Historians & Economic Life Study
Historians & Economic Life Study
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/41300054?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Wesleyan University, Wiley are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to History and Theory
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
History and Theory, Theme Issue 49 (December 2010), 146-166 © Wesleyan University 2010 ISSN: 0018-2656
A STRANGE CAREER:
THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE
ABSTRACT
This article attempts to account for professional historians' relative neglect of the history
of economic life over the past thirty years, looking mainly at the American case. This ne-
glect seems paradoxical, considering the remarkable transformations that have taken place
in world capitalism during this same period. I trace the neglect to the capture of the once
interdisciplinary field of economic history by mathematically inclined economists and to
the roughly simultaneous turn of historians from social to cultural history. I conclude by
suggesting some topics in the history of economic life that seem both timely and exciting.
I also suggest some intellectual resources that other disciplines, particularly economic so-
ciology and economic history, could offer should historians decide to tackle the history of
economic life once again.
Keywords: economic life, economic history, social history, cultural history, economic soci-
ology, macro-dynamics of capitalism.
I do not believe it is possible to make useful predictions about the next fifty years
of historical scholarship. Instead, I attempt something far more modest: to identify
an area of inquiry that I feel has been neglected by historians in recent decades-
the study of economic life- but that I expect to figure much more centrally in
historical scholarship over the next decade or two. I try to assess the historical
causes of this neglect, which I regard as highly paradoxical, and to suggest how
it might be overcome. The history of economic life- by which I simply mean the
history of human participation in the production, exchange, and consumption of
goods- has, in my opinion, had a strange and unfortunate career in the United
States over the decades since the end of World War II.
Economic life was initially studied primarily by economic history- a new, ro-
bust, and promisingly interdisciplinary field in the middle years of the twentieth
century. The emergence of economic history as a distinct field of study was marked
by the appearance of specialized journals: the Economic History Review in Britain
in 1927; the Annates d'histoire economique et sociale in France in 1929; and the
Journal of Economic History in the United States in 1941 . In the postwar decades,
economic history thrived in America in both history and economics departments.
But over the course of the 1970s and 1980s, the field came to be increasingly dom-
inated by economists. This development was over-determined: on the one hand,
mathematically inclined economic historians, based in economics departments,
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 47
developed new and intellectually powerful methods (dubbed "the new economic
history") that proved intimidating to most history-based economic historians, who
normally lacked the mathematical training either to use or to criticize them effec-
tively. Meanwhile, over the same years, social historians, who in the 1960s and
1970s had been deeply interested in economic aspects of social change, and who
were close allies of economic historians in an effort to develop more quantitative
and social-scientific forms of historical inquiry, increasingly turned to the new
cultural history in the 1980s and in the process lost interest in both quantifica-
tion and the economy. Indeed, cultural history was marked by an intense reaction
against economic determinism, against quantification, and against the positivist
epistemological outlook that had previously united social and economic histori-
ans. The result has been the development of an economic history almost entirely
dominated by the concerns of professional economists and a shrinking-back of
work on the history of economic life carried out by historians.
This has, in my opinion, left the history profession in an increasingly untenable
position. Precisely in the years since 1980, when globalization, deindustrializa-
tion, repeated financial crises, and soaring economic inequality should have made
obvious the need for a deeper historical understanding of modern capitalism's
dynamism and perversity, historians have largely abandoned the historical study
of economic life while economists turned economic history into a branch of math-
ematical development economics. My goal in this article is to understand how
this situation came about and to make some suggestions about how it might be
remedied.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
148 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 49
5. Robert T. Patterson, "Government Finance on the Eve of the Civil War," JEH 12 (1952), 30-44.
6. Marc Bloch, "Classification et choix des faits en histoire Economique: Reflexions de methode a
propos de quelques ouvrages recents," Annates d' histoire economique et sociale 1 (1929), 257.
7. See, among other works, Bloch, French Rural History: An Essay on Its Basic Characteristics,
foreword by Bryce Lyon, transl. Janet Sondheimer (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1926),
and Feudal Society, transl. L. A. Manyon (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1961).
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1 50 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 5 1
tory's contributions. "The common thread running through the New Economic
History" they said in this article, "is a commitment to the efficacy of theory in
specifying useful counterfactuals, and to quantitative methods in implementing
them." The implementation of counterfactual propositions and their comparison
to the actual facts required the generation of masses of new data. As Fishlow and
Fogel made clear, "The data categories- national income, capital stock, etc." are
inventions of the modern economist, not the concerns of past government of-
ficials, and are therefore not readily available in printed sources. The categories
of data being sought are defined by economic theory, by "economic models of
production and income determination," like those pioneered by Simon Kuznets.
