, Korea has placed heavy emphasis on the mass production of memory
chips. As of 1996, Korea controlled around 40% of the world DRAM market,
allowing Korea a share of the world DRAM market equal to that enjoyed by its
technologies. Samsung Electronics, for instance, announced at the end of June 1999
the successful development of the world's first 1 Gb DDR SDRAM (Double Data
4
coming information era. It is therefore astonishing to note progress made by Korea’s
semiconductor industry, from a scratch starter to a world beater in less than fifteen
years. How has Korea managed to develop its semiconductor industry so successfully
in such a short period of time? What are the historical precedents which allowed
Korean firms such an advantage over international competitors? What effect did the
recent financial turmoil have on the industry, and what are the future prospects in the
wake of the economic crisis? It is the aim of this paper, using broad sources of
information, to firstly outline the historical background, recent economic and political
5
In the early 1960s semiconductor producers from the United States were
seeking skilled and relatively cheap labour in foreign countries. South Korea was an
ideal place for this purpose because of its highly skilled human resources, low wages,
and peaceful environment ensured by the authoritarian government. The first foreign
investment in the Korean semiconductor industry was made by the U.S. firm Komy,
in December 1965. Although the size of investment was relatively small, this was the
The first sizeable investment was made by Fairchild in 1969. At that time, it
was one of the largest semiconductor firms in the United States. Fairchild set two
preconditions : 100% ownership and free access to the domestic market. It was almost
impossible for the Korean government to satisfy these conditions due to existing
Planning Board of Korea (EPB). The EPB decided to use its right to amend the
legislation governing foreign investment with the view to attract more foreign capital
and technologies in the future. Large foreign investment was crucial for the
from this fact, that even laws and regulations were changed in order to create
exclusively owned firms (see table 2.1). Following the example of Toshiba in 1969,
6
Table 2.1 - Foreign Investment in Korean Semiconductor Firms (1965-1973)
Approval Name of Foreign Country Investment Foreign Location
Date by the Firm Investor Amount Ownership
EPB ($1000) (%)
12.1965 KOMG KOMG USA 76 25 Seoul
4.1966 Semikor Fairchild USA 2250 100 Seoul
7.1966 Signetics Signetics USA 1750 100 Seoul
12.1966 Korea-Micro KMI USA 224 49 Seoul
3.1967 Motorola Motorola USA 8000 100 Seoul
7.1968 IMEC Komy USA 1210 100 Seoul
1.1969 Minsong Han- USA 145 35 Seoul
American
7.1969 Toshiba Toshiba Japan 1400 70 Kumi
9.1969 Samsung- Sanyo + Japan 1500 40 + 10 Seoul
Sanyo Sumitomo
3.1970 Taehan AMI USA 2264 100 Seoul
3.1970 Electrovoice EV USA 50 50 Kumi
7.1970 Varadyne Varadyne USA 294 49 Kumi
7.1970 Korea IC Tesco USA 700 50 Kumi
12.1970 Toko Toko Japan 390 100 MAFEZ
9.1971 KTK Toko Japan 100 MAFEZ
7.1972 Rohm Rohm Japan 95 Seoul
11.1972 Tokyo Sanyo Japan 1624 100 MAFEZ
Silicon
5.1973 Sanken Sanken Japan 700 100 MAFEZ
Sources: Soh Changrok, September 1997
important objectives of the Electronics Industry Promotion Law. President Park was
personally involved in this issue. The Kumi Electronics Industrial complex was
officially opened in April 1970. The complex was granted numerous privileges and
al 1987)
7
Masan Free Export Zone (MAFEZ) was established together with the Kumi
Industrial Complex, following the instructions of the Korean government. The main
purpose of MAFEZ was to attract Japanese investment. The port of Masan in the
southern part of Korea was especially selected because of its geographical proximity
MAFEZ, and in 1974 it accounted for more than 90% in terms of number of foreign
companies as well as in terms of the size of total investment. (Lee Changrok 1974,
1212-1257)
foreign investment as possible. At the same time, it shows the great dependence of
Korean economy on imported capital. MAFEZ made clear the state attitude towards
foreign capital. The government evidently favoured joint ventures over to 100%
different types of incentives for foreign investment such as five year tax holidays,
duty-free imports of capital goods and raw materials, and 50 per cent income tax
reduction. It is worth noting that the Foreign Capital Inducement Law did not have
detailed instructions regarding foreign investment, stating that the process of foreign
direct investment should be regulated by the Economic Planning Board and the
related ministries, including the Ministry of Trade and Industry. (Yoon 1989, 50)
8
the 1967 ‘State of the Nation Address’. Professor Wan- Hee Kim of the Department of
and Industry in an effort to help promote the Korean electronics industry. Mr. Kim
prepared a report on the issue and submitted it to the president Park in September
March 1967. Both recommendation packages, one by the Economic and Scientific
Council and the other by the MTI were almost identical and included the following
points:
- export promotion;
and export promotion. In order for the industry to become more competitive in the
international market, the government tried to induce large conglomerates to enter the
electronics sector. Two chaebol, Taehan Electric Wire and Samsung, entered the
electronics industry in 1968 and 1969 respectively. One of the most important
milestones in the government’s vigorous efforts to promote the industry was the
enactment of the Electronics Industry Promotion Law in 1969. At the same time, The
9
'Eight-Year plan for the Electronics Industry Promotion (1969-76)' was prepared by
the Ministry of Trade. This plan consisted of the following three main points:
industry grew rapidly reaching 5% of total exports by 1973. The share of private
1968 numbered 120 (115 domestic, 3 exclusively foreign subsidiaries, and 2 joint
ventures). (EIAK 1989, 40) It is obvious from this fact that despite of various
incentives by the Korean government to attract foreign investment into the electronics
industry, the government policies did not bring the desired results due to negative
attitude towards 100% foreign owned enterprises, and constraints in accessing the
domestic market. The situation in the semiconductor industry was quite different from
that described above, as foreign capital and investment were crucial for the
As a part of the plan to promote the domestic electronics industry, The Korea
under the patronage from the Ministry of Trade and Industry. The KEIC was created
industry as a whole, rather than with individual producers. (EIAK, 1989, 86-90)
10
Although big conglomerates at that time were not involved in the
in 1969 was an important occurrence for the long-term development of the industry.
