0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views50 pages

Pension Risk Retirement Saving and Insurance

The document analyzes how individuals perceive the risk associated with their future pension benefits in Italy. It finds that perceived pension risk varies substantially across individuals and is related to factors like time to retirement and income risk as implied by the pension system. Higher perceived pension risk leads individuals to increase retirement savings through pension funds and life insurance, as well as purchase more health and casualty insurance, suggesting people take actions to buffer against pension risk.

Uploaded by

Daesu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views50 pages

Pension Risk Retirement Saving and Insurance

The document analyzes how individuals perceive the risk associated with their future pension benefits in Italy. It finds that perceived pension risk varies substantially across individuals and is related to factors like time to retirement and income risk as implied by the pension system. Higher perceived pension risk leads individuals to increase retirement savings through pension funds and life insurance, as well as purchase more health and casualty insurance, suggesting people take actions to buffer against pension risk.

Uploaded by

Daesu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 50

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/255585411

Pension Risk, Retirement Saving and Insurance

Article · January 2009

CITATIONS READS

11 876

3 authors, including:

Luigi Guiso Tullio Jappelli


Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance University of Naples Federico II
225 PUBLICATIONS   22,911 CITATIONS    184 PUBLICATIONS   14,920 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Tullio Jappelli on 25 June 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

EUI Working Papers


ECO 2009/18
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

PENSION RISK, RETIREMENT SAVING AND INSURANCE

Luigi Guiso, Tullio Jappelli and Mario Padula


EUROPEAN UNIVERSITY INSTITUTE, FLORENCE
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Pension Risk, Retirement Saving and Insurance

LUIGI GUISO, TULLIO JAPPELLI


and
MARIO PADULA

EUI Working Paper ECO 2009/18


This text may be downloaded for personal research purposes only. Any additional reproduction for
other purposes, whether in hard copy or electronically, requires the consent of the author(s), editor(s).
If cited or quoted, reference should be made to the full name of the author(s), editor(s), the title, the
working paper or other series, the year, and the publisher.

The author(s)/editor(s) should inform the Economics Department of the EUI if the paper is to be
published elsewhere, and should also assume responsibility for any consequent obligation(s).

ISSN 1725-6704

© 2009 Luigi Guiso, Tullio Jappelli and Mario Padula


Printed in Italy
European University Institute
Badia Fiesolana
I – 50014 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI)
Italy
www.eui.eu
cadmus.eui.eu
Pension Risk, Retirement Saving and Insurance

Luigi Guiso
European University Institute, EIEF and CEPR

Tullio Jappelli
University of Naples “Federico II”, CSEF and CEPR

Mario Padula
University of Venice “Ca’ Foscari and CSEF

14 April 2009

Abstract

Using a representative sample of Italian investors, we estimate the risk associated with
pension benefits by eliciting for each individual the subjective distribution of the
replacement rate as a summary indicator of social security wealth. We find substantial
heterogeneity of pension risk and show that it is consistently related to observable
features in the pension system that have different effects on individuals with different
characteristics. We then relate subjective pension risk to individuals’ financial decisions.
We find that people try to attenuate the adverse consequences of pension wealth
uncertainty by increasing demand for targeted retirement saving and for insurance.
Individuals facing more pension wealth risk tend to enroll more often in private pension
funds, invest more in life insurance and buy more private health insurance. These effects
are consistent with people becoming more risk-averse when pension wealth becomes less
predictable, leading them to search for greater financial security.

Keywords: Pension Risk, Retirement Saving, Insurance


JEL Classification: H55, E21

Acknowledgments. We are grateful to Michael Hurd and participants in the 2008


Fundación Ramón Areces Conference on Population Ageing and its Economic
Consequences (Madrid, November 20-21 2008) for helpful comments and suggestions; to
the UniCredit Group, and particularly Daniele Fano and Laura Marzorati, for allowing us
contribute to the design of the UniCredit Customer Survey.

1
1. Introduction

As a reflection of the still incomplete process of pension reform and of the nature of
the reforms adopted, there is a widespread belief that for the citizens of most
industrialized countries, pension entitlements have become much more uncertain than in
the past. It is fair to say that even an informed worker would find it difficult to estimate
her pension benefits at retirement. The long-term nature of pension arrangements makes it
all the more difficult to predict what the eventual pension will be and particularly for the
young. Their longer time horizons mean that young people are more subject to two
fundamental sources of pension uncertainty that occur particularly in countries such as
Italy, where future benefits are closely linked to contributions.
The first source of uncertainty in Italy is based on the reforms already undertaken,
which have resulted in lower public pension coverage, and also, and by design, in greater
benefit uncertainty: future pensions will reflect idiosyncratic income risk during a
working life, future fluctuations in aggregate GDP growth, and population-wide survival
rates. The second source of uncertainty lies in the reforms that have still to be introduced,
because the reform process is incomplete. Being unable to predict pension benefits can be
of first order importance to consumer welfare, particularly where perceptions of the true
uncertainty are biased, and not sufficient action is taken to buffer against risk. Thus,
understanding how much uncertainty is perceived, whether what is perceived is consistent
with the reality, and whether an individual should respond to this uncertainty are of
primary relevance.
In this paper we investigate each of these three aspects. We rely on the 2006
UniCredit Customer Survey (UCS), which covers a random sample of customers of
UniCredit, one of the largest banks in Europe. The survey asks for detailed information
on income, assets and demographic variables and, quite uniquely, elicits the subjective
probability distribution of the replacement rate for each individual in the sample. We rely
on the subjective distributions to quantify the amount of uncertainty about future pensions
that working-age individuals perceive. We find substantial heterogeneity in the expected
replacement rate, which ranges from as low as 20 percent to ratios as high as full

2
coverage, with an average of 67 percent. Furthermore, expectations are held with
significant uncertainty: the average standard deviation of the subjective replacement rate
is 20 percent, with considerable differences across sample participants.
Though we cannot check whether the perceived level of uncertainty is close to the
actual level of uncertainty that individuals face, we show that subjective uncertainty
varies across individuals in ways that are consistent with what we might expect a priori,
due to observable heterogeneity in information sets and in the way that people with
different characteristics are affected by current pension schemes. For example, we find
that individuals a long way from retirement and who thus face more career uncertainty
report more subjective pension risk and that people with higher labor income risk are
more uncertain about pension benefits. These features are implied by the design of the
new pension system in Italy, and reassure us that people are likely to be aware of the risks
they face, a necessary condition for them to be able to caution properly against them.
Prudent individuals should have strong incentives to adjust their savings and
financial decisions in order to caution against the risk of having to curtail consumption
after retirement. Intuitively, people who perceive greater pension risk should increase
retirement saving to buffer against the additional source of risk. Hence, we investigate
whether pension risk leads individuals to revise their demand for retirement savings (life
insurance and pension funds) and increases the propensity to insure against other risks (in
particular, health and casualty risks).
We find that the propensity to enroll in a private pension fund and to invest in life
insurance are negatively associated with the expected replacement rate (a 10 percentage
point increase in the replacement rate reduces the demand for private pension funds by 2
percentage points) and positively associated with the perceived riskiness of social security
benefits (a 1 point increase in the standard deviation is associated with a 3 percentage
point increase in pension fund ownership). We also find that the propensity to enroll in
health insurance plans is higher for those who perceive greater pension risk. Overall, our
results lend support to models of investor behavior in which background uncertainty (as
measured by pension risk) affects portfolio and insurance decisions (Kimball, 1992;
Gollier and Pratt, 1996).

