Can A Catholic Be A Socialist (Trent Horn Catherine R Pakaluk)
Can A Catholic Be A Socialist (Trent Horn Catherine R Pakaluk)
Pakaluk
All rights reserved. Except for quotations, no part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in
any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording, uploading to
the internet, or by any information storage and retrieval system without written permission from the
publisher.
978-1-68357-162-9
978-1-68357-163-6 Kindle
978-1-68357-164-3 ePub
Table of Contents
Introduction
1. The Return of Socialism
2. What Is Socialism?
3. Socialism’s Fatal Flaws
4. What About Democratic Socialism?
5. The False “First Socialists”
6. The Real “First Socialists”
7. Leo XIII on Private Property
8. Leo XIII and Human Nature
9. Socialism Gets a State
10. Pius XI and Socialism’s Victims
11. Socialism Goes Global
12. Modern Popes vs. Modern Socialism
13. Capitalism and Human Nature
14. The Church on Capitalism
15. The Church on Just Wages
16. Capitalism and Human Labor
17. The Nordic Myth
18. The Venezuelan Reality
19. Debunking Catholic Socialism
20. Catholicism and Moral Capitalism
Appendix: What About Distributism?
About the Authors
INTRODUCTION
In the middle of the third century, the Roman emperor Valerian launched a
fierce persecution against the Church that resulted in the martyrdom of
Pope Saint Sixtus II along with seven deacons. St. Ambrose tells us that
when the Roman authorities demanded that one of the deacons, named
Lawrence, hand over “the treasures of the Church,” he agreed. According to
Ambrose, “On the following day he brought the poor together. When asked
where the treasures were which he had promised, he pointed to the poor,
saying, “These are the treasures of the Church.”
Christ commanded his followers to care for the poor and warned them that
ignoring the poor was the same as ignoring him (Matt 25:40). As the
Church grew within the Roman Empire, Christians became famous for their
generosity, which included not just almsgiving but the construction of the
first hospitals that served the poor. The Roman emperor Julian the Apostate
lamented how Christians “support not only their own poor but ours as well;
all men see that our people lack aid from us.” For the most marginalized
people in Roman society, like widows and abandoned newborns, it was only
the generosity of Christians that stood between them and a premature death.
Christian generosity continued to be the difference between life and death
for many people even after Christians became the rulers of medieval
kingdoms, in which there simply wasn’t enough wealth for the state to lift
the masses out of poverty. But this began to change with the rise of modern
capitalism, as is evident in Adam Smith’s famous 1776 essay, “An Inquiry
into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.” Christians now had
the ability to create wealth, and with that power came moral questions
about how to address the perennial problem of poverty.
In the century after Smith’s essay was published, revolutionaries in
America and Europe tore down the authority of the monarchy and replaced
it with democratic republics. Ultimate authority, the revolutionaries said,
should lie with the people instead of the king. Other revolutionaries took
this democratic ideal even further and said wealth and property should not
lie with a few people (be they monarchs or capitalists) but should be owned
by all. In 1871, some of these revolutionaries even took over the city of
Paris for two months, establishing a “socialist commune” until the French
army retook the city, killing thousands of communards in the process.
By the end of the nineteenth century, the revolutionary spirit showed no
sign of slowing and even many Christians were becoming sympathetic to
the socialist cause. Christians now had access to more wealth and political
power than they had ever possessed in the history of the world, but it wasn’t
clear how those things should be used to help the poor. All of this was on
the mind of Pope Leo XIII as he wrote the introduction to the most famous
papal encyclical to address the issue of socialism: Rerum Novarum (Latin:
“New Things”). He says this “spirit of revolutionary change” is not
surprising and notes:
The elements of the conflict now raging are unmistakable, in the vast
expansion of industrial pursuits and the marvelous discoveries of science;
in the changed relations between masters and workmen; in the enormous
fortunes of some few individuals, and the utter poverty of the masses; the
increased self-reliance and closer mutual combination of the working
classes; as also, finally, in the prevailing moral degeneracy.
The pope goes on to describe how everyone is talking about these “new
things” and so the Church, which teaches us on matters of faith and morals,
“thought it expedient now to speak on the condition of the working
classes.”
The socialist revolutions of the nineteenth century spurred the creation of
the Church’s social doctrine: the application of its teaching to issues that
arise as society changes over time. When it comes to the application of
timeless truths to changing circumstances the pope admitted:
The discussion is not easy, nor is it void of danger. It is no easy matter to
define the relative rights and mutual duties of the rich and of the poor, of
capital and of labor. And the danger lies in this, that crafty agitators are
intent on making use of these differences of opinion to pervert men’s
judgments and to stir up the people to revolt.
Although much has changed in the century since Pope Leo XIII penned
these words, many things are still the same. There may not today be calls
for violent revolution in America or Europe, but there are grassroots
movements seeking to establish socialism through democratic activism.
Some of those movements even claim that a Christian is obligated to
support socialist economies or else he does not truly follow Christ’s
command to “love your neighbor as yourself.”
In this book we will apply the Church’s social doctrine to the debate on
socialism and show that not only are Catholics not obligated to be socialists,
they—we—cannot be socialists. It is not a permissible or prudent way to
address the problem of poverty.
In part one, we will examine the modern resurgence of socialism and
explain why so many people, including faithful Catholics, are attracted to
this ideology. Then we will “pull back the curtain” and show why socialism
is an inherently contradictory and unsustainable approach to economics.
In part two we will refute the claim that Christianity gave birth to
socialism and show how it was actually conceived in nineteenth-century
Europe. We’ll also explore Pope Leo XIII’s arguments against socialism,
especially his claim that it violates the natural right to private property and
poses a grave danger to the family.
In part three we continue our historical survey and reveal, in all its
horrors, the destruction socialism wrought in the twentieth century.
In part four we turn our attention to capitalism and, while not providing an
exhaustive summary and defense, refute arguments that try to justify
socialism by saying capitalism is worse or unacceptable as an economic
system.
Finally, in part five, we return to the present to examine modern, Catholic
defenses of socialism and present a trajectory toward a “moral capitalism.”
For the best approach to economics will not only produce the most wealth
and alleviate the most poverty, but will create conditions for the human
spirit to flourish, grow in virtue, and be perfected by God’s grace.
Part One
Socialism
Deconstructed
1
• Most people have an incoherent understanding of socialism and often conflate it with government
entitlement programs.
• The Catholic Church has consistently and strongly denounced socialism as an evil that Christians
can never support.
1 Mohamed Younis, “Four in 10 Americans Embrace Some Form of Socialism,” Gallup, May 20, 2019,
https://news.gallup.com/poll/257639/four-americans-embrace-form-socialism.aspx.
2 “Victims of Communism 2018 Annual Report,” https://www.victimsofcommunism.org/2018-annual-report.
3 Glen H. Elder, Children of the Great Depression: Social Change in Life Experience (New York: Routledge, 2018), 44–45. Some
median income losses reached as high as 64 percent, though anything above 40 percent usually required the sale of assets like
homes to make up the difference.
4 John Steinbeck, The Grapes of Wrath (New York: Penguin, 2002), 348–349.
5 See Harvey Klehr, The Heyday of American Communism: The Depression Decade (New York, Basic Books, 1984).
6 Huey Long, “Every Man a King” in American Political Speeches, ed. Richard Beeman (New York: Penguin, 2012), 66.
7 Letter to Norman Thomas (September 25, 1951). See David Mikkelson, “Norman Thomas on Socialism” snopes.com
(September 26, 2009), https://www.snopes.com/fact-check/norman-thomas-on-socialism/.
8 Rakesh Kochhar, “A Recovery No Better than the Recession Median Household Income, 2007 to 2011,” Pew Research Center
(2012), https://www.pewresearch.org/wp-content/uploads/sites/3/2012/09/median-household-incomes-2007–2011.pdf.
9 Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Of the 1 percent, by the 1 percent, for the 1 percent” Vanity Fair (May 2011),
https://www.vanityfair.com/news/2011/05/top-one-percent-201105.
10 For a criticism Frank Newport, “Democrats More Positive About Socialism Than Capitalism,” Gallup (August 13, 2018),
https://news.gallup.com/poll/240725/democrats-positive-socialism-capitalism.aspx.
11 Keith A. Spencer, “Some millennials aren’t saving for retirement because they don’t think capitalism will exist by then,”
salon.com (March 18, 2018), https://www.salon.com/2018/03/18/some-millennials-arent-saving-for-retirement-because-they-
do-not-think-capitalism-will-exist-by-then/.
12 “Tradinista Manifesto,” https://tradinista.tumblr.com/manifesto.
13 David Bentley Hart, “Can We Please Relax About ‘Socialism’?” The New York Times (April 27, 2019),
https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/opinion/sunday/socialism.html.
14 Dean Dettloff, “The Catholic Case for Communism,” America (July 23, 2019),
https://www.americamagazine.org/faith/2019/07/23/catholic-case-communism.
15 Derek Thompson, “Millennials’ Political Views Don’t Make Any Sense,” The Atlantic (July 15, 2014),
https://www.theatlantic.com/politics/archive/2014/07/millennials-economics-voting-clueless-kids-these-days/374427/.
16 Frank Newport, “Democrats More Positive About Socialism Than Capitalism,” Gallup (August 13, 2018),
https://news.gallup.com/poll/240725/democrats-positive-socialism-capitalism.aspx.
17 Derek Thompson, “Millennials’ Political Views Don’t Make Any Sense,” The Atlantic (July 15, 2014),
https://www.theatlantic.com/politics/archive/2014/07/millennials-economics-voting-clueless-kids-these-days/374427/.
18 David Bentley Hart, “Can We Please Relax About ‘Socialism’?” The New York Times (April 27, 2019),
https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/opinion/sunday/socialism.html.
2
What Is Socialism?
When most people think of the “Pilgrims,” they think of people in big hats
eating luxurious Thanksgiving feasts. But in the spring of 1621, the
Plymouth colonists were in danger of starving to death and, despite what
you were told in elementary school, it wasn’t harsh weather or ignorance
about farming that led to these dire circumstances. Instead, it was the
pilgrims’ policy of sharing communal plots of land that nearly led to their
ruin.
Even after local tribes helped the pilgrims survive their first harsh winter,
the colonists still suffered from food shortages. That was because people
weren’t allowed to grow their own food. Instead, food was grown
communally and then equally distributed to everyone—even to people who
didn’t help farm any of it. In choosing this method of farming, the colony’s
governor William Bradford said the pilgrims thought “the taking away of
property, and bringing in community into a commonwealth, would make
them happy and flourishing; as if they were wiser than God.”19
It took several painful years for the pilgrims to learn they were not so
wise.
THAT WHICH IS COMMON
According to Bradford’s journal, the strongest of the young men
complained about “spend[ing] their time and strength to work for other
men’s wives and children without any recompense.” Wives viewed forced
work for other husbands and families as “a kind of slavery.” Even the older
residents who couldn’t work (and thus actually had more to eat than they
otherwise would have) “thought it some indignity and disrespect unto
them.”
People were mad because no matter how hard they worked, their situation
in life wouldn’t improve. And they resented neighbors who barely worked
but still got the same rations as they did. These bitter colonists may have
thought, “I’m done with back-breaking work in the fields. Instead, I’ll just
do the bare minimum like everybody else.”
The communal farming system could tolerate a few lazy people as long as
everyone else worked hard. But once enough people only had incentive to
do the bare minimum, then it would only take bad luck or uncooperative
weather to ruin their meager food supplies. Fortunately, Bradford
recognized that because “all men have this corruption in them, God in his
wisdom saw another course fitter for them.”
He responded to the crisis by assigning each family its own parcel of land
and letting them keep the food they produced. Bradford recalled, “This had
very good success; for it made all hands very industrious, so as much more
corn was planted than otherwise would have been.” Bradford had
discovered what the Greek philosopher Aristotle proved to be true 2,500
years ago: “That which is common to the greatest number has the least care
bestowed upon it. Everyone thinks chiefly of his own, hardly at all of the
common interest.” He added that a person only thinks of the common good
“when he is himself concerned as an individual.”20
The sad truth is that every generation has individuals in it who fail to learn
this lesson about human nature. The pilgrim’s plight isn’t just interesting
history; it’s a cautionary tale that shows why no one (especially Catholics
who share the pilgrim’s worship of “God in his wisdom”) should be a
socialist.
THE MEANING OF SOCIALISM
One May 2019 poll revealed that a third of people associate socialism with
providing people with health care, housing, and jobs, and ending poverty,
while 20 percent don’t know what socialism is. Only one in five could name
the mechanisms by which socialism is supposed to achieve its grand
promises: government ownership of the economy and the abolishment of
private property.21
Bhaskar Sunkara, editor of the popular socialist magazine Jacobin, writes,
“Radically changing things would mean taking away the source of
capitalists’ power: the private ownership of property.”22 Sunkara faithfully
adheres to the teachings of the most famous socialist in history, Karl Marx,
who declared in The Communist Manifesto that “the theory of the
Communists may be summed up in the single sentence: abolition of private
property.”23 This is why Pope Leo XIII said socialism is contrary to the
natural right to own property and that, “the main tenet of socialism, [the]
community of goods, must be utterly rejected” (Rerum Novarum 15).
This communal ownership of wealth and property also means that no one
could exchange privately owned goods in order to make a profit. Instead,
society would simply produce goods by the command of government-
owned industries, and those industries alone would sell them. Political
scientist Frances Fox Piven notes, “The academic debates about socialism’s
‘meaning’ are huge and arcane and rife with disagreements, but what all
definitions have in common is either the elimination of the market or its
strict containment.”24
Such regimes are called command economies or planned economies
because in order for such a system to work without a market (a means for
people to voluntarily buy and sell from one another) the economy would
have to be centrally planned. Administrators and bureaucrats—accountants,
economists, and statisticians—would have to direct factories, farms, and
businesses (or what are commonly grouped under the term “the means of
production”) to produce enough of the right kind of goods and services that
people desire, or at the very least, need.
In his book Socialism . . . Seriously: A Brief Guide to Human Liberation,
activist Danny Katch envisions a future in which the community produces
so many goods and services that most people only have to work Tuesday
through Thursday. His fictional socialist wistfully explains, “Each year the
whole money thing feels increasingly pointless in a society in which
everyone has more than enough of what they need and plenty of what they
want. But money is still the main way for planning committees to keep
track of how goods and services are being distributed and used.”25
SOCIALISM OR COMMUNISM?
Later we will look at how central planning led to horrifying results in
socialist countries like the Soviet Union, but some people may say we
shouldn’t use Communism’s failures as an argument against socialism.
After all, they say, “Communism isn’t the same thing as socialism.”
But according to the textbook Essentials of Sociology “The terms
socialism and Communism are often used more or less interchangeably.”26
For many collectivists, socialism and Communism are not separate
systems of economic thought; they are successive stages in the same
scheme to create a world of collective ownership. Vladimir Lenin wrote in
The State and Revolution that, “in the first phase of communist society
(usually called socialism) ‘bourgeois law’ is not abolished in its entirety, but
only in part, only in proportion to the economic revolution so far attained.”
Communism isn’t the embarrassing, authoritarian cousin that gives
socialism a bad name. Instead, Communism is the end point to which
socialism inevitably tends, at least for Marxists.
Marx defended a limited “dictatorship of the proletariat” that would rule
until a classless, Communist society came into existence. But, as we will
see later, socialism has inherent authoritarian tendencies. That’s why it’s no
surprise that any “dictatorship of the proletariat” would refuse (like almost
every other dictator in history) to give up its power once its goal of creating
a centrally planned economy had been achieved.
One reason Marxists give for why no socialist country has ever reached
the endgame of peaceful Communism is that socialism isn’t just for nations;
it’s for the entire world. Marx wanted to “abolish countries and nationality”
because “the working men have no country.”27 His collaborator Friedrich
Engels said that social classes “fall as inevitably as they once arose. The
state inevitably falls with them.” He believed the idea of a governing state
belonged in “the museum of antiquities, next to the spinning wheel and the
bronze axe.”28
Modern socialists tend to follow Marx on this point, as is evident in the
World Socialist Party’s claim that “central to the meaning of socialism is
common ownership. This means the resources of the world being owned in
common by the entire global population.”29
But not all socialists historically have wanted to adapt this “international
Communism.” Some preferred a “national socialism” grounded in a
powerful authoritarian state. The most famous example of this approach
was the German National Socialist Workers’ Party, or as you probably
know them, the Nazis.
The Nazi party platform required the nationalization of industries and
charged the state with providing for people’s livelihoods. Its defenders
taught the importance of respecting the maxim, “The common good goes
before the individual’s good.”30 Even historians who dispute Hitler’s
socialist credentials admit that Nazi Germany used planning methods
similar to those of socialists. According to one such historian, Ian Kershaw,
this meant that “the state, not the market, would determine the shape of
[Germany’s] economic development.”31
SOCIALISM OR CAPITALISM?
Another misconception about socialism is that there are only two kinds of
economic systems: complete government control of the economy and
complete lack of government control (so-called laissez-faire capitalism).
But it’s incorrect even to think about economic systems as existing on a
control or regulatory spectrum. What divides socialism from capitalism is
not whether the government controls the economy or how much it does, or
how big it is, but its role in creating and sustaining the economy
Under socialism, governments create and sustain the production of goods
and services by running businesses and employing individuals. In contrast,
under capitalism, governments create and sustain the conditions under
which individuals and firms produce goods and services. In a modern
market economy, these conditions include a robust system of property rights
that allow for the sale and transfer of property as well as regulations that set
the “rules of the game” for all types of market transactions.
Many of the “freest” economies, then, actually operate under many
government regulations; in fact, they couldn’t exist without governments to
enforce contracts that regulate all their economic exchanges.
If economies exist on a spectrum, then it isn’t a spectrum of control or
regulation. Instead, it’s a spectrum of how many functions the central
government takes to be its own, and how many are left to subsidiaries—
private individuals and firms, communities, and local governments. In this
book we are concerned with economies that lie toward the socialist end of
that spectrum, or ones where the greater number of functions are tasked to
the central government.
In this book, then, we use the terms socialism and Communism to refer to
the same kind of centrally planned economic system that rejects the
ownership of private property. We will show that Catholics cannot support
these economic systems because they violate our natural rights and lead to
human misery. Even apart from the authoritarian abuses that often
accompany these systems, socialism contains undeniable flaws that make it
unfit for any modern nation to accept.
It’s important to remember . . .
• Socialism is opposed to the private ownership of property and believes that the community as a
whole should “own” the means of producing goods and services.
• Socialism and Communism represent different stages in the ultimate goal of eliminating economic
and social classes; both systems advocate for centrally planned economies that leave no room for a
free market.
• The choice in the modern world is not between socialism and completely unregulated capitalism but
between keeping the means of production primarily in the hands of private businesses or primarily
in the hands of government.
19 William Bradford, “Of Plymouth Plantation,” The English Literatures of America: 1500–1800, eds. Myra Jehlen and Michael
Warner (New York: Routledge, 1997), 187.
20 Politics, II.3.
21 Matthew Sheffield, “20 percent of Americans can’t define ‘socialism’ even as it’s become the focus of 2020,” The Hill (May
31, 2019), https://thehill.com/hilltv/what-americas-thinking/446377-20-percent-of-americans-cant-define-socialism-even-as-its.
22 Bhaskar Sunkara, “End Private Property, Not Kenny Loggins,” Jacobin (February, 2016),
https://jacobinmag.com/2016/02/socialism-marxism-private-property-person-lennon-imagine-kenny-loggins.
23 Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party (1848), Chapter II,
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch02.htm.
24 Jeff Stein, “9 questions about the Democratic Socialists of America you were too embarrassed to ask,” Vox (August 5, 2017),
https://www.vox.com/policy-and-politics/2017/8/5/15930786/dsa-socialists-convention-national.
25 Danny Katch, Socialism . . . Seriously: A Brief Guide to Human Liberation (Chicago: Haymarket Books, 2015), 76.
26 George Ritzer, Essentials of Sociology (Los Angeles: Sage Publications, 2016), 289.
27 Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party (1848), Chapter II,
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch02.htm.
28 Friedrich Engels, Origin of the Family, Private Property, and the State (1884),
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/download/pdf/origin_family.pdf.
29 https://www.worldsocialism.org/english/what-socialism.
30 Fritz Oerter, “Our Speakers in the Anti-Marxist Struggle,” in The Third Reich Sourcebook, eds. Anson Rabinbach and Sander
L. Gilman (Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press, 2013), 34.
31 Ian Kershaw, Hitler: A Biography (New York: W.W. Norton, 2008), 270.
3
If there’s one thing socialists are great at doing, it’s coming up with
appealing visions of what a socialist future would look like. This kind of
literature was especially popular in the early nineteenth century, before the
gritty reality of socialism became a historical fact. One of the most popular
was Étienne Cabet’s 1842 novel Voyage to Icaria, about a traveler who
visits the fictional nation of Icaria and is impressed by its cleanliness and
lack of poverty.
The traveler credits this paradise to the community’s abandonment of
private property and its commitment to living a simple, communal lifestyle.
He utters what could be considered a mantra for socialists: “Nothing is
impossible for a government that wants the good of its citizens.”32 But
history has repeatedly shown, in lessons that become more painful every
time they must be taught, that a utopia (a word that literally means “no
place”) is impossible to create in this world.33
In fact, when we stop to think about how a socialist society would even
work—beyond the presumption of “free” housing and health care for all—
we see that true socialism, the kind endorsed by thinkers like Marx, aren’t
even hypothetical—they are impossible.
THE INCENTIVE PROBLEM
The ultimate goal of socialists, especially those influenced by Karl Marx, is
the elimination of social classes. According to them, inequalities are the
source of all conflict between human beings and so, once classes like rich
and poor are a thing of the past, then conflict between human beings will
cease as well. But this theory only works if “classes” aren’t just noticeable
differences between groups of human beings that will always exist.
For example, if no one were richer than anyone else because everyone
received the same wages, why would anyone be motivated to choose a dirty
or dangerous occupation? If you would get paid the same amount of money,
would you rather make sausage or snow cones? Would you rather clean car
windshields or the windows on a skyscraper?
Of course, most people will want the more pleasant job, which means that
the less-desirable jobs will have to pay more. Unequal wages thus adjust
compensation to create incentives for people to do the jobs that need to be
done. But when higher wages are given according to the job, some people
will naturally make more money and so Marx’s dreaded “classes” will still
persist.
If such incentives were abolished by giving everyone the same wages,
then the less-desirable jobs will go unfilled. Or, what is more likely to
happen in a command economy, some people will be forced to work at
these jobs even against their will. Yet even then, classes will still exist—in
the form of the pleasantness or safety of one’s work or just its basic
desirability—creating inequality and envy.
Some jobs, like oil drilling or cattle farming, require people to live in
harsh climates while other jobs, like lifeguarding, let people live near the
beach. Which lifestyle do you think most people would prefer? So you
would be stuck with a higher class of people lucky enough to draw work
assignments in Malibu and a lower class that gets stuck in Timbuktu.34
And you can be sure that those who have connections with governmental
planners will be able to secure the pleasant upper-class jobs while the lower
classes are compelled to do everyone else’s dirty work.