Based on its early entry, Samsung managed first to capture the leading position in the
Korean semiconductor industry, and later, in the world market. Other companies
prevent the state's approval of Samsung's joint projects with Sanyo and NEC. They
were afraid that Samsung, already superior in many terms, would drive them out of
the domestic market. Responding to the efforts of existing firms, the government
(EIAK, 1981)
Samsung's entry into the electronics industry illustrates well the relationships
existing at that time between the state and private manufacturers. Under pressure
from the opposition, the government placed certain constraints on the company
11
The creation of the Korean semiconductor industry was initiated as a result of
state efforts to attract foreign investment, and due to the willingness of American and
to the enactment of the Foreign Capital Inducement Law in 1969. It should be noted,
firms, today.
only after the mid-70s, when Samsung absorbed Korea Semiconductor Inc. In general,
we could say that at this stage the state was reasonably successful in the promotion of
12
Due to the high levels of export dependency of the Korean economy, the
world economic downturn of the 1970s, the dismantling of Bretton Woods system, as
well as the announcement of the Nixon doctrine were quite detrimental. The first Oil
Shock of 1973 worsened the situation further. The policy of the United States
government to withdraw a portion of their troops from the Korea, as well as the
uncertainty brought about by the Nixon doctrine pushed the Korean government to
In the 1973 ‘State of the Nation Address’ heavy and chemical industry development
was announced by the Korean president as the new direction for economic
development.
The main principles embodied in the Heavy and Chemical Industrialization were stated as
follows:
scale
Taking into account its high export potential, the electronics industry was
selected for promotion under the heavy and chemical industrialization program. The
electronics industry during that period grew rapidly and was focused mainly on the
13
industry brought about an increase in demand for semiconductors. The majority of the
domestic demand for semiconductors at that time was met by the Japanese producers.
semiconductors from Japan. This situation was usually becoming more acute during
capital and technologies which were not easy to obtain. This fact created constraints
main objectives of the Korean government when promoting the electronics industry
under heavy and chemical industrialization plan. In 1975 the Economic Planning
sector. A six-year plan was prepared by the Ministry of Trade and Industry to promote
local production of six electronic components, including memory devices and silicon
wafers.
The economic boom of the 1970s began to decline in Korea from the mid
1980s. Taking into account the relatively low technological level of the
the acquisition of foreign technologies. It was extremely difficult to obtain such large
quantities of modern technology as foreign (and especially Japanese) firms were quite
14
much foreign investment as possible into the semiconductor industry, it did not allow
more than 50% equity share by the foreign firms, with the result that the level of
Samsung and Goldstar. Priority was placed on the promotion of the heavy and
the exports of electronics were growing, the government did not expend large
amounts of effort in promoting the semiconductor industry despite its original plan to
do so. A major portion of already limited resources were being channeled to the heavy
and chemical industries making further investments into the domestic electronics
upon enactment of the Electronics Industry Promotion Law, was not created until
developmental state shown in its very strong push for heavy and chemical
low. Unlike the Taiwanese state during the same period, the Korean state did not
facilities, though these were planned as part of heavy and chemical industrialization.
The entry of Samsung and Goldstar in the semiconductor business was a real
15
achieved in the semiconductor industry during the second phase was not only far from
the original plans but also not directly linked to the subsequent development in
(46.6% average annual growth rate during 1971-79) of the electronics industry was
electronics sector increased demand for semiconductors and led to the inducement of
large conglomerates such as Samsung and Goldstar into the semiconductor industry.
started to invest heavily in the semiconductor business, and thus, this period is
16
Starting from the end of the 1970s, the Korean economy was in recession and
its GNP growth declined to 2.5% per year from an average of 9.9% from 1962 to
1978. In 1980 the Korean economy growth rate of -4.9% was Korea’s first experience
of negative growth since 1962. Inflation rates increased to 26.4% in the same year.
Trade deficits rose from $1.8 billion in 1978 to $4.4 in 1979 (World Bank 1980). Part
of the reason for this decline in economic performance may be attributed to external
factors, such as the second Oil Shock in 1979, and rising international interest rates.
Internal factors included the political instability that concluded with the assassination
of President Park in October 1979, (Lee 1980, 63-67) and the tremendous over-
capacity of, and inflation caused by, the heavy and chemical industrialization. (KDI
Measures for Economic Stabilization (CMES) that differed greatly from the previous
import substitution;
3. a general reduction of state intervention and wider play for market forces;
219).
In May 1980, Major General Chun Doo-Whan seized the power in the
country by means of military coup and immediately set about reshuffling the heavy
17
and chemical industries. Those in charge of the creation of CMES continued their
work during the Fifth Republic (1981-87). This gave a new direction to the industrial
policies of the 1980s. Two main objectives were to be reached under the new
planning' was to replace active state intervention under these changing conditions.