3
This is not the first study to measure subjective pension risk. Manski (2004) and
Dominitz and Manski (2006) used telephone surveys to measure probabilistic beliefs
about pension benefits, while Delavande and Rohwedder (2008) relied on an Internet
survey to elicit the subjective probability distributions of pension benefits. Despite their
different survey techniques, these authors also find substantial heterogeneity in expected
benefits and large uncertainty. However, unlike in our case, they do not have information
on consumers’ financial decisions and thus were unable to study whether and how they
respond to pension risk.
Our paper also has ties to a more traditional and large literature on the relation
between pension wealth and the accumulation of private wealth, pioneered by Feldstein
(1974) and Feldstein and Pellechio (1979), who studied the displacement effect of
pension wealth on national saving using US time series and microeconomic data. Since
then, researchers have used individual level data to estimate the displacement effect in the
US and other countries imputing pension wealth from legislation, see Gale (1998) and
Attanasio and Rohwedder (2003). The evidence suggests that pension wealth crowds out
private savings, but by far less than one to one.1 In contrast to studies that impute social
security wealth based on legislation or that rely on point expectations, we study the
portfolio effects of higher moments of future pension wealth, based on information on the
respondent-specific probability distributions of replacement rates.
Our paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the pension rules in Italy and
clarifies the sources of uncertainty about social security benefits. Section 3 presents data
on the respondent-specific subjective distributions of replacement rates and provides
descriptive evidence on the extent of heterogeneity in respondents’ beliefs about pension
entitlements. In Section 4 we test whether people facing higher pension risk (as measured

1
Other related research looks at how pension wealth affects the retirement and labor participation decisions
of the elderly, and simulates the effects of policy reforms (Gruber and Wise, 1999, 2004). Using Italian
survey data, Attanasio and Brugiavini (2003) estimate the displacement effect exploiting changes in pension
wealth across cohorts and employment groups induced by the 1992-95 Italian pension reforms. Bottazzi,
Jappelli and Padula (2006) study the impact of Italian pension reforms relying on an estimate of pension
wealth based on expected retirement age and expected replacement rate, rather than computations based on
legislation.

4
by the standard deviation of the respondent social security risk) show increased demand
for private pension funds, life insurance and health insurance. Section 5 concludes.

2. Pension risk in the current regime

Until the early 1990s, the Italian social security system had high replacement rates
(first pension benefit to last income ratio), earnings-based benefits, indexation of pensions
to real earnings and cost of living, generous provision for early retirement, and a large
range of social pensions (i.e., old-age income assistance). This resulted in the ratio of
pension benefits to GNP reaching almost 16 percent in 1992, the highest value among the
industrialized countries.
The high pension benefits burden on the state budget prompted several reforms,
implemented between 1992 and 2008. The main features of these reforms were increase
to the retirement age and to the minimum years of contributions for pension eligibility,
abolition of seniority pensions for all those starting to work after 1995, and a new formula
to compute benefits.2
As of 2009, benefits and eligibility vary according to number of years of
contributions at end 1995. A defined benefit formula applies to those with 18 years or
more of contributions in 1995: we term this formula the “earnings model” and the
workers to whom it applies as the “old”. A notionally defined “contribution model”
applies to those who entered the labor market after 1995 (the “young”), while benefits for
those who had less than 18 years of contributions in 1995 (the “middle-aged”) are
computed according to a “pro-rata” model. The upper panel in Table 1 summarizes the
pension award formulas. For the old, pension benefits are proportional to the average of
the last 10 years salary (15 for the self-employed), with an accrual rate of 2 percent for
each year of contribution. For the young, benefits are linked to lifetime contributions,
capitalized at retirement on the basis of a 5-year moving average of GDP growth, and

2
Seniority pensions were de-facto re-introduced in 2004 for everyone, including those who started working
after 1995.

5
then transformed in flow benefits using an annuitization factor based on retirement age
and life expectancy:3

γτ ∑ t =0 wt (1 + g ) N −1−t
N −1
(1)

where w is gross individual earnings, N is retirement age, τ is the contribution rate, g a 5-


year moving average of the GDP growth rate and γ the annuitization factor. Since τ=0.33
for private and public employees, and 0.20 for the self-employed, the latter will receive
substantially lower pensions than the former. The pro-rata regime applies to the middle-
aged. For them pensions are earnings-related for working years before 1995, and
contributions-related after 1995. Thus, there is considerable heterogeneity in the current
regime: more generous provisions for workers closer to retirement, and different
contribution rates for employed (private and public) and self-employed people.
Also, pension eligibility depends on the pension regime. In the earnings and pro-
rata regimes, for retirement in 2008-09 retirement age is 60 years (61 for self-employed),
with a minimum working career of 35 years of contributions. For those who will retire in
2010-2013, retirement age is 61 (62 for self-employed), increasing to 62 (63 for self-
employed) for those retiring in 2014 or later. In the contribution regime pension eligibility
is either 40 years of contribution, or 65 years of age (60 for females), as shown in the
lower panel of Table 1. Thus future pension benefits of Italian workers depend on a wide
set of variables, including year of birth, occupation and the earnings profile. To forecast
pension benefits workers must also take account of population aging (reflected in the
annuitization factor) and future growth, both of which are likely to prompt further
reforms.
In this paper we focus on the replacement rate, defined as the ratio of the first
pension payment to the last salary payment, as a synthetic indicator of pension wealth.
Even without considering possible changes in future legislation, forecasting one’s pension
is not an easy task because future benefits depend on the timing and volatility of earnings.
To illustrate this effect, we assume that log-earnings have a deterministic component
3
Currently, γ increases from 4.720 percent for somebody retiring at 57 to 6.136 percent for somebody
retiring at 65.

6
growing at the constant 2 percent rate, and that, in each period, earnings are hit by
permanent and transitory shocks. The Appendix shows that under these assumptions the
first two moments of the replacement rate depend on the standard deviation of permanent
(σv) and transitory (σu) income shocks. We use the income process to simulate a
benchmark “true” pension risk over the life-cycle, measured by the coefficient of
variation of the replacement rate distribution. We then compare simulated pension risk
with the risk that people perceive over the life cycle as measured in our survey.
We start with the contribution method and simulate the replacement rate
distribution using equation (1). To isolate the role of earnings risk, we assume that the
average GDP growth rate is 1.5 percent per year, the annuitization factor γ is 0.0551
(under the current rules, this is the annuitization factor for those retiring at age 62), and
the standard deviation of transitory and permanent income shocks is 1 percent. Under
these assumptions the expected replacement rate is 61.7 percent for an employee (τ=0.33)
and 37.4 percent for a self-employed individual (τ=0.20).
Figure 1 plots the coefficient of variation of the replacement rate distribution
against age. Pension risk is about four times higher for someone just entering the labor
market (at age 25) than for someone retiring after 37 years at age 62. Doubling the
standard deviation of permanent income shocks (σv=0.02) doubles the pension risk (see
the dashed line in Figure 1).4
Uncertainty about future GDP growth and demographic developments (as reflected
in the γ factor) are two further sources of pension risk. Their effects are documented in
Figure 2, which displays three lines: the continuous line refers to the baseline case, the
dashed line assumes that the growth rate of GDP is uncertain and uniformly distributed
between 1 and 2 percent, and the dotted line assumes that the annuitization factor is
uncertain and uniformly distributed between 5 and 6 percent. The figure shows that
pension risk increases by about 3 percentage points at each age when aggregate GDP
growth is uncertain; the effect of demographic risk is quantitatively similar in each case.

4
The Appendix shows that the coefficient of variation of the replacement rate 1 year before retirement is
almost equal to the standard deviation of permanent income shocks.

7
Pension risk also depends on the pension regime. Figure 3 compares regimes for a
private employee. If pensions are proportional based on the last 10 years of earnings,
pension risk is much lower, especially at the young end: the coefficient of variation is
constant at 1.4 percent until age 52 (10 years before retirement), and then falls gradually
to less then 1 percent just before retirement. Not surprisingly, in the pro-rata regime, risk
is at values between the earnings model and the contribution model.
In summary, our simulations show that pension risk is higher for young workers
and workers with riskier earnings, such as the self-employed. Also, in the new
contribution-based regime, demographic risk and aggregate income uncertainty raise
pension risk. To check whether people actually perceive the pension risk implied by the
current legislation, in Section 3 we use subjective expectations of replacement rates to
construct individual replacement rate distributions. Since the pension risk that individuals
should perceive is not directly observable, because it depends on unobservable aggregate
uncertainty (including political risk related to future reforms), we cannot check whether
the level of perceived pension risk is consistent with the actual risk individuals face.
However, we can check whether observable differences in perceived pension risk vary in
a way that is consistent with what is implied by the simulations discussed above.

3. The subjective probability distribution of the replacement rate

Several surveys attempt to measure the subjective expectations of Social Security


benefits. For the US, Bernheim analyzes the accuracy of pre-retirement expectations
concerning social security benefits in the Retirement History Survey, and Gustman and
Steinmeier (1999, 2005) study point expectations of the level of future benefits available
in the Health and Retirement Study. Disney and Tanner (1999) and Bottazzi, Jappelli and
Padula (2006) analyze point expectations of the replacement rate respectively for the UK
and Italy. Of course, point expectations do not provide information about pension
uncertainty.