As Fishlow and Fogel put it, "because such data are not directly available, it is
necessary to resort to the art of synthetic reconstruction." This synthetic recon-
struction "is in itself based upon application of theoretical relationships to limited
information."15 In other words, by mathematically manipulating the equations
used in preparing contemporary national income accounts, cliometricians were
able to generate estimates of key unstated quantities. Although such theoretically
specified quantities (for example, productivity or net capital expenditure) cannot
be measured directly, algebraic manipulation of the appropriate mathematical for-
mulae reveal what sorts of existing data (for example, figures on prices, imports
and exports, rents, insurance rates, or the quantities of different types of goods
produced) can be plugged into the equations to generate valid estimates of the
theoretically specified quantities. The procedures, in short, are based on multiple
levels of mathematical abstraction. Neither the independent nor the dependent
variables, nor, for that matter, the questions being asked about them, would exist
without specification by economic and econometric theory and by the mathemati-
cal equations and the statistical estimation techniques of modern economics.
In their joint article, Fishlow and Fogel were quite explicit about how the new
economic history was transforming the field.
Two principal factors have shaped the directions, and thereby the contributions, of the New
Economic History. The first has been an unabashedly developmental interest. Cliometri-
cians have been concerned with rates of growth rather than levels, with economic aggre-
gates rather than persons, and with production rather than distribution. This has meant an
inevitable shift of focus from earlier writing in which the description of the institutional
structure was the central objective, and in which much attention was bestowed upon distri-
butional problems reflected in the farmers' discontent, the rise of unions, business concen-
tration and government regulation. A parallel list of topics covered by the new economic
historians would read agricultural productivity, investment in human capital, industrial sup-
ply and demand responses, and government promotion of social overhead investment.16
This account makes it clear that the new economic history had a much more ab-
stract epistemological object than the old economic history: not persons, institu-
tions, and social movements, but growth rates, economic aggregates, productivity,
and investment. This was, precisely, a move from economic history as the study
15. Albert Fishlow and Robert W. Fogel, "Quantitative Economic History: An Interim Evaluation
of Past Trends and Present Tendencies," JEH 32 (1971), 15-42.
16. Ibid., 18.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
152 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
Table 1:
Percent of Articles in the Journal of Economic History
containing Different Methodological Apparatuses
Let us follow convention and take the publication of Fogel's and Fishlow's
books as marking the beginning point of the new economic history as a scholarly
movement. Table 1 shows that already in the mid-1960s, when these books had
just been released, research practices in the field had changed markedly since
the early 1950s. Fully three-quarters of the articles in the JEH volumes of 1965
and 1966, as against only a third in the early 1950s, used some form of quan-
titative methodological apparatus, mostly statistical tables of some description.
Thus, even before the new economic history movement got its name, economic
historians had already begun to adopt more rigorous quantitative techniques. In
1970-1971, the percentage of articles using some quantitative apparatus was ac-
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 53
tually no higher than it had been a half-decade earlier. But on closer inspection the
change over that half-decade was profound. In the mid-1960s only one article in
ten contained a mathematical equation; by the early 1970s, fully half did. It is the
use of mathematical notation that most clearly indicates acceptance of the schol-
arly norms of the new economic history. Any diligent historian could arrange her
or his findings into a tabular form, but using equations indicates a working knowl-
edge of modern, mathematically based economic theory that only rare working
historians could have mustered. To include equations in an article was a badge of
membership in the new intellectual regime.17
I read Table 1 as indicating that the new economic history was well entrenched
in the journal and the association as early as the beginning of the 1970s. The
figures for the mid-1970s show that this position was yet further strengthened. Al-
though the proportion of articles using mathematics had remained constant, only
one article in seven now lacked quantitative apparatus, and the proportions using
both statistical graphs and theoretical diagrams rose. By 2008, which I include to
indicate the shape of the field in the present, only one of the twenty-nine articles
lacked quantitative apparatus altogether, sixty-two percent used mathematics,
ninety percent used statistical tables, and three quarters- a big increase- used
graphs.18 If we take this as the portrait of a field entirely won over to economic
history as a branch of economics, we can see that most of the way had already
been traveled as early as 1970 and 1971 . It is therefore understandable that nearly
all the distinguished economic historians trained after the early 1970s were edu-
cated and made their careers in economics departments. Economic history was
by then well on its way to becoming the study of economic growth in the past by
means of methods developed and employed in economics departments.