The new direction of the government policy was also influenced by the
increasing pressure from the developed countries for liberalization of the Korean
market. In response to this pressure in the beginning of 1980s the Korean government
had to introduce new trade and finance liberalization programs. (Yoffie 1983; Odell
The Electronics Industry Law was amended in 1981 and a new, long-term
promotion plan for the Electronics Industry was announced by the Ministry of Trade
and Industry. Comparing to previous state devised plans, this plan was less
authoritarian in its tone and basically represented the government guideline for the
becoming quite successful. This fact had a great resonance within the Korean
government and private circles, as it was a clear sign of Korea’s future competitive
“A major difference between the policy measures adopted in this period and
the previous ones lies not in the content, but in the nature and process of developing
18
semiconductor policies. In sharp contrast to the promotion efforts up until the 1970s,
the programs in the 1980s were 'indicative' in nature, meaning that the state simply
drew the guidelines rather than actively pushing the policy targets specified in those
plans. In addition, most of these policies were demanded by the private sector rather
than directly initiated by the state. In many cases, the state simply endorsed the
One of the biggest differences between mid 1980s and the preceding period is
that in mid 1980s private businesses took the initiative both in terms of investment
and production. The role of the government in promoting the semiconductor industry
has declined to the degree where some private manufacturers called upon the
semiconductor mass production facilities. Between 1981 and 1982 Samsung created a
semiconductor research center. In 1982, the former Chairman Lee Byung-chull, and
the founder of the Samsung Group announced that Samsung’s future strategy will be
DRAM. First of all, DRAM is the most widely used semiconductor device and
consequently has the biggest market share. Secondly, DRAM requires relatively
simple technology allowing its mass production. At the end of 1983 Samsung
developed the 64K DRAM. This was a big technological advancement followed by
19
followed by a 64K SRAM in 1985, a 1M DRAM in 1986, a 256K SRAM in 1986, a 4
and a 256M DRAM in 1995. Although the initial technology for production of these
devices was borrowed from abroad we can clearly see that Samsung’s developments
Valley” in the United States with investment s totaling $1 billion. The main purpose of
such investments was the acquisition of modern technology, staff training and
investment was channeled to the production facilities rather than research and
development. For example, between 1982 and 1986, 53 technology transfer contracts
were signed, from which 48 were related to wafer fabrication. (Park et al. 1987, 281).
The United States provided 36 out of the total 53 (68%) transfers. Japan was the
20
In 1985 Korean semiconductor producers were severely affected by a volatile
character of the world semiconductor market. The demand and price of memory
“Samsung, however, continued its push for the more advanced memory chips
and accelerated the development of more sophisticated DRAMs, though it was the
most severely hit by the price drop. Goldstar took a moderate step, and focused its
production for in-house consumption and the long-term OEM production for Hitachi.
Hyundai had to close down its pilot production facility in Silicon Valley, but
automobile firm. Daewoo also had to scale down its semiconductor project drastically.
When the market recovered in 1986, Daewoo was far behind in the semiconductor
business and never came back to the leading position, Samsung, LG and Hyundai
continued their business, and by 1986, the combined sales of these firms accounted
for more than 90 per cent of Korean wafer fabrication” (Hong 1997, 103).
Nonetheless, during that period South Korea along with other East Asian
nations significantly improved its ranking following the regional pattern of rapid
Table 4.1 GNP per capita levels and country rankings (US$, current prices) 1962 and 1986
21
Rank a/ economies Rank/ Economies
amount Amount
Taiwan 85/ Zaire 38/ Greece
170 Congo, PR 3,580 Malta
South Korea 99/ Sudan 44/ Surinam
110 Mauritania 2.,372 Argentina
Hong Kong 40/ Spain 28/ Saudi Arabia
450 Malta 6,906 Israel
Singapore 38/ Greece 25/ New Zealand
490 Spain 7,411 Bahamas
Notes:
a- Ranking out of 129 countries
b- Comparable refers to countries immediately above and below the four dragons in
the World Bank Atlas listing.
Source: (Hobday M., 1995, p.15)
industry we will observe the following picture: only 20% of the investment was
financed by the industry itself before 1986. The remaining 80% came in the form of
loans from domestic and foreign financial markets. Foreign borrowing accounted for
almost 32% of investments made until 1986 (Park et al. 1987, 278). Consequently,
about 48% of the required investment was provided by the domestic financial market
where the state still played a dominant role. For example, some semiconductor R&D
related projects received funding under government sponsored programs for Special
Research Projects.
Summarizing the above, it could be said that after 1983 large conglomerates
have taken the initiative in expanding production as well as R&D related activities
directed development of the semiconductor industry in 1970s and private sector led
22
reinforcement of the sector is evident. During this period chaebol participated actively
in the strengthening of the semiconductor industry not due to the incentives offered by
the government, but because of the importance of the industry itself for the future of
these groups.
transition. Roh Tae-woo, a retired military general and a close friend of President
23
Chung became the next president of Korea representing Democratic Justice Party.
There was also growing pressure for democratization from different strata of society
including the labour unions, the opposition political parties, church and students. The
atmosphere was generally tense and further exacerbated by labour unrest and student
demonstrations.
Increasing demands from the United States for the liberalization of trade after
Starting from the mid 1980s, Korea opened its wine, tobacco and insurance markets
and made an effort toward liberalizing the banking sector. Under pressure from the
United States, Korea was also forced to appreciate its currency from W890 per dollar
in 1986, to about W720 in early 1991. The main reason for this appreciation was to
reduce bilateral trade deficits ($9.9 billion in 1988) between Korea and the United
States.