8
Dominitz and Manski (2006) go a step further; based on information from the
Survey of Economic Expectations (SEE), they provide information about the probabilistic
expectations of social security retirement benefits. SEE was a telephone survey, addressed
to individuals aged between 18–69 who were first asked to report the lowest possible and
highest possible levels of their future benefits. Their responses were used to set thresholds
for up to six probabilistic questions about the level of benefits. The subjective
probabilities elicited from respondents were used to fit a respondent-specific parametric
distribution following the procedure described in Manski (2004). Since the SEE asks only
for basic demographic information (age, gender, education), and does not inquire about
portfolio choice, it is not possible to relate pension subjective probabilities to outcomes
such as portfolio choice or the demand for insurance.5
Delavande and Rohwedder (2008) measured the distribution of the level of future
pension benefits via an Internet survey of respondents to the Health and Retirement Study
which is representative of the US population aged 51 and over. They obtained a
distribution of pension benefits using the Dominitz and Manski percent chance format
and a visual representation of future benefits.6 Both formats generate a similar central
tendency, but the percent chance format generates a more widely dispersed distribution.
Furthermore, the dispersion of the elicited distribution is correlated to other sources of
uncertainty (such as years to expected claiming age and subjective probability of losing
one’s job in the next year), in the expected direction for both designs. Overall, their
findings suggest that the main advantage of the visual over the percent chance format is
that it minimizes the loss of observations due to inconsistencies.7
In line with British and Italian evidence, we focus on the subjective replacement rate
as an indicator of social security wealth, rather than on the level of future pension
benefits. Therefore, we cannot compare subjective pension uncertainty using previous US
evidence. For instance, workers might be uncertain about their future level of benefits, but
much less uncertain about their replacement rate. For example, consider a public
5
As the SEE is based on telephone interviews the variables are potentially subject to higher measurement
error than would be the case with face to face interviews.
6
Respondents are asked to allocate a total of 20 balls across 7 bins to represent what they believe are the
chances of their future Social Security benefits falling into any one of these categories.
7
In the percent chance format about 20 percent of responses are lost due to inconsistencies.

9
employee at the time when benefits were proportional to income received in the last year
of paid work. Since income in the last year is uncertain, she might be uncertain about the
level of benefit, although she knows the replacement rate with certainty.
In our paper we use subjective expectations available from the 2006 UniCredit
Survey (UCS), a national representative sample of the eligible population of UniCredit
Group customers. The sample design is similar to that used by the Bank of Italy Survey of
Household Income and Wealth (SHIW). The interviews were conducted between May
and September 2007 by a leading poll agency using Computer Assisted Personal
Interviews. The total sample size is 1,686 customers; the replacement rate questions were
addressed to 1,024 working individuals (employees and self-employed). The Appendix
includes further details on the survey, and compare sample statistics with the 2006 SHIW.
In the rest of this section we describe our elicitation method, the central tendency and
dispersion of subjective distributions, and the correlations between pension uncertainty
and the variables affecting income uncertainty.

3.1. Elicitation method

To elicit pension expectations in the UCS we follow a similar procedure to


Dominitz and Manski (2006). All employees and self-employed (1,024 observations) are
first asked to report the minimum (ym) and maximum (yM) values of the future
replacement rate and then to rank on a scale from 0 to 100 the probability that the
replacement rate will be less than the mid-point between the minimum and the maximum,
Prob(y ≤ (ym+ yM)/2) = π. The wording of the questions is reported in the Appendix.
To estimate the moments of the subjective distributions of the replacement rate, we
assume the subjective distribution is either uniform or triangular. Based on the range of
the distribution and on the subjective probability elicited, we can compute the respondent-
specific mean, standard deviation and coefficient of variation. The formulae for these
statistics are reported in the Appendix.
We set to missing observations for which ym, yM or π are missing, and for which
respondents provide inconsistent answers (ym≥yM). Therefore the usable answers to

10
estimate the subjective distribution are 72.7 percent of the eligible sample (1,024
employees). This is higher than the 66 percent value in Dominitz and Manski (2006), but
lower than the 97 percent of usable answers in Delavande and Rohwedder (2008).
Whether these differences are due to sample characteristics, elicitation method or survey
design (telephone, Internet or face to face interviews) is beyond the scope of this paper.

3.2. Descriptive statistics

Table 2 reports cross-sectional statistics of the central tendency and dispersion of


the subjective replacement rate distribution. The average expected replacement rate for
the sample is 66 percent (for both the uniform and triangular distributions), close to the
statutory rate for an average individual in the sample (the median is 70 percent).8
Although there is substantial heterogeneity in expected replacement rates (the coefficient
of variation is 29 percent), expectations on average are in line with legislation. The
dispersion of the subjective replacement rate depends on the assumptions made about the
distribution. Assuming that the distribution is uniform, the average of the respondent-
specific coefficient of variation is 5.08 percent (3.64 percent using the triangular
distribution). The median coefficients of variation are slightly lower (3.85 and 2.73
percent, respectively).
While cross-sectional averages are useful to describe the subjective distribution of
the average individual, they hide important differences across individuals. Figure 4 plots
the cross-sectional distribution of the mean and coefficient of variation of the 744
respondent-specific distributions. The figure highlights considerably heterogeneity in the
responses. For instance, 10 percent of respondents expect a replacement rate of less than
40 percent, while another 10 percent expect it to be over 85 percent. In terms of perceived
risk, for almost 5 percent of respondents the coefficient of variation is close to 1 percent,
while for 9.6 percent it exceeds 10 percent. The next step in the analysis is to show
whether pension expectations are related to individual characteristics. We are particularly

8
Bottazzi, Jappelli and Padula (2006) provide details on computation of the statutory rate, and a comparison
of statutory and point expectations of the replacement rates in the SHIW.

11
interested in checking whether subjective probabilities correlate with characteristics (such
as cohort and occupation) that are predicted to influence pension uncertainty based on
some of the features of the current pension regime.

3.3. Determinants of subjective probabilities

Figure 5 presents kernel-smoothed means of the average and coefficient of variation


of the respondent-specific replacement rate distributions, by education and age. In this
figure and the rest of the paper we focus on the triangular distributions (by construction,
the uniform distribution is more dispersed, but the results are qualitatively similar). The
graphs in Figure 5 show that the expected replacement rate increases with age (upper-left
panel), but is not strongly correlated to education (bottom-left panel). In particular, 35-
years old workers expect a replacement rate of 63 percent, while workers close to
retirement expect a replacement rate of 70 percent or higher. As explained in Section 2, a
positive relation between age and expected replacement rate mirrors the features of the
current pension legislation, which grants more generous pensions to workers close to
retirement.
The dispersion of the replacement rate distribution declines substantially during the
life-cycle, signaling that younger workers perceive substantially more risk than workers
close to retirement: in the upper-right panel the coefficient of variation is 4.5 percent for
30-year olds and about 3 percent for workers over 60. The lower-right panel shows that
workers with lower levels of education face substantially higher pension risk than
workers with a high-school or a college degree, reflecting the higher income risk related
to blue-collar jobs.
To investigate these relations in more depth, in Figure 6 we present kernel-
smoothed 0.25, 0.50, and 0.75-quantile regressions of the subjective central tendency and
dispersion of the subjective distributions by age and education groups. Figure 6 shows
that pension risk is substantial among young persons for each quantile (upper-right panel),
confirming the evidence in Dominitz and Manski (2006). Even middle-aged workers tend
to be rather uncertain about their future pension entitlements. That this uncertainty about

12
benefits should decrease with age, is in line with the simulations in Section 2 as well as
the intuition, because income risk and uncertainty about the future structure of social
security should decrease with approaching retirement.
Figure 7 explores the relation between subjective expectations and occupation, by
plotting the mean and coefficient of variation of the respondent-specific distributions by
occupation and income deciles. We find that expected replacement rates do not vary with
income (upper-left panel), while the relation between income and the coefficient of
variation is non-linear (upper-right panel): uncertainty is greatest at the lowest and highest
ends of the income distribution. Furthermore, professionals and the self-employed, who
will receive lower pensions because of their lower contribution rates, do indeed expect
their pensions to be lower (lower-left panel). They also perceive greater pension risk;
given the pension award formula, this is in line with the fact that they also face higher
income risk, as shown by the simulations in Figure 3.