It is indisputable that the triumph of the new economic history increased the rig-
or and intellectual power of the field of economic history. Although this increase
in power was based on mathematical abstraction from the concrete experience of
economic life in the past, economic historians were by no means uninterested in
collecting empirical data. Quite the contrary, they greatly expanded the collection
of data, often exploiting new and unsuspected sources of quantifiable evidence
with tremendous ingenuity and assiduity. But the questions they were interested
in answering ceased to be primarily about forms of economic life. Although one
might study the cotton textile industry or railroads, what was important to eco-
nomic historians about such topics was not, for example, how work experiences
or clothing fashions were changed by the advent of mechanized cotton produc-
tion, or how the development of street railroads enabled new forms of urban life,
but rather what effects technological change, rising capital investment, decreased
turnover time, and labor productivity in the cotton or railroad industry had on the
growth of GDP per capita.
17. One could, of course, be a card-carrying econometrician and not include an equation in one's
article. Neither Kuznets in his 1952 J EH article nor Fogel in his 1962 JEH article included equations,
but this was probably so as not to intimidate their expected readers, which, in those years, would have
included historians.
18. My guess is that the increase in the use of graphs is a consequence of the development of digital
graphing software, which makes high-quality diagrams much easier to prepare.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1 54 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
It is important to recognize that there was both gain and loss in the transition to
the new economic history. But initially the gains were much more obvious than
the losses. This was largely because history as a whole was being transformed in
the 1960s and 1970s by the rise of what was called "the new social history" and by
the application of quantitative techniques to many fields of historical study. The
new economic history may have been unique in its extensive use of mathematics,
but in these years it was very common for historians to borrow both theory and
methods from a whole range of quantitative social sciences- especially sociol-
ogy, political science, demography, and geography- in addition to economics.
This tendency is nicely illustrated by the foundation of the Social Science His-
tory Association, which held its first annual meeting and began publishing its
journal, Social Science History , in 1976. According to the editors' foreword in the
journal's first issue, the SSHA was to bring together "historians seeking a more
rigorous and consciously theoretical orientation" and "social scientists interested
in longitudinal analysis." The journal would publish "research that attempts gen-
eralizations of some breadth verified by systematic examination of the relevant
evidence and supported by quantitative analysis when appropriate."19 Although
the SSHA carefully avoided language that might exclude historians using meth-
ods other than quantification or adhering to non-positivist epistemologies, this
statement of purpose made clear the founders' commitment to the Hempelian pro-
gram we have already encountered among the new economic historians.20
Within this vibrant and growing community of interdisciplinary historians and
social scientists, the study of economic life actually figured quite prominently,
even though economic historians had turned almost entirely to the question of
economic growth. Most of this work on economic life was actually carried out
by scholars who identified themselves as social historians. A major priority of the
new social historians was to trace out the effects of economic change on society;
studies of the social effects of industrialization were particularly prominent. But
even social histories of pre-industrial societies- of peasants, lords, merchants,
artisans, religious congregations, cities, regions, or professional groups- nearly
always paid close attention to the economic forces and economic experiences that
social historians typically saw as underlying the social structures, social institu-
tions, or social movements they were studying. Indeed, in the 1960s and 1970s,
social historians themselves carried out the sort of research that once would have
been published in economic history journals- about guild structures, food prices,
business practices, wage patterns, or technological innovations- often supplying
far more extensive quantitative evidence on these issues than would have been
typical in articles in the JEH in the 1940s or 1950s.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 155
One reason for this close attention to economic life was a widespread assump-
tion that economic structures and changes determined other aspects of social life.
One certainly didn't have to be a Marxist in the 1960s and 1970s to be an eco-
nomic determinist. Few social historians would have disagreed with the British
Marxist historian Eric Hobsbawm in 1971 when he attempted to sketch a "com-
mon working model" for social historical research:
One starts with the material and historical environment, goes on to the forces and tech-
niques of production (demography coming somewhere in between), the structure of the
consequent economy- divisions of labor, exchange, accumulation, distribution of the sur-
plus and so forth- and the social relations arising from these. These might be followed by
the institutions and the image of society and its functioning which underlie them. . . . The
practice is thus to work outwards and upwards from the process of social production in its
specific setting.21
This statement aptly sketches the working assumptions not only of the British
Marxist historians but also of French social historians of the Annales School or of
American new social historians. As long as there was a consensus that one should
work "outwards and upwards" from forces and relations of production to politics,
thought, and social institutions, social historians could be counted on to engage in
serious study of economic life.