Maybe this inequality could be solved by having people share and rotate
jobs—like being a kindergarten teacher one week and a sewer repairman
the next? This would only result in a society of unskilled workers, since it
takes years of experience to master a trade. Yet this seems to be the solution
Marx has in mind when he dreams about how, once production results in a
superabundance of goods, it will be “possible for me to do one thing today
and another tomorrow, to hunt in the morning, fish in the afternoon, rear
cattle in the evening, criticize after dinner, just as I have a mind, without
ever becoming hunter, fisherman, herdsman, or critic.”35
Whatever conception of genteel living Marx had in mind, most of us don’t
want our doctor, lawyer, plumber, or electrician to be someone who was a
window-washer last week, or who decided to try this field out as a hobby.
Differences in wages play a huge role in getting the right people—those
who have the interest, talent, or taste, to invest the right resources (e.g.,
specialized schooling or apprenticeship) in order do the right work—the
thing that needs doing.
The incentive problem also beguiles moderate socialism, which doesn’t
rely on outright government control of businesses but simply confiscates
wealth or income above a certain amount. If a person has no hope of
retaining income above a certain amount, then he has no incentive to put in
the necessary work to produce the income he never receives (and then it’s
the pilgrims’ starvation problem all over again). But, the biggest incentive
problem for socialism lies in getting people to work in the first place.
As we shall see, socialists often complain about the injustice of having to
“sell your labor-power to capitalists” in order to survive. They think that if a
person’s livelihood depends on how much he works, then he is just a “wage
slave.” They say that a socialist economy will guarantee everyone’s basic
needs and so no one has to be subjected to “wage slavery.” But if that’s true,
why would anyone choose to work at all? Sure, some people may work here
and there when they feel bored, but why would most people work full-time
to produce the goods that other people need to live when they can get what
they need without working?
Some socialists try to evade this problem with the motto, “Those who
don’t work, don’t eat” and say they will deny freeloaders access to the
community’s resources (St. Paul gave this same advice in 2 Thessalonians
3:10 in order to deal with freeloaders in the early Church). But now the
injustice of “selling your labor-power to capitalists” has simply been
replaced with the privilege of “selling your labor-power to the state”—
which, unlike businesses in a free market, doesn’t have to compete for it.
Even if socialists reached their “post-state” communist utopia, there would
still be a class of workers in constant conflict with a class of moochers
trying to game the system.
THE KNOWLEDGE PROBLEM
If you have ever watched a flock of starlings, sometimes thousands of birds,
move in unison, then you know it’s a mesmerizing experience. How do they
all know to change direction together so quickly? It’s not like there is one
bird directing their movement like how a conductor directs an orchestra.
Instead, each individual bird receives a cue from the birds around him and
this sends an “information wave” through the whole flock letting them
know which way they should go.
The knowledge of how the flock should move is dispersed among many
birds. It isn’t in the hands of a single bird leader who directs everything, nor
could it be. And the same is true when it comes to the most important
economic knowledge: the “knowledge of the particular circumstances of
time and place” as 1974 economic Nobel Prize winner Friedrich Hayek
called it.
“We need to remember,” he said, “how much we have to learn in any
occupation after we have completed our theoretical training, how big a part
of our working life we spend learning particular jobs, and how valuable an
asset in all walks of life is knowledge of people, of local conditions, and
special circumstances.”36
This knowledge, which by its nature can’t be summed up in a statistic,
doesn’t exist in a single place for a central planner to use in his calculations.
Instead, it’s dispersed among millions of people who wouldn’t be able to
communicate it even if there were a calculus sophisticated enough to make
use of it all.
Economic knowledge dispersed among people also captures realities that
are—like the starlings—constantly changing.
Think about all the decisions that have to be made to produce something
as simple as a loaf of bread. The farmers have to decide what kinds of grain
to plant along with what kind of machinery to buy in order to harvest the
crops. The bakers have to decide what kinds of ovens to use and which
kinds of bread to make. The shipping companies have to decide which
kinds of trucks or rail cars to use to ship the product. Wholesalers have to
know how much bread to purchase from factories and retailers have to
know how much they need to purchase from the wholesalers. And now add
the complexity of the plastic used to wrap the loaves, which begins as oil
drilled from the earth.
In a free market, there’s a simple way to coordinate tens of thousands of
people who produce millions of tons of bread every year: prices. A central
planner doesn’t have to tell the entire “flock” not to buy a rare item in order
to prevent a shortage. Instead, individual producers will naturally respond
to increased demand by raising the price of the good. This incentivizes both
the consumer to buy less of the product and the producer to make more of
it. Lowering prices, on the other hand, incentivizes producers to stop
producing things that aren’t profitable and incentivizes consumers to reduce
unwanted surpluses.
In contrast to the idea of prices communicating information, Marx thought
that the price of a good should reflect how much work went into it, and thus
the price compensates the worker for his labor. To be fair to Marx, many
people feel this way. It is intuitive to think that when we pay for a good or a
service we are satisfying a balance that is owed for value created in the past.
But this is only partly true, because prices aren’t static descriptions of past
behavior—even if payments rendered do compensate for value provided
(which includes the labor used to create the product). Instead, prices are
constantly-changing “signal devices” that send information to buyers in the
same way wing positions send information to the birds in a flock.
When there is a shortage of rye, for example, the price of rye bread goes
up to signal to consumers that there is a shortage. The farmer doesn’t have
to call the store and have the manager tell the customers, “We’re low on
rye, so if you all buy a lot of it then it will be gone!” Through a long chain
of financial transactions, the storeowner learns from other people with
localized knowledge and he then changes the price of the rye bread.
The price change signals to the consumer that rye is scarce and so more
money has to be spent on each loaf to keep rye production viable. It also
signals enterprising suppliers that they have an opportunity to make a profit
if they spend the capital that is needed to deliver this scarce, desirable
product to customers. When products stop being desirable, consumers don’t
have to call farmers to let them know that. Their lack of purchasing leads
the storeowner to drop the price, and the producer learns that he needs to
respond to this change in demand.
But without free markets and the prices that go with them, socialist
planners have to make their best guesses about what kind of goods should
be produced and what services are worth providing. Historically, this leads
to the overproduction of unwanted goods and the underproduction of
wanted goods. This underproduction can lead to shortages of vital products
like food and medicine, as we saw in the famines and “bread lines” of the
Soviet Union.
In 1982, the New York Times noted how the Soviet Union’s official state
newspaper Pravda claimed that Soviet collective farming was more
productive than American capitalist farms. It then said, “Unfortunately for
the people in the food lines, statistics [about the Soviet Union] suggest
otherwise.” Not even Soviet propaganda could hide the inferiority of
planned economies to free ones. As the Times pointed out, while the
U.S.S.R. suffered shortages, “The United States, with less than 5 percent of
the labor force working in agriculture, keeps supermarkets stocked from
one end of the country to the other and still exports nearly a third of its farm
output.”37
CAN IT EVER WORK?
There have been small social “communes” that operated effectively with
this mentality, but not large socialist states. Even many of these communes
experienced difficulties because socialist principles often contradict human
nature (see chapter eight).
For example, when communal villages in Israel called kibbutzim (singular,
kibbutz) were first implemented in 1909, children slept in communal houses
and only saw their parents for a few hours a day. Couples were even
discouraged from having tea kettles in their apartment for fear that it would
encourage private time away from the community. Kibbutzim grew in
popularity throughout much of the twentieth century, but since the 1970s
most have fallen away from the strict communitarian guidelines that tried to
impose more radical socialist principles on their members.38
But other small-scale socialist experiments were not as successful.
In mid-nineteenth-century America, followers of Etienne Cabet started
their own Icarian colonies to bring his utopian dream to life. One of these
colonies, in Iowa, housed a dozen families and became the longest-running
non-religious commune in American history. Property was owned
communally and decisions were made collectively. But the colonies never
grew because the children ended up leaving.39 Religious monasteries can
make communal life sustainable only, it seems, because they’re small and
made up of adults who freely join them (and are driven by convictions other
than socialism).
“Fine,” a critic may say, “Maybe we have to allow people to have private
property, and the ability to exchange goods on the market, but isn’t there a
kind of socialism that still looks out for the poor in the midst of the free
market?”
We will address that question in the next chapter; but you should know
that the Church has been aware of this kind of “moderate socialism” and
still rejects it. Pope Pius XI said, “Such just demands and desire have
nothing in them now which is inconsistent with Christian truth, and much
less are they special to socialism. Those who work solely toward such ends
have, therefore, no reason to become socialists” (Quadragesimo Anno 115).
• Socialism’s mandated equality in wealth cannot incentivize people to do the most difficult or
necessary jobs.
• Central planners can never access the knowledge that is necessary to determine the amount and
variety of goods and services to produce, which inevitably leads to shortages.
32 Etienne Cabet’s, Voyage to Icaria (1842), https://www.marxists.org/subject/utopian/cabet/icarus.htm.
33 Pope Paul VI acknowledged the peril of those who avoid realistic solutions in favor of unrealistic utopianism when he said,
“The appeal to a utopia is often a convenient excuse for those who wish to escape from concrete tasks in order to take refuge in
an imaginary world. To live in a hypothetical future is a facile alibi for rejecting immediate responsibilities.”
34 A similar point is made in Justin Haskins, Socialism Is Evil: The Moral Case Against Marx’s Radical Dream (Boston: The
Henry Dearborn Institute for Liberty, 2018), 36.
35 Karl Marx, The German Ideology (1845), https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/german-ideology/ch01a.htm.
36 F.A. Hayek, “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 35, No. 4. (September 1945), 522.
37 John F. Burns, “Soviet Food Shortages: Grumbling And Excuses,” The New York Times (January 15, 1982),
https://www.nytimes.com/1982/01/15/world/soviet-food-shortages-grumbling-and-excuses.html.
38 Melford E. Spiro, “Utopia and Its Discontents: The Kibbutz and Its Historical Vicissitudes,” American Anthropologist, Vol.
106, No. 3 (September 2004), 556–568.
39 As one historian puts it, “communities dwindled and dissolved due to lack of able-bodied, hard-working members. Each time
they experienced a setback, they started anew, until finally there were no more young members—and there was no more fresh
energy—to continue the community.” Jyotsna Sreenivasan, Utopias in American History (Santa Barbara: ABC-CLIO, 2008),
188.
4
• Catholics cannot support the establishment of socialist policies even through democratic means.
40 Frank Newport, “The Meaning of ‘Socialism’ to Americans Today,” Gallup (October 4, 2018),
https://news.gallup.com/opinion/polling-matters/243362/meaning-socialism-americans-today.aspx.
41 Friedrich Engels, “The Principles of Communism” (1847), https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/11/prin-
com.htm.
42 Shaw said that Chesterton’s crimes were those “of imagination and humor, not of malice,” while Chesterton said of Shaw, “It is
necessary to disagree with him as much as I do in order to admire him as much as I do,”
https://www.jstor.org/stable/40681668?seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents.
43 Chesterton, following a model proposed by fellow Catholic author Hilaire Belloc, argued that it was not wealth that should be
re-distributed among people but the means to produce wealth. This “distributism” would take power away from governments
and factories and return it to individual families who could produce their own livelihoods. That’s why Chesterton is reported to
have said, “The problem with capitalism is not that there are too many Capitalists, but that there are too few.” (Chesterton even
blamed capitalism for “killing the family” because it drew men away from the home to work in factories and kept them from
being self-sufficient.)
44 Dorothy Day, “Communists Communicate,” The Catholic Worker (January 1937), 5,
https://www.catholicworker.org/dorothyday/articles/527.html. Cited in Stephen Beale, “The Dorothy Day Few of Us Know,”
Crisis (March 19, 2013), https://www.crisismagazine.com/2013/the-dorothy-day-few-of-us-know.
45 “We believe that social security legislation, now billed as a great victory for the poor and for the worker, is a great defeat for
Christianity. It is an acceptance of the idea of force and compulsion. It is an acceptance of Cain’s statement, on the part of the
employer. ‘Am I my brother’s keeper?’ Since the employer can never be trusted to give a family wage, nor take care of the
worker as he takes care of his machine when it is idle, the state must enter in and compel help on his part.” Dorothy Day, “On
Pilgrimage,” The Catholic Worker (January 1973) 2, 6, https://www.catholicworker.org/dorothyday/articles/150.pdf. “Actually
if the State, City, and the whole secular world with its ‘inspector generals’ and bureaucracies did not demand our conformity to
such insane standards of luxury, Holy Mother the Church would not have to be pleading for funds for schools, and books, and
buses, and health and welfare aids. (As St. Hilary wrote a thousand (or a few days) ago, ‘The less we ask of Caesar, the less we
will have to render to Caesar.)’” Dorothy Day, “More About Holy Poverty. Which Is Voluntary Poverty,” The Catholic Worker
(February 1945) 1-2, https://www.catholicworker.org/dorothyday/articles/527.html.
46 Maurice Isserman, The Other American: The Life Of Michael Harrington (New York: PublicAffairs, 2000), 70.
47 Michael Harrington, Socialism: Past and Future (New York: Little, Brown & Co., 1989), 197.
48 “About us,” Democratic Socialists of America, https://www.dsausa.org/about-us/.
49 Danielle Kurtzleben, “Getting To Know The DSA,” National Public Radio (July 19, 2018),
https://www.npr.org/2018/07/19/630394669/getting-to-know-the-dsa.
50 Neal Meyer, “What is Democratic Socialism,” Jacobin (July 2018), https://jacobinmag.com/2018/07/democratic-socialism-
bernie-sanders-social-democracy-alexandria-ocasio-cortez.
51 Friedrich Engels, Origin of the Family, Private Property, and the State (1884),
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/download/pdf/origin_family.pdf.
52 Lillian Cicerchia laments that, when it comes to abortion, Catholic hospitals aren’t “compelled to offer the service” though she
hopes that through government-backed universal health care, “The waiting periods, the counseling, the religious exemptions,
the feticide laws, [would] all have to go.” Lillian Cicerchia, “What Medicare for All Means for Abortion Rights,” Jacobin
(January 18, 2019), https://www.jacobinmag.com/2019/01/medicare-for-all-abortion-hyde-trap-laws-reproductive-justice.
53 Rationing of palliative care leading people to feel that assisted suicide is the only way to treat their pain has become a problem
in Canada’s nationalized health care program. See Peter Stockland, “Assisted dying was supposed to be an option. To some
patients, it looks like the only one,” Maclean’s (June 22, 2018), https://www.macleans.ca/society/assisted-dying-was-supposed-
to-be-an-option-to-some-patients-it-looks-like-the-only-one/.
54 Neal Meyer, “What is Democratic Socialism,” Jacobin (July 2018), https://jacobinmag.com/2018/07/democratic-socialism-
bernie-sanders-social-democracy-alexandria-ocasio-cortez.
Part Two
The Birth of
Socialism
5
Some people say Catholics not only can be socialists, they should be
socialists because that was how the first Christians lived. David Bentley
Hart says the book of Acts describes how Christians “affirmed their new
faith by living in a single dwelling, selling their fixed holdings,
redistributing their wealth ‘as each needed,’ and owning all possessions
communally.”55 Jose Mena assures us that “no God-fearing Christian would
want to condemn the apostolic Communism described in Acts 2 and 4.”56
Others say socialism comes straight from Jesus himself, as can be seen in
Barbara Ehrenreich’s description of Jesus as a “wine-guzzling vagrant and
precocious socialist.”57 Erika Christakis argues in Time that “Jesus would
advocate a tax rate somewhere between 50 percent (in the vein of, ‘If you
have two coats, give one to the man who has none’) and 100 percent (if you
want to get into heaven, be poor). Mostly, he suggested giving all your
money up for the benefit of others.”58
But when we examine the biblical and historical evidence, a different
picture emerges: the first Christians lived in communities that practiced
voluntary charity rather than mandatory Communism.
WAS JESUS A SOCIALIST?
As Trent has argued in his previous book Counterfeit Christs, Jesus was not
a socialist because he did not seek to either abolish private property or
centralize wealth redistribution.59 Jesus commanded people to give money
to the poor (Luke 12:33), but he never specified whether that money should
be given directly to the poor, donated to charities, or be taxed and
redistributed though government programs.
St. Luke even describes how a person following Jesus said to him,
“Teacher, bid my brother divide the inheritance with me.” Instead of
helping this man “redistribute wealth” Jesus answered him, “Man, who
made me a judge or divider over you?” Jesus then said to the crowd
following him, “Take heed, and beware of all covetousness; for a man’s life
does not consist in the abundance of his possessions” (Luke 12:13–15).
But if that’s true, why did Jesus criticize the rich and say in Matthew
19:24 that it was easier for a camel to pass through the eye of a needle than
for a rich man to enter heaven?
In the first century, ordinary people could grow or acquire only enough
food to meet their basic needs, and any surplus was shared with relatives or
kin who were not so well off. The rich in Jesus’ time were seen as hoarders
whose excess consumption directly contributed to everyone else’s poverty.
That’s why Jesus condemned the “rich fool” who stored up resources in his
barns instead of putting them to use to help others (Luke 12:16–21). As a
Mediterranean proverb declares, “Every rich man is a thief or the son of a
thief.”60
But this does not mean that Jesus wanted every rich person (much less
every person) to give away all he owned.
When Jesus agreed to dine with the diminutive tax collector Zacchaeus,
the man said, “Behold, Lord, the half of my goods I give to the poor; and if
I have defrauded any one of anything, I restore it fourfold” (Luke 19:8).
Instead of saying, “Half isn’t good enough! Sell everything and follow me,”
Jesus said, “Today salvation has come to this house” (Luke 19:9).
Zacchaeus and other wealthy disciples of Jesus, like Joseph of Arimathea
(who could afford an expensive rock tomb for Jesus’ burial), show that it is
not impossible for the rich to inherit the kingdom of God—as long as they
do not serve money instead of God (Matt. 6:24) or let a “love of money”
become the root of their evils (1 Tim. 6:10).
WERE THE FIRST CHRISTIANS SOCIALISTS?
The second chapter of the Acts of the Apostles records how Peter’s first
sermon after the Jewish festival of Pentecost (which Jews call Shavuot)
resulted in 3,000 people being baptized and joining the fledgling Christian
church. The Jewish historian Josephus and St. Luke, the author of Acts,
confirm that many of the visitors to Jerusalem at this time were pilgrims
from all over the Roman Empire. But instead of returning home after the
festival, these new converts “devoted themselves to the apostles’ teaching
and fellowship, to the breaking of bread and the prayers” (Acts 2:42).
The early Church now had a “blessing of a problem” on its hands. These
visitors needed help finding a place to live and a way to sustain themselves.
Fortunately, the Christian community in Jerusalem responded generously so
that “all who believed were together and had all things in common; and they
sold their possessions and goods and distributed them to all, as any had
need” (Acts 2:45). But does this arrangement entail “apostolic
Communism”?
First, there is doubt about whether first-century Christians completely
renounced private property. Acts 2:45 uses an imperfect verb to say of their
possessions, “They were selling and were dividing them to all” (in Greek,
hyparxeis epipraskon kai diemerizon auta) instead of saying in the simple
past tense, “They sold and distributed them to all.” This seems to describe a
continuing process of selling extra property and goods in order to support
the poor. But in order to do that, Christians would have had to retain some
property even after becoming believers.
Moreover, although the New Testament contains many commands to help
the poor, it does not contain any commands for believers to give up their
possessions to communal ownership. If that were the case, we would expect
the biblical authors to discuss the issue of tithing, or required giving. But as
New Testament scholar Craig Blomberg points out, although tithing was
commanded of God’s people in the Old Testament, “no New Testament text
ever mandates a tithe but rather commands generous and sacrificial giving
instead.”61
This can be seen in St. Paul’s petition to the Corinthians that they give to a
collection for poor believers in Judea. Paul never commanded them to do
this but instead he hoped it would be seen “not as an exaction but as a
willing gift. . . . Each one must do as he has made up his mind, not
reluctantly or under compulsion, for God loves a cheerful giver” (2 Cor.
9:5,7).
But even if the first Christians renounced some or all of their private
property, that doesn’t mean every Christian is bound to do the same. There
is a difference between a description of what some Christians did and a
prescription of what all Christians ought to do.
For example, the New Testament describes Christians meeting in private
homes for worship (1 Cor. 16:19), but that doesn’t mean it is wrong for
Christians to worship in churches today. Likewise, the description of
Christians selling property and bringing the proceeds to the apostles’ feet
for communal distribution (Acts 4:34–35) doesn’t mean this behavior was a
moral requirement for all believers then—or is now.
In response, critics like Hart contend that the story of Ananias and
Sapphira shows that renouncing property and giving it to the apostles was
mandatory because the couple was struck down for withholding their
property from the collection. But a careful reading of the passage shows
that the couple’s sin was not their mere withholding of property. Peter says
the property was theirs before they sold it and they would have retained
their right to use it even after selling it (Acts 5:4). Rather, it was their lie to
the apostles who represented God’s authority that incurred the fatal
judgment against them.
WAS THE EARLY CHURCH SOCIALIST?
Ancient pagan critics like Lucian and Christian apologists like Justin
Martyr both attest to Christians living a common life together and sharing
what they had with one another.62 This isn’t surprising, given that by the
second century Jews who worshipped Jesus had been expelled from the
synagogues and the Romans often persecuted people who openly admitted
to being Christian. In the absence of civil or religious support, Christians
relied on one another to survive.
But there’s no reason why we must infer from this communal living was
or is essential to the Christian faith. The prescription for us may be more
general. As Pope Benedict XVI notes, “As the Church grew, this radical
form of material communion could not in fact be preserved. But its essential
core remained: within the community of believers there can never be room
for a poverty that denies anyone what is needed for a dignified life” (Deus
Caritas Est 20).
As Christians became more accepted in the Roman Empire, reports of
their generosity preceded them. The Roman emperor Julian the Apostate
even griped about how Christians “support not only their own poor but ours
as well; all men see that our people lack aid from us.”63 Once Roman
persecution ended, some Christians were able to climb the social ladder and
achieve wealth, which they were not required to renounce but could
prudently manage instead.
Hart claims that the early Christians always condemned the accumulation
of wealth; and some of them, like Ambrose, did—when it was not put to
good use in serving the poor. But Hart goes further when he claims that the
Church Fathers condemned the possession of wealth itself regardless of
how it’s used. He asserts “The great John Chrysostom frequently issued
pronouncements on wealth and poverty that make Karl Marx and Mikhail
Bakunin sound like timid conservatives.”64 But from Marx’s perspective,
Chrysostom probably sounded like an enemy of the socialist cause when he
wrote:
A rich man is one thing, a rapacious man is another: an affluent man is
one thing, a covetous man is another. Make clear distinctions, and do not
confuse things which are diverse. Are you a rich man? I forbid you not.
Are you a rapacious man? I denounce you. Have you property of your
own? Enjoy it. Do you take the property of others? I will not hold my
peace.65
In the centuries after the fall of Rome in A.D. 476, invading northern
tribes, plagues, and poor crop yields decimated the European population.