3.4. Regressions analysis

Table 3 presents the measures of the central tendency and dispersion of the
respondent-specific distributions of the replacement rate in relation to demographic
characteristics (age, gender, education), occupation (dummies for private employees and
self-employed), region of residence and income. Other variables (e.g. sector of
occupation) are excluded from the regression because the coefficients were not
statistically different from zero.
The estimates in column 1 confirm that older workers expect a higher replacement
rate than younger workers, owing to the more generous pension award formula (linked to
average wages in the 10 or 15 years before retirement rather then contributions over the
entire career). Private sector employees expect a replacement rate that is 4 percent lower
than the reference omitted category (public employees), while the self-employed expect a
replacement rate of 11.5 points lower. Residents in the Centre of Italy expect a higher
replacement rate than individuals living in the North (the coefficient is 6.2), and in the
South (8 points higher).

13
In addition to formal education (measured by years of schooling), financial literacy
might affect the ability to process financial information and perceive risk. Column 2 of
Table 3 includes in the set of regressors an index of financial literacy computed from
survey responses. We computed this index by defining two dummy variables equal to 1 if
respondents answered questions on interest rates and inflation correctly,9 four dummies
that measure the ability to rank asset riskiness correctly,10 and two dummies related to
ability to understand financial diversification and rank the risks among specific
portfolios.11 The index ranges from 0 (no questions answered correctly) to 8 (all correct
answers), with a median of 3. Column 2 shows that people with above average financial
literacy tend to expect a lower replacement rate. However, the coefficients are not
statistically different from zero.
In columns 3 and 4 of Table 3 the dependent variable is the standard deviation of the
respondent-specific subjective distribution of the replacement rate. Pension benefits are
more uncertain for the self-employed than for employees, consistent with their greater
income volatility and different pension regime. Perceived pension risk falls with age, in
line with the descriptive analysis and the finding of Dominitz and Manski (2006). The age
coefficient captures several effects: first and most importantly, lifetime income risk is
higher for younger workers; second, pension regimes differ according to age - earnings-
related for older workers and contribution-based for younger ones; third, in the
contribution regime benefits depend on a broader range of variables, including GDP
growth expectations and demographic risk, which are likely to vary with age. Moreover,
as discussed in Section 2, the contribution method potentially amplifies the effect of
income uncertainty on pension risk. Finally, individuals presumably have a stronger
9
The interest rate question is: Suppose that in the next 6 months interest rates will increase. Do you think it
is a good idea to buy fixed interest rate bonds today? The inflation question is: Suppose that a savings
account earns an interest rate of 2 percent per year (net of costs). If the annual inflation rate is 2 percent,
after two years (with no withdrawals), do you think that you could buy more than you could buy today / less
/ the same / don’t know?
10
We consider whether the respondents’ rankings of asset categories satisfy each of the following
inequalities: (a) bonds are at least as risky as transaction accounts; (b) stocks are at least as risky as bonds;
(c) equity mutual funds are at least as risky as bond mutual funds; (d) housing is riskier than transaction
accounts.
11
The list of portfolios is: 70 percent invested in T-bills and 30 percent in a European equity fund; 70
percent in T-bills, 15 percent in a European equity fund, and 15 percent in 2-3 stocks; 70 percent in T-bills
and 30 percent in 2-3 stocks; 70 percent in T-bills and 30 percent in a stock I know well.

14
incentive to learn about benefits as retirement approaches, reducing perceived
uncertainty.
The standard deviation of the replacement rate distribution is positively associated
with the index of financial literacy: increasing the index by 1 raises the pension risk by
0.8 percentage points, about 5 percent of the sample mean. This finding suggests that
more financially informed investors may also be more aware that pensions are risky.
For robustness, in columns 5 and 6 of Table 3 we report regressions where the
dependent variable is the coefficient of variation of the replacement rate distribution. The
results confirm that perceived pension risk is greater for the self-employed, and smaller
nearer to retirement. In this case the coefficients of education, financial literacy and
region of residence are not statistically different from zero.
Table 3, therefore, shows that there is substantial predictable heterogeneity in the
subjective distributions of the replacement rate, and that the effects of observable
variables, such as age and occupation, are consistent with how the distribution of pension
benefits is reflected in people’s expectations. Next we investigate whether individuals
react to perceived pension risk, by looking at how it affects the demand for retirement
saving and insurance.

4. The demand for retirement saving

People who expect a lower replacement rate could supplement their public pension
by increasing retirement saving. This link relates to the offset between social security and
private wealth, which has received much attention since the seminal work of Feldstein
(1974). Our data on subjective probabilities allow us to focus on a related but unexplored
question: does pension risk increase the demand for retirement saving above any effect
that expected replacement rates may have? Following the standard arguments, we would
expect participation in private pension funds and life insurance – the two main vehicles
for retirement saving – to be negatively associated with the expected replacement rate;
however, under the assumption that individuals dislike risk and become more risk averse

15
when pension risk increases, we also expect demand for private pension funds and life
insurance to be positively associated with the riskiness of social security, as measured by
the standard deviations of the subjective distributions. Importantly, our data allow us to
distinguish between these two channels.12
Previous evidence on life insurance and pension funds refers mostly to the
effectiveness of tax incentives for saving. Since the mid 1980s, Italian legislators have
tried to encourage investment in private pension funds and life insurance through tax
incentives. Preferential fiscal treatment of life insurance contributions was introduced in
1986, and later extended to pension fund contributions. More recent policy interventions
have been directed at shifting contributions from severance payments funds to individual
and occupational pension plans.13 Whether these measures have been effective in
increasing savings is an open question, although the evidence in Jappelli and Pistaferri
(2003) suggests that fiscal incentives have not induced large reallocations of household
portfolios. Here, we investigate a different issue, e.g. whether pension expectations affect
the demand for discretionary retirement saving.

4.1. Descriptive analysis

Figure 8 plots the fraction of individuals with private pension funds and life
insurance, against the expected replacement rate (Figure 8 also includes health and
casualty insurance, which are discussed in Section 5). The upper-left graph shows a
negative relation between pension funds ownership and the replacement rate: people who
expect relatively low coverage from their public pension (the expected rate is less than 70
percent) exhibit a greater propensity to invest in private pension funds (about 25 percent).
Among those who expect high coverage, pension fund ownership is only 10 percent. For
life insurance the relation is essentially flat (upper-right panel).
The upper-left panel in Figure 9 shows that among those who perceive public
pensions as being relatively safe (a coefficient of variation of 2 percent or less)
12
Since wealth amounts are subject to considerable measurement error, in this section we focus on the
decision to enroll in a retirement saving plan.
13
Since 2007 workers can choose to redirect contributions to severance pay to private pension funds.

16
participation in pension funds is considerably lower (15 percent) than among those who
perceive higher risk (participation of at least 20 percent for those with coefficient of
variation greater than 6 percent). There is also a positive relation between life insurance
ownership and pension risk (upper-right graph).

4.2. Regression analysis

We focus first on the demand for retirement saving, and relate the probability of
ownership of private pension funds and life insurance to the central tendency and
dispersion of the replacement rate distribution. The probit regressions in Table 4 control
for demographic variables (age, gender, education), employment type, region of
residence, income and, in some specifications, indicators of financial literacy and risk
aversion.14 Table 4 reports the marginal effects and associated standard errors.
The coefficient of the expected replacement rate is negative, while the coefficient
of the standard deviation pension risk is positive; both coefficients are sizable and
statistically different from zero. A 10-percentage point increase in the expected
replacement rate reduces the probability of owning a pension fund by 2 percentage points,
while a one standard deviation increase in the cross-sectional distribution of subjective
standard deviations is associated with a 3-point increase in ownership. Thus, variation in
uncertainty is economically at least as important as variation in expected replacement,
which is the focus in the literature.
Ownership probability is negatively related to age, is lower in the South, and
increases with income. The remaining columns in Table 4 show that pension fund
ownership is positively associated with financial literacy, and that people who are more
risk averse invest less in pension funds. The last column in Table 4 also controls for

14
The dummy is based on the following question: “In managing your financial investment, you think you
are a person that is interested in investments that offer the possibility of: (1) a high return, with a high risk
of losing the capital; (2) a good return, and reasonable safety; (3) a moderate return, but at the same time a
good degree of safety; (4) a low return, without any risk of losing the capital.” The risk aversion dummy is
defined as (3) or (4).