Korean exports in the world market. For example, the annual growth rate of
electronics exports decreased from 35.4% in 1988 to just 9.5% in 1989 (Hong 1997,
105).
During this period the chaebol gained more and more independence. The
state could no longer disregard private sector opinion “given the dominant economic
position of the chaebol, and taking into account that their performance was a crucial
24
Since 1988 there was an ever- increasing pressure for more equitable wealth
distribution. Huge profits earned by the chaebol were considered by a majority of the
public to be unfair. During that period government was frequently blamed for
manufacturers. Following Vernon’s product life cycle theory (Vernon 1966, 1971),
already had unpleasant experiences with the Japanese leapfrogging and were
Because of the increasing pressure from the United States, Korea had to
comply with the international norms for intellectual property right protection that
rights. The Uruguay Round and the resulting World Trade Organization (WTO) have
25
also increased restraints on the Korean government with regard to promoting
particular industries.
technology related policies has significantly increased during that time under the
pressure of the aforementioned constraints. At the same time, the state’s reduced
ability to promote the semiconductor industry was counterbalanced by the growth and
Despite of the fact that the private research capabilities were increasing
rapidly during 1980s, still most of the advanced technologies were purchased from
abroad. Before 1993 R&D investment from private sources was around 14% of total
revenues, and it decreased to less than 10% afterwards. This does not mean that R&D
spending has decreased, on the contrary, the absolute amount of investment by private
increase comparing to the previous year). Still this amount was smaller than of
Japanese Matsushita and Sony who spent US$2.3 billion and US$1.1 billion
Table 5.1 points out the smaller size of Korean electronics companies
larger comparing to the majority of European and US companies (except IBM). Even
26
during the global economic recession in 1992 were quite profitable, while many
Japanese, European and US companies suffered from heavy losses (Hobday 1995,
p.72).
Table 5.1 - Sales of Electronics by South Korean and Japanese conglomerates; 1991
and 1992 (trillion Won, US$ billions)
and marketing networks, planning and coordination departments of the chaebol were
able to efficiently gather information about the semiconductor market including future
market size, strategies of rival companies and related government policies in different
counties.
27
Despite of the fact that the Korean semiconductor manufacturers attained
unchanged. For instance, according to 1995 figures, the share of memory products in
total semiconductor production was around 91% and only the remaining 9% was
was exported, whereas, almost 70% of domestic semiconductor demand (mainly for
devices of relatively high sophistication) has been met by imports (see table 5.2 and
$million, %)
B/A (%) 81 82 78 76 69 68
Table 5.3 - Domestic Demands, Production, and Imports of Equipment and Materials,
(1990-95, $million)
Year 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
28
Equipment
Materials
various globalization policies. After 1993, the Korean government strongly pushed for
creating industrial alliances with foreign and especially the U.S. semiconductor
companies. One of the reasons for forming such alliances was to press jointly for the
achievements. As the United States were competitive in cutting the edge technology,
it was thought to combine this advantage with Korea’s manufacturing strength and
highly skilled labour force to counterbalance the structural weaknesses outlined above.
(Abramowitz, 1990) argues that a relatively low income economies may be able to
advance faster than the ones with high income levels since they have an opportunity
When we look at figures for Korea (see Annex 1), a number of differences are
29
obvious. Intensity of Korea’s R&D as well as the number of scientific and technical
articles per unit of GDP is quite low in comparison to other advanced nations. In
countries and the transfer and adoption of foreign technology still plays an important
role.
Summarizing the aforesaid, we could say that during this phase the private
sector has been the major driving force of the semiconductor industry in Korea. Smart
decisions taken by Korean private businessmen were the main factors in Korea’s
leapfrogging in the semiconductor industry. At the same time, it should be noted that
such decisions were supported by the government, which at that time was still in
30
6.1 The Economic Crisis of 1997
South Korea has transformed itself from the position of being one of the
world’s poorest countries at the end of WWII into the eleventh largest economy in the
synonymous with this economic expansion as it saw South Korea build a dominant
position in the memory market. But, in 1996, the collapse of prices within the world
DRAM market seemed to predict the imminent demise of Korea’s economic boom
years.
market shares of DRAM. According to 1995 and 1996 statistics, the three major
semiconductor production. Although the entire market share was less than that of
Japan, Korea was establishing its position in the market. From 1993 to 1995, the
DRAM market reached its climax with profitability being high. Under such
production capacity in an effort to increase their market share in this highly lucrative
and improvement of production process, toward the end of 1995, the supply of
DRAM came to exceed market demand. New production capacity was downscaled
capabilities and strove to win further market share of DRAM, since 1996, both
31
earnings and profits were decreasing continuously. Finally, under bitter market
Due to the expansion of its economy, South Korea has suffered from a
situation of chronic excess capacity, not only in the semiconductor industry but also in
automobiles and other products. Companies that could not make adequate returns on
investors lost confidence. Finally, the Won came under attack ending Korea’s years of
market boom.
Like Japan, South Korea’s banks became over-burdened with bad debts
during Korea’s rapid economic expansion and many of the bank’s assets were held in
the form of stocks or real estate rather than in hard currency. Nevertheless, there are
some significant differences between South Korea and Japan. Japan had very small
amount of foreign debt, especially in dollars. On the contrary, while Japan was
running large trade surpluses in years when the economy was booming, it was able to
amass significant holdings of foreign currency. In comparison with Japan, Korea had
a very large level of foreign debt and relatively low foreign capital reserves.
They differ greatly from the kind of merchant banks which may be found in the
whereas, the Korean “merchant” banks specialize in short-term loans. Many of these
from Korea’s illegal ‘curb’ money markets to legitimate banking institutions within
32
government control. Many of these “merchant” banks took on short-term loans from
favourable exchange rates. The problem occurred when the customers started to
default. The merchant banks had insufficient reserves to pay back their offshore loans.
At the same time, there was an unusual problem with credit checking, “cronyism” and
For several weeks during 1997, the South Korean government tried to survive
without requesting help from the IMF. But finally, in December, an agreement was
reached for $57 billion dollars of IMF loans to be paid to Korea. The won was
depreciated by 40.0% against the U.S. dollar, and Korea finally had to face the reality
of its situation. The IMF stand-by agreement included clauses that stipulated that the
government must let banks fail rather than bailing them out, and financial markets
public attention by the crisis included unbelievably high debt/equity ratios, massive
foreign borrowing and the lack of discipline within the financial sector.
“Since the typhoon of the International Monetary Fund hit the South Korean
Peninsula, the semiconductor industry in Korea has been among the most seriously
$13.5 billion, 5% lower than the same period in 1997” (H.Y. Kim, 1999).
Due to the terms and requests of the IMF stand-by agreement, the Korean
33
UK and LG Semiconductor postponed indefinitely a similar investment project in
Wales, UK.
delayed investment into a new facility for the development and production of 256 Mb
merger proved to be time consuming. In the meantime, at the end of 1998, Samsung
announced that it was going to complete its ninth fabrication facility for 64 Mb
DRAM by the first half of 1999. This would allow Samsung to keep its status of being
Semiconductor was taken at the end of 1998. According to U.S. consulting firm,
Arthur D. Little, Hyundai was given the controlling stake of the merger. As a result of
this merger Hyundai becomes the second largest company in the world DRAM
market. By means of this merge r, the Korean government and the industry authority
assert that up to $2.5 billion of duplicated investment on R&D, royalties and expenses
The financial crisis of 1997 caused the worst recession in Korea since the
postwar era and had a devastating impact on the economy of the country. Real GDP
fell from 5% to 10% before crisis to -5.8% in 1998. Unemployment increased from
34
pre-crisis levels of 2% to 6.8% in 1998 and 8.1% in March 1999. (Joon-Ho Hahm,
East and South-East Asia are revealing a striking ability to recover rapidly to the
will reach $18.2 billion, an 11% increase compared to 1998. (H.Y. Kim, 1999).
When the crisis started, foreign investors and businessmen working in East
Asia thought they were the unluckiest people on the planet. One day they benefited
from an economic miracle and the next they fell into a financial crisis, as capricious
foreign capital fled the currenc y and stock markets, for no obvious reason.
be returning to them and the capital is flooding back in. It seems now that affected by
the crisis economies of East and South-East Asia are capable of making rapid
recoveries. Next, probably, will come a gaggle of books and articles promulgating a
35
In South Korea, for instance, the recovery has been exceptional. Private
economists are forecasting 5 - 8% GDP growth this year. Thailand and Malaysia are
also rebounding quickly. Even Indonesia, which has experienced a 20% drop in GDP,
speed and magnitude has surprised even the optimists. Looking at the change in
sentiment in the stock markets we can see that over one year after the crisis those in
Thailand and Malaysia have almost doubled. The major indexes in Seoul and
Graph # 1) within the region. Now, export volumes are soaring. The even more
process itself shows us that a recovery of East Asian economies has actually started.
Graph 1.
25,000
20,000
Memory
15,000 Microcomponents
Digital Logic
10,000 Analog-Monolithic
Discrete
5,000 Optical
0
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
36
Asia/Pacific semiconductor consumption started gradual recovery during at
the end of 1998. It is expected to have positive growth in 1999 due to increased
increase by 14 percent in 1999 and total $35 billion. This follows a 4 percent decline
for 1998. Long-term regional revenue will grow at a 13 percent CAGR (Compounded
Annual Growth Rate) and reach $58 billion by 2003 (Graph 1).
products will achieve the highest regional growth rates. Communications equipment
will also contribute to the rapid Asia/Pacific semiconductor growth. This application
will support the demand growth for ASICs, DSPs, ASSPs, and analog ICs (Dataquest,
Spring 1999).
Graph 2.
100,000
80,000 Memory
Microcomponents
60,000
Digital Logic
40,000 Analog-Monolithic
Discrete
20,000
Optical
0
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
37
Dataquest forecasts that worldwide semiconductor revenue will grow by 12.6
percent in 1999, totaling $153 billion following a 7.5 percent reduction in 1998. By
2003 (Graph 2), worldwide semiconductor revenue is predicted to reach $244 billion,
which is a 12.4 percent compound annual growth rate for the five-year period 1998-
2003.
exceed 20 percent, due to continued weakness in DRAM pricing through at least the
first half of the year. While economic conditions in Japan continue to be inert, the
worst of the economic crisis in the Asia/Pacific region appears to have been overcome.
rate for 1999-2003, I feel it is pertinent to examine the semiconductor forecast for the
same time period including and excluding DRAM (see graph 3).
Graph 3.
45
40
35
30
25
+ DRAM
20 - DRAM
15 DRAM
10
5
1999
2000 0
2001
DRAM
2002 - DRAM
2003 + DRAM
38
This Graph provides a somewhat different forecast. It shows the worldwide
semiconductor market growth rates for 1998 through 2003 for total semiconductor,
DRAM). The graph shows a somewhat more stable and flattering long-term
semiconductor market growth rate prediction when DRAM are excluded. It also
highlights the more volatile growth rate forecasted for DRAM (Dataquest, Spring
1999).
organization, called the “World Semiconductor Council,” (WSC) announced its main
WSC stated that it “condemns dumping” and appealed to the governments undertake
effective anti-dumping measures in compliance with the rules and regulations of the
39
“The competitiveness of companies and their products, not the intervention of
and Energy the council will consist of representatives from Korea, the United States
the European Union, Japan and Taiwan. The meetings of the council will be held
annually with the aim to discuss the semiconductor related government policies in the
participating states.
measures aimed at opening up the Japanese market,” the ministry statement said. “But
the new system follows independent agreements made at the private sector levels
between the United States, Japan the European Union and Korea.”
The founding members of the WSC are the Electronic Industries Association
40
6.7 Korean Semiconductor Market, Revenue Forecast by Korean Semiconductor
The semiconductor industry in Korea has been seriously affected by the East
Asian Financial Crisis of 1997. Even prior to the crisis, the semiconductor industry
had been influenced by the price drop in the world memory market.
$13.5 billion, 5% lower than the same period in 1997. Nevertheless, the Korean
Semiconductor Industry Association (KSIA) forecasts that the total exports in 1999,
including those by assembly and packaging firms, will total around $18.2 billion, an
Due to the decline in the semiconductor industry and the fall-out from the
41
manufacturers in Korea in 1998 except the investment made by Samsung at the end of
the year.
value - added areas such as computer central processor units (CPU), application
products. With the expanded capacity, Samsung has projected sales of system LSI
chips will increase by at least 44% per annum, from $1.2 billion in 1999 to $1.8
billion in 2000, and further to $2.5 billion by 2001. At the same time Samsung plans
For the Korean semiconductor industry the future looks bright. WSTS
forecasts that the memory market in 1999 will expand by 13% to $14.6 billion, by
26% to $18.4 billion in 2000 and by 28% to $23.7 billion in 2001. The supply is going
Korean semiconductor and LCD manufacturers in the world market. According to the
Korea Information Society Development Institute (KISDI), the price rise in computer
42
parts is unavoidable due to interruptions in supply of Taiwanese semiconductors and
circuit boards. The price of DRAM was rising even before the earthquake with
Dataquest predicting a 0.4% oversupply. However, after the natural disaster in Taiwan
the world market is going to experience around 5% shortage of memory devices. The
price of TFT/LCD, one of the strategic products for Korean semiconductor producers
is also expected to rise due to the damage to Taiwanese production lines. It will be
discrete, and optical semiconductor suppliers and distributors reported raising demand
and relative price stability. Early second quarter Dataquest reports show raising
demand for the majority of semiconductor products. DRAM price reductions that
began in the second quarter caused an insignificant growth decline in the second
quarter of 1999. The aforementioned price reductions caused concern throughout the
semiconductor industry over revenue expectations for the second half of 1999.
growth in the third quarter of 1999 with a strong fourth quarter forecast. (Dataquest,
Spring 1999)
43
7. POSITIVE SIDES OF THE CRISIS AND IT’S LESSONS
Although in the short term Korea's economy was badly damaged, in the long
run, it will be able to recover, and build a more solid structure due to the following
reasons:
Another positive outcome of the IMF crisis is that most of Japanese DRAM
manufacturers have already decided to drop the production of memory devices, as U.S.
manufacturers did in the past due to low profitability and intensive competition
caused by the excess supply. There was an opinion that Korean DRAM manufacturers
will face the same problems within five years because of strong challenges from the
Taiwan semiconductor industry. However, due to the IMF, Korean manufacturers are
It could be said that the IMF provided the Korean semiconductor industry
with an opportunity to prolong the enjoyment of its leading position in the world
memory market.
44
In order to ensure healthy economic environment and stability of the Asian
economies the following lessons should be learned from the crisis of 1997:
will only further aggravate the existing problems. Government directed lending to
including semiconductors.
- Any new financing for industry must be commercially feasible and not
borrower. Companies that cannot operate in the free market environment must be
restructured or sold.
The accounting system used should be clear enough to allow effective monitoring of
45
8. CONCLUSION
of the Korean semiconductor industry has changed with time. The Korean
government which put a lot of efforts into the promotion of heavy and chemical
industrialization in the 1970s was not in a position to offer similar incentives during
the take-off of the domestic semiconductor industry in the beginning of 1980s. This
abroad. Because of these changes in business and political environment, private firms
the industry, the government and chaebol cooperated actively in elaborating and
We can say that the existing economic structure in Korea was not favourable
Korean industrialization that was focused on imitation rather than innovation. From
technologies. At the same time, it was overstressing the importance of the economies
of scale. In this regard we can recall Alice Amsden stating (Amsden 1989) that that
Starting from the 1970s, the Korean economical structure was very well suited to the
46
essential for innovation mechanism to start working. The institutional arrangements
that facilitated Korea’s rapid late industrialization based on foreign technologies are
innovator in the semiconductor industry. Although skeptics claimed that it lacked the
business, Samsung Electronics has, in only a decade, transformed itself from a mere
producer of discrete devices to the renowned leader in the world memory market.
environment. The strong authoritarian bureaucracy of the previous years has been
gradually loosing its power, while private businessmen have started to realize the
necessity to restructure their companies. Still and all, a switch from one system to
economic development. The strong fundamentals conducive to this rise were - export
skilled and educated labour force. One year later, in 1997, the uncompromising
financial crisis sweeping over entire Asia region has damaged the Korean economy
significantly.
47
“Tthe South Korean economy has been shaken to its very core and the ability
to recover to the prosperous levels of the past decades will require more structural
reform. With the rest of Asia recovering and with the re-emergence of the several key
reforms that will bolster the financial sector, improve corporate management
practices and further open the once closed economy to more foreign
Graph 5 shows South Korea’s GDP rates/forecast according to Cahners In- Stat Group
Graph 5
12.0%
10.0%
8.0%
6.0%
4.0%
2.0%
0.0%
-2.0%
-4.0%
-6.0%
-8.0%
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0
48
Many of East Asian countries consider the on-going recovery as a return to
the phenomenal growth rates they enjoyed in early 1990s (see annexes No.2 and
No.3). Eventually such speedy growth will be much harder to achieve now than it was
in the past. Asian economies are more developed now than they were in the beginning
of their developmental take-off. They will retain the advantages of youth for many
years yet, but growth will depend less on injecting more people and capital, and more
promised reforms, they will fail to lay the groundwork for more efficient use of
capital and for faster growth in productivity not only in the semiconductor industry
49
Annex I
Semiconductors
DRAMs
Memory Logic
Others
Microprocessor Application
Specific Devices
Representative End-Users
50
Annex II Income and Technological Performance in OECD countries, 19951
Country Income level, 1996 In
dicators of scientific and technological performance
GDP per head Gross Researchers Scientific Government Government Business Technological Technologic
Domestic al
of population Expenditure per 10,000 and technical financed R&D financing expenditure strength intensity,
as a % of OECD On R&D labour force articles as a % of of R&D on R&D as per US$ of 19954
GDP a% R&D
average as a % of GDP 1995 per unit 1995 as a % of total of business 19953
1995 of GDP R&D, 1995 GDP, 1995
19952
United States 140 2.6 74 20 0.9 34.6 2.1 410 10.4
Norway 128 1.7 73 21 0.8 43.5 1.4 .. ..
Switzerland 126 2.7 46 37 0.8 28.4 2.2 .. ..
Japan 121 2.8 83 15 0.6 20.9 2.2 354 10.6
Iceland 118 1.5 72 23 0.9 62.9 0.8 .. ..
Denmark 117 1.8 57 31 0.7 39.2 1.7 87 1.6
Canada 114 1.7 53 25 0.6 33.7 1.4 203 3.3
Belgium 112 1.6 53 20 0.5 26.4 1.4 111 1.8
Austria 111 1.5 34 18 0.8 47.6 1.1 125 1.9
Australia 107 1.6 64 24 0.8 47.5 0.9 .. ..
Germany 107 2.3 58 21 0.8 37 1.9 215 5.0
Netherlands 106 2.0 46 31 0.9 42.1 1.3 170 3.5
France 103 2.3 60 20 1.0 42.3 1.9 115 2.7
Italy 102 1.1 33 13 0.5 46.2 0.8 101 1.0
Sweden 100 3.6 68 41 1.0 33 3.9 147 5.3
United Kingdom 98 2.1 52 29 0.7 33.3 1.8 160 3.2
Finland 96 2.3 61 35 0.9 35.1 2.2 114 2.7
Ireland 92 1.4 59 16 0.3 22.6 1.4 69 1.0
New Zealand 88 1.0 35 29 0.6 52.3 0.3 .. ..
Spain 77 0.9 30 16 0.4 43.6 0.5 21 0.2
Korea 72 2.7 48 5 .. 19 2.3 25 0.7
Portugal 70 0.6 24 7 0.4 65.2 0.2 8 0.0
Greece 67 0.5 20 16 0.2 46.9 0.2 .. ..
Czech Republic 64 1.2 23 15 0.4 35.5 0.9 .. ..
Hungary 47 0.8 26 20 0.4 47.9 0.4 115 0.7
Mexico 36 0.3 6 2 0.2 66.2 0.1 15 0.0
Poland 35 0.7 29 17 .. 64.7 0.4 .. ..
Turkey 30 0.4 7 4 0.2 64.5 0.1 .. ..
1. Or latest available year.
2. Scientific and technological articles per billion of US$ of GDP. See National Science Foundation (1988).
3. Technological strength is determined by multiplying the number of patents with an index of their impact. This index measures how frequently a country’s recent patents are cited by all of a current year’s patents. The patents refer those
granted at the US Patent Office. Data are from CHI research.
4. Technology intensity compares the technological strength of a country with its GDP expressed in PPP$. See OECD, Science, Technology and Industry Outlook 1998 for details. Source: OECD calculations on the basis of the MSTI database.
CHI Research, National Science Foundation (1998), and OECD, Science, Technology and Industry Outlook 1998.
51
Annex III
Country/group 1960-69 1970-79 1980-88 1988 1991 1992 1993a 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
Four NIEs
Hong Kong 10.0 9.4 8.0 10.5 3.9 5.2 5.6 12.9 6.1 10.8 11.7 -4.8
South Korea 7.7 9.5 8.7 15.9 8.4 5.5 6.3 14.4 19.7 6.4 -8.7 9.5
Singapore 8.9 9.5 7.0 10.0 6.7 5.6 6.5 22.4 19.7 10.6 2.1 6.0
Taiwan 9.5 10.2 7.5 9.5 7.0 6.7 n/a 8.1 7.9 4.6 4.0 0.1
ASEAN-4
Indonesia 3.4 7.8 5.8 7.5 7.0 5.5 6.0 12.0 14.1 12.4 -5.3 3.0
Malaysia 6.5 8.1 5.3 6.6 8.6 8.5 8.0 14.1 19.2 13.8 -1.0 0.2
Philippines 3.0 6.3 1.6 6.4 0.0 3.3 1.5 18.5 15.6 12.2 -1.2 7.8
Thailand 8.3 7.4 5.6 7.1 7.9 7.5 7.8 15.2 16.7 7.7 -14.9 7.7
Other Asia
China 2.9 7.5 9.2 10.2 4.6 12.0 10.0 -8.7 30.0 17.3 10.1 -1.7
Developed
Canada 5.7 4.7 3.1 4.3 -0.2 0.3 2.8 -1.1 4.9 4.9 2.7 -1.6
Japan 10.9 5.2 5.3 5.1 3.1 0.9 2.4 9.7 9.6 -10.6 -8.7 14.8
United States 4.1 2.8 2.6 3.6 0.4 2.2 2.5 5.8 4.7 5.1 5.8 -3.7
a – official 1992 estimates
Updated from Michael Hobday, 1995, p.14. (Source for all economies 1994-1998 - APEC Secretariat Web-site: www.apecsec.org.sg/member/gdp.html)
52
Annex IV APEC Economies’ GDP figures (1989 – 1998)
Current Price GDP 1989 (a) 1990 (a) 1991 (a) 1992 (a) 1993 (b) 1994 (b) 1995 (b) 1996 (b) 1997 (b) 1998 (b)
(US$ billion)
Australia 292 296 283 300 285 327 353 395 394 394
Brunei Darussalam 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.7 4 4 5 5 5 5
Canada 575 574 561 564 553 547 574 602 618 608
Chile 29 30 32 35 44 51 65 69 77 77
China 356 370 399 452 599 547 711 834 918 902
Hong Kong, China 69 72 75 79 116 131 139 154 172 163.8
Indonesia 99 106 113 121 158 177 202 227 215 221.5
Japan 2817 2952 3079 3120 4275 4689 5137 4595 4193 4812.1
Korea 232 254 277 291 333 381 456 485 443 485.2
Malaysia 39 43 47 50 64 73 87 99 98 98.2
Mexico 234 244 253 260 403 421 286 329 403 348.6
New Zealand 44 44 43 43 44 51 60 66 65 59.5
Papua New Guinea 3 3 4 4 5 5 5 5 5 4.2
Peru n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 41 50 59 61 65 63.7
Philippines 43 44 44 44 54 64 74 83 82 88.4
Russian n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 173 279 348 434 450 394.9
Singapore 34 37 39 41 58 71 85 94 96 101.8
Chinese Taipei 153 161 173 183 223 241 260 272 283 283.4
Thailand 73 80 93 100 125 144 168 181 154 165.8
USA 5478 5522 5458 5637 6553 6936 7265 7636 8080 7783
Vietnam n.a. n.a. n.a n.a. 13 16 20 23 26 24
(a) figures are expressed in 1990 prices and exchange rates
(b) figures are expressed in 1997 prices and exchange rates
Source: The APEC Region Trade and Investment, http://www.apecsec.org.sg/member/gdp.html
53
References
Amsden Alice, (1989), “Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization.”
London: Oxford University Press
EIAK 1989, Thirty-year History of Korean Electronics Industry. Seoul. Korea: The
Electronic Industries Association of Korea.
Haggard, Stephan, and Chung-in Moon, (1990) “Institutions and Economic Policy:
Theory and a Korean Case Study.” World Politics 17, No.2: 210-37
Hobday Michael, (1995) “Innovation in East Asia, The Challenge to Japan”, Edward
Elgar Publishing Limited.
Hong Sung Gul, (1997), “The Political Economy of Industrial Policy in East Asia.”
Edward Elgar: Cheltenham - UK, Northampton, MA – USA.
Hong Sung Gul, (1988) “Korean Response Strategies to the U.S.:The Open and Fair
Trade Campaign.” Master’s Thesis, Iowa State University.
Kim Chang Soo, “Samsung Electronics Sets Annual System LSI Chip Sales at $2.5
Billion by 2001”, Dataquest Alert, Semiconductor Asia/Pacific, June 23 1999.
54
Kim Linsu, “The Dynamics of Samsung’s Technological Learning in Semiconductors,”
1997 by the Regents of the University of California, CMR, Volume 39, Number 3,
Spring 1997.
Korea Herald, (14/10/1999), “Taiwan earthquake good news for Korea’s chip, LCD
companies” by Kim Hoo-ran, Staff reporter.
Lee Chong- Sik, (1980) “South Korea 1979: Confrontation, Assassination, and
Transition.” Asian Survey 20 (January)
Lee Changrok, (1974), “The Reality of the Masan Free Export Zone.”
Odell John S. (1985) “The Outcomes of International Trade Conflicts: The US and South
Korea,” International Studies Quarterly 29.
Park Hee-chun, Seok-hee Kim, Tae-young Chu, Kook-hwi Kwak, and Tong –jin Yoon,
(1987) “The Current Status and Promotion Strategy of Korean Semiconductor
Industry, Seoul,” Korea Institute for Economics and Technology.
Soh Changrok. September (1997) “From Investment to Innovation? The Korean Political
Economy and Changes in Industrial Competitiveness,” International Trade and
Business Institute, Korea (ITBI)
Woo Jung-en, (1991), “Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialization”,
New York. Columbia University Press.
World Bank, (1980) “Korea: Current Developments and Policy Issues,” Washington DC:
World Bank, Report #3005-KO
Yoffie David, (1983) “Power and Protectionism: Strategies of the Newly Industrializing
Countries,” New York: Columbia University Press.
Yoon Jeong-ro (1989) “The State and Private Capital in Korea: The Political Economy of
the Semiconductor Industry, 1965-1987,” Ph.D Dissertation, Harvard University.
55
List of Acronyms
56