BA1 Chapter 2
BA1 Chapter 2
Given that resources are limited (‘scarce’), it is not possible to make everything
everyone would want (‘unlimited wants’). All societies are thus faced with a
fundamental economic problem:
There are three main economic systems or approaches to solve this problem:
Market forces:
In a free market, the quantity and price of goods supplied in a market are
determined by the interaction between supply and demand.
A market price will be set by the 'invisible hand of the market' through the
interaction of supply and demand.
Demand:
Individual demand:
For most goods, the lower the price, the higher will be its demand.
When the demand for a good or service changes in response to a change in its
price, the change is