17
expected retirement age and standard deviation of the distribution of retirement age.15 The
magnitude and significance of the coefficients of the expected replacement rate and of the
standard deviation of the replacement rate are not affected.
Table 5 presents the propensity to own a life insurance policy. We find that life
insurance ownership is highest among the young and people in more risky occupations.
The coefficient of the standard deviation of the replacement rate distribution is positive in
all specifications, but statistically different from zero only in the first two columns.

5. The demand for health and casualty insurance

Individuals who expect pensions to be risky presumably will tend to protect


themselves from other sources of risk. Here, we focus on the demand for health and
casualty insurance, and test the hypothesis that the propensity to insure against these risks
is negatively related to pension risk, as measured by the standard deviation of the
replacement rate distribution.
The data in Figures 8 and 9 lend some support to the hypothesis that pension
expectations affect the demand for insurance. Figure 8 (lower panels) shows a negative
relation between health or casualty insurance and the expected replacement rate. Figure 9
shows that the proportion of individuals with health insurance is less than 15 percent for
those who perceive relatively low pension risk, and over 20 percent for those who
perceive above average pension risk.
The probit regressions reported in Table 6 confirm a negative association between
the expected replacement rate and the propensity to have health insurance. The effect of
the standard deviation of the replacement rate is positive and statistically different from
zero, suggesting that pension risk induces people to insure against health risk. We also
find that the demand for health insurance is higher for the young, and positively

15
Interviewees were asked to provide minimum and maximum values for expected retirement age, and
indicate the probability that it would be greater than the mid-point of the range. We apply the same
procedure used for replacement rates to estimate the respondent-specific subjective distributions for
retirement age.

18
associated with education, income and self-employment. Controlling for financial
literacy, risk aversion and the respondent-specific expectation and standard deviation of
retirement age does not change the results.
Finally, Table 7 reports the regressions for casualty insurance. Some of the
patterns are similar to those for health insurance: education, self-employment and income
are positively associated with the probability of having casualty insurance. In this case,
the coefficient of pension risk is not statistically different from zero. This could be
interpreted as in retirement, health risk is more relevant than casualty risk, leading people
exposed to pension risk to anticipate its adverse consequences on health expenditures.

6. Conclusions

There is a large literature on the offset between pension and private wealth. The
baseline life-cycle model prescribes that as pension wealth decreases private wealth
should increase accordingly. A crucial assumption in this literature is that pension wealth
is not risky. Our paper deviates from this assumption, recognizing that pension
entitlements are risky in their own right, and investigates the link between pension risk
and household investment in dedicated pension saving vehicles.
We use a representative sample of the clientele of a leading European bank to elicit
information on the respondent-specific distribution of the replacement rate and
characterize the main features of this subjective distribution, highlighting the extent of
individual heterogeneity in perceptions. Our survey provides data on subjective
probabilities, and also information on financial and insurance decisions and demographic
and economic characteristics of respondents. It thus offers the opportunity of conducting a
systematic exploration of how perceived pension risk is correlated with individual
characteristics and how it conditions people’s financial decisions.
We find that the expected replacement rate on average is close to the statutory
value, but with important differences across individuals. The expected replacement rate is

19
higher for older people and lower for the self-employed, confirming previous evidence
that is consistent with the current social security system rules. Pension risk falls when
people approach retirement, and it is lower for public employees and higher for the self-
employed, consistent with the design of the current pension system, suggesting that those
who should perceive more pension risk do indeed do so. However, our evidence also
shows that heterogeneity in perceived pension risk is only partially explained by socio-
demographic variables, suggesting that eliciting subjective expectations remains crucial to
understanding people’s beliefs about future pensions.
In terms of the effect of pension risk on financial choices, we find that the demand
for retirement saving is negatively related to expectations of a higher pension, and that
people who experience greater public pension risk also choose to increase private
retirement saving. We also find that the demand for health insurance is positively related
to pension risk, while we detect no effect for casualty insurance.
Our results suggest that the perception of pension risk affects the household
portfolio choices in relation to retirement and, thus, imply that overly optimistic (or
pessimistic) expectations of pension benefits might lead to potentially large biases in
household portfolios.

20
References

Attanasio, Orazio P., and Agar Brugiavini (2003), “Social Security and Households’
Saving,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 1075-1119.

Attanasio, Orazio P., and Susan Rohwedder (2003), “Pension Wealth and Household
Saving: Evidence from Pension Reforms in the United Kingdom,” American
Economic Review 93, 1499-1521.

Bernheim, B. Douglas (1988), “Social Security Benefits: An Empirical Study of


Expectations and Realizations,” Issues in Contemporary Retirement, R.R Campbell
and E. Lazear eds. Stanford: Hoover Institution.

Bottazzi, Renata, Tullio Jappelli and Mario Padula (2006), “Retirement expectations,
pension reforms, and their impact on private wealth accumulation,” Journal of
Public Economics 90, 2187-2212.

Disney, Richard, and Sarah Tanner (1999), “What Can We Learn from Retirement
Expectations Data?,” IFS Working Paper n. W99/17. London: Institute for Fiscal
Studies.

Delavande, Adeline and Susann Rohwedder (2008), “Eliciting Subjective Expectations in


Internet Surveys,” WP 589, RAND Labor and Population Working Paper Series.

Dominitz, Jeff and Charles F. Manski (2006), “Measuring Pension-Benefit Expectations


Probabilistically,” Labour 20, 201-236.

Feldstein, Martin (1974), “Social Security, Induced Retirement and Aggregate Capital
Accumulation,” Journal of Political Economy 82, 357-74.

Feldstein, Martin, and Anthony Pellechio (1979), “Social Security and Household
Accumulation: New Microeconometric Evidence,” Review of Economics and
Statistics 61, 361-68.

Gale, William G. (1998), “The Effect of Pension Wealth on Household Wealth: a


Reevaluation of Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Political Economy 106, 706-23.

Gollier Christian, and John W. Pratt (1996), “Risk Vulnerability and the Tempering
Effect of Background Risk,” Econometrica 4, 1109-1124.

Gruber, Jonathan, and David A. Wise (1999), Social Security and Retirement Around the
World. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

21
Gruber, Jonathan, and David A. Wise (2004), Social Security Programs and Retirement
Around the World: Micro Estimation. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

Gustman, Alan L., and Thomas L. Steinmeier (1989), “An Analysis of Pension Benefit
Formulas, Pension Wealth and Incentives from Pensions,” Research in Labor
Economics 10, 53-106.

Gustman, Alan L., and Thomas L. Steinmeier (2005), “Imperfect Knowledge, Retirement
and Saving,” Industrial Relations 44, 373 -95.

Jappelli, Tullio, and Luigi Pistaferri (2003), “Tax Incentives and the Demand for Life
Insurance: Evidence from Italy, Journal of Public Economics 87, 1779-99.

Kimball, Miles (1992), “Precautionary Motives for Holding Assets,” in John Eatwell,
Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (Eds.) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money
and Finance. London: MacMillan.

Manski, Charles (2004), “Measuring Expectations,” Econometrica 72, 1329-1376.

22
Figure 1
Coefficient of variation of replacement rate for a private employee

9
σ u =σ v =0.01
8 σ u=0.01,σ v =0.02

1
25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65

Note: The simulations assume that the growth rates of individual annual earnings and aggregate GDP are 2
percent and 1.5 percent, respectively, the retirement age is 62, the number of years of contribution is 37, the
annuitization factor is 0.0551 and the mean of transitory and permanent income shocks is 1. The continuous
line is obtained by setting the standard deviations of permanent (σv) and transitory (σu) income shocks to 1
percent, the dashed line by setting σu =0.01) and σv =0.02.

23
Figure 2
Coefficient of variation of replacement rate, with aggregate and demographic risk

3
Baseline
Aggregate Uncertainty
2 Demographic Uncertainty

1
25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65
Age

Note: The simulations assume that the growth rate of annual earnings is 2 percent, the retirement age is 62,
the number of years of contribution is 37, the mean of transitory and permanent income shocks is 1, and σu
=σv=0.01. The continuous line is obtained by setting the annuitization factor to 0.0551 and the GDP growth
rate to 1.5 percent, the dashed line assuming that the GDP growth is uniformly distributed between 1 and 2
percent and the annuitization factor is 0.0551, the dotted line that the annuitization factor is uniformly
distributed between 5 and 6 percent and the GDP growth rate is 1.5 percent.