Apart from a few Christian monasteries that preserved ancient knowledge,
what remained were powerful local rulers whose wealth consisted of land
they owned and the peasants, called serfs, who were subject to them (a
system we call feudalism).
Today, serfdom is considered on par with slavery, but in the Middle Ages
it was considered a moral improvement because whereas slaves had the
same value as livestock, serfs were recognized as persons made in the
image of God.66 As persons they were baptized and had rights their feudal
lord had to respect, though they did not have meaningful freedom. They
were forced to farm for a lord (or one of his vassals), who in return
provided them with food, shelter, and protection. And, unlike slaves, serfs
could own property and keep some of what they produced.
This is important because the concept of serfdom will be referenced both
in the arguments of the true “first socialists” of the nineteenth century and
in the writings of their twentieth-century critics. The latter claimed that
socialism does not move humanity forward to a utopian ideal but that it
takes it backward on a ruinous “road to serfdom” that turns the state into the
new lord, making the rest of us its servants.
It’s important to remember . . .
• Jesus required his followers to help the poor, but he did not tell them to support government
confiscation and allocation of wealth.
• The early Church practiced charity but did not require believers to renounce private property or
support what we would now call socialism.
55 David Bentley Hart, “Can We Please Relax About ‘Socialism’?” The New York Times (April 27, 2019),
https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/opinion/sunday/socialism.html.
56 Jose Mena, “The Catholic turn to socialism is something to celebrate,” Catholic Herald (May 30, 2019),
https://catholicherald.co.uk/commentandblogs/2019/05/30/the-catholic-turn-to-socialism-is-something-to-celebrate/.
57 Barbara Ehrenreich, Nickel and Dimed: On (Not) Getting By in America (New York: Henry Holt and Company, 2001), 68.
58 Erika Christakis, “Is Paul Ryan’s Budget ‘Un-Christian’?” Time Magazine, August 14, 2012,
http://ideas.time.com/2012/08/14/why-paul-ryans- budget-unchristian/.
59 According to economist Lawrence Reed, “The fact is, one can scour the scriptures with a fine-tooth comb and find nary a word
from Jesus that endorses the forcible redistribution of wealth by political authorities. None, period.” Lawrence Reed, Render
Unto Caesar: Was Jesus a Socialist? (Atlanta, GA: Foundation for Economic Education, 2015), Kindle edition.
60 “By and large, only the dishonorable rich, the dishonorable nonelites, and those beyond the pale of public opinion (such as city
elites, governors, regional kings) could accumulate wealth with impunity. This they did in a number of ways, notably by
trading, tax collecting, and money lending. . . . In the first century [these methods] would all be considered dishonorable and
immoral forms of usury.” Bruce Malina, The New Testament World: Insights from Cultural Anthropology (Louisville, KY:
Westminster John Knox Press, 2001), 104–105.
61 Craig Blomberg, “Neither Capitalism nor Socialism: A Biblical Theology of Economics,” Journal of Markets & Morality, Vol.
15 No. 1 (Spring 2012), 211.
62 Justin Martyr wrote to the Roman Emperor “[W]e who valued above all things the acquisition of wealth and possessions, now
bring what we have into a common stock, and communicate to every one in need . . .” (First Apology, 14). Lucian had a more
cynical view saying in The Passing of Peregrinus, “they despise all things indiscriminately and consider them common
property, receiving such doctrines traditionally without any definite evidence. So if any charlatan and trickster, able to profit by
occasions, comes among them, he quickly acquires sudden wealth by imposing upon simple folk.”
63 Julian the Apostate, Letter to Arsacius.
64 David Bentley Hart, “Can We Please Relax About ‘Socialism’?” The New York Times (April 27, 2019),
https://www.nytimes.com/2019/04/27/opinion/sunday/socialism.html.
65 Homily II on Eutropius.
66 Serf comes from the Latin servus, which means “slave” and while serfdom is considered on par with slavery today, in the
medieval world serfdom was considered a moral improvement to Roman slavery. In the time of Jesus a slave was not a person
but rather, as one historian notes, “a slave was res, a thing, property, an object . . . wounding or killing a slave was usually
counted as damage to property.”
6
Around the corner from the Louvre in Paris is the small Café de la Régence,
a haven for chess players both literal and metaphorical. On an August
afternoon in 1844, two German twenty-somethings, Karl Marx and
Friedrich Engels, sat among these players for lunch.
Engels had just come from working at a mill in England where his parents
had sent him in hopes he would abandon his radical philosophies. Instead,
the poverty and filthy conditions he witnessed in the mill towns motivated
him to write The Condition of the Working Class in England. This
confirmed Marx’s belief that history was just one long story about the rich
oppressing the poor, but this time factory owners took the place of feudal
lords or Roman slave drivers.
There had been self-identified socialists before Marx, but they were
“utopian dreamers” who hoped the rich would adopt their elaborate plans
for a better world.67 Marx and Engels, in contrast, believed that a just
society was achieved not by persuading kings and queens but by equipping
the pawns to overthrow them. And so, in 1848, they published The
Communist Manifesto, which declared, “Let the ruling classes tremble at a
Communistic revolution. The proletarians (poor workers) have nothing to
lose but their chains. They have a world to win.”68
We can’t understand the first socialists, though, unless we understand the
capitalism they rejected. And we can’t understand capitalism unless we
examine it at its origins in fourteenth-century Italy.
TRADING FEUDALISM FOR CAPITALISM
If you were glancing over Leonardo Da Vinci’s desk as he painted The Last
Supper, you might have seen this reminder in one of his notebooks: “Learn
multiplication from the root from Maestro Luca.” If Da Vinci was history’s
most famous inventor, then his friend, the Franciscan friar Luca Pacioli,
was its most famous accountant. You have probably never heard of him, but
his mathematics textbook has been called “the most influential book on
capitalism” ever written.69
To see why, we need to return to the issue of trade.
You’ll recall that serfs could own some property; but it was always
meager and what their property produced was primarily traded with
relatives. Some could amass enough goods to sell at local fairs, but no one
got rich with this kind of trading. That began to change in the thirteenth and
fourteenth centuries when mercantile capitalists like Marco Polo began
transporting large numbers of goods from locations where they were cheap
over long distances in order to sell them in places where they were
expensive.
Other merchants wanted these profits without personally making a 7,000-
mile trek into China, so they formed companies that provided the money (or
capital) to fund these trading expeditions. The investors in these “joint-
stock” companies would receive returns from successful expeditions and
share the losses from unsuccessful ones, thereby minimizing risk and
encouraging more investors to join the company. As more investors joined,
companies were able to use some of their profit to grow their enterprise.
Markets had always existed in one form or another since antiquity, but
now wealth could be created instead of just being discovered, and that
meant it could be reinvested to create more wealth. Hence, capitalism (in
the nascent form of “merchant capitalism”) was born.
As these companies grew and global trade increased, there came to be a
shortage in precious metals like gold and silver that were used to mint
coins. In addition, transporting coins became a hazardous way of moving
wealth because caravans could be robbed and ships often sank. Banks
became a safer place to deposit wealth because a person could deposit coins
in one area and then withdraw the same amount in another area through a
banknote. But while a local, traveling merchant only had to keep track of
how many coins were in his purse, trading companies had to keep track of
hundreds or even thousands of transactions taking place across different
continents.
And that’s where Da Vinci’s friend Master Luca enters the picture.
Two years after Columbus discovered the New World and opened up even
more trading opportunities, Pacioli published a summary of mathematics
that included instructions for performing “double-entry book keeping.” This
method of accounting requires two entries for every transaction: one for the
debited account on the left side of the ledger and one for the credited
account on the right. Both columns should add up to the same amount,
which helps prevent errors and allows for more complex transactions.
Jewish merchants had used this tidy method for centuries, but the printing
press made Pacioli’s description of it accessible to a growing class of
entrepreneurs who were leading an economic revolution.
For the first time in human history, wealth was not something that
belonged solely to lords who merely inherited it from other’s labor. Now
men like Josiah Wedgwood could create wealth through their ingenuity and
effort. Wedgewood grew up in poverty as the youngest of thirteen children,
but by the middle of the eighteenth century he had started a pottery business
that eventually produced affordable ceramics for palaces and humble homes
alike. He advertised pottery as “Queen’s Ware” and pioneered the use of
retail methods like catalogues and money-back guarantees.70 Wedgewood
was also an abolitionist who fought the slave trade and saw businesses that
used efficient mass production as the moral alternative to slavery. The
expansion of private business also drove down the cost of goods so that the
average person could have access to goods that once belonged only to
royalty.
This was true not just of Wedgewood’s pottery but also of basic
necessities like bread, milk, meat, and medicine, the wider availability of
which vastly improved the quality of life—and the span of life—for all
workers. For example, it took tens of thousands of years for the global
population to reach 600 million by the year 1700. But in just a hundred
years the population grew to 900 million, and by the year 1900 it had hit
1.65 billion.71 In other words, thanks to economic advancements, hundreds
of millions of people reached adulthood and had families of their own who
would have otherwise died young of starvation or disease.
CAPITALISM’S MELANCHOLY MADNESS
As cities expanded to accommodate rapidly growing businesses, the
resulting influx of people led to crowded, unsanitary, and dangerous places.
In his 1854 novel Hard Times, Charles Dickens describes a fictional version
of Manchester, England called Coketown, whose red bricks had become
choked by smoke and ash from the numerous mills. He writes, “It had a
black canal in it, and a river that ran purple with ill-smelling dye, and vast
piles of building full of windows where there was a rattling and a trembling
all day long, and where the piston of the steam-engine worked
monotonously up and down, like the head of an elephant in a state of
melancholy madness.”72
Engels echoed Dickens descriptions of the town’s “measureless filth and
stench” and described it as disease-ridden and indicative of how the poor
“must really have reached the lowest stage of humanity.”73 Engels also
believed that workers had better wages and quality of life before the
Industrial Revolution when they worked on farms.74 Marx and Engels
predicted in The Communist Manifesto that English workers would no
longer tolerate this oppression and would rise up against their capitalist
overlords. But the revolution never came, partly because the English
government passed laws that restricted child labor, regulated workplaces,
and improved public sanitation.
A similar episode took place in the U.S. five decades later, when Upton
Sinclair published installments of his novel The Jungle in a socialist
newspaper in 1905. It depicted the grim conditions of Chicago meatpacking
plants through a fictional story about a Lithuanian immigrant named Jurgis
Rudkus. Sinclair’s descriptions of the plants are like a trip through Dante’s
inferno where workers endure unique, hellish conditions based on their
tasks rather than their sins. For example, some men get their fingernails
peeled off as they prepare meat while others fall into steam vats and have
their remains turned into lard.75
The American author Jack London called Sinclair’s book “the Uncle
Tom’s Cabin of wage slavery” and Sinclair hoped it would spark a socialist
revolution in the same way that that book helped ignite the Civil War.76 But
the book’s most notable accomplishment was spurring passage of the 1906
Pure Food and Drug Act, which created what is now known as the Food and
Drug Administration. Food was now safer, but socialism now seemed less
attainable: a fact Sinclair noted when he said of his book, “I aimed at the
public’s heart, and by accident I hit it in the stomach.”77
CAPITALISM’S GREATEST SIN
Although inhuman working conditions (which the Church also condemned
along with socialism) played a part in socialist arguments, they were not
socialism’s primary complaint. Instead, the greatest injustice of capitalism
was that workers depended on wages from capitalists and they were cheated
out of the wages they truly deserved.
Engels said that having to earn a wage at all put workers “in the most
revolting, inhuman position conceivable for a human being.” He even
claimed that slaves and serfs were better off than nineteenth-century lower-
class workers:
The slave is assured of a bare livelihood by the self-interest of his master,
the serf has at least a scrap of land on which to live; each has at worst a
guarantee for life itself. But the proletarian must depend upon himself
alone, and is yet prevented from so applying his abilities as to be able to
rely upon them.78
Marx further protested the fact that mass-production techniques multiplied
worker productivity but worker compensation did not increase at the same
rate. He concluded that capitalists were stealing this “surplus value” of a
worker’s labor and calling it profit. Marx argued instead for a “labor value”
of a worker’s labor that an employee could redeem from a “socially owned”
source of income based on how long or hard he worked.79 But in order to do
this, capitalists would have to be stripped of their means of production and
prevented from retaining profits that belonged to their employees.
At the same time Marx and Engels published The Communist Manifesto,
revolutions were breaking out across Europe, overthrowing constitutional
monarchies in places like France, Denmark, and Hungary and establishing a
free press and parliamentary governments in their place. A few decades
later, labor riots broke out in America and socialists captured the city of
Paris and ruled it for nearly two weeks.80 All this prompted Pope Leo XIII
to write an encyclical on these “new things,” in which he acknowledged
that “the discussion is not easy, nor is it void of danger” because there are
“crafty agitators” who “pervert men’s judgments and to stir up the people to
revolt.”
Even still, the pope defended his foray into politics and economics in
Rerum Novarum because “the responsibility of the apostolic office urges us
to treat the question of set purpose and in detail, in order that no
misapprehension may exist as to the principles which truth and justice
dictate for its settlement” (2).
• Early socialists seized on these social injustices to argue that capitalism itself needed to be
abandoned in order to protect the dignity of workers.
67 This can be seen in the writings of figures like Henri Saint-Simon and Robert Owens. For precursors see J.C. Davis Utopia and
the Ideal Society: A Study of English Utopian Writing, 1516–1700 (1983).
68 Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party (1848),
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch04.htm.
69 Tim Harford, “Is this the most influential work in the history of capitalism?” BBC (October 23, 2017),
https://www.bbc.com/news/business-41582244.
70 Mark Dodgson & David Gann, Innovation: A Very Short Introduction (New York: Oxford University Press, 2010), 9.
71 Peter R. Cox, Demography, 5th ed. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1976), 195.
72 Charles Dickens, Hard Times, ed. Graham Law (Toronto: Broadview Press, 2000), 60.
73 Friedrich Engels, “The Great Towns,” (1845), https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/condition-working-
class/ch04.htm.
74 Modern research refutes this. See for example Peter H. Lindert and Jeffrey G. Williamson, “English Workers’ Living Standards
during the Industrial Revolution: A New Look,” The Economic History Review New Series, Vol. 36, No. 1 (February 1983),
20–25.
75 “. . . and as for the other men, who worked in tank rooms full of steam, and in some of which there were open vats near the
level of the floor, their peculiar trouble was that they fell into the vats; and when they were fished out, there was never enough
of them left to be worth exhibiting—sometimes they would be overlooked for days, till all but the bones of them had gone out
to the world as Durham’s Pure Leaf Lard!” Upton Sinclair, The Jungle (New York: Doubleday, Page & Company, 1906), 117.
76 Earle Labor, Jack London: An American Life (New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux, 2013), 230.
77 Carl Jensen, Stories that Changed America: Muckrakers of the 20th Century (New York, Seven Stories Press, 2000), 56.
78 Friedrich Engels, The Condition of the Working Class in England (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), 127.
79 “He receives a certificate from society that he has furnished such-and-such an amount of labor (after deducting his labor for the
common funds); and with this certificate, he draws from the social stock of means of consumption as much as the same amount
of labor cost. The same amount of labor which he has given to society in one form, he receives back in another.” Karl Marx,
Critique of the Gotha Programme (1875), https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1875/gotha/.
80 These include the 1886 Haymarket riot and the radical anarchist Paris commune that ruled the city during the Spring of 1871.
7
• The Church teaches that socialism is wrong because it denies man’s natural right both to acquire
wealth and property and to dispose of them as he pleases.
• Socialism is flawed because it fails to see that private property allows people to carry out their
moral duties to one another, such as by providing for one’s family or creating goods and services
for one’s fellow man.
81 Jean Jacques Rousseau, “On the Origin of the Inequality of Mankind: The Second Part” (1754),
https://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/rousseau/inequality/ch02.htm.
82 P.J. Proudhon, Qu’est-ce que la Propriété?, ou, recherches sur le principe du droit et du Gouvernement (Paris, 1840), 2.
83 Karl Marx, “Letter to J. B. Schweizer ‘On Proudhon’” (1865),
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1865/letters/65_01_24.htm.
84 “That the civil government should at its option intrude into and exercise intimate control over the family and the household is a
great and pernicious error. True, if a family finds itself in exceeding distress, utterly deprived of the counsel of friends, and
without any prospect of extricating itself, it is right that extreme necessity be met by public aid, since each family is a part of
the commonwealth” (Rerum Novarum 14).
85 De Finibus, Book III.
86 Marissa Fessenden, “Making a Sandwich from Scratch Took This Man Six Months,” Smithsonian Magazine (September 18,
2015), https://www.smithsonianmag.com/smart-news/making-sandwich-scratch-took-man-six-months-180956674/.
87 Adam Smith, An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Vol. 2 (London, William Clowes and Sons,
1835), 55.
8
• Socialism is wrong because it tries to equalize that which is essentially unequal (e.g., talents and
abilities) and prevents human beings from charitably relying on one another because of this natural
inequality.
• Work is not evil in itself, but has become burdensome because of original sin. However, human
beings can redeem work by offering their bodily labor for the good of others and themselves.
88 Clarence Darrow, The Essential Words and Writings of Clarence Darrow, eds. Edward J. Larson and Jack Marshall (New York:
Random House, 2007), 236.
89 Jean-Jacques Rousseau, Emile or On Education, trans. Allan Bloom (USA: Basic Books, 1979), 237.
90 Stephen White, Communism and its Collapse (New York: Routledge, 2001), 3.
91 Peter Gahan, Bernard Shaw and Beatrice Webb on Poverty and Equality in the Modern World, 1905–1914 (Palgrave
Macmillan, 2017), 106.
92 “Dialog of Catherine of Siena,” 4.2.5, https://www.ccel.org/ccel/catherine/dialog.iv.ii.vii.html.
93 Paul Lafargue, The Right to be Lazy (1883), https://www.marxists.org/archive/lafargue/1883/lazy/ch01.htm.
94 “Tradinista Manifesto,” https://tradinista.tumblr.com/manifesto.
95 Mark Schmitt, “The case for helping the ‘unwilling to work,’” Vox (February 20, 2019),
https://www.vox.com/polyarchy/2019/2/20/18233515/unwilling-to-work-jobs-employment-aoc-green-new-deal.
96 Aaron Bastani, Fully Automated Luxury Communism (New York, Verso, 2019).
97 “What is Democratic Socialism?” https://www.dsausa.org/about-us/what-is-democratic-socialism/. Other writers claim that
once technology advances enough we will be like characters in the Star Trek series who do not worry about acquiring scare
resources and focus on leisure and exploration. Of course, even people on the Enterprise had jobs and some of them seemed
quite demanding (not to mention hazardous for the red shirted crew members).
Part Three
The Rise
of Socialism
9
Marx said, “There is only one way in which the murderous death agonies of
the old society and the bloody birth throes of the new society can be
shortened, simplified and concentrated, and that way is revolutionary
terror.”98 Marx and Engels believed this worker’s revolution would take
place in a highly industrialized country like England where factory workers
would overthrow their capitalist overlords. But the revolution actually
arrived in an economically backward part of the world: Russia.
WAR AND REVOLUTION
In 1898, industrial workers made up less than 3 percent of the Russian
population, and socialists wondered how the peasant population could ever
be unified to overthrow their royal rulers.99 In 1901, Vladimir Ulyanov, a
member of the Russian Social Democratic Labor party, published a
pamphlet entitled What Must Be Done? In it he argued that a political party
must lead the small working class to a socialist victory and “professional
revolutionaries” would have to maintain control over these workers even
after the revolution, lest they backslide into the old order.
Fearing for his personal safety, Ulyanov published the pamphlet under the
pen name Vladimir Lenin and he would have to wait until 1917 before his
revolutionary vision came to pass.
In that year, massive fatalities and food shortages related to Russia’s
involvement in World War I turned public opinion against the monarchy.
Groups of workers councils, called soviets, led revolts in major cities, and
Tsar Nicholas II abdicated the throne. Lenin returned from exile in
Germany to lead the majority (or Bolshevik) faction of the Russian socialist
party.
During this period, the Bolshevik “Red Army” enacted a policy of militant
Communism, taking up civil war against the opposing “White Army” of
anti-communist Russians. They banned private enterprise, nationalized
industry, and confiscated grain from farmers for central planning purposes.
This proved to be a disaster and contributed to a famine that killed five
million people. But the Bolsheviks prevailed, and in 1922 the country was
reconstituted as the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics, or U.S.S.R.
THE TEN-POUND NAIL IN THE COFFIN
In 1875, Marx had proposed that in the highest phase of Communism,
“after labor has become not only a means of life but life’s prime want” and
automation has produced more resources than are demanded, society can
live by the motto, “From each according to his ability, to each according to
his needs.”100 But until then, people must live under a lower phase of
Communism and would have to settle for the motto, “To each according to
his contribution.”
Under this view, workers would receive “labor vouchers” they could
exchange for goods and services. That way, as Lenin put it, “every worker,
therefore, receives from society as much as he has given to it.”101 Soviet
factories and businesses were then encouraged to produce as many goods as
possible so that they could be easily distributed to everyone.
But remember the knowledge problem we discussed in chapter three. No
central planner can ever know the millions of variables that go into deciding
when it’s worthwhile to produce a good or offer a service. For example,
most hardware stores carry dozens if not hundreds of different kinds of
nails. How does the store know how many and what kind of nails to stock?
How does the factory know what type and number of nails to produce?
The answer is that individual purchases of nails communicate information
about each product. This information is then reflected in prices that owners
set in order to maintain profits based on available supplies and consumer
demand, as well as in production decisions made by nail manufacturers.
Through millions of individual exchanges enough information is
communicated— without any central organization—for business owners to
set and, more importantly, change prices for all their goods and services to
reflect what is going on in the market.
But unlike capitalist economies that allow prices (and production) to
adjust according to consumer choice, the Soviet system set rigid production
targets, and consumers just had to “choose” whatever was offered to them.
So, instead of a factory producing nails based on sales reports from
retailers, the government would just tell a nail factory that 100,000 nails
were needed by the end of the month. Even though socialist factories
couldn’t go out of business, coercive threats motivated them to meet the
government’s quotas, even when this led to absurd results and provided no
benefit to consumers.
For example, if the government’s production target was based on the
number of nails the factory had to produce, then the factory could simply
make 100,000 tiny, useless nails in order to quickly satisfy the quota. If, on
the other hand, the target was based on the gross weight of the nails, the
factory could produce ten tons of large, clunky nails that were easier to
make than well-crafted nails. And, as one researcher notes: it wasn’t just
nails the Soviet economy had trouble producing:
The prevalence and severity of shoddy workmanship in goods produced
under the Soviet production system boggles the American mind. Factories
turned out washing machines that did nothing but wet clothes, sewing
machines missing essential screws, hair dryers that immediately short-
circuited, and refrigerators without motors (yet Samarkand Refrigerator
Factory won numerous awards and increased annual subsidies for
continually exceeding its production plan).102
No central computer system today, much less a planning committee a
century ago, could calculate the supply and demand variables for every
conceivable product on the market. Even if it could, as Hayek showed,
getting the knowledge for those calculations is impossible because it’s
dispersed across millions of producers and consumers.