But this interest in economic life faded out in the 1980s and 1990s as social
21. E. J. Hobsbawm, "From Social History to the History of Society," Daedalus 100 (1971), 31.
22. Lynn Hunt, The New Cultural History (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989).
23. William H. Sewell, Jr., Logics of History: Social Theory and Social Transformation (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 2005), chap. 2. For another recent account, see Geoff Eley, A Crooked
Line: From Cultural History to the History of Society (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press,
2005).
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1 56 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
24. 1 believe that the value of cultural history of the economy was eff
such early works as Garreth Stedman Jones, Languages of Class: Studie
History, 1832-1982 (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press,
The Rise of Market Culture: The Textile Trade and French Society , 1
Cambridge University Press, 1984); and my own Work and Revolution
Labor from the Old Regime to 1848 (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Unive
25. For a splendid discussion of this transformation, see E. J. Hobsawm
History of the World, 1914-1991 (New York: Penguin Books, 1994).
26. This declining interest in the history of economic life was by no
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 57
phenomenon. In France the famous Annales: Economies, Societes, Civilisations changed its title to
Annales: Histoire, Sciences Sociales in 1994. A quick counting exercise seems to indicate that drop
ping of the word economie was indicative of a change in the contents of the journal. In 1975, th
Annales published fifty-three articles, of which thirty-nine, or 74%, concerned some aspect of eco-
nomic life. In 2004, only four of the thirty-six articles, or 11%, were on aspects of economic life.
27. Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation [1944] (New York: Octagon Books, 1975).
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1 58 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 59
in the 1970s. In the ensuing years, important economic theorists and econometri-
cians, including a number of Nobel laureates, have, for example, explored the role
of human capital formation, of nutrition and health, and of a variety of institutions
in fostering economic growth.31
The influence of the economics of institutions is a particularly telling case. Oli-
ver Williamson and Douglass North, who were major figures in the development
of contemporary institutional economics, were both concerned- one might even
say obsessed- to work out how institutions such as private property rights, capital
markets, contract law, insurance, or the corporate form of enterprise increased
economic efficiency by lowering transaction costs. But the analytical framework
they developed could also be applied to explain why institutions failed to develop
efficient forms- otherwise, how could one explain the differences between ef-
ficiency-enhancing and efficiency-blocking institutions? The analytical apparatus
of institutional economics therefore gave economic historians certified theoreti-
cal and methodological tools that they could use to study the history of institu-
tions of all kinds- and they have proceeded to do so.32 Meanwhile Gary Becker's
theory of family consumption and labor-allocation decisions was not focused on
the contribution of family organization to rates of economic growth; his goal was
to expand the economist's approach to decision making to human organizations
of all sorts.33 At the same time, new means of gauging the nutritional status of past
populations gave economists surprising insights into the history of human well-
being.34 And economic theories about human capital formation made it possible
for innovative studies of the history of education, and for clever attempts to esti-
mate premodern numeracy, to count as legitimate pieces of economic research.35
31. To mention only the work of Nobel laureates, on human capital, see Gary S. Becker, Human
Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Emphasis on Education (New York:
Columbia University Press, 1975). On nutrition, see Robert William Fogel, The Escape from Hunger
and Premature Death, 1700-2100 (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2004). On the
economics of institutions, see the pioneering article by Ronald Coase, "The Problem of Social
Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3 (1960), 1-44; Douglass North, Structure and Change in
Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), and Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic
Performance (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Oliver Williamson, Markets and
Hierarchies, Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study of the Economics of Internal Organization
(New York: New York University Press, 1975); and, for a different style of institutional economics,
Gary S. Becker, A Treatise on the Family (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1981).
32. Thus one finds in recent numbers of the JEH studies of peonage on haciendas, of the dynam-
ics of convict migration to the American colonies from Britain, or of Louis XIV' s use of corporate
bodies to finance royal debts, all of which are more concerned to set forth the logics of the institu-
tions than to gauge their contributions to economic growth. Lee J. Alston, Shannan Mattiace, and
Tomas Nonnemacher, "Coercion, Culture, and Contracts: Labor and Debt on Henequen Haciendas in
Yucatan, Mexico, 1870-1915," JEH 69 (2009), 104-137; Farley Grub, "The Transatlantic Market for
Convict Labor," JEH 60 (2000), 94-122; Mark Potter, "Good Offices: Intermediation by Corporate
Bodies in Early Modern French Public Finance," JEH 60 (2000), 599-626.