24
Figure 3
Coefficient of variation of replacement rate in different pension regimes

4.5
Earnings model
4 Pro-rata model
Contribution model

3.5

2.5

1.5

0.5
25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65
Age

Note: The simulations assume that the growth rate of earnings and aggregate GDP are 2 percent and 1.5
percent per year, respectively, the retirement age is 62, the number of years of contribution is 37, the
annuitization factor is 0.0551, the mean of transitory and permanent income shocks is 1 and σu =σv=0.01. In
the pro-rata regime the year of job market entry is 1977. The continuous line refers to the earnings model,
the dot-dashed line to the pro-rata regime, the dashed line to the contribution model.

25
Figure 4
Expected replacement rate and coefficient of variation
of the replacement rate distribution

Uniform distribution Uniform distribution


.15

.25
.1 .15 .2
.1
Fraction

Fraction
.05

.05
0

0
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 5 10 15 20
Expected replacement rate Coefficient of variation (%)

Triangular distribution Triangular distribution


.15

.3
.1

.2
Fraction

Fraction
.05

.1
0

0 20 40 60 80 100 0 5 10 15 20 25
Expected replacement rate Coefficient of variation (%)

26
Figure 5
The expected replacement rate and the coefficient of variation of the replacement
rate distribution, by age and education

C.v. of replacement rate (%)


Expected replacement rate

2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5


60 65 70 75

30 40 50 60 70 30 40 50 60 70
Age Age

C.v. of replacement rate (%)


Expected replacement rate
60 62 64 66 68 70

3 3.5 4 4.5 5

5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20
Education Education

27
Figure 6
Quantiles of the expected replacement and coefficient of variation of the
replacement rate distribution, by age and education

Expected replacement rate Coefficient of variation


50 60 70 80 90

8
6
4
2
0
20 30 40 50 60 70 20 30 40 50 60 70
Age Age

0.25 quantile 0.50 quantile 0.25 quantile 0.50 quantile


0.75 quantile 0.75 quantile

Expected replacement rate Coefficient of variation


8
50 60 70 80

6
4
2
0

5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20
Education Education

0.25 quantile 0.50 quantile 0.25 quantile 0.50 quantile


0.75 quantile 0.75 quantile

28
Average of replacement rate Average of replacement rate
Bl 0 20 40 60 80 60 62 64 66 68 70
ue

0
co
lla
W r
hi
te

2
co
lla
r
M

4
an
ag
er
Pr
of
es

6
si

Income decile
on
Se al
lf-
em

8
pl
oy
ed

10

29
C.v. of replacement rate (%) C.v. of replacement rate (%)
Figure 7

Bl 0 1 2 3 4 2.6 2.8 3 3.2 3.4 3.6


ue
0

co
lla
W r
hi
te
2

co
lla
r
M
4

an
ag
er
Pr
of
es
6

si
Income decile

on
Se al
lf-
em
8

pl
The replacement rate distribution, by income and occupation

oy
ed
10
Figure 8
Retirement saving, health insurance and the replacement rate distribution

.2 .25 .3 .35
.3
Pension funds

Life insurance
.15 .2 .25

.15
.1

50 60 70 80 90 50 60 70 80 90
Expected replacement rate Expected replacement rate
.3

.5
Casualty insurance
Health insurance

.3 .4
.2 .25

.2
.15

.1

50 60 70 80 90 50 60 70 80 90
Expected replacement rate Expected replacement rate

30
Figure 9
Retirement saving, health insurance and the coefficient of variation
of the replacement rate distribution

.2 .25 .3 .35
.3
.1 .15 .2 .25
Pension funds

Life insurance
.15
0 2 4 6 8 10 0 2 4 6 8 10
C.v. of replacement rate (%) C.v. of replacement rate (%)
.1 .15 .2 .25 .3 .35

.15 .2 .25 .3 .35 .4


Casualty insurance
Health insurance

0 2 4 6 8 10 0 2 4 6 8 10
C.v. of replacement rate (%) C.v. of replacement rate (%)

31
Table 1
Pension award formula

Pension award formula

Private sector Public sector Self-employed


Old 2% × years of 2% × years of 2% × years of
contribution × average of contribution × contribution ×
last 10 years of earnings average of last 10 average of last 15
years of earnings years of earnings.

Middle-aged Earnings model before 1995, contribution model after 1995.

Young Contributions (33% of gross wage for employees and 20% for self-
employed) are capitalized on the basis of the 5-year moving average of
GDP growth. The capitalized sum is multiplied by a coefficient that
varies by retirement age, taking into account life expectancy.

Pension eligibility

Seniority pensions Old age pensions


Minimum years of Retirement age
contribution
Old and Middle-aged retiring in Private Public Self-
employees employees employed
2008-09 35 60 60 61
2010-13 35 61 61 62
After 2014 35 62 62 63
Young 40 65 65 65
(60) (60) (60)

Note. Old, middle-aged and young refer, respectively, to workers with more than 18 years of contributions
in 1995, less than 18 years of contribution in 1995, and who started working after 1995. Figures in
parentheses are retirement ages for women.

32
Table 2
Cross-sectional statistics of the subjective replacement rate distribution

Statistics of the Cross-sectional statistics


subjective distributions
Mean Median Standard Minimum Maximum
deviation
Mean
Uniform 65.57 70.00 18.78 1.30 98.75
Triangular 65.68 70.00 18.71 1.37 98.33

Standard deviation
Uniform 2.90 2.71 1.74 0.14 8.53
Triangular 2.08 1.93 1.24 0.12 6.04

Coefficient of variation
Uniform 5.08 3.85 3.93 0.29 30.09
Triangular 3.64 2.73 2.77 0.24 20.67

Note. The table reports cross-sectional statistics computed from the moments of the subjective replacement
rate distributions.

33
Table 3
Determinants of the replacement rate distribution

Expected replacement rate Standard deviation Coefficient of variation

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Age 0.222 0.222 -0.008 -0.008 -0.030 -0.030


(0.063)*** (0.063)*** (0.004)* (0.004)* (0.010)*** (0.010)***
Male -1.505 -1.443 0.054 0.036 0.003 -0.017
(1.514) (1.518) (0.107) (0.107) (0.233) (0.233)
Education 0.046 0.058 -0.009 -0.012 -0.020 -0.023
(0.175) (0.176) (0.012) (0.012) (0.027) (0.027)
Private -3.964 -3.897 0.201 0.181 0.622 0.600
(3.111) (3.114) (0.219) (0.219) (0.479) (0.479)
Self-employed -11.517 -11.559 0.198 0.210 1.275 1.289
(1.333)*** (1.336)*** (0.094)** (0.094)** (0.205)*** (0.205)***
Resident in the Centre 6.227 6.152 0.177 0.199 -0.094 -0.069
(1.592)*** (1.598)*** (0.112) (0.112)* (0.245) (0.246)
Resident in the South 8.533 8.500 0.138 0.147 -0.368 -0.357
(1.580)*** (1.581)*** (0.111) (0.111) (0.243) (0.243)
Log income -0.558 -0.523 0.050 0.040 0.159 0.148
(0.979) (0.981) (0.069) (0.069) (0.151) (0.151)
Index of financial literacy -0.283 0.082 0.094
(0.464) (0.033)** (0.071)
Constant 63.370 63.778 1.815 1.696 3.065 2.929
(10.325)*** (10.351)*** (0.728)** (0.727)** (1.588)* (1.591)*

Observations 744 744 744 744 744 744


R-squared 0.14 0.14 0.02 0.03 0.07 0.07

Note. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *** indicate statistical significance at the 1% confidence
level, ** statistical significance at the 5% level, * statistical significance at the 10% level.

34
Table 4
Probability of investing in pension funds

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Expected replacement rate -0.002 -0.002 -0.002 -0.002


(0.001)** (0.001)** (0.001)** (0.001)**
S.d. of replacement rate 0.029 0.029 0.027 0.030
(0.011)*** (0.011)*** (0.011)** (0.011)***
Age -0.002 -0.002 -0.002 -0.003
(0.001)* (0.001)* (0.001) (0.001)*
Male 0.054 0.054 0.045 0.048
(0.031)* (0.031)* (0.031) (0.031)
Education 0.005 0.005 0.004 0.005
(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004)
Private -0.055 -0.055 -0.065 -0.064
(0.056) (0.056) (0.052) (0.052)
Self-employed -0.031 -0.031 -0.029 -0.022
(0.031) (0.031) (0.030) (0.031)
Resident in the Centre -0.042 -0.042 -0.039 -0.038
(0.032) (0.032) (0.032) (0.032)
Resident in the South -0.101 -0.101 -0.099 -0.101
(0.030)*** (0.030)*** (0.030)*** (0.030)***
Log income 0.040 0.040 0.036 0.038
(0.022)* (0.022)* (0.022)* (0.022)*
Index of financial literacy 0.001 0.001 0.001
(0.010) (0.010) (0.010)
High risk aversion -0.116 -0.116
(0.031)*** (0.031)***
Retirement age (average) -0.002
(0.003)
Retirement age (s.d.) -0.038
(0.025)

Observations 744 744 744 744

Note. The table reports marginal effects. Asymptotic standard errors are reported in parentheses. ***
indicate statistical significance at the 1% confidence level, ** statistical significance at the 5% level, *
statistical significance at the 10% level.

35
Table 5
Probability of investing in life insurance

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Expected replacement rate -0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.000


(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
S.d. of replacement rate 0.025 0.021 0.020 0.019
(0.013)** (0.013)* (0.013) (0.013)
Age -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.000
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Male 0.005 -0.004 -0.010 -0.007
(0.037) (0.038) (0.038) (0.039)
Education 0.004 0.003 0.002 0.003
(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005)
Private -0.104 -0.110 -0.118 -0.115
(0.059)* (0.058)* (0.055)** (0.056)**
Self-employed 0.069 0.078 0.078 0.076
(0.035)** (0.035)** (0.035)** (0.035)**
Resident in the Centre -0.039 -0.031 -0.029 -0.033
(0.038) (0.038) (0.039) (0.038)
Resident in the South -0.048 -0.045 -0.042 -0.043
(0.038) (0.038) (0.038) (0.038)
Log income 0.044 0.041 0.037 0.036
(0.024)* (0.024)* (0.024) (0.024)
Index of financial literacy 0.033 0.033 0.033
(0.012)*** (0.012)*** (0.012)***
High risk aversion -0.104 -0.103
(0.040)*** (0.040)***
Expected retirement age -0.002
(0.003)
S.d. of retirement age 0.030
(0.024)

Observations 744 744 744 744

Note. The table reports marginal effects. Asymptotic standard errors are reported in parentheses. ***
indicate statistical significance at the 1% confidence level, ** statistical significance at the 5% level, *
statistical significance at the 10% level.

36
Table 6
Probability of having health insurance

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Expected replacement rate -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001


(0.001)* (0.001)* (0.001)* (0.001)*
S.d. of replacement rate 0.033 0.031 0.031 0.031
(0.011)*** (0.011)*** (0.011)*** (0.011)***
Age 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Male 0.004 0.000 -0.001 -0.000
(0.034) (0.034) (0.035) (0.035)
Education 0.013 0.012 0.012 0.012
(0.004)*** (0.004)*** (0.004)*** (0.004)***
Private -0.048 -0.051 -0.053 -0.052
(0.053) (0.052) (0.052) (0.052)
Self-employed 0.089 0.093 0.093 0.092
(0.031)*** (0.031)*** (0.031)*** (0.032)***
Resident in the Centre -0.075 -0.071 -0.070 -0.072
(0.032)** (0.032)** (0.032)** (0.032)**
Resident in the South -0.045 -0.043 -0.042 -0.042
(0.033) (0.033) (0.033) (0.033)
Log income 0.079 0.077 0.076 0.076
(0.021)*** (0.021)*** (0.021)*** (0.021)***
Index of financial literacy 0.016 0.016 0.015
(0.010) (0.010) (0.010)
High risk aversion -0.029 -0.028
(0.041) (0.041)
Expected retirement age -0.001
(0.003)
S.d. of retirement age 0.014
(0.022)

Observations 744 744 744 744

Note. The table reports marginal effects. Asymptotic standard errors are reported in parentheses. ***
indicate statistical significance at the 1% confidence level, ** statistical significance at the 5% level, *
statistical significance at the 10% level.

37
Table 7
Probability of having casualty insurance

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Expected replacement rate -0.003 -0.002 -0.003 -0.002


(0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)***
S.d. of replacement rate -0.015 -0.017 -0.018 -0.018
(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)
Age -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Male 0.098 0.096 0.092 0.087
(0.038)*** (0.038)** (0.038)** (0.039)**
Education 0.007 0.006 0.006 0.005
(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005)
Private -0.067 -0.069 -0.078 -0.082
(0.069) (0.068) (0.067) (0.066)
Self-employed 0.193 0.196 0.196 0.193
(0.036)*** (0.036)*** (0.036)*** (0.037)***
Resident in the Centre 0.001 0.006 0.009 0.013
(0.042) (0.042) (0.043) (0.043)
Resident in the South -0.093 -0.091 -0.087 -0.085
(0.040)** (0.040)** (0.040)** (0.040)**
Log income 0.098 0.096 0.094 0.094
(0.026)*** (0.026)*** (0.026)*** (0.026)***
Index of financial literacy 0.015 0.015 0.015
(0.012) (0.012) (0.012)
High risk aversion -0.083 -0.084
(0.045)* (0.045)*
Expected retirement age 0.004
(0.003)
S.d. of retirement age -0.014
(0.026)

Observations 744 744 744 744

Note. The table reports marginal effects. Asymptotic standard errors are reported in parentheses. ***
indicate statistical significance at the 1% confidence level, ** statistical significance at the 5% level, *
statistical significance at the 10% level.

38
Appendix

A1. The survey

The 2006 UniCredit Survey (UCS) is a national representative sample of the eligible population
of UniCredit Group customers. The eligible population of customers excludes customers under 20
and over 80, and customers with assets of less than 10,000 Euros with UniCredit. The sampled
population size is around 1.3 million customers. The survey was aimed at acquiring information
on the behavior and expectations of UniCredit Group customers and focused on multi-banking,
attitude towards saving and investing, financial literacy and propensity for risk, pensions and need
for insurance.

The sampling scheme is similar to that of the Bank of Italy Survey of Household Income and
Wealth (SHIW). The population is stratified along two criteria: geographical area of residence
(North-East, North-West, Central and Southern Italy) and wealth held with UniCredit as of June
30 2006. The sample size is 1,686 customers, of whom 1,580 are from UniCredit Retail Bank, and
106 from UniCredit Private Bank (the upper tier customer bank). The survey was administered
between May 1 and September 30 of 2007 by a leading Italian polling agency, which also
conducts the SHIW for the Bank of Italy. Most interviewers had substantial experience of
administering the SHIW, which is likely to increase the quality of the data. The UCS was piloted
in the first quarter of 2007, and the Computer Assisted Personal Interview methodology was
employed for all interviews. To overcome some of the problems arising from non-responses, the
sample was balanced ex-post with respect to the true distribution of assets, area of residence, city
size, gender, age and education of the eligible population.

The questionnaire comprises 9 sections. Sections A and B refer, respectively, to respondent and
household demographic and occupation variables. Section C focuses on saving, investment and
financial risk. Section D asks detailed questions about financial wealth and portfolio allocation,
and Section E enquires about consumer debt and mortgages. By design, Sections A, B, D and E
allow a perfect matching with the SHIW questionnaire. Questions on real estate and
entrepreneurial activities are included in Section F. Section G contains questions on subjective
expectations, and section H focuses on insurance and private pension funds. The last two sections
ask about income and expectations and need for insurance and pension products.

As shown in Table A1, compared with the Italian population, as surveyed by the 2006 Bank of
Italy SHIW, UniCredit Group customers are older, more educated, less likely to work in the
manufacturing sector, and more likely to live in the North.

39
A2. Wording of questions

The UCS uses three questions to elicit the subjective probability distribution of the replacement
rate. All employees and self-employed are asked to report the minimum (ym) and the maximum
(yM) replacement rate he or she expects after retirement, and the probability that the replacement
rate is less than the midpoint of the support of the distribution, Prob(y ≤ (ym+ yM)/2) = π. All
respondents are first asked:

Think about when you will retire, and consider only the public pension (i.e., exclude private
pension if you have one).

(a) At the time of retirement, what is the minimum fraction of labor income that you expect to
receive?

(b) And what is the maximum value?

(c) What are the chances that the fraction will be greater than X (where X is computed by the
interviewer as (a+b)/2? In other words, if you were to assign a score between 0 and 100
to the chance that the fraction will be greater than X, what score would you assign? (“0”
if you are certain to receive a pension greater than X, “100” if you are certain to receive
a pension less than X). The following table is shown to the respondent:

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
I am sure I will
I am sure I will
earn more than
earn less than X
X

A3. The subjective probability distribution of the replacement rate

Let f(y) denote the distribution of the replacement rate for each individual. The survey provides
information on the support of the distribution [ym, yM] and on the probability mass to the left of the
mid-point of the support, Prob(y≤(ym+yM)/2) = π. Knowing the support of the distribution, we can
express the expected value and variance of y as:

yM
E ( y) = ∫ yf ( y)dy
ym

⎡ yM ⎛ yM ⎞ ⎤
2

Var ( y ) = ⎢ y 2 f ( y ) dy − ⎜ y f ( y )dy ⎟ ⎥ .
∫ ∫
⎢ ⎜ ⎟ ⎥
⎣⎢ ym ⎝ ym ⎠ ⎦⎥

We consider two assumptions concerning f(y). The first is that y is uniformly distributed over each
of the two intervals [ym, (ym+yM)/2] and ((ym+yM)/2, yM]. If π=0.5 the distribution collapses to a
single uniform distribution defined in the interval [ym, yM]. A second possibility is to assume that

40
the distribution is triangular over the same two intervals; if π=0.5 the distribution again collapses
to a single triangular distribution over the interval [ym, yM]. Note that in both cases E(y) and Var(y)
depend only on the three known parameters ( y m , y M , and π). The triangular distribution is a
more plausible description of the probability distribution of the replacement rate, because
outcomes further away from the mid-point receive less weight. Figures A1 and A2 show the p.d.f.
under the uniform and the triangular assumptions.

Figure A3 plots the raw data, i.e. the subjective distributions of y m , y M , 1-π and y M - y m .
Slightly less than 30 percent of respondents report a limited range of the subjective distribution;
instead, for 30 percent the range of the replacement rate is between 10 and 15 percent.

A4. The moments of the replacement rate distribution

We assume that before retirement the income process is given by:

Yt = g t Y0 PtU t
Pt = Pt −1Vt

where {ln U t } and {ln Vt } are Gaussian white-noise random terms with mean and standard
deviations, respectively, equal to μ u and σ u and to μ v and σ v . Here we refer to the case of a
private employee. The calculations for public employees and self-employed are similar and
available upon request.

A4.1. Earnings model

In the earnings model the replacement rate is:

0.02 ⎡ 1 4 t ~ ⎤
⎢ ∑
U T ⎣ 5 t =1
δ U T −t PT −t ⎥

(A1)

where T is years of contribution at retirement; δ is the ratio between growth factor of prices
and growth factor of income and:
~ 1
Pt = T

∏V
s =t +1
s

To compute the average, the standard deviation and the coefficient of variation of the replacement
rate distribution, we need the first two moments of the term inside the braces in equation (A1).
These are:

41
⎡1 4 s ~ ⎤
μ1|t = 0.02e − μ ⎢ 5 ∑ δ Et (U T − s PT − s )⎥
u + 0.5σ u
2

⎣ s =1 ⎦
1 ⎡ 4
~2 3 4
~ ~ ⎤
μ 2|t = 4 * 10 − 4 e − 2 μu + 2σ u ∑ δ ∑ ∑ δ s δ r Et (U T − s PT − sU T − s PT − s )⎥
2


2s
E t (U 2
T −s P T −s ) + 2
25 ⎣ s =1 s =1 r = s +1 ⎦

A4.2. Contribution model

The replacement rate in the contribution model is:

γτ T −1 ~
{ [∑ α T −tU t Pt ]} + γτ (A2)
U T t =1

where γ ,τ and α respectively are the annuitization factor, the payroll rate, and the ratio of
growth factor of GDP to growth factor of income. The first two moments of the term inside the
braces in (A2) are:

T −1
~
μ1|t = γτe − μ u + 0.5σ u 2
∑α
s =1
T −s
E t (U s Ps )

⎡ T −1 2(T − s ) 2 ~2
T − 2 T −1
~ ~ ⎤
μ 2|t = (γτ ) 2 e − 2 μ u + 2σ u 2
⎢ ∑
⎣ s =1
α E t (U s P s ) + 2 ∑ ∑ α T − s α T − r E t (U s PsU r Pr )⎥
s =1 r = s +1 ⎦

A4.3. Pro-rata model

The replacement rate in the pro-rata model is:

1 ⎡ t1992 4
~ T −1
~⎤ t
⎢0.02
UT ⎣ 5
∑δ U t
T −t PT −t + γτ ∑α T −t
U t Pt ⎥ + (0.02 1992 + 0.06 + γτ )
5
(A3)
t =1 t =t1995 ⎦

The first two moments of the term inside the braces of A3 are:

⎡ t1992 4
~ T −1
~ ⎤
μ1|t = e − μ u + 0.5σ u 2
⎢0.02
5
∑ δ s E t (U T − s PT − s ) + γτ ∑α T −s
E t (U s Ps )⎥
⎣ s =1 s = t1995 ⎦
t1992 ⎡ ~ ⎤
2 4 3 4
~2 ~
μ 2|t = e − 2 μ u + 2σ u 2
{4 * 10 − 4 ⎢ ∑
25 ⎣ s =1
δ 2s
E t (U 2
T − s P T − s ) + 2 ∑ ∑ δ s δ r E t (U T − s PT − sU T − s PT − s )⎥ +
s =1 r = s +1 ⎦
⎡ T −1 ~ T − 2 T −1
~ ~ ⎤
+ (γτ ) 2 ⎢ ∑ α 2 (T − s ) E t (U 2 s P 2 s ) + 2 ∑ ∑ α T − s α T − r E t (U s PsU r Pr )⎥ +
⎣ s =t1995 s = t1995 r = s +1 ⎦
T −1
t 4
~ ~
+ 2 * 0.02 * 1992 * γτ ∑ ∑ δ s α T − r E t (U T − s PT − sU r Pr )}
5 s =1 r = t1995

42
Table A1: UCS – SHIW comparison

UCS SHIW SHIW


Highest income earner Bank account holder
Gender
Male 0.69 0.69 0.71
Female 0.31 0.31 0.29
Age
up to 30 0.04 0.06 0.06
31 to 40 0.18 0.19 0.20
41 to 50 0.22 0.22 0.22
51 to 65 0.36 0.24 0.24
over 65 0.20 0.29 0.27
Education
elementary school 0.10 0.27 0.22
middle school 0.29 0.36 0.37
high school 0.41 0.27 0.30
university degree 0.20 0.10 0.10
Sector of activity
Agriculture 0.03 0.03 0.03
Industry 0.13 0.21 0.23
Public Administration 0.19 0.15 0.17
other sector 0.30 0.19 0.20
not employed 0.35 0.40 0.37
Household size
1 member 0.21 0.25 0.23
2 members 0.29 0.28 0.29
3 members 0.26 0.21 0.22
4 members 0.20 0.18 0.19
5 or more members 0.04 0.07 0.06
Geographical area
Northern Italy 0.73 0.48 0.52
Central Italy 0.14 0.20 0.21
South and Islands 0.13 0.32 0.27

Note: The table compares sample means of selected demographic variables in the UCS and 2006 SHIW.
Means are computed using sample weights.

43
Figure A1
The uniform distribution

Figure A2
The triangular distribution

44
Figure A3
The subjective replacement rate
.3

.3
.2

.2
Fraction

Fraction
.1

.1
0

0
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
Minimum replacement rate (ym) Maximum replacement rate (yM)
.3

.3
.2
Fraction

Fraction
.2
.1

.1
0

0 20 40 60 80 100 0 10 20 30 40 50
Prob. replacement rate >(ym+yM)/2 Range of the subj. distribution of replacement rate

45

View publication stats

You might also like