Without prices, planners would need consumer surveys that relied on
honest opinions that don’t change in the future. For example, people may
say they want more educational programming on television but end up
watching (and thus paying for) reality television or cable news. That’s why
a socialist system of supply that is blind to demand often leads to the
overproduction of useless products and the underproduction, or shortages,
of vitally important products.
But if socialism is impossible, some may ask, how did the Soviet Union
exist for nearly seventy years under this system?
The answer is that the Soviets could partially avoid the knowledge
problem by relying on prices determined by other, market-based economies
to guide their production targets. This wasn’t ideal, and it still led to
shortages, but it allowed the system to limp along until it finally collapsed
at the end of the twentieth century. In the meantime, the economic
consequences of the system were often hidden from the world, including its
most horrifying consequence: the Ukrainian famine.
MURDER BY ANY OTHER NAME
In 1921, Lenin allowed people to participate in “state-controlled capitalism”
(strict government oversight of private businesses) in order to get the
economy on track. This resulted in some farmers getting rich and being
derided as kulaks, from the Ukrainian for “tight fist.” But in 1928, under the
leadership of Lenin’s successor Joseph Stalin, the Soviets launched their
“Five-Year Plan” to industrialize the country and make it capable of
defending itself against both foreign and domestic threats.
In the real world, a country can’t just over-produce goods in order to
alleviate poverty. It has to choose which resources to produce, and the
Soviets focused on heavy industry at the expense of things like food
production. In 1929, Stalin seized the Kulaks’ assets and “liquidated” the
Kulaks themselves through murder and deportation. Soviet propaganda
blamed the country’s food shortages on “greedy Kulaks,” but the true cause
were Soviet troops that confiscated livestock and grain from peasants of all
classes because those materials “belonged” to the government’s central
planners.
The famine that swept through Ukraine between 1932–1933, killing five
million, was not a natural one caused by something like a bad crop yield. It
was, like the Holocaust, state-sanctioned murder. Today it is called the
Holodomor, which means “to kill by starvation.”103 In an area that once
produced the most grain in all of Europe, hunger drove desperate people to
cook shoes, bones, and finally, as one observer described, “There were
people who cut up corpses, who killed their own children and ate them. I
saw one.”104
Even more appalling, some Western intellectuals who supported the
Soviets’ policies denied the existence of the famine. George Bernard Shaw
wrote to the Manchester Guardian after visiting the Soviet Union in 1933,
“Everywhere we saw hopeful and enthusiastic working class” that provided
“an example of industry and conduct which would greatly enrich us if our
systems supplied our workers with any incentive to follow it.”105
Pulitzer-prize-winning journalist Walter Duranty wrote in the New York
Times that “any report of a famine in Russia is today an exaggeration or
malignant propaganda.”106 When Cardinal Theodor Innitzer pleaded for
Western relief efforts for Ukrainians who were resorting to infanticide and
cannibalism, the Times uncritically published the Soviet Union’s chilling
response: in the Soviet Union we have neither cannibals nor cardinals.107
George Orwell, whose novels 1984 and Animal Farm contained villains
modeled after the Soviet leadership, chastised fellow Westerners for
obscuring what the Soviets were doing. He specifically called out their use
of ambiguous language, a tactic we now call doublespeak in reference to the
deceptive newspeak language of 1984. Orwell writes:
Millions of peasants are robbed of their farms and sent trudging along the
roads with no more than they can carry: this is called transfer of
population or rectification of frontiers. People are imprisoned for years
without trial, or shot in the back of the neck or sent to die of scurvy in
Arctic lumber camps: this is called elimination of unreliable elements.
Such phraseology is needed if one wants to name things without calling
up mental pictures of them.108
It’s no wonder Pope Pius XI grimly warned (one year before the
Holodomor) about socialism “sinking” into Communism and how
Communism seeks two objectives: unrelenting class warfare and absolute
extermination of private ownership.
Not secretly or by hidden methods does it do this, but publicly, openly,
and by employing every and all means, even the most violent. To achieve
these objectives there is nothing which it does not dare, nothing for which
it has respect or reverence; and when it has come to power, it is incredible
and portentlike in its cruelty and inhumanity (Quadragesimo Anno 112).
Pius XI also acknowledged the existence of a more moderate form of
socialism that stood in contrast to authoritarian Communism. He noted how
these systems were “opposing each other and even bitterly hostile” to one
another. However, this conflict continued without either the tyrants or the
moderates “abandoning a position fundamentally contrary to Christian truth
that was characteristic of socialism” (111).
We will see why in the next chapter, as we take a closer look at Pope Pius
XI’s condemnation of all types of socialism.
• The infamous Soviet “Five Year Plan” included the forced nationalization and state central planning
of agriculture, resulting in a Ukrainian famine that
killed millions.
• While sympathetic Western intellectuals and journalists downplayed the evils of Soviet policies,
Pope Pius XI warned of Communism’s inherent “cruelty and inhumanity.”
98 Karl Marx, “The Victory of the Counter-Revolution in Vienna” (1848),
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/11/06.htm.
99 Abraham Ascher, The Revolution of 1905: A Short History (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2004), 5.
100 Karl Marx, Critique of the Gotha Programme (1875), https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1875/gotha/ch01.htm.
101 Vladimir Lenin, The State and Revolution (1917), https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1917/staterev/ch05.htm
102 Myles J. Kelleher, Social Problems in a Free Society: Myths, Absurdities, and Realities (Lanham, MD: University Press of
America, 2004), 60. The origin of the nail factory example can be traced all the way back to Krokodil, a satirical Russian
magazine, that featured a cartoon depicting a proud factory manager hoisting a single giant nail as evidence of his plant’s
successful output.
103 “Throughout the Soviet Union, the direct loss of life due to the famine and associated hunger and disease was likely to be six
to eight million. Three to five million of this number died in Ukraine and in the heavily Ukraine-populated northern Kuban,
among the richest grain producing areas of Europe. The Ukrainian word Holodomor derives from a combination of the word
for hunger, holod, and mor, to exterminate or eliminate.” Norman M. Naimark, Stalin’s Genocides (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2010), 70.
104 Robert Conquest, The Harvest of Sorrow: Soviet Collectivization and the Terror-Famine (New York: Oxford University Press,
1986), 257.
105 Marcel H. Van Herpen, Putin’s Propaganda Machine: Soft Power and Russian Foreign Policy (Lanham, MD: Rowan and
Littlefield, 2016), 68.
106 Walter Duranty, The New York Times, August 23, 1933. In 2003 Mark von Hagen, a Columbia University history professor,
hired by the Times to review Duranty’s work, said, “For the sake of The New York Times’ honor, they should take the prize
away.” “N.Y. Times urged to rescind 1932 Pulitzer” (October 22, 2003), https://usatoday30.usatoday.com/news/nation/2003-
10-22-ny-times-pulitzer_x.htm.
107 Dana G. Dalrymple, “The Soviet Famine of 1932–1934,” Soviet Studies, Vol. 15, No. 3 (January 1964), 250–284.
108 George Orwell, “Politics and the English Language” (1968),
https://faculty.washington.edu/rsoder/EDLPS579/HonorsOrwellPoliticsEnglishLanguage.pdf.
10
• Socialism rejects the Catholic principle of subsidiarity, which says that government power should
be exercised on the most local level possible.
• Just as socialism can have no private economic rivals to its control over the economy, it likewise
naturally opposes the family (and its inherent “inequalities”) as the basic unit of society.
109 Jose Mena, “The Catholic turn to socialism is something to celebrate,” Catholic Herald (May 30, 2019),
https://catholicherald.co.uk/.commentandblogs/2019/05/30/the-catholic-turn-to-socialism-is-something-to-celebrate/.
110 Vladimir Lenin, “The Attitude of the Workers’ Party to Religion” (1909),
https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1909/may/13.htm.
111 Patrick McNamara, A Catholic Cold War: Edmund A. Walsh, S.J., and the Politics of American Anticommunism (New York:
Fordham University Press, 2005), 28.
112 Kent R. Hill, The Soviet Union on the Brink: An Inside Look at Christianity & Glasnost (Portland, OR: Multnomah, 1991),
83.
113 Katherine Bliss Eaton, Daily Life in the Soviet Union (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 2004), 289.
114 Brianne Jacobs, “Yes, democratic socialism is compatible with Catholic social teaching,” America (October 1, 2018),
https://www.americamagazine.org/politics-society/2018/10/01/yes-democratic-socialism-compatible-catholic-social-teaching.
115 Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party (1848), chapter II,
https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/communist-manifesto/ch02.htm.
116 Leon Trotsky, The Revolution Betrayed (1936), https://www.marxists.org/archive/trotsky/1936/revbet/ch07.htm.
117 Philip Boobyer, The Stalin Era (New York: Routledge, 2000), 154.
118 “The Feminists vs. The Institution of Marriage,” Sisterhood is Powerful, ed. Robin Morgan (New York: Random House,
1970), 537.
119 Cited in John Hirschauer, “Candace Bushnell’s Childless Misery,” National Review (July 31, 2019),
https://www.nationalreview.com/2019/07/candace-bushnells-childless-misery/.
120 Rosemarie Ho, “Want to Dismantle Capitalism? Abolish the Family,” The Nation (May 16, 2019),
https://www.thenation.com/article/want-to-dismantle-capitalism-abolish-the-family/.
121 John O. Koehler, Stasi: The Untold Story Of The East German Secret Police (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1999), 9.
11
Mao Zedong’s 1964 book of quotations (commonly called the “Little Red
Book”) is alleged to have sold nearly a billion copies worldwide, making it
one of the best-selling books of all time. Along with its call for a
“changeover from individual to socialist, collective ownership” it includes
bits of wisdom like, “Political power grows out of the barrel of a gun.”122
This was certainly true for Mao after his Chinese communist party
established itself as a powerful guerilla force whose membership grew from
100,000 in 1937 to 1.2 million in 1945.123
In 1949, Mao’s forces defeated the Chinese nationalist party and the
country was renamed the People’s Republic of China. The nationalists fled
to an island off the coast and formed the Republic of China, which is now
called Taiwan. But whereas Taiwan’s free-market policies helped it grow
into an economic powerhouse over the next few decades, China’s socialist
policies led to one of the worst disasters in the history of humanity.
THE GREAT LEAP FORWARD
The country’s new leader, now Chairman Mao, promised that all citizens
would never have to worry about hunger because the Party would institute
an “iron rice bowl” policy. Workers’ jobs and wages would be guaranteed
for life, with the expectation that worker productivity would increase
because there would be no more worries about poverty. In reality, though,
the absence of incentives and the necessity of turning all profits over to the
government led workers and managers to become less and less productive.
The worst drop in production came in agriculture, where workers were
prohibited from owning their own farms. Instead, farms were collectivized
and all food production was turned over to the government. Most of the
food was sold in order to support the plan for industrializing the country in
accordance with a campaign dubbed the “Great Leap Forward.” As with the
Soviets before them, the government’s mismanagement of food caused a
famine. But the death toll from this famine dwarfed that of the Holodomor
—the Soviet-caused Ukrainian famine in 1932–1933—to become the worst
famine in the history of the world. According to Neil Hughes in his book
China’s Economic Challenge:
The famine that followed in the wake of the Great Leap Forward claimed
30 million lives. Children especially suffered, as reflected in mortality
data showing the median age at death, which fell from 17.6 years of age in
1957 to 9.7 years of age in 1963. One-half of the people dying in China
were under ten years old.124
Yang Jisheng was once a member of the Communist Party but left after its
brutal killing of hundreds of peaceful protesters in Tiananmen Square in
1989. He then wrote the most in-depth history of the Chinese famine ever
published, called Tombstone: the Great Chinese Famine, 1958–1962. He
explains the book’s title by saying that he sought to erect three tombstones:
“for my father, who died of starvation in 1959 . . . for the 36 million
Chinese who died of starvation, and . . . for the system that brought about
the Great Famine.”125
The book includes grotesque details of corpses being kept in beds in order
to trick government officials into thinking they were alive so that relatives
could receive their food rations.126 Cannibalism was common; children who
ate their own parents admitted “the heels and palms tasted the best.”127 A
government official who opened a granary for starving peasants later
committed suicide in response to what other officials considered to be an
act of treason. Jisheng says, “No matter how loud the peasants’ laments of
starvation, those in the top leadership regarded them as the cries of
opposition to socialism.”128
And, like Walter Duranty before them, Western intellectuals denied the
existence of the famine and praised Mao as a revolutionary figure who
fought for the poor.
The feminist philosopher Simone de Beauvoir said in 1958 that “life in
China today is exceptionally pleasant.” American journalist Hans Koning,
writing in 1966, said China was “almost as painstakingly careful about
human lives as New Zealand.” Also in 1966, Mao launched the “Cultural
Revolution” that sought to purge capitalist influences in the country. An
estimated one million people were killed; Mao bragged that the first
Chinese emperor “only buried alive 460 scholars, while we buried
46,000.”129
THE DARKNESS OF NORTH KOREA
Defenses of socialist China still pop up today, as is evident in British
socialist Jeremy Corbyn’s claim that “the present prosperity in China is
based upon a collective economy and not on an individual and market
oriented economy.” But this is false: China’s economic growth did not
begin to catch up to Hong Kong’s and Taiwan’s until after it adopted a
limited market-based economy beginning in 1980. The anthology
Reforming Asian Socialism: the Growth of Market Institutions shows that
almost all socialist countries in Asia have embraced some form of
capitalism in order to avoid economic stagnation. There is only one notable
exception: the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea—or North Korea.
After World War II, the Korean peninsula ceased to be under Japanese
control and was divided between the pro-American Republic of Korea
(South Korea) and the Communist, Soviet-backed Democratic People’s
Republic of Korea (North Korea). Both nations fought for control of the
peninsula during the Korean War, which ended with an armistice in 1953
and both countries are divided by a heavily guarded “de-militarized zone”
to the present day. North Korea adopted the principle of Juche, or self-
reliance, developed by their first leader Kim Il-Sung. The North Korean
leaders believed their superior lifestyle and production numbers would
encourage a worker’s revolution in South Korea and finally reunite both
countries. Fast-forward six decades and a single nighttime satellite image
proves this kind of thinking is delusional.
When viewed from space, South Korea twinkles like any modern, vibrant
country at night whereas North Korea is almost entirely dark. Ninety-seven
percent of North Korea’s roads are unpaved and, outside the capital of
Pyongyang, some of the best-looking homes are in a fake “Peace Village”
that has no residents and was built along the border solely to impress (and
possibly attract immigrants from) the south.130
The two Koreas weren’t always this unequal, however. In 1960, both
countries had a gross domestic product of about $5 billion. Today, North
Korea’s GDP is barely at $20 billion whereas South Korea has surpassed
$1.5 trillion, making it the fourth-largest economy in Asia. This difference
in wealth is starkly evident not only in satellite photos— thanks to better
access to food and medicine, South Korea’s people average about two
inches taller than their northern counterparts.131 One researcher concludes,
“North Korean performance faltered due to its inward-looking policies . . .
[it] remains a poor country with low growth and a generally isolationist
communist party.”132
But this doesn’t stop Western intellectuals like the World Health
Organization’s Margaret Chan from acting like fools in their stubborn
defense of anything socialist. Because it’s a crime to leave North Korea, the
population has a relatively high percentage of doctors, something Chan says
“most other developing countries would envy.” She also spins the people’s
undernourishment as a good thing: unlike in other Asian countries, North
Koreans don’t suffer from obesity!133
Well, that’s one way to describe the effects of food shortages and the
occasional famine that results from communal food production.
FAULTY LIBERATION THEOLOGY
While socialism was mixing with Korean and Chinese philosophy in East
Asia, in the Western Hemisphere, particularly in Central and South
America, it became tragically intertwined with Catholicism through
liberation theology.
As Trent notes in Counterfeit Christs, one of liberation theology’s key
ideas is the Marxist principle of “class struggle,” or the claim that the upper
classes always cause others to be poor and so the lower classes must seize
political power and establish their own “dictatorship” with the goal of
creating a “classless society.” In Gustavo Gutierrez’s classic text A
Theology of Liberation, he writes, “The class struggle is a fact that
Christians cannot dodge and in the face of which the demands of the gospel
must be clearly stated.”134
In 1984, the Congregation for the Doctrine of the Faith (CDF) released its
Instruction on Certain Aspects of the “Theology of Liberation.” The CDF
agreed that Christians have a special obligation to help the poor (sometimes
called the “preferential option for the poor”) and should not tolerate unjust
conditions that create widespread poverty. But it also noted that liberation
theology errs when it locates the source of evil in class conflict instead of in
man’s inherent tendency to sin because of our fallen nature.135
In his encyclical Spe Salvi, Pope Benedict XVI similarly criticized
Marxism, saying that man “is not merely the product of economic
conditions, and it is not possible to redeem him purely from the outside by
creating a favorable economic environment” (21). The CDF also warned
about the consequences that can result from trying to join theology with
something as contrary to the Faith as Marxism. It quoted Pope Paul VI, who
said it was “dangerous” to “enter into the practice of class struggle and of
its Marxist interpretation while failing to see the kind of totalitarian society
to which this process slowly leads.”136
In fact, by opposing the conditions for a thriving business economy,
liberation theologians and their political allies have wrought nothing but
harm for the poor that they profess to champion.
COMMUNISM IN CUBA
A prime example of this kind of society is Communist Cuba, which formed
after Fidel Castro’s revolution in 1959 and has since seen the execution of
more than 10,000 people.137 One of Castro’s most important allies was
Ernesto “Che” Guevara, a young revolutionary whose steely gaze can be
found on posters and T-shirts at colleges across the country. The many
students who lionize Che as a “rebel” apparently don’t know that he banned
newspapers and executed people even if he wasn’t sure they were guilty of
anything.138 The new Communist government, like every other one before
and after it, also imprisoned dissidents into forced labor camps—in this
case with the absurd euphemism of “Military Units to Aid Production.”139
Like every other socialist regime, Cuba’s policy of collective food
production led to food shortages and required the government to issue
“ration tickets” for citizens to redeem in small quantities. Yes, U.S. trade
embargoes hampered the economy, but they don’t explain why Cuba
experienced shortages in its own domestically produced goods (especially
during the Cold War when Soviet funds offset the impact of U.S.
embargoes). In Eliana Cardsos and Ann Helwege’s book Cuba After
Communism, the authors explain that under the state’s socialist policies,
Cubans cannot easily set up a small business on the side. People say there
are hairdresser and seamstresses, but few hang up a sign for services. A
broken pipe meant waiting a few weeks for the state plumber to arrive.
Access to most goods is too limited and the penalties too high for people
to set up illegal shops and kiosks. The state not only fails to provide goods
but prohibits people from filling the gap with informal markets.140
Even as recently as 2019, Cubans were reporting long lines at grocery
stores to buy basic food items like eggs and chicken. One report noted that
“Cuba imports 60 to 70 percent of its food. A handful of agricultural
reforms in recent years have failed to boost output in its inefficient,
centrally planned economy.”141 People who try to circumvent these
inefficiencies through black market sales of things like eggs or meat can be
imprisoned for up to twenty years.142
Despite the state’s harsh penalties, illegal markets supply people with
most of their needs through networks of socios: citizens who steal goods
that can’t be bought in normal markets and then trade with one another for
basic goods. Katherine Hirschfield, who spent nine months in Cuba for her
dissertation research, described how one man would steal towels from his
hotel for his socio, who then repays him with beer he steals from his
factory. The first man, according to one of Hirschfield’s sources, “will then
trade the beer to the maid for a supply of soap, which he’ll either give to his
[suppliers] or sell on the black market. Everybody does it. It’s the only way
to survive.”143
Some socialists denounce Cuba’s violent past but tout its modern
achievements such as its allegedly high life expectancies and low infant
mortality rates. They say this disproves the idea that socialism is
detrimental to the common good. But a 2018 study in the Journal of Health
and Policy Planning paints a darker picture.
It says that health care workers, under pressure to meet government
quotas, alter data, and even pressure women to have abortions. The authors
reveal how “physicians likely reclassified early neonatal deaths as late fetal
deaths, thus deflating the infant mortality statistics and propping up life
expectancy. . . . If we combine the misreporting of late fetal deaths and
pressured abortions, life expectancy would drop by between 1.46 and 1.79
years for men.”144
As a result of these repressive policies, over a million Cubans have fled
the country in makeshift boats to the United States. During the 1960s the
number of unaccompanied minors became so great that the Catholic
Welfare Bureau launched “Operation Pedro Pan” to provide housing and
resources for children whose parents could not join them in their flight from
Castro’s communist regime.145 Even in 2019, Cuba ranked sixth among
countries whose citizens were fleeing to the United States with “credible
fear” asylum claims.146
And, as we’ll see, this constant human desire to flee socialism is what led
to the demise of the largest socialist country in the history of the world.
• Socialism in North Korea has made it a literal and figurative dark spot in what is otherwise an
economically bustling East Asia.
• In South America and the Caribbean, socialism has likewise produced predictable poverty and
human misery. In some places it gets mixed up with Catholic teaching into something called
liberation theology.
122 Mao Zedong, “Problems of War and Strategy” (1938), Selected Works of Mao Tse-tung: Vol. II,
https://www.marxists.org/reference/archive/mao/selected-works/volume-2/mswv2_12.htm#p6.
123 Gabe T. Wang, China and the Taiwan Issue: Impending War at Taiwan Strait (Lanham, MD: University Press of America,
2006), 56–57.
124 Neil C. Hughes, China’s Economic Challenge: Smashing the Iron Rice Bowl (New York: Routledge, 2015), 7.
125 Yang Jisheng, Tombstone: The Great Chinese Famine, 1958–1962 (New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux, 2012), 3.
126 Ibid, 289.
127 Ibid, 40.
128 Ibid, 322.
129 Mao Zedong, “Speeches At The Second Session Of The Eighth Party Congress” (1958),
https://www.marxists.org/reference/archive/mao/selected-works/volume-8/mswv8_10.htm.
130 “North Korea,” CIA World Factbook, https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/kn.html. See also
David Wharton, “‘Peace Village,’ a fake city just outside the DMZ, serves as metaphor for North Korean athletes at the
Olympics” Los Angeles Times (February 17, 2018), https://www.latimes.com/sports/olympics/la-sp-olympics-north-korea-
mystery-20180217-story.html.
131 Chloe Pfeiffer and Elena Holodny, “14 fascinating facts about North Korea,” Business Insider (April 18, 2017),
https://www.businessinsider.com/weird-facts-about-north-korea-2017-4
132 Chris Coney, “East Asia: History and Economic Development,” Encyclopedia of the Developing World, Vol., 1 ed. Thomas
M. Leonard (New York: Routledge, 2006), 511.
133 A transcript of the press conference says, “Question from Shabtai Gold at DPA: Can I clarify something earlier, you said the
height and weight in DPRK is similar to that of other Asian countries, did I hear you right? Dr. Chan: I said what I saw in
Pangung might not be representative for the entire country, but that is what I saw in the capital. Of course, one thing I
recognized is that walking is quite well observed in that country, and I suggest that is why I didn’t see many obese people. And
if you look at me I am also an Asian, I am pretty short by Asian standards, so when I compare to most of the people I saw on
the street, I can only make a very broad comparison. But mind you, as I said, now in Asian countries, because of affluence and
intake of food we are seeing obesity which I don’t see in DPRK.” Transcript of press briefing at WHO headquarters, Geneva
Dr. Margaret Chan, WHO Director-General (April 30, 2010),
https://www.who.int/mediacentre/news/releases/2010/20100430_chan_press_transcript.pdf. And while Chan was born in Hong
Kong, her later education in Canada and Harvard certainly qualify her to be a “western intellectual” who whitewashes the
impact of socialism on the health of North Korean people.
134 Gustavo Gutierrez, A Theology of Liberation (Maryknoll, NY: Orbis Books, 1988), 157.
135 The CDF rebuked the idea that evil can be localized “principally or uniquely in bad social, political, or economic ‘structures’
as though all other evils came from them so that the creation of the ‘new man’ would depend on the establishment of different
economic and socio-political structures” (15).
136 Instruction on Certain Aspects of the “Theology of Liberation,” 7.
137 Mary Anastasia O’Grady, “Counting Castro’s Victims,” The Wall Street Journal (December 30, 2005),
https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB113590852154334404.
138 “The intention of Cuba’s new leaders was deviously clear. Carlos Franqui, editor of the official newspaper Revolución, has
reported that in a speech of May 18, 1962 at State Security offices in Havana, Ché Guevara stated: ‘It is logical that in times of
excessive tension we cannot proceed weakly. We have imprisoned many people without knowing for sure if they were guilty.
At the Sierra Maestra, we executed many people by firing squad without knowing if they were fully guilty. At times, the
Revolution cannot stop to conduct much investigation; it has the obligation to triumph.’” María C. Werlau, “Ché Guevara’s
Forgotten Victims,” Free Society Project (2011), http://cubaarchive.org/home/images/stories/che-guevara_interior-
pages_en_final.pdf. University students who love to sport Ché paraphernalia would be shocked to know that people who
identified as homosexual were considered a byproduct of “bourgeoisie decadence” that needed to be imprisoned and forced
into hard labor. Andrea Pitzer, One Long Night: A Global History of Concentration Camps (New York: Little, Brown, and
Company, 2018), 278–279.
139 These included not just conscientious objectors and minority religious groups like Jehovah’s Witnesses, but also homosexuals
whose sexual behavior was seen as a bourgeoisie defect. See Ian Lumsden, Machos Maricones & Gays: Cuba and
Homosexuality (Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press, 1996), 66–71.
140 Eliana Cardsos and Ann Helwege, Cuba After Communism (Boston, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1992), 42.
While the authors’ predictions of Cuba’s collapse or renouncement of socialism by the 21st century were incorrect, the book’s
descriptions of life in Cuba under Castro during the end of the Cold War are still a valuable resource.
141 The article also mentions the U.S. trade embargo as a reason for Cuba’s shortages, but that doesn’t explain why the nation
fails to produce sufficient domestic foodstuffs that do not need to be imported in large quantities (though the collapse of its
major trading partner Venezuela may also be a factor in Cuba’s shortages). Sarah Marsh and Nelson Acosta, “Cuba to ration
more products due to economic crisis, U.S. sanctions,” Reuters (May 10, 2019), https://www.reuters.com/article/us-cuba-
economy/cuba-to-ration-more-products-due-to-economic-crisis-u-s-sanctions-idUSKCN1SG2HA.
142 Joe Lamar, “For Cubans, the struggle to supplement meager rations is a consuming obsession,” The Guardian (April 24,
2015), https://www.theguardian.com/world/2015/apr/24/cubans-food-struggle-rations-consuming-obsession
143 Katherine Hirschfeld, “Re-examining the Cuban Health Care System: Towards a Qualitative Critique,” Cuban Affairs, Vol. 2,
Issue 3 (July 2007), 7.
144 Gilbert Berdine, Vincent Geloso, and Benjamin Powell “Cuban infant mortality and longevity: health care or repression?”
Health Policy and Planning, Vol. 33, Issue 6, (July 2018) 755–757.
145 See Yvonne Conde, Operation Pedro Pan: The Untold Exodus of 14,048 Cuban Children (New York: Routledge, 1999).
146 Part of this rise in Cuban asylum claims comes from the reversal of previous immigration policies that allowed Cubans who
reached American shores to remain in the country to pursue citizenship. See Santiago Perez, “Cuban Migrants Are Thwarted in
Mexico by New Asylum Rules,” The Wall Street Journal (August 2, 2019), https://www.wsj.com/articles/cuban-migrants-are-
thwarted-in-mexico-by-new-asylum-rules-11564738202
12
Soviet first secretary Nikita Khrushchev was not one for subtlety. During a
1960 meeting at the U.N. General Assembly, Khrushchev became enraged
when a delegate from the Philippines spoke of “the peoples of Eastern
Europe and elsewhere which have been deprived of the free exercise of
their civil and political rights and which have been swallowed up, so to
speak, by the Soviet Union.”147 In response, Khrushchev banged his shoe on
a table in order to disrupt the delegate and get his own turn to speak.148
Some people think the shoe-banging incident was also when Khrushchev
told the U.S., “We will bury you,” but that actually happened four years
earlier at a gathering of Western ambassadors. He said, “About the capitalist
states, it doesn’t depend on you whether or not we exist. If you don’t like
us, don’t accept our invitations, and don’t invite us to come to see you.
Whether you like it or not, history is on our side. We will bury you!”149
Khrushchev later claimed that he meant the Soviet Union would outlive
capitalist states that would eventually succumb to workers’ revolutions.
And as the twentieth century progressed there were worker revolutions—
but they consisted of workers who overthrew Communist chains as Western
nations and the Catholic Church faithfully stood by them.
SOCIALISM IN GERMANY
In 1961, Pope St. John XXIII published the encyclical Mater et Magistra,
which continued the denunciation of socialism made under Leo XIII and
Pius XI. He affirmed that private property has its origin in natural law and
that paying wages to workers is not unjust in itself but only becomes unjust
under certain conditions that must be avoided. Echoing Pius XI before him,
he wrote, “Justice demands that account be taken not only of the needs of
the individual workers and their families, but also of the financial state of
the business concern for which they work and of ‘the economic welfare of
the whole people” (Mater et Magistra 33). The pope then turned his
attention to socialism:
Pope Pius XI further emphasized the fundamental opposition between
Communism and Christianity, and made it clear that no Catholic could
subscribe even to moderate socialism. The reason is that socialism is
founded on a doctrine of human society which is bounded by time and
takes no account of any objective other than that of material well-being.
Since, therefore, it proposes a form of social organization which aims
solely at production, it places too severe a restraint on human liberty, at
the same time flouting the true notion of social authority (34).
Three months after Mater et Magistra was published, the Soviets unveiled
their newest “restraint on human liberty” in the form of the Berlin Wall,
which was part of the larger, post-war division of the country. East
Germany became a Soviet-occupied “workers’ state” while West Germany
became an independent country that functioned under a capitalist economy.
Like North and South Korea, East and West Germany became perfect
“laboratories” to test socialism’s economic merits. Before World War II, the
eastern part of Germany had a higher per-capita income than the west, but
post-war socialist policies turned East Germany into a drab, run-down
country that Indian economist B.R. Shenoy likened to “a prison camp.”150
During the 1950s, what had been 50 percent marginal tax rates for income
over $600 (recall that the Third Reich was a “national socialist” regime)
were changed in the West only to apply to people who made more than
$42,000 a year. The ensuing growth of efficient industries led to the
Wirtschaftswunder—an “economic miracle” of growth and prosperity—
while East Germany’s economy remained stagnant and unproductive.151 To
provide one example: by the 1980s, the West German automotive industry
had become a global engineering force whereas East German companies
were still mass-producing outdated cars like the infamous Trabant, which
lacked basic amenities like a fuel gauge and rear seat belts and required
drivers to pre-mix gas and oil for its ancient two-stroke engine.152
Shenoy concludes:
The contrast in prosperity is convincing proof of the superiority of the
forces of freedom over centralized planning. It is difficult to resist the
inference that workers in East Berlin, deprived of the incentives of full
property rights over the fruits of one’s effort, are loath to put in their
best.153
So many Germans fled the country that a 1955 East German propaganda
tract described this behavior as “an act of political and moral
backwardness” for which “workers throughout Germany will demand
punishment.”154 When threats and propaganda failed to stem the exodus,
travel was legally prohibited and, overnight, an 87-mile-long wall was
erected to isolate West-controlled zones in the capital of Berlin. The wall
included barbed wire, 116 guard towers, and “dead zones” in front of the
wall that made it easier to find and shoot would-be defectors.
Socialists may fantasize about workers leaving capitalist countries for
socialist ones, but in the real world, people who want to provide their
children with basic necessities and a hopeful future choose capitalism over
socialism every time. The proof of this can be seen in the contrast between
capitalist countries that use barriers to keep people from illegally entering
and socialist countries (like East Germany and North Korea) that use
barriers to keep people from illegally escaping.
BACK IN THE U.S.S.R.
In 1971, Pope Paul VI lamented about Christians being deceived into
supporting an unrealistic socialism over sound Catholic social doctrine. He
wrote, “Too often Christians attracted by socialism tend to idealize it in
terms which, apart from anything else, are very general: a will for justice,
solidarity, and equality” (Octogesima Adveniens 31). He pointed out that
support for the dignity of workers and human rights is properly found in
Christian moral teaching. An example of this during the Cold War was
Poland’s Solidarity movement.
In the 1980s, Polish workers formed the first non-state-controlled trade
union in a Communist country and called it Solidarity. It used non-violent
tactics to oppose Communist oppression of workers and received significant
support from the Catholic Church. For example, when Communists
imposed martial law in order to disrupt union activity, Catholic Masses
became one of the few safe places for people to gather in public.
This wasn’t just for political show: many members of Solidarity were
devout Catholics who kept pictures of the Blessed Virgin at their factory
work posts. One outspoken priest, Fr. Jerzy Popiełuszko, not only offered
Mass but explicitly preached against the government’s socialist policies. He
knew such actions were dangerous but considered them better than doing
nothing in the face of evil:
To preserve one’s dignity as man is to remain interiorly free even in
external slavery, to remain oneself in all situations of life, to remain in the
truth, even if that is to cost us dearly. Because it costs a lot to speak the
truth. Only the weeds, in other words, petty, mediocre things, are cheap.
But for the wheat of truth, as with all great and beautiful things, one must
pay the demanding price of self-sacrifice.155
Fr. Popiełuszko finally paid this price on October 19, 1984 when three
members of the country’s security service kidnapped him, beat him to
death, and dumped his body into a reservoir. He was thirty-seven.
But far from crushing the movement, Popiełuszko’s death galvanized
Solidarity, and the Church has declared him a beatified martyr.
For the previous forty years, the Soviet Union had subsidized its satellite
states’ failing economies, but falling oil prices in the mid-eighties forced
Soviet premier Mikhail Gorbachev to cut off economic aid.156 This loosened
the U.S.S.R.’s grip, and Solidarity members were now able to fight for
Poland’s freedom. As a result, in 1989, Solidarity’s leader, Lech Walesa,
was elected president of Poland in the country’s first free election in
decades.
As other former Communist states renounced their ties to the Soviet
Union, the dismantling of old Soviet borders caused a surge of East German
citizens to bypass the wall and enter West Germany. The flood of refugees
leaving East Germany became so difficult to manage that the government
authorized limited, round-trip travel directly through the Berlin Wall. On
November 9, 1989, East German spokesman Gunter Schabowski made a
media appearance to announce the plan—but hadn’t been told all the details
about the regulations.
When asked when the plans would go into effect, he said, “As far as I
know . . . a decision has been made . . . to issue a regulation that will make
it possible for every citizen . . .
to emigrate.” When German reporter Peter Brinkmann asked Schabowski,
“When does that go into force?” the Communist party leader scanned his
unfamiliar notes and simply blurted out, “Right away.”157 This gaffe
motivated thousands of East Germans to test out their newfound freedom
and overwhelm the wall’s security checkpoints. The crowds were
eventually allowed to pass without any restrictions and, later that night,
exuberant people young and old to begin to demolish the Berlin Wall.
COMMUNIST FAILURES, CAPITALIST WARNINGS
In May 1991, two years after the fall of the Berlin Wall but four months
before the Soviet Union officially dissolved, Pope John Paul II wrote an
encyclical called Centesimus Annus, or “one hundred years later” in honor
of Pope Leo XIII’s publication of Rerum Novarum. He said, “By defining
the nature of the socialism of his day as the suppression of private property,
Leo XIII arrived at the crux of the problem” (Centesimus Annus 12). He
then says “the Marxist solution has failed” because:
A person who is deprived of something he can call “his own,” and of the
possibility of earning a living through his own initiative, comes to depend
on the social machine and on those who control it. This makes it much
more difficult for him to recognize his dignity as a person, and hinders
progress toward the building up of an authentic human community (13).
The fall of Communism did not mean that the answers to man’s economic
problems were now abundantly clear. It “certainly removes an obstacle to
facing these problems,” he wrote, but he also made it clear that the
problems of poverty and corruption still remained. Some might have said
that capitalism could now take over and address those problems, but the
Church took a more nuanced approach. The pope even warned of a radical
capitalistic ideology that “blindly entrusts their solution to the free
development of market forces” (42).
As we’ll see, this does not mean that capitalism is an opposing evil to
socialism. Instead, it means that any science that aims to increase human
well-being, be it medicine, politics, or economics, must be guided by sound
principles ordered toward our ultimate well-being as human beings made in
the image of God.
It’s important to remember . . .
• In the second half of the twentieth century, the Church continued its consistent denunciation of
socialism.
• Popular movements in Soviet satellite states, particularly in Poland where the papacy of John Paul
II was a rallying point, worked for increased economic and personal freedom until the eventual
collapse of the Soviet Union.
147 “Nikita Khrushchev: Speech on Decolonization,” The Cold War: Interpreting Conflict through Primary Documents, Vol. 2,
ed. Priscilla Roberts (Santa Barbara, CA: ABC-CLIO, 2019), 507.
148 William Taubman, Khrushchev: The Man and His Era (New York: W.W. Norton & Company Inc., 2003), 657. Most accounts
say Khrushchev banged his shoe on his desk, but New York Times reporter James Feron claims that he never saw Khrushchev
bang the shoe, but only menacingly wave it in the air.
149 Ibid., 427.
150 B.R. Shenoy, “East and West Berlin: A Study in Free vs. Controlled Economy” (August 15, 1960),
https://www.libertarianism.org/publications/essays/east-west-berlin-study-free-vs-controlled-economy.
151 “It was this systematic lowering of unnecessarily high taxes that produced the German ‘economic miracle.’” Jude Wanniski,
“Taxes, Revenues, and the ‘Laffer Curve,’” The Politics of American Economic Policy Making, 2nd edition, ed. Paul Peretz
(New York, Routledge, 2015), 232.
152 And, to add insult to injury, the East German socialist economy required people to stay on a waiting list for ten years before
they could buy one! Neil Harris, European Business (London: Macmillan Press, 1996), 117.
153 B.R. Shenoy, “East and West Berlin: A Study in Free vs. Controlled Economy” (August 15, 1960),
https://www.libertarianism.org/publications/essays/east-west-berlin-study-free-vs-controlled-economy.
154 See Randal Bytwerk, “German Propaganda Archive,” https://research.calvin.edu/german-propaganda-archive/notiz3.htm.
Bytwerk lists his source as: Wer die Deutsche Demokratische Republik verläßt, stellt sich auf die Seite der Kriegstreiber,
Notizbuch des Agitators (Agitator’s Notebook), published by the Socialist Unity Party’s Agitation Department, Berlin District,
November 1955. See also Jim Willis, Daily Life Behind the Iron Curtain (Santa Barbara, CA: ABC-CLIO, 2013), 40.
155 Bernard Brien, Blessed Jerzy Popieluszko: Truth versus Totalitarianism, trans. Michael J. Miller (San Francisco: Ignatius
Press, 2016), 110.
156 Socialist leaders often rely on the raw sale of natural resources on the open (world) market to get cash to buy foodstuffs and
other goods that their deformed economies cannot produce. When the world price of such a resource, like oil, plummets,
terrible misery can ensue when the government could no longer import food or medicine. This is what happened in Venezuela
as we note in chapter nineteen.
157 Mary Elise Sarotte, The Collapse: The Accidental Opening of the Berlin Wall (New York: Basic Books, 2014), 117–118.
Part Four
Is Capitalism
the Answer?
13
In the 1987 film Wall Street, cutthroat businessman Gordon Gekko lectures
the members of a shareholder’s meeting. “Greed,” he tells them, “is good.
Greed is right. Greed works.”
For many people since, Gekko became the embodiment of the greedy,
selfish capitalist who elevates profits over people. One author says,
“Capitalism takes the position that ‘greed is good,’ which its supporters say
is a positive thing—greed drives profits and profits drive innovation and
product development, which means there are more choices available for
those who can afford them.”158
Are critics right? Is capitalism an evil economic system that Catholics
can’t support because it relies on the sin of greed?
FROM WANTS TO CREATION
If you ask people what fundamental values drive capitalism, they might
indeed talk about greed, profits, or selfishness. That’s understandable if
their only reference point for capitalism is a character like Gordon Gekko or
an Ayn Rand book like The Virtue of Selfishness. But the fundamental
values that drive capitalism are actually good ones: freedom and creativity.
In a free market, no one can force you to buy what a business is selling;
the business has to persuade you to enter freely into a mutually beneficial
exchange. When I buy a donut for a dollar, it’s because, at that moment, I
value the donut more than the dollar and the baker values the dollar more
than the donut. In that sense, capitalism can be summarized as: Give me
what I want and I will give you what you want. (In contrast, we might
summarizes socialism as: Give the state what you have and it will give you
what it thinks you need.)
Obviously, this isn’t a profound altruism like, “Give to those in need
regardless of what you want,” but capitalism isn’t meant to be a profound
moral system. Capitalism is a tool, based on discovery of the nature of
things, that in spite of its weaknesses encourages people to channel their
natural self-interest in a way that indirectly brings about good for others.
Capitalism also flows from our natural human creativity. When you see
any ten-year-old boy with Lego bricks you see the natural human desire to
wonder, “What can I make” followed by the will to take an idea and “make
it real.” Animals don’t create new or better tools and, as Adam Smith
pointed out, they don’t make deals or exchanges. But human beings have an
innate desire to create and exchange their creations with one another, and
this benefits humanity as a whole even if some people may use it to cause
harm.
Sure, some people will create frivolous goods that don’t really benefit
anyone. The world today doesn’t mourn the disappearance of past fads like
pet rocks! But most entrepreneurs will create useful things or improve
existing goods to make them more beneficial to the world, and some will
create things we couldn’t imagine living without—like cars or computers.
In all these cases, capitalism is a force for good.
Yes, some will create sinful goods and services the world would be better
off without, like pornography or prostitution. But as an economic tool,
capitalism shouldn’t be blamed when it’s used to serve sinful desires any
more than other tools (like kitchen knives) are blamed when they’re used
for evil ends (like stabbing innocent people).
To make an even better analogy, dating (or what we could call “romantic
markets”) can be opportunities for people merely to satisfy their lusts and
engage in fornication. But that wouldn’t justify forbidding free, romantic
interactions and having government central planners arrange everyone’s
marriages. Such a solution would create more evils than it tries to solve, and
of course it would do nothing to reduce sins of lust. In the same way,
forbidding commercial markets in favor of centrally allocating goods only
creates greater evils, and in the end does not eliminate the tendency toward
greed that is part of our fallen nature.
Some critics say that we are only selfish because capitalism, with its
emphasis on satisfying endless wants, makes us that way. They say that if
we adopted socialism we could restore the primitive altruism our ancestors
practiced before we were inundated with a consumerist culture that
brainwashed us into thinking we need “stuff” to be happy. But this view
ignores thousands of years of history that lacked capitalism but still had lots
of avarice—and with it, violent crime. The cognitive scientist Steven Pinker
argues that we live in the least criminal and war-torn age in all of human
history, and capitalism helped bring this about, because “when it’s cheaper
to buy things than to steal them, people don’t steal them.”159
This tendency for free markets to curb our base impulses is summarized in
Adam Smith’s example of an “invisible hand” that guides producers in the
market to benefit others “in spite of their natural selfishness and
rapacity.”160 Capitalism doesn’t require greed; it restrains it through
voluntary, mutual exchange. In his book Money, Greed, and God, Jay
Richards explains:
Even if the butcher is selfish, even if the butcher would love nothing more
than to sell you a spoiled chunk of grisly beef in exchange for your
worldly goods and leave you homeless, the butcher can’t make you buy
his meat in a free economy. He has to offer you meat you’ll freely buy.
The cruel, greedy butcher, in other words, has to look for ways to set up
win-win scenarios. Even to satisfy his greed, he has to meet your desires.
The market makes this happen. That’s making the best of a bad situation,
and of a bad butcher.161
We must remember that greed and selfishness are not strictly the same as
self-interest, which is a good inclination God instilled within us. The
conflation of a good, healthy type of self-interest with mere greed or
selfishness contributes to a great deal of confusion about economies built on
free exchanges.
Jesus said that we should love our neighbor as ourselves, not that we
should love our neighbor instead of ourselves. There is a proper kind of
self-love, rooted in humility, that moves us to care for our own animal and
spiritual needs in a manner befitting a son or daughter of God. We
ordinarily meet our own needs before we meet the needs of others, which is
good because if we didn’t meet our basic needs we wouldn’t be much help
to others for long.
It’s the same reason that airplane attendants instruct us to secure our own
oxygen masks before those of children next to us. St. Thomas Aquinas put
it this way, “man’s love for himself is the model of his love for another. But
the model exceeds the copy. Therefore, out of charity, a man ought to love
himself more than his neighbor.”162
THE “P” WORD
In Letters to a Young Evangelical, Christian author Tony Campolo
complains that the typical good produced in a capitalist system “doesn’t
meet anybody’s needs, but is simply designed to generate profits.”163 Yet
profit is not the same thing as “money” nor is it something that only exists
for greedy people to hoard.
Profit is a sign that a business is meeting people’s needs by providing
them with something they want at a price that is higher than the cost of
producing it. It’s an indicator of a healthy business, which is a business
poised to grow and thus benefit more people with the good or service.
When critics of capitalism quip about how the system “values profits over
people” they forget that profitable businesses show that people are being
benefited. Workers are getting paid and consumers are getting what they
want, and not just the “well off” ones. The economist Joseph Schumpeter
says, “The capitalist achievement does not typically consist in providing
more silk stockings for queens but in bringing them within reach of factory
girls in return for steadily decreasing amounts of effort.”164
Instead of measuring business success with profits, socialist economies
measure it with output. Industries that produce the most goods (irrespective
of whether people actually want them) are considered the most important
and, as a result, are given the biggest budgets by the state. This means
socialist businesses do whatever they can to increase their budgets, even if
that means not meeting consumer needs. When a business in the free market
fails to meet people’s needs, it loses profits and either adapts or closes. But
when industries under socialism (or even some public-sector businesses in
market economies) fail to meet people’s needs, they can operate indefinitely
as long as the state subsidizes them.165
It’s also a fallacy to compare real-world capitalism, with its admitted fair
share of greedy, unscrupulous entrepreneurs, to an idealized socialism that
never has and never can exist because of our fallen human nature. In the
real world, socialism reaps a “harvest of misery” because it expects people
to act in ways that are contrary to their fallen human nature. Remember
what happened when the pilgrims expected everyone to act only for the
interest of others? They quickly used that as an excuse to do whatever they
could to benefit themselves, and this almost led to their ruin.
That capitalism is not essentially built upon greed is evident in the fact
that even if people weren’t greedy they would still be needy—and free
markets allow people to exchange goods and services in order to meet their
needs. In fact, capitalism allows people to accumulate so much wealth that
they are capable of engaging in acts of altruism to a degree previously
unknown in human history.
A GENEROSITY OPPORTUNITY
In 2012, Bruce Springsteen began his “Wrecking Ball Tour” throughout
Europe, dedicating songs to those experiencing economic hardship. One
song described “greedy thieves and robber barons” who “destroyed our
families, factories and they took our homes.” But although it makes for
doleful lyrics, the idea that capitalists are just a bunch of “robber barons”
who get rich at the expense of the poor is a myth.
The term “robber baron” comes from the medieval German raubritter or
“robber knights” who charged illegal tolls on public rivers and roads.166 But
whereas these thieves use force to steal money from poor people who were
just using public goods that actually belonged to them, modern capitalists
like Cornelius Vanderbilt and John D. Rockefeller helped create massive
amounts of wealth by providing, among other things, better ways to traverse
public roads and rivers.167
Rockefeller has been called the richest man who ever lived, and he got
that way in the late nineteenth century because his company, Standard Oil,
made affordable kerosene that everybody wanted. He said, “Let the good
work go on. We must ever remember we are refining oil for the poor man
and he must have it cheap and good.”168 Even the poorest of Americans
could now have reliable heating and lamp oil, and the byproducts of
kerosene were used to create cheap gasoline for the newly invented
automobile.
Rockefeller became the world’s first billionaire and he gave away half his
fortune (worth $10 billion today) to charity. His philanthropy included
founding a black women’s college and a medical foundation that later
eradicated hookworm.169 That’s why it’s painfully ironic to hear a socialist
like Che Guevara complain about the “poverty and suffering required for a
Rockefeller to emerge” given the violence and suffering that was required
for someone like Guevara to emerge as a socialist icon.170
The generosity of someone like Rockefeller is not an anomaly. The
Charities Aid Foundation has shown the nations that provide the most help
to strangers are those that have the freest economies. The five most
“individualistic” countries in the survey (United States, Australia, New
Zealand, Canada, and the United Kingdom) ranked second, third, fourth,
sixth, and eighth respectively when it comes to having generous citizens. In
contrast, those few countries that bucked the global trend toward
individualism included some with the lowest socioeconomic development,
including Armenia, Malaysia, Mali, and Uruguay.171
Just to be clear, we are not saying that capitalism by itself creates a just
world and makes everyone charitable and morally upright. Capitalism is a
tool—discovered in nature—that facilitates the exchange of goods and
services, and like any tool it can be abused. For example, some of the
“robber barons” of the early twentieth century did increase their wealth
through unethical business practices, such as insider trading. But abusus
non usum tollit: abuse does not take away the proper use, and this will
become clear when we examine what the Church has to say about
capitalism.
• Profit is a natural marker for economic success; and although it can be acquired immorally and used
viciously, it’s also necessary for the creation of wealth, the alleviation of poverty, and the practice
of philanthropy.
158 Kim Kelly, “What ‘Capitalism’ Is and How It Affects People” Teen Vogue (April 11, 2018),
https://www.teenvogue.com/story/what-capitalism-is
159 Zack Beauchamp, “Steven Pinker explains how capitalism is killing war,” Vox (June 4, 2015),
https://www.vox.com/2015/6/4/8725775/pinker-capitalism.
160 Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (New York: Penguin Books, 2009), Kindle edition.
161 Jay Richards, Money, Greed, and God: Why Capitalism is the Solution and Not the Problem (New York: HarperCollins,
2009), 123.
162 ST. II-II Q. 26 A4
163 “[W]e reject the ‘greed principle’ that motivates so many in the capitalistic world. Capitalism relies solely on the idea that
people work for profits.” Tony Campolo, Letters to a Young Evangelical (New York: Basic Books, 2006), 142.
164 Joseph Alois Schumpeter, Capitalism, socialism, and democracy (New York: Harper Perennial, 1950), 67.
165 A similar phenomenon occurs under “crony capitalism” when failing businesses are propped up by government spending,
which distorts free-market exchanges since government has almost endless abilities to raise revenues and continue this kind of
spending through taxation or borrowing.
166 The modern robber-baron myth comes from Matthew Josephson’s 1934 book The Robber Barons. It was a best-seller in an
economically depressed United States eager to pain the rich as villains and markets as their chief weapon against the poor.
167 Vanderbilt started his first ferry service with a $100 loan from his mother. It later grew into the People’s Line which competed
at the time with a state-funded monopoly called the Hudson River Steamboat Association controlled ferry travel into New York
and kept prices artificially high. Through ingenious business plans, Vanderbilt was able to offer lower prices along with more
reliable service. At one point, he was able to give away free tickets because he made more than enough profit by selling food
and drink on his boats. Eventually the other steamboat operators paid Vanderbilt not to compete with them, and it was this act
that earned him the title of “Robber Barron” among later biographers like Matthew Josephson.
168 Ron Chernow, Titan: The Life of John D. Rockefeller, Sr. (New York: Random House, 2004), 257.
169 Ibid., 487.
170 Ché Guevara, “Socialism and man in Cuba” (1965), https://www.marxists.org/archive/guevara/1965/03/man-socialism.htm.
171 Abigail Marsh, “Could A More Individualistic World Also Be A More Altruistic One?” National Public Radio (February 5,
2018), https://www.npr.org/sections/13.7/2018/02/05/581873428/could-a-more-individualistic-world-also-be-a-more-altruistic-
one.
14
• The science of economics is a matter for economists, not popes. Catholic social doctrine offers
moral principles but not a comprehensive “Catholic economics” that the faithful must follow.
• Still less does the Church mandate a “middle way” that splits the difference between capitalism and
socialism.
172 Ibid., 120.
173 Adam Smith, An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Vol. 2 (London, William Clowes and Sons,
1835), 54.
174 “Participation At The Second World Meeting Of Popular Movements Address Of The Holy Father” (July 9, 2015),
http://w2.vatican.va/content/francesco/en/speeches/2015/july/documents/papa-francesco_20150709_bolivia-movimenti-
popolari.html
175 William F. Buckley credits the quote to early National Review collaborator Willi Schlamm. For more, see
https://quoteinvestigator.com/2016/06/30/trouble/#return-note-13985-5.
176 “Visit To The Joint Session Of The United States Congress Address Of The Holy Father” (September 24, 2015),
http://w2.vatican.va/content/francesco/en/speeches/2015/september/documents/papa-francesco_20150924_usa-us-
congress.html
177 Thomas D. Williams, “Pope Francis’s praise of capitalism a surprise on US trip,” Crux (September 21, 2016),
https://cruxnow.com/commentary/2016/09/21/pope-franciss-praise-capitalism-surprise-us-trip/.
178 Collin Ruane, “Pope Francis: ‘The Marxist ideology is wrong,’” Atlanta Journal Constitution (December 15, 2013),
https://www.ajc.com/news/national/pope-francis-the-marxist-ideology-wrong/aNTHEz6PA621Kurl0ZHJWP/.
179 James M. Buchanan, What Should Economists Do? Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 30, No. 3 (January 1964), 213–222.
15
In 1 Timothy 5:18, St. Paul defends paying priests a salary for their work by
citing the words of Jesus: “The laborer deserves his wages” (Luke 10:7).
Employers must pay workers what they were promised, and unjustly
holding back these wages is the sin of wage theft. St. James has a frightful
message for these sinners: “Behold, the wages of the laborers who mowed
your fields, which you kept back by fraud, cry out; and the cries of the
harvesters have reached the ears of the Lord of hosts” (5:4).
But there is more to the Church’s teaching on what constitutes a just wage
than merely keeping a promise to pay someone (CCC 2434). In Rerum
Novarum, Leo XIII reminds employers that the most important thing they
must give an employee is not a wage, per se, but respect as a human being.
WRONG PRINCIPLES FOR RIGHT WAGES
Leo says that “to misuse men as though they were things in the pursuit of
gain, or to value them solely for their physical powers—that is truly
shameful and inhuman.” Workers are not mere instruments that produce
labor for a company. Employers owe them fair conditions along with fair
wages, which includes conditions that support the worker’s spiritual good:
The employer is bound to see that the worker has time for his religious
duties; that he be not exposed to corrupting influences and dangerous
occasions; and that he be not led away to neglect his home and family, or
to squander his earnings. Furthermore, the employer must never tax his
work people beyond their strength, or employ them in work unsuited to
their sex and age. (Rerum Novarum 20)
In the forty years that elapsed between Rerum Novarum and
Quadragesimo Anno, Pius XI noted how the state passed numerous laws,
unknown in Leo’s time, that mandated these fair conditions. These laws
“undertake the protection of life, health, strength, family, homes,
workshops, wages, and labor hazards, in fine, everything which pertains to
the condition of wage workers, with special concern for women and
children” (Quadragesimo Anno 28).
Leo says the employers’ “great and principal duty is to give everyone
what is just” which includes right conditions along with right wages (Rerum
Novarum 20). Justice means giving people what they deserve and though
it’s obvious that laborers deserve their wages, it’s less clear what makes any
particular wage just or unjust.
For example, Leo rejects the idea that the only just wage is the one a
worker agrees to receive. This may be the case for certain personal kinds of
labor (like agreeing to fix a friend’s fence) that are be done for little or no
money at all. But because labor is primarily ordered toward man’s self-
preservation, “there underlies a dictate of natural justice more imperious
and ancient than any bargain between man and man, namely, that wages
ought not to be insufficient to support a frugal and well behaved wage-
earner” (45). Because God gave human beings labor as a way to provide for
their own existence, it follows that there must be a way for people to
support themselves through honest work. The fruit of labor is meant to
benefit the worker in this way, but that fruit does not solely belong to the
worker.
On the other hand, Pius XI dismisses the Marxist “labor theory of value”
that says a worker is simply entitled to all the surplus value of his work.
Pius calls it a “fictitious moral principle” that claims “all products and
profits, save only enough to repair and renew capital, belong by very right
to the workers” (Quadragesimo Anno 55). According to this fictitious
principle, if a worker makes a pair of shoes that are sold for $50, he is
entitled to that sum minus expenses and overheads. Pius says approaches
like these are “shallow” because those who peddle them “think this most
difficult matter [about wages] is easily solved by the application of a single
rule or measure—and one quite false” (67).
We’ll talk more about the labor of theory of value in the next chapter, but
for now you can see this theory is flawed because it denies the employer the
right to be compensated for the risks he takes in creating and operating the
shoe company. Pius speaks of these entrepreneurs as representing
“property” interests because they own property like factories, whereas
workers represent “labor” interests. Pius says that “it is wholly false to
ascribe to property alone or to labor alone whatever has been obtained
through the combined effort of both, and it is wholly unjust for either,
denying the efficacy of the other, to arrogate to itself whatever has been
produced” (53).
Instead, this value must be divided between the parties and, although the
Church does not give an exact formula for how to do this, it does give
principles that set upper and lower limits for wages.
FAIR PRINCIPLES FOR FAIR WAGES
Concerning the upper limit for wages, Pius says that “it would be unjust to
demand excessive wages which a business cannot stand without ruin and
consequent calamity to the workers.” If a company reduces wages because
of its own mismanagement, he adds, they are morally responsible for the
harm that befalls its workers. But, if an external pressure forces companies
to, for example, “sell its product at less than a just price,” then companies
are not morally responsible for providing less-fair wages. Instead, it is the
parties who exerted these unfair external pressures that are to blame.
Moreover, there must be an upper limit to wages in order to preserve a kind
of equilibrium in the workforce that provides “suitable means of livelihood
. . . to the greatest possible number.” Pius explains how
the opportunity to work [ought] be provided to those who are able and
willing to work. This opportunity depends largely on the wage and salary
rate, which can help as long as it is kept within proper limits, but which on
the other hand can be an obstacle if it exceeds these limits. For everyone
knows that an excessive lowering of wages, or their increase beyond due
measure, causes unemployment (Quadragesimo Anno 74).
When wages are too low, people don’t have incentive to work and thus
they remain unemployed. But when wages are too high, employers may
reduce their operating costs by hiring fewer workers.
Even though labor is not merely a commodity, the price for a person’s
labor does behave like the prices for other goods. When a certain kind of
labor skill is relatively rare (like dishwasher repair and maintenance) the
price to buy this labor is higher than the price for more-common labor skills
(like dishwashing). Catholic social doctrine strikes a balance between
paying someone for the objective value of his labor (which is always a
function of the overall supply of labor) and insuring that his basic human
needs are met. The Catechism says,
In determining fair pay both the needs and the contributions of each
person must be taken into account. Remuneration for work should
guarantee man the opportunity to provide a dignified livelihood for
himself and his family on the material, social, cultural, and spiritual level,
taking into account the role and the productivity of each, the state of the
business, and the common good (CCC 2434).
Pope Leo said that “the worker must be paid a wage sufficient to support
him and his family.” But in a modern economy, it’s not possible for every
single occupation to pay a “family wage” that can support a spouse and
children. The federal minimum wage, for example, is about half or a third
of a family wage that can support dependents in most places.
For popes like Leo XIII and Pius XI, the answer to this dilemma is not
found in a simple government policy like a law mandating a family wage
for all jobs, which would raise unemployment to obscene levels. Leo
proposes that, following the principle of subsidiarity, workers should seek
just wages through organized bodies like labor unions, with state
intervention being a last resort to ensure they are treated justly (Rerum
Novarum 45). The pope sees unions operating under Christian principles as
the best replacement for defunct guilds (which in the Middle Ages kept
wages higher by restricting competition) and adds:
The state should watch over these societies of citizens banded together in
accordance with their rights, but it should not thrust itself into their
peculiar concerns and their organization, for things move and live by the
spirit inspiring them, and may be killed by the rough grasp of a hand from
without (55).
Pius warns that these incursions into the market can be bad for the state as
well as workers. If the state took over every labor issue that used to belong
to guilds and unions, it would be “overwhelmed and crushed by almost
infinite tasks and duties” (Quadragesimo Anno 78). Such incursions would
also fail to respect “the role and the productivity of each [worker], the state
of the business, and the common good,” so a more complex solution is
required to make sure that a worker’s needs are met without disrupting the
common good of society.
• The Church recognizes that just wages take into account the legitimate interests of labor and
ownership, which both play an indispensable role in the creation of wealth.
• Leo XIII and Pius XI believed that organized bodies of workers, such as labor unions, negotiating
with ownership, is a better way to achieve just wages than state intervention.
16
Some critics of capitalism say it is unjust to expect people to work for any
wage, be it high or low. One critic claims, “The ruthless emphasis on profits
over people [leads to] the proliferation of wage slavery—in which people
have no choice but to sell their labor.”180 The “wage slavery” argument
asserts that there is no morally relevant difference between forcing a person
to work under the threat of punishment (i.e., traditional slavery) and forcing
a person to work under the threat of withholding the wages he needs to
survive.
The anarchist Emma Goldman once compared working for a wage to
working for a slave owner, saying, “The only difference is that you are
hired slaves instead of block [auction-bought] slaves.”181 Noam Chomsky
agrees, saying, “It’s not an odd view, that there isn’t much difference
between selling yourself and renting yourself.”182 These kinds of arguments
are common among socialists, especially anarchist socialists who believe
human beings should not have to submit to any authority. But they aren’t
persuasive because, as Leo XIII said, they don’t “see the world as it really
is.”
THE MYTH OF “WAGE SLAVERY”
Slave owners in the antebellum South made the same basic argument as
Chomsky, saying that if blacks could be “forced” to work in Northern
factories for wages then there was nothing wrong with forcing them to work
on Southern plantations.183 But obviously there is a difference between
working for a master and working for an employer. Slaves can’t quit and
choose to work for another master, but wageworkers can. Not only does this
respect human freedom, unlike slavery, but it also encourages employers to
compete for their labor and helps raise wages over time.
“Wage slavery” is really just an obtuse way of saying that people have to
work even if they don’t want to, because the alternative is starvation. This
objection also assumes that capitalists never have to worry about money
because they own the means of production. But factories don’t produce
money; they produce goods, and if no one buys what the capitalist offers
then he can’t support himself either.
Comparatively few people want to undertake the risks and long hours that
most business owners face. That’s why most of us choose to work for
someone else, someone who has taken on those entrepreneurial risks for us.
Does the fact that we choose not to live off the land or run our own business
(or are unable to) in order to survive really make us slaves? On the other
hand, the economist Bryan Caplan says that if society can take all of your
excess wealth and redistribute it, then you would essentially be a slave,
since in exchange for their labor slaves are only given enough to survive.184
EXPLOITATIVE WORK?
Even if we aren’t “wage slaves,” many other critics say that jobs under
capitalism still exploit workers, since work is by its nature onerous. Marx
said that modern industries “destroy every remnant of charm in his work
and turn it into a hated toil.”185 Socialist journalism professor Robert Jensen
laments that “the jobs we do are not rewarding, not enjoyable, and
fundamentally not worth doing. We do them to survive. Then on Friday we
go out and get drunk to forget about that reality.”186
Except, when we look at actual data, this isn’t true.
In 1830, Americans in manufacturing jobs worked close to seventy hours
a week.187 But as companies increased their production output that number
dropped to sixty hours in 1890 and then to forty-two hours in 1930.188 And
while the number of hours has remained at that level, the number of
Americans who reported being completely or somewhat satisfied with their
job has continued to rise, going from 79 percent in 1993 to 90 percent in
2018.189
What about developing countries? Some socialists claim we are only able
to work less because capitalism exploits poor workers abroad. Jensen says
we should “put this in a global context. Half the world’s population lives on
less than $2 a day. That’s more than three billion people.”190 But this is like
blaming a firefighter because he was only able to keep half the house from
burning down. If he hadn’t shown up, the entire home would be in ashes,
and the same is true when it comes to capitalism and global poverty.
In 1820, 94 percent of people lived on the equivalent of less than $2 a day,
and for all previous human history that figure was probably closer to 99
percent.191 Today, it is not half of people that live in such extreme poverty
(as Jensen claims), but 10 percent.192 That’s still hundreds of millions of
people who are suffering, but capitalism shouldn’t be blamed for this, but
rather be given credit for doing in 200 years what the human race couldn’t
achieve in the previous 20,000.
Indeed, areas of extreme poverty around the world need more capitalism,
not less.
FREE MARKETS AND PROSPEROUS PEOPLE
In 1990, 60 percent of people in East Asia lived in extreme poverty, higher
even than sub-Sahara Africa. By 2015, less than 3 percent of East Asia
experienced extreme poverty while southern African poverty was still stuck
at around 40 percent.193 Capitalism explains much of this difference. East
Asian “tiger economies” like Taiwan, Singapore, and South Korea (along
with China, a latecomer to some free market activity) respect private
property rights and have allowed businesses to grow and flourish. But in
many sub-Saharan African countries, socialism, corruption, and
government incompetence have combined to repress property rights and
stifle the generation of wealth.
As Greg Mills describes in his book Why Africa Is Poor, the nation of
Zambia suffered for three decades under the policies of the socialist UNIP
party and its president Kenneth Kaunda. Mills shows how
Kaunda’s socialism has created a civil service geared to protectionism and
regulation at all costs, and a private sector attuned to working within a
system that rewards insiders and discourages independent
entrepreneurship. (We should not underestimate the fact that this system, a
feature of most African countries, works just fine for the elite.)194
Critics often point to manufacturing sweatshops and other harsh working
conditions in Asian countries as evidence that capitalism is evil. And in
many cases there certainly is room for making those conditions more just
and humane. But we must also bear in mind that for many of these workers
the alternatives are even worse. The economist Paul Kruger points out that
when sweatshops in Bangladesh stopped hiring children, the “displaced
child workers ended up in even worse jobs, or on the streets—and that a
significant number were forced into prostitution.”195 What the Austrian
economist Ludwig von Mises said of nineteenth-century factory workers is
still true for many workers around the world today:
It is a distortion of facts to say that the factories carried off the housewives
from the nurseries and the kitchens and the children from their play. These
women had nothing to cook with and to feed their children. These children
were destitute and starving. Their only refuge was the factory. It saved
them, in the strict sense of the term, from death by starvation.196
Many people today labor under unjust or undignified conditions. The
solution to their suffering, however, is to improve those conditions, not do
away with the economic system that offers the best chance to provide those
improvements. To that end, we should remember the old saying, “Do not
make the perfect the enemy of the good.”
NO EASY SOLUTIONS
When Marxist sociologist Erik Olin Wright quipped that “the hallmark of
capitalism is poverty in the midst of plenty,” he did have a point. We should
be upset when some people don’t have enough to eat while others eat so
much that it becomes a health problem. The title of Ronald Sider’s 1978
book on poverty—Rich Christians in an Age of Hunger—is a gut punch for
people of faith. But we must remember that capitalism did not create
poverty among the wealthy: it created wealthy people among the poor.
Poverty was the normal existence for 99 percent of all human beings
before the Industrial Revolution, and since that time poverty levels around
the globe have fallen. The reason poverty persists is not primarily an
economic problem; it’s a moral problem. This is why Popes Leo XIII and
Pius XI emphasized the so-called “social question,” which is the problem of
poverty.
This wasn’t a new question because poverty was new—it was a new
question because with modern economic growth not all men were poor.
Since there were now more people who were not poor and more people who
were rich, the “problem” was how the new, relatively wealthy were
supposed to use their wealth (to provide relief to the poor) and how the poor
were to bear their lot (that is, not agitate for socialism). Whence, in relation
to the newly wealthy, Pope Pius XI said:
A person’s superfluous income, that is, income which he does not need to
sustain life fittingly and with dignity, is not left wholly to his own free
determination. Rather the sacred scriptures and the Fathers of the Church
constantly declare in the most explicit language that the rich are bound by
a very grave precept to practice almsgiving, beneficence, and munificence
(Quadragesimo Anno 50).
People have a moral obligation to use their excess wealth to help those
who cannot even afford the basic necessities of life. But the Church also
teaches that the state should not legally enforce all of our moral obligations.
Imagine if it was a crime to break any promise or tell any lie. The evils
created by a state that meddled in every aspect of our lives would be worse
than the evils it tried to eliminate. St. Thomas Aquinas said on this matter:
The purpose of human law is to lead men to virtue, not suddenly, but
gradually. Wherefore it does not lay upon the multitude of imperfect men
the burdens of those who are already virtuous, viz. that they should
abstain from all evil. Otherwise these imperfect ones, being unable to bear
such precepts, would break out into yet greater evils.197
Our study of history shows that the same is true when the state uses
socialist policies to force people to carry out their duty to help the poor.
Socialists have never succeeded in creating the classless, poverty-free
worker’s paradise they perpetually promise to the impoverished who put
their hope in them. Instead, their collectivist solutions simply increase
poverty for everyone—except for leaders who end up having more than
they need.
As we will see in our examination of the modern “return of socialism,”
what Winston Churchill said sixty years ago is still true today: “The
inherent vice of capitalism is the unequal sharing of blessings. The inherent
virtue of socialism is the equal sharing of miseries.”198
• In places where people still labor in comparative poverty, evidence suggests that economic freedom
rather than collectivist control offers the best chance for the development necessary to lift them out
of poverty.
180 Kim Kelly, “What ‘Capitalism’ Is and How It Affects People,” Teen Vogue (April 11, 2018),
https://www.teenvogue.com/story/what-capitalism-is.
181 Emma Goldman, “Anarchy,” Emma Goldman: A Documentary History of the American Years, Volume One: Made for
America 1890–1901, ed. Candace Falk (Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press, 2008), 283.
182 Harry Kreisler, “Activism, Anarchism, and Power: Conversation with Nam Chomsky” (March 22, 2002),
http://globetrotter.berkeley.edu/people2/Chomsky/chomsky-con2.html
183 See, for example, Wilfred Carsel, “The Slaveholders’ Indictment of Northern Wage Slavery,” The Journal of Southern
History, Vol. 6, No. 4 (November 1940), 504–520.
184 “I loathe hyperbole, but if a socialist government enforced the obligation to give away all your surplus to the poor, you would
literally be a slave.” Bryan Caplan, “Capitalism vs. Socialism: The Bruenig-Caplan Debate” (March 2018),
https://www.econlib.org/archives/2018/03/capitalism_vs_s.html
185 Karl Marx, Capital, Chapter XXV (1867), https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch25.htm.
186 Robert Jensen, Anti-Capitalism in Five Minutes Counter Punch (April 30, 2007),
https://www.counterpunch.org/2007/04/30/anti-capitalism-in-five-minutes/
187 Robert A. Margo, “The Labor Force in the Nineteenth Century,” The Cambridge Economic History of the United States vol.
II, eds. Stanley L. Engerman and Robert E. Gallman (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000), 229-230.
188 Ethel B. Jones, “New Estimates of Hours of Work Per Week and Hourly Earnings, 1900–1957,” The Review of Economics
and Statistics, Vol. 45, No. 4 (November 1963), 375.
189 “Work and Workplace,” Gallup, https://news.gallup.com/poll/1720/work-work-place.aspx.
190 Robert Jensen, Anti-Capitalism in Five Minutes Counter Punch (April 30, 2007),
https://www.counterpunch.org/2007/04/30/anti-capitalism-in-five-minutes/
191 François Bourguignon and Christian Morrison, “Inequality among World Citizens: 1820–1992,” The American Economic
Review, Vol. 92, No. 4. (September 2002) 733. Cited in Max Roser and Esteban Ortiz-Ospina, “Global Extreme Poverty,” Our
World in Data (March 27, 2017), https://ourworldindata.org/extreme-poverty.
192 “Nearly Half the World Lives on Less than $5.50 a Day,” The World Bank (October 17, 2018),
https://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2018/10/17/nearly-half-the-world-lives-on-less-than-550-a-day
193 “Regional aggregation using 2011 PPP and $1.9/day poverty line,” The World Bank,
http://iresearch.worldbank.org/PovcalNet/povDuplicateWB.aspx Cited in Max Roser and Esteban Ortiz-Ospina, “Global
Extreme Poverty” Our World in Data (March 27, 2017), https://ourworldindata.org/extreme-poverty
194 Greg Mills, Why Africa is Poor (New York: Penguin Books, 2012), Kindle edition.
195 Paul Krugman, “Reckonings: Hearts and Heads” The New York Times (April 22, 2001),
https://www.nytimes.com/2001/04/22/opinion/reckonings-hearts-and-heads.html
196 Ludwig Von Mises, Human Action: The Scholar’s Edition (Auburn, AL: Ludwig Von Mises Institute, 1998), 615.
197 Summa Theologiae, I–II, Q. 96, A. 2
198 James C. Humes, Churchill: The Prophetic Statesman (Washington, D.C.: Regnery Books, 2012), 73.
Part Five
Socialism
Reconstructed
17
There was once a group of mice that wanted a solution to the cat who
constantly hunted them. One mouse proposed that a bell be tied around the
cat’s neck to provide them with a warning whenever it was near. The other
mice applauded his plan until an older mouse spoke up and said, “Yes, but
who will bell the cat?”
One collection of fables describes the lesson to be learned: it is easy to
propose impossible remedies. The same lesson applies to socialism.
Like belling the cat, the rewards and goal are easy to explain. They want
to eliminate poverty by planning the economy and redistributing wealth.
But the mechanism to achieve the goal isn’t spelled out, because it can’t be
done. Central planners can never efficiently meet diverse consumer needs,
which is something all the failed socialist states we’ve examined in this
book prove beyond doubt.
“But they didn’t practice true socialism!” the critic responds.
Well, if they weren’t practitioners of “true socialism,” then who is?
Socialists know that they can’t be taken seriously if they can’t provide
even one example of their theory working in real life. That’s why when
critics ask them about China, North Korea, and the Soviet Union, they
usually reply in kind by asking, “What about Denmark, Norway, and
Sweden? They practice democratic socialism and they have the highest
living standards in the world!”
(NON-) SOCIALIST SCANDINAVIA
In her Catholic defense of democratic socialism, Brianne Jacobs says young
people are not afraid of socialism because, unlike their parents, they don’t
associate socialism with threats to freedom like the Soviet Union. Instead,
“We tend to associate socialism with democracies: Sweden, Norway,
Denmark, Finland—countries that have low economic inequality and a high
quality of life, achieved through universal social programs and financed
through high tax rates.”199
But remember that social welfare, or government spending on the poor, is
not the same as socialism, or government planning of the economy. Nordic
countries have generous social welfare programs, but they are nowhere near
socialism because they have a robust system of private property protections.
According to the Heritage Foundation’s economic freedom index, Hong
Kong and Singapore are the most capitalist economies on earth while North
Korea and Venezuela are the most socialist. In between these two extremes,
you have countries with mixed models like France, which ranks 70 out of
180 when it comes to economic freedom. This is probably due to that
country’s “indicative planning” that relies on government persuasion to
plan the economy through things like grants and tax breaks instead of
government coercion through socialist policies like price controls and
production quotas.200
So where do the Nordic countries fall on the economic freedom index?
Denmark, Sweden, Finland, and Norway rank fourteen, nineteen, twenty,
and twenty-six respectively.201 Compared with the rest of the world, they
have relatively free markets and are much more like the United States
(which ranks twelfth) than socialist Venezuela (which ranks at 177). When
Denmark was held up as an example of socialism in the 2015 presidential
primary debates, the prime minister of Denmark said in response:
I know that some people in the U.S. associate the Nordic model with some
sort of socialism. Therefore I would like to make one thing clear. Denmark
is far from a socialist planned economy. Denmark is a market economy.
The Nordic model is an expanded welfare state which provides a high
level of security for its citizens, but it is also a successful market economy
with much freedom to pursue your dreams and live your life as you
wish.202
ECONOMIC TRADEOFFS
It’s understandable why so many people are attracted to Nordic economic
models. They claim to offer free college, free health care, generous
minimum wages, along with vacation plans and retirement benefits for
workers. These countries also have relatively low poverty rates and come in
at the top of lists that rank countries by the quality of life they provide for
their citizens. But economic models always involve trading one kind of
good for another kind of good, and the Nordic model is no exception.
Unlike with socialism, Catholics can reasonably disagree over whether the
Nordic model should be replicated in other countries, but that debate should
highlight some of the tradeoffs inherent in these models as well as
misconceptions people have about them, such as:
• Nordic countries do not have minimum wage laws. Their higher wages are
usually the result of collective bargaining agreements between unions and
employers, which, you’ll recall, was Pope Leo XIII’s preferred alternative
to government regulation.203
• Nordic countries have very high tax rates and their citizens have lower
average incomes than citizens in countries like Japan or the United
States.204
• Nordic countries have some of the longest wait times to see medical
providers, which may explain why the number of private health insurance
plans doubled in Sweden between 2006 and 2011.205
• Although Nordic schools, including colleges, do not charge tuition, they
often charge high fees, and students still accumulate debt because of the
region’s high cost of living.206 Education options are also limited, which
can be seen in the non-existence of private schools in Finland and the
illegality of homeschooling in Sweden.207
• Welfare states like those in Scandinavia can experience slower economic
growth when immigration rates increase.208 Consequently, these countries
have to make a choice between reducing social services or reducing the
number of immigrants they are willing to accept into the country.
In some cases, these tradeoffs would make these models impermissible
from a Catholic perspective. These include policies that forbid parents from
providing their children with religious education by outlawing home and
parochial schools in favor of government education. But in other cases they
can represent a legitimate model Catholics may support, provided that these
models are not employed as a path to socialism.
THE SCALING PROBLEM
Economic models cannot be applied universally and, at certain scales, they
stop working. Centralizing food storage and allocating it based on
individual need works great for a single-family home or even a small
religious community. But such a model would be impractical for entire
neighborhoods and, as history grimly reminds us, can be fatal for entire
countries. The same is true for some national economic policies, which can
work in smaller, more homogenous countries whose citizens share similar
values but may become unwieldy in larger, more diverse ones.
Monaco and Luxembourg have even higher standards of living than the
Nordic countries, but they only have populations of 40,000 and 600,000
people respectively. After the 2008 financial crisis, Barack Obama was
asked about copying Sweden’s plan to nationalize banks in order to protect
them from insolvency due to bad investments. In response, President
Obama said, “Sweden looks like a good model. Here’s the problem:
Sweden had like five banks. We’ve got thousands of banks. You know, the
scale of the U.S. economy and the capital markets are so vast . . . it
wouldn’t make sense.”209
Among countries that have more than 100 million citizens, Japan and the
United States rank first and second when it comes to providing people with
a high quality of life.210 Of course, when a country has both a large
geographic area and a high population, there can be dramatic differences in
the quality of life people enjoy in the various cities in that country. But the
cities across the globe with the highest quality of life tend to be found in
free democracies, whereas the worst cities in the world, such as Lagos,
Nigeria and Caracas, Venezuela, tend to be found in countries that restrict
both personal and economic freedoms.211 As we turn in the next chapter to
the reality of what happens when countries fully embrace socialist policies,
you’ll see why Venezuela earns this failing grade.
• Economic and political models that are reasonably successful on small scales—a family, a town,
even a small nation—often do not translate to larger scales.
• These “Nordic models” also come with tradeoffs, some of which would be intolerable from a
Catholic perspective.
199 Brianne Jacobs, “Yes, democratic socialism is compatible with Catholic social teaching,” America (October 1, 2018),
https://www.americamagazine.org/politics-society/2018/10/01/yes-democratic-socialism-compatible-catholic-social-teaching.
200 For an overview, see chapter seven of Barkley Rosser Jr. and Marina V. Rosser’s Comparative Economics in a Transforming
World Economy (2004).
201 See “2019 Index of Economic Freedom,” https://www.heritage.org/index/ranking.
202 “Danish PM in US: Denmark is not socialist,” The Local (November 1, 2015), https://www.thelocal.dk/20151101/danish-pm-
in-us-denmark-is-not-socialist
203 “None of the Nordic countries has a statutory minimum wage. Nor, with the exception of Finland, do they have a tradition of
extending collective agreements to unorganized enterprises.” Kristine Nergaard, “Social Democratic Capitalism,” The Oxford
Handbook of Employment Relations, eds. Adrian Wilkinson, Geoffrey Wood, Richard Deeg (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2014),
204 “The 4.4 million or so Americans with Swedish origins are considerably richer than average Americans, as are other
immigrant groups from Scandinavia. If Americans with Swedish ancestry were to form their own country, their per capita GDP
would be $56,900, more than $10,000 above the income of the average American. This is also far above Swedish GDP per
capita, at $36,600. Swedes living in the USA are thus approximately 53 per cent more wealthy than Swedes (excluding
immigrants) in their native country (OECD, 2009; US Census database).” Nima Sanandaji, “The surprising ingredients of
Swedish success – free markets and social cohesion,” IEA Discussion Paper, No. 41 (August 2012), https://iea.org.uk/wp-
content/uploads/2016/07/Sweden percent20Paper.pdf
205 “Voluntary health insurance in Europe: Country experience,” Observatory Studies Series, No. 42. eds. A. Sagan and S.
Thomson (2016), https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/NBK447719/.
206 Matt Phillips, “The High Price of a Free College Education in Sweden,” The Atlantic (May 31, 2013),
https://www.theatlantic.com/international/archive/2013/05/the-high-price-of-a-free-college-education-in-sweden/276428/
207 “Only a small number of independent schools exist in Finland, and even they are all publicly financed. None is allowed to
charge tuition fees. There are no private universities, either. This means that practically every person in Finland attends public
school, whether for pre-K or a Ph.D.” Anu Partanen, “What Americans Keep Ignoring About Finland’s School Success,” The
Atlantic (December 29, 2011), https://www.theatlantic.com/national/archive/2011/12/what-americans-keep-ignoring-about-
finlands-school-success/250564/. “Placing much more control in the hands of the government, the new law affects not only
homeschoolers but all families in Sweden. The law now mandates a national curriculum and obliterates the notion of
‘independent’ (or private) schools and school choice.” John Warwick Montgomery, “The Justification of Homeschooling Vis-à-
vis the European Human Rights System,” Homeschooling in America and in Europe: A Litmus Test of Democracy, ed. John
Warwick Montgomery (Eugene, OR: Wipf and Stock, 2013), 80.
208 Marianne Frank Hansen and Marie Louise Schultz-Nielsen, “The fiscal impact of immigration to welfare states of the
Scandinavian type,” Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 30, Issue 3 (July 2017), 925–952.
209 Joe Weisenthal, “Obama: Swedish Model Would Be Impossible Here,” Business Insider (February 11, 2009),
https://www.businessinsider.com/obama-swedish-model-would-be-impossible-here-2009-2.
210 As of 2019, the countries with populations of more than 100 million include China, India, United States, Indonesia, Pakistan,
Brazil, Nigeria, Bangladesh, Russia, Mexico, Japan, Ethiopia, and the Philippines. According to the Numbeo quality of life
index, Japan scores a 180.5 and the U.S. scores a 179.2. The next closest is Mexico with a 123.48. The highest scoring country
is Denmark with a 198.57. “Quality of Life Index for Country 2019,” https://www.numbeo.com/quality-of-
life/rankings_by_country.jsp?title=2019.
211 “Quality of Life Index 2019 Mid-Year,” https://www.numbeo.com/quality-of-life/rankings.jsp.
18
The Venezuelan
Reality
In the 1970s, Venezuela was one of the richest, most stable countries in
Latin America, due in large part to its vast oil reserves. The government’s
revenue quadrupled during the 1973 oil crisis and politicians made plans
like La Gran Venezuela that would nationalize the oil industry and allow the
country to splurge on public entitlement programs. According to journalist
Michael McCaughan, “Venezuelan workers enjoyed the highest wages in
Latin America and subsidies in food, health, education, and transport
sectors.”212
But when oil prices began to decline in the 1980s, so did the Venezuelan
economy.
By the late 1990s, worker income was half of what it had been in the
1970s, and riots in the city’s capital of Caracas left hundreds dead.213 In
1998, populist presidential candidate Hugo Chavez promised to use
Venezuela’s oil reserves for the benefit of the poor and campaigned on the
slogan, “Motherland, Socialism, or Death.”214 Chavez won the election with
56 percent of the vote, most of it coming from the country’s poor and
middle-class citizens. He appointed his own advisers to lead the country’s
oil industry, which subsequently became a piggy bank from which Chavez
spent lavishly on social programs. In a speech he gave to the World Fund he
declared:
We must transcend capitalism. But we cannot resort to state capitalism,
which would be the same perversion of the Soviet Union. We must
reclaim socialism as a thesis, a project, and a path, but a new type of
socialism, a humanist one, which puts humans and not machines or the
state ahead of everything.215
¡VIVA CHAVEZ!
In the early 2000s, Chavez launched a series of welfare programs called
“missions” that provided subsidized food and free medical care to
impoverished citizens. One 2006 report showed that the programs helped
Chavez win reelection, but problems were already starting to emerge with
the demand they created. The reporter observed “long lines form outside the
supermarkets known as Mercals,” with a “mother of three shout[ing] at
security guards keeping her waiting for an hour.” However, the mother
admitted she would still vote for Chavez because, “He’s giving us all these
benefits and needs our support . . . so he can keep giving more benefits.”216
In order to keep the welfare system functioning, Chavez initiated price
controls on staples like rice, milk, and meat. He ordered companies that
produced these goods both to sell them at low prices and increase their
production in order to meet consumer demand. When the companies
complained that they would go out of business by being forced to sell goods
at such low prices, Chavez sent his troops in to make sure they would
comply. When that didn’t work, he had the government take over the
businesses through a process called expropriation.
According to a 2019 feature in the Washington Post, “In two decades, the
government seized nearly five million acres of productive farmland that has
now been largely abandoned. In 1999, there were 490,000 private
companies in Venezuela. By last June—the most recent count available—
that number had fallen to 280,000.”217 Venezuela also drove out foreign oil
companies and nationalized domestic steel, glass, and food production. A
2010 article in The Economist described how a typical “expropriation”
occurs with the example of Owens Illinois, an American-owned bottle
manufacturer:
In his usual style, Mr. Chavez offhandedly slipped the announcement into
the middle of a speech lasting several hours, which all radio and television
stations were required to carry . . . Owens Illinois was given no advance
warning of the measure, and new management entered the factory just a
few days after it was announced.218
The article goes to describe how Chavez was committed to “the
elimination of capitalism” and that he “believes individuals should be
entitled to their personal belongings, but not control of the means of
production.” But although in theory “the people” owned the means of
production, it was the state that controlled the factories that produced the
goods. And without any profit motivation, their production rates steadily
declined until Venezuela went from being a country that produced most of
its own food to one that imported most of it.219
In spite of these moves, Venezuela was still surviving economically
because of oil prices that went (when adjusted for inflation) from $19 a
barrel when Chavez was first elected to nearly $100 a barrel when he died
in 2013. In the wake of his death, journalists, academics, and celebrities
lionized Chavez and praised Venezuela as evidence that socialism can work
if it’s “done right.”
A BETTER WORLD
Remember that, at this point, hardly anyone doubted that Venezuela
represented “true socialism.” The economy was centrally planned, the
government abolished large sectors of private industry, such as factories and
farms, and the wealth produced from these resources was redistributed
among the people, just as with every other socialist country in history.
Noam Chomsky visited the country in 2009 and said, “What’s so exciting
about at last visiting Venezuela is that I can see how a better world is being
created.”220 David Sirota of Salon.com admitted “Chavez was no saint” due
to his authoritarian policies but he still called the Venezuelan economy “a
miracle” that can teach us how to alleviate poverty.221 Jacobin magazine
likewise praised Venezuela’s reduction in poverty and said, “Today we
mourn the death of Chavez, tomorrow we return to the grind for
socialism.”222
When conditions deteriorated after Chavez’s death and lines to buy items
like toilet paper started to emerge, economist Mark Weisbrot called those
who predicted disaster “haters” who had “cried wolf.” He asked, “How can
a government with more than $90bn in oil revenue end up with a balance-
of-payments crisis?” His answer: “It can’t, and won’t.”223
Weisbrot had also served as an adviser to Oliver Stone’s 2009 film South
of the Border, which portrayed Latin American socialism as an economic
boon to the region and its socialist leaders as friendly rulers that people
would love if they got to know them. In one scene, Chavez rides a bicycle
in his grandmother’s backyard but the bicycle collapses under his weight—
a prophetic symbol of the Venezuelan economy.
When Chavez died, filmmaker Michael Moore wrote on social media,
“Hugo Chavez declared the oil belonged to the people. He used the oil
money to eliminate 75 percent of extreme poverty, provide free health care
and education for all.”224 Stone simply said that Chavez “will live forever in
history.”225
CONSEQUENCES AND EXCUSES
From 2014 to 2016, oil prices dropped from $110 a barrel to less than $40,
gutting Venezuela’s economy. Without ample revenue from oil exports, the
government had to cut back on its social programs and could no longer
subsidize its thousands of nationalized industries.
The electric companies, which were supposed to provide “free electricity”
for the people, were now experiencing weekly blackouts.226 The national
water company made similar promises of cheap utilities, but because it had
no incentive to invest in its infrastructure, water pumps failed and people in
the capital of Caracas could only access water for about an hour a day.227
Food also became scarce because imports necessary to offset the loss of
domestic food production were now too expensive.
In 2016, the government tried to offset the shortage by passing a law
allowing it to force people to engage in agricultural work. Not only was this
repressive and hypocritical according to socialism’s alleged “pro-worker”
ideals, it was also futile. As a director of the human rights organization
Amnesty International said in response, “Trying to tackle Venezuela’s
severe food shortages by forcing people to work the fields is like trying to
fix a broken leg with a band aid.”228
Indeed, grocery store shelves remain empty. In 2017, the average
Venezuelan lost 24 pounds, thanks to what the locals wryly dubbed the
“Venezuelan diet.”229 The country has refused to release medical statistics
since 2013, but outside researchers estimate infant mortality has increased
by about 50 percent, to a level that hadn’t been seen in nearly two
decades.230 Chavez’s successor Nicholas Maduro tried to solve the problem
by printing more money, but this led to hyperinflation, making Venezuelan
currency essentially worthless.
By 2019, the Venezuelan economy was half of what it had been under
Chavez and inflation rates were at nearly ten million percent.231 Maduro
raised the country’s minimum wage to 18,000 bolivars, which in previous
years would have been equivalent to $3,000. However, because the bolivar
wasn’t worth the paper it was printed on, this monthly minimum wage was
equivalent to six U.S. dollars; enough to buy three pounds of chicken.232
With the currency now worthless, people resorted to bartering to get what
they needed. Taxi rides were paid in cigarettes and you could get a haircut
for five bananas and two eggs.233
Defenders of socialism have come up with a variety of excuses for the
Venezuelan crisis that try to place the blame on anything but socialism.
Most point to falling oil prices; but that doesn’t explain how countries with
similar dependencies on oil exports, like Kuwait and Saudi Arabia,
managed to avoid economic catastrophe. Others blamed the collapse on
“mismanagement,” but that’s just a variation on the claim that when
socialism fails it’s because it wasn’t “true” (properly managed) socialism.
Yet the reality is, that’s what always happens in socialist economies. Instead
of allowing prices to be set by natural consumer demand and realistic
business supply, socialist governments like Venezuela set price controls and
production quotas that can’t be sustained. Socialism is mismanagement by
definition.
Since 2014, four million Venezuelans have fled the country, resulting in
the largest displacement of people in recent Latin-American history.234 In an
editorial with the headline, “Venezuela was my home, and socialism
destroyed it. Slowly, it will destroy America, too,” Venezuelan expatriate
Daniel Di Martino calls the government’s excuses for the country’s woes
“hollow.” He writes, “Venezuela has the largest proven oil reserves in the
world to use for electricity, and three times more fresh water resources per
person than the United States. The real reason my family went without
water and electricity was the socialist economy instituted by dictators Hugo
Chavez and Nicolas Maduro.”235
• The hyperinflation, degradation of industry and agriculture, and political repression that socialism
brought to Venezuela are features, not bugs, of that economic system.
212 Michael McCaughan, The Battle of Venezuela (New York: Seven Stories, 2005), 63.
213 Ibid., 65–66.
214 Adriana Bolívar, Political Discourse as Dialogue: A Latin American Perspective (New York: Routledge, 2018), electronic
edition.
215 Mike Cole, Critical Race Theory and Education: A Marxist Response (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009), 127.
216 Julie McCarthy, “Chavez Reaches Out with ‘Bolivarian Missions,’” NPR (December 3, 2006),
https://www.npr.org/templates/story/story.php?storyId=6572676
217 Anthony Faiola, “In socialist Venezuela, a crisis of faith not in just their leader but their economic model,” The Washington
Post (February 11, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/the_americas/in-socialist-venezuela-a-crisis-of-faith-not-in-
just-their-leader-but-their-economic-model/2019/02/11/ea67849e-2b33-11e9-906e-9d55b6451eb4_story.html
218 “Full speed ahead,” The Economist (October 29, 2010), https://www.economist.com/americas-view/2010/10/29/full-speed-
ahead.
219 Emma Graham-Harrison, “Hunger eats away at Venezuela’s soul as its people struggle to survive,” The Guardian (August 26,
2017), https://www.theguardian.com/world/2017/aug/26/nicolas-maduro-donald-trump-venezuela-hunger.
220 James Suggett, “Chomsky praises Venezuela’s revolution” Green Left Weekly (September 5, 2009),
https://www.greenleft.org.au/content/chomsky-praises-venezuelas-revolution.
221 David Sirota, “Hugo Chavez’s economic miracle,” Salon.com (March 6, 2013),
https://www.salon.com/2013/03/06/hugo_chavezs_economic_miracle/
222 Jeffrey Webber, “Venezuela after Chávez,” Jacobin (March 8, 2013), https://www.jacobinmag.com/2013/03/venezuela-after-
chavez
223 Mark Weisbrot, “Sorry, Venezuela Haters: This Economy Is Not the Greece of Latin America,” Common Dreams (November
7, 2013), https://www.commondreams.org/views/2013/11/07/sorry-venezuela-haters-economy-not-greece-latin-america.
224 “Hugo Chavez declared the oil belonged 2 the ppl. He used the oil $ 2 eliminate 75 percent of extreme poverty, provide free
health & education 4 all” (March 5, 2013). We have edited the tweet for readability.
https://twitter.com/mmflint/status/309124649244057600?lang=en.
225 “Hated by the entrenched classes, Hugo Chavez will live forever in history. My friend, rest finally in a peace long earned. 2/2”
(March 5, 2013), https://twitter.com/theoliverstone/status/309106639426949120.
226 Sam Jones, “Venezuela blackout: what caused it and what happens next?” The Guardian (March 13, 2019),
https://www.theguardian.com/world/2019/mar/13/venezuela-blackout-what-caused-it-and-what-happens-next.
227 Anatoly Kurmanaev and John Otis, “Water Shortage Cripples Venezuela,” The Wall Street Journal (April 3, 2016),
https://www.wsj.com/articles/water-shortage-cripples-venezuela-1459717127. See also “Venezuelan water shortage deepens
humanitarian crisis,” The Washington Post (April 4, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/the_americas/why-are-
you-crying-mami-in-venezuela-the-search-for-water-is-a-daily-struggle/2019/04/04/39972ce4-5547-11e9-814f-
e2f46684196e_story.html.
228 “Venezuela: New regime effectively amounts to forced labour,” Amnesty International (July 28, 2016),
https://www.amnesty.org/en/latest/news/2016/07/venezuela-new-regime-effectively-amounts-to-forced-labour/.
229 Vivian Sequera, “Venezuelans report big weight losses in 2017 as hunger hits,” Reuters (February 21, 2018),
https://www.reuters.com/article/us-venezuela-food/venezuelans-report-big-weight-losses-in-2017-as-hunger-hits-
idUSKCN1G52HA.
230 Jenny García, Gerardo Correa, and Brenda Rousset, “Trends in infant mortality in Venezuela between 1985 and 2016: a
systematic analysis of demographic data,” The Lancet Vol. 7, Issue 3, (March 1, 2019),
https://www.thelancet.com/journals/langlo/article/PIIS2214-109X(18)30479-0/fulltext
231 Megan Specia, “Five Things You Need to Know to Understand Venezuela’s Crisis,” The New York Times (May 3, 2019),
https://www.nytimes.com/2019/05/03/world/americas/venezuela-crisis-facts.html
232 Renzo Pipoli, “Maduro raises minimum wage in Venezuela to $6 per month,” United Press International (January 15, 2019),
https://www.upi.com/Top_News/World-News/2019/01/15/Maduro-raises-minimum-wage-in-Venezuela-to-6-per-
month/9171547575404/
233 Fabiola Zerpa, “In Venezuela, a Haircut Costs 5 Bananas and 2 Eggs,” Bloomberg (May 4, 2018),
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2018-05-04/in-caracus-venezuela-a-haircut-costs-five-bananas-and-two-eggs.
234 “The United Nations says more than 4 million refugees and migrants have left the country, which is suffering from political
chaos, food shortages and hyperinflation. The U.N. has called this exodus the ‘largest in the recent history of Latin America
and the Caribbean.’” Merritt Kennedy, “U.N. Says More Than 4 Million People Have Left Venezuela,” NPR (June 7, 2019),
https://www.npr.org/2019/06/07/730687807/u-n-says-more-than-4-million-people-have-left-venezuela.
235 Daniel Di Martino, “Venezuela was my home, and socialism destroyed it. Slowly, it will destroy America, too,” USA Today
(February 15, 2019), https://www.usatoday.com/story/opinion/voices/2019/02/15/donald-trump-venezuela-socialism-bernie-
sanders-ilhan-omar-column/2861461002/.
19
• Collectivist solutions to poverty and economic injustice substitute political fiat for the free and
virtuous living-out of human interdependence.
• Government-controlled wealth redistribution exploits “the poor man’s envy of the rich” to grow the
power of the state at the expense of the Church, the family, and other institutions that we should
trust and love more.
236 Fyodor Dostoyevsky, The Brothers Karamazov (New York: Dover, 2005), 56.
237 “Tradinista Manifesto,” https://tradinista.tumblr.com/manifesto.
238 “Ortega supporters try to infiltrate parishes. Security forces surround churches during Mass. Priests suffer harassment and
death threats. Police ring the Jesuit university when students dare to wave Nicaraguan flags and chant anti-government
slogans.” Mary Beth Sheridan, “Spies, harassment, death threats: The Catholic Church in Nicaragua says it’s being targeted by
the government.” The Washington Post (July 23, 2019), https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/the_americas/spies-
harassment-death-threats-the-catholic-church-in-nicaragua-says-its-being-targeted-by-the-government/2019/07/23/2881f814-
a3ec-11e9-a767-d7ab84aef3e9_story.html.
239 Matthew Schmitz, “I Think I’m Not a Contra,” First Things (September 29, 2016),
https://www.firstthings.com/blogs/firstthoughts/2016/09/i-think-im-not-a-contra.
240 “Employment by industry, 1910 and 2015,” Bureau of Labor Statistics (March 3, 2016),
https://www.bls.gov/opub/ted/2016/employment-by-industry-1910-and-2015.htm
241 Jose Mena, “The Catholic turn to socialism is something to celebrate,” Catholic Herald (May 30, 2019),
https://catholicherald.co.uk/commentandblogs/2019/05/30/the-catholic-turn-to-socialism-is-something-to-celebrate/.
242 Matthew Shadle, “Tradinistas: A New Catholic Socialism?, Part 2,” Political Theology Network (October 9, 2016),
https://politicaltheology.com/tradinistas-a-new-catholic-socialism-part-2-matthew-shadle/.
243 Ronald Reagan, “Socialism,” Stories in His Own Hand: The Everyday Wisdom of Ronald Reagan, eds. Kiron K. Skinner,
Annelise Anderson, and Martin Anderson (New York: The Free Press, 2001), 91. This quote comes from a letter Reagan wrote
in 1976 about a young conservative named Brad Linaweaver’s interaction with a woman who was defending socialism. Brad
said that government should guarantee people not just food and medicine but also a yacht. When his critic said that people like
him were what kept socialism from working, he deftly replied, “How many are there like me?” That’s why the original quote
ends by saying, “They don’t understand that we dream—yes, even of sometime owning a yacht.”
244 Instruction on Certain Aspects of the “Theology of Liberation,” 15.
20
For some people, the aspiration to pursue “moral capitalism” sounds like
the claim of being an “honest thief.” Even those who know that capitalism
is not intrinsically wrong may still imagine that walking the path of “moral
capitalism” is like strolling along the edge of a cliff: step over the line too
far in one direction or another and you might fall into exploitation, abuse, or
greed.
But this isn’t how the Church sees it, and it isn’t how we should see it.
The reason that Church teaching has always stressed the importance of
principles of right order is just this: so we can have confidence and peace
that in applying ourselves with hard work and diligence we can joyfully
participate in God’s co-creation—a task we are urged to take up for the
good of our families and our communities.
FOR WANT OF WANTS
Capitalism satisfies our desires to create and consume but, of itself, it
cannot tutor or censor our wants. So, for instance, capitalism is a very
effective way of satisfying the seemingly insatiable demand (want) for
pornographic material, and this was true long before the internet age.
Unlike greed, which finds a natural check of sorts in competitive markets,
disordered, evil desires do not find a natural check.
This is why Michael Novak, Catholic philosopher and friend of John Paul
II, wrote his greatest work, The Spirit of Democratic Capitalism, to talk
about the “three-legged” stool that was needed for a healthy political
economy, comprising: 1) free and democratic political order, 2) economy of
free enterprise, and 3) virtuous citizens shaped by a sound moral order.
Each of these, he believed, vitally depended upon a strong religious
framework, and the absence of any of these elements would sabotage any
economy.
For even if people are to vote, buy, and sell whatever they want, they can
still enslave themselves to inhuman wants and desires. As St. Paul said, “If
you yield yourselves to any one as obedient slaves, you are slaves of the
one whom you obey, either of sin, which leads to death, or of obedience,
which leads to righteousness?” (Rom. 6:16).
A good analogy to how we can practice moral capitalism is how we can
morally relate to food. Modern economies have made food and drink nearly
omnipresent. And since eating is pleasant, it is really easy to slide into a
kind of “food-ism” analogous to consumerism. It can happen even without
overeating or practicing the vice of gluttony in the traditional sense. We
might think of ourselves as a “foodie” who becomes obsessed with our
food, where it’s made, what it will do to us, how much we will have, and
when we will have it. Our sense of self becomes a little too wrapped up in
what we eat and how we eat.
What goes into making this possible? The easy availability of an activity
(or thing) that is pleasant, good for us, and intended by God for our joy. It’s
the same with our economic life. There was a time when we poked fun at
businessmen clutching Blackberries with a whole keyboard at their palms.
Now we are all “that guy,” and we have the capacity with a little device to
engage in more economic transactions in ten minutes than merchants of
Venice hoped for in a year’s time.
Modern capitalism makes the temporary euphoria and pleasure associated
with the activities of buying and selling a temptation to engage in too much,
too often, to where it becomes an idol, wholly divorced from its purpose of
serving virtue and the genuine human needs of ourselves and others.
Buying and selling becomes our identity, or at least a place where we
inadvertently deposit too much of our sense of security. Whatever else
happens today, we may effectively think to ourselves, at least I bought
something.
As sons and daughters of God, we are more than “producers,”
“consumers,” “utility maximizers” or even “shoppers” (no matter many
preferred customer membership cards are bloating our wallets). We are
Christians, which means capitalism isn’t a way of life, much less our
identity. However optimistic we are about entrepreneurship, business, and
free markets, economic values are not, and cannot be, the only values
(Centesimus Annus 39).
So how do we practically break free from capitalism’s consumerist
temptations?
PUTTING THINGS DOWN
First, we have to notice and understand the temptation, which is the
warping of a good thing. Just as food isn’t the problem, but giving it too
much importance is. Similarly, shopping, work, and market economies
aren’t the problem; giving it all too much importance makes it a problem.
Second, the task is to put things in order, which is also a way of putting
ourselves and our souls in order. Putting things in order has been described
as part of the virtue of justice, which is one reason why justice is not just a
cardinal virtue but is chief among the cardinal virtues. The first task of
social justice is to put ourselves into right order: in relation to ourselves, to
our neighbor, and to God.
This is a simple exercise of the sort that children practice naturally—like
putting blocks or rings of different sizes into place. The liturgical calendar
is designed for us to do just this: We put food, or drink, or other pleasures,
in their right place. We fast when a special occasion calls for it; and when
things that are not God have creeped too high in our lives, we put them
down and elevate prayer and penance above them. The wisdom of
Ecclesiastes reminds us, “For everything there is a season, and a time for
every matter under heaven . . . a time to mourn, and a time to dance; a time
to cast away stones, and a time to gather stones together” (3:1,4).
We do this repeatedly year after year because we need it. We should trust
this solution. It works—because it conforms to how we were made, and
how we are able to be sanctified in the world.
The greatest prayer of the Church is the sacramental life: thus, the path to
living morally within a market economy is to renew and exercise our
commitment to grounding our identity in God who is the supreme and final
good for us, and in the life of grace that the Church offers to us as a good
mother. We can say with confidence: If prayer and the sacraments have the
first place in our lives, we do not have to worry about falling off the
consumerist cliff. Because we were made to be vessels of grace, and when
we are filled with grace we are filled with virtue; and virtue, as the great
saints have always shown, is a life of balance and stability.
WITH ALL OUR STRENGTH
To put this in relation to our lives in a market economy—whether we think
about our role as buyers or sellers, workers or entrepreneurs, or members of
the new creative class—at the very least we need to fast from market
activities as often as sensible. This means spending more time reflecting on
the ancient traditions.
Many traditional Christian cultures have discouraged shopping on Sunday.
It’s not that shopping is wrong—but that a fast helps put it in its place, and
provides room for moving prayer and time spent outside the market higher
in our lives. John Paul II said, “When Sunday loses its fundamental
meaning and becomes merely part of a ‘weekend,’ it can happen that people
stay locked within a horizon so limited that they can no longer see ‘the
heavens.’ Hence, though ready to celebrate, they are really incapable of
doing so” (Dies Domine 4).
Other ways of fasting from economic activity—or putting things in their
place—include examining and rededicating ourselves to charitable giving.
This also helps us fight the temptation to hoard money and goods once we
accumulate a lot of them. Psychology researcher Paul Piff has shown that
poor people are actually more charitable than the wealthy because they are
better at identifying with the suffering of the poor and thus having
compassion for them.245 This leads them to make more sacrificial gifts than
wealthy people who may only give away a small percentage of their wealth.
When you read this study you can’t help but think of the widow who
deposited two coins in the temple treasury while the rich deposited their
abundant gifts. But Jesus tells us that the widow gave more than all of those
rich men put together because “they all contributed out of their abundance,
but she out of her poverty put in all the living that she had” (Luke 21:4).
In Deuteronomy 6:5, the Israelites were commanded, “Love the Lord your
God with all your heart, and with all your soul, and with all your might [or
strength].” The word for “might” is meodekah and probably referred to
one’s material possessions.246 In both the ancient and modern world, a
person’s “strength” comes not from what he can bench press but from what
he can purchase. We are commanded to love God with all our economic
strength and to use that strength to love our neighbor as ourselves. When
we don’t, we incur the same condemnation Pope Pius XI gave to the stingy
rich of his time that gave credence to the arguments of the socialists:
It is certainly most lamentable, venerable brethren, that there have been,
nay, that even now there are men who, although professing to be
Catholics, are almost completely unmindful of that sublime law of justice
and charity that binds us not only to render to everyone what is his but to
succor brothers in need as Christ the Lord himself (Quadragesimo Anno
125).
But sacrifices cannot stop at just giving money to the needy (as important
as that is). We can also sacrifice our felt need to buy things by making do
with what we have for longer, repairing instead of replacing them. We can
also sacrifice our time for the poor through volunteering or by offering up
prayers for them (indeed, in the Church’s tradition prayer and fasting
always go together).
A first step toward living good lives in a capitalist order is to follow the
five recommendations of all holy men and women: daily Mass, daily rosary,
morning and evening offering, daily reflection on Scripture, and frequent
confession. If all Catholics in capitalist economies practiced these norms,
capitalism’s inherent weaknesses would be less evident in society and its
strengths would shine brighter.
WHAT’S OLD IS STILL NEW
We have focused mainly on consumer behavior, since that reflects the
position of most readers, but moral capitalism also entails that producers
engage in acts of sacrifice for the good of their workers.
This can include making the best effort to provide high wages and benefits
that do not adversely affect overall the company’s overall financial health. It
could also include voluntarily adopting policies that allow for profit sharing
and for corporate decision-making to be more widely dispersed among a
firm’s employees. For example, witness the Catholic Mondragon
Corporation in Spain, the largest worker-owned cooperative in the world—
though socialists like Noam Chomsky still complain that it exploits its
workers because it seeks profits.247
Such proposals for employers could fill an entire other book, but we raise
them here to make it clear that opposition to socialism does not entail
support of the capitalism that John Paul II condemned: a system that lacks
moral principles and a “strong juridical framework.” Edward Feser, editor
of The Cambridge Companion to Hayek, says capitalism is immoral when it
turns into “fetishizing capitalism, of making market imperatives the
governing principles to which all other aspects of social order are
subordinate.” He notes that even a stalwart critic of socialism like Hayek:
explicitly allows for regulations to ensure safe working conditions, and for
a safety net for those unable to provide adequate food, shelter, and health
care for themselves. The Hayek who thought that the smallest tax increase
is but the first step toward the Gulag exists only in the imaginations of
uncharitable critics and simple-minded admirers.248
But carefully crafted economic policies by themselves are not enough to
bring about authentic human fulfillment. Pope Leo insists that the only way
to “restore” a fallen civilization is the “correction of morals”—transforming
hearts and minds according to human and Christian virtue whose source is
the life of God: grace. The pontiffs who have weighed in on—and against—
socialism and Communism have tirelessly proclaimed that rejecting
socialism is only part of the solution. The other part, as Pope Leo put it:
The instruments which [the Church] employs are given to her by Jesus
Christ himself for the very purpose of reaching the hearts of men, and
drive their efficiency from God. They alone can reach the innermost heart
and conscience, and bring men to act from a motive of duty, to control
their passions and appetites, to love God and their fellow men with a love
that is outstanding and of the highest degree and to break down
courageously every barrier which blocks the way to virtue (Rerum
Novarum 26).
There is no magic bullet. There is no quick fix—be it a bloody or
unbloody revolution, or a set of policy platforms, or an accumulation of
regulatory laws, that can make the world perfectly good. There is always
the cross, and the task of evangelization that is ever the job of Christians.
Though this is, properly speaking, apolitical, that doesn’t mean the Church
has no role guiding men and nations to the principles of right order—
correcting and admonishing when, for instance, wicked solutions are
proposed.
But the Church’s mission to souls means that it fully exercises her role by
lifting up and offering the food that never perishes, the food that leaves you
never hungry again, the food that no political order can offer but is
necessary for happiness in the order of this life, and more importantly, in
the order of the life to come.
• Even though wealth and free markets can be good things, as with all good things we need to fast
from them periodically in order to keep our priorities
in perspective.
• Our first identity is not that of laborer, producer, or consumer but disciple of Jesus Christ, working
out our salvation through his Church.
245 “Across these experiments, the main variable that we find that consistently explains this differential pattern of giving and
helping and generosity among the upper and lower class is feelings of sensitivity and care for the welfare of other people and,
essentially, the emotion that we call compassion. So it’s really compassionate feelings that exist among the lower class that’s
seen to provoke these higher levels of altruism and generosity toward other people.” “Study: Poor Are More Charitable than
the Wealthy,” National Public Radio (August 8, 2010), https://www.npr.org/templates/story/story.php?storyId=129068241.
246 Norman Lamm, The Shema: Spirituality and Law in Judaism (Philadelphia: The Jewish Publication Society, 2000), 142.
247 “Take the most advanced case: Mondragon. It’s worker owned, it’s not worker managed, although the management does come
from the workforce often, but it’s in a market system and they still exploit workers in South America, and they do things that
are harmful to the society as a whole and they have no choice. If you’re in a system where you must make profit in order to
survive, you’re compelled to ignore negative externalities, effects on others.” Laura Flanders, “Talking with Chomsky,”
Counterpunch (April 30, 2012), https://www.counterpunch.org/2012/04/30/talking-with-chomsky/
248 Edward Feser, “Hayek’s Tragic Capitalism,” The Claremont Review of Books (Spring 2019), 88.
APPENDIX: WHAT ABOUT DISTRIBUTISM?
After his conversion to the Catholic faith, Trent Horn earned master’s
degrees in the fields of theology, philosophy, and bioethics. He serves as a
staff apologist for Catholic Answers, where he specializes in teaching
Catholics to graciously and persuasively engage those who disagree with
them. Trent models that approach each week on the radio program Catholic
Answers Live and on his own podcast, The Counsel of Trent. He has also
been invited to debate at UC Berkeley, UC Santa Barbara, and Stanford
University. Trent is an adjunct professor of apologetics at Holy Apostles
College, has written for The National Catholic Bioethics Quarterly, and is
the author of nine books, including Answering Atheism, The Case for
Catholicism, and Why We’re Catholic: Our Reasons for Faith, Hope, and
Love.
Catherine Ruth Pakaluk, Ph.D, is assistant professor at the Busch School
of Business at The Catholic University of America. She specializes in the
economics of education and religion, family studies and demography,
Catholic social thought, and political economy. Pakaluk earned her
doctorate at Harvard University in 2010 where she studied under 2016
Nobel-laureate Oliver Hart. She has authored and co-authored highly cited
articles in journals including Economic Inquiry, Journal of Markets and
Morality, Demography, and the Journal of the National Cancer Institute.
Pakaluk is a widely admired writer and sought-after speaker on matters of
culture, gender, social science, the vocation of women, and the work of
Edith Stein. She lives in Maryland with her husband, philosopher Michael
Pakaluk, and eight children.