33. For a fascinating application of Becker's household allocation equations, see Joel Mokyr,
"Why 'More Work for Mother?' Knowledge and Household Behavior, 1870-1945," JEH 60 (1960),
1-41.
34. Trevan D. Logan, "The Transformation of Hunger: The Demand for Calories Past and Present,"
JEH 69 (2009), 388-408; Alexander Moradi, "Towards an Objective Account of Nutrition and Health
in Colonial Kenya: A Study of Stature in African Army Recruits and Civilians, 1880-1980," JEH
69 (2009), 719-754.
35. Christiana Stoddard, "Why Did Education Become Publicly Funded? Evidence from the
Nineteenth-Century Growth of Public Primary Schooling in the United States," JEH 69 (2009),
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1 60 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
Consumption
In the last few decades modern consumption regimes have spread all over the
world and consumption has become the chief driver of U.S. economic perfor-
mance. The issue of consumption is actually one of the few economic topics that
has been adequately studied by historians over the past few decades. In part this
is because consumption has long been a flagrantly obvious feature of modern
life, at least in America. Consumption has been studied more by historians than
other flagrantly obvious facts of economic life (for instance, the dominance of
contemporary societies by business corporations or finance) because consumption
is a profoundly symbolic and expressive form of behavior that lends itself easily
to the research agendas of cultural history. Some of the best recent work attempts
not only to read consumption as a text or to indicate its political valences but also
to show how changing consumption patterns reacted back onto production and
onto the larger structures of the economy. Maxine Berg demonstrates that the flow
of Asian commodities into early modern Britain, especially Indian calicoes and
Chinese and Japanese porcelains, not only was instrumental in the burgeoning
of new forms of consumption, but stimulated British entrepreneurs to produce
domestically manufactured substitute goods, including Manchester calicoes and
Staffordshire pottery, which eventually dwarfed the original Asian items in eco-
nomic significance.36 Jan de Vries has recently published a book that creatively
combines the "new home economics" of Gary Becker with studies of the chang-
ing culture of consumption and with quantitative studies of personal possessions
(based on inventories after death) in early modern Britain, France, Holland, and
America. He argues that consumption was a central component of what he calls
an "industrious revolution" in the long eighteenth century- a new ordering of the
family economy in which both rural and urban labor (especially that of women
172-201; Brian A'Hearn, Jorg Baten, and Dorothee Crayen, "Quantifying Quantitative Literacy: Age
Heaping and the History of Human Capital," J EH 69 (2009), 783-808.
36. Maxine Berg, From Imitation to Invention: Creating Commodities in Eighteenth-Century
Britain," Economic History Review 45 (2002), 1-30; Berg, Luxury and Pleasure in Eighteenth
Century Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005).
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 6 1
and children) was applied more intensively to the production of goods for sale in
the market in order to maximize income for the purchase of other market-supplied
goods, such as textiles, crockery, furniture, clocks, and tableware. He argues that
this largely voluntary increase of labor intensity was a crucial factor in stimulating
economic growth in the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries. The de Vries
book is particularly notable for using the tools of modern professional economic
history- with its equations, diagrams, and statistical tables- in such a way that
they illuminate changing forms of economic life.37
Globalization
The Environment
37. Jan de Vries, The Industrious Revolution: Consumer Behavior and the Household Economy,
1650 to the Present (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2008).
38. Two recent books that do this for the Indian case are Manu Goswami, Producing India: From
Political Economy to National Space (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2004), and Andrew
Sartori, Bengal in Global Concept History: Culturalism in the Age of Capital (Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 2008).
39. See, for example, Sanjay Subrahmanyam, Improvising Empire: Portuguese Trade and Settle-
ment in the Bay of Bengal, 1500-1700 (Delhi and New York: Oxford University Press, 1990); R. Bin
Wong, China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience (Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press, 1997); Kenneth Pomerantz, The Great Divergence: China, Europe , and the
Making of the Modern World Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000),
40. Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System, 3 vols. (New York: Academic Press,
1974-1989); Janet Abu Lughod, Before European History: The Modern World System, 1250-1350
(New York: Oxford University Press, 1989); Andr£ Gunder-Frank, Reorient: Global Economy in the
Asian Age (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998).
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
162 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 63
The recent financialization of the American economy since the late 1970s is but
one aspect of a thoroughgoing, neoliberal transformation of the world capitalist
economy over the past three decades- one I have sketched out briefly above.
The neoliberal turn reversed the tendencies of a long period of increasing state
involvement in the management of the economy, one that reached back as far
as World War I and that was consolidated in the advanced industrial economies
after World War II with the development of Keynesian welfare states. Hobsbawm
has labeled this period of managed capitalism stretching from the late 1940s to
the early 1970s a "Golden Age" because it witnessed the most rapid sustained
economic growth in the history of world capitalism and because it ushered ordi-
nary European, North American, and Japanese citizens into an era of high wages,
relative material equality, economic security, high mass consumption, and seem-
ingly endless material progress 49 In retrospect, it seems clear that a form of world
capitalism that had brought great prosperity for a quarter of a century went into a
47. The first of these is by Erika Vause, the second by Mark Loeffler, and the third by Jonathan Ira
Levy. Two of these projects have resulted in publications: Jonathan Ira Levy, "Contemplating Deliv-
ery: Futures Trading and the Problem of Commodity Exchange in the United States, 1875-1905,"
American Historical Review 111 (2006), 307-335; and Mark Loeffler, "Das 'Finanzkapital' zur
Jahrhundertwende. Der Diskurs in Deutschland und England," forthcoming in Kapitalismusdebatten
um 1900: Zur sozialdkonomischen Semantik des Jiidischen , ed. Nicolas Berg (Leipzig: Universitats-
verlag, 2010).
48. Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambndge, MA: Harvard Univer-
sity Press, 1990); Greta Krippner, "The Financialization of the American Economy," Socio- Economic
Review 3 (2005), 173-208; Giovanni Arrighi, The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the
Origins of Our Times (London: Verso, 1994).
49. Eric Hobsbawm, The Age of Extremes: A History of the World, 1914-1991 (New York:
Pantheon, 1994).
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
164 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
This way of putting the issue rests on assumptions that are certainly not shared
by all who work on the history of economic life. Most basically, it assumes that
50. Bob Jessup, "Towards a Schumpeterian Workfare State? Preliminary Remarks on Post-Fordist
Political Economy," Studies in Political Economy 40 (1993), 7-40.
51. Joseph Stiglitz, Globalization and Its Discontents (New York: W. W. Norton, 2002).
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
A STRANGE CAREER: THE HISTORICAL STUDY OF ECONOMIC LIFE 1 65
52. See, especially, Wallerstein, Modern World-System ; Arrighi, Long Twentieth Century and
Adam Smith in Beijing: The Lineages of the Twenty-First Century (London: Verso, 2007); and
Giovanni Arrighi and Beverly J. Silver, Chaos and Governance in the Modern World System (Min-
neapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1999).
53. The form of capitalism characteristic of the "Golden Age" was dubbed "Fordist" by neo-Marx-
ist economists of the French "regulationist" school whose analyses of the then-dying form were pub-
lished between the late 1970s and mid-1980s. See Michel Aglietta, A Theory of Capitalist Regulation:
The US Experience (London: New Left Books, 1979); Robert Boyer, La theorie de la regulation: Une
analyse critique (Paris: La Decouverte 1986); and Alain Lipietz, Mirages and Miracles: The Crisis in
Global Fordism , transl. David Macey (London: Verso, 1987). See also David Harvey, The Condition
of Postmodernity: An Inquiry into the Origins of Cultural Change (Oxford: Blackwell, 1989) and
A Brief History of Neoliberalism (New York: Oxford University Press, 2005); Bob Jessop, Beyond
the Regulation Approach: Putting Capitalist Economies in their Place (Cheltenham, UK: Edward
Elgar, 2006); Fredric Jameson, Postmodernism , or, the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism (Durham,
NC: Duke University Press, 1991); Robert Brenner, The Boom and the Bubble: The US in the World
Economy (London: Verso, 2002) and The Economics of Global Turbulence: The Advanced Capital-
ist Economies from Long Boom to Long Downturn, 1945-2005 (London: Verso, 2006). It is notable
that although the questions pursued by all these authors are eminently historical, only Brenner is a
historian by training.
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1 66 WILLIAM H. SEWELL, JR.
University of Chicago
This content downloaded from 193.61.13.36 on Wed, 07 Nov 2018 19:45:07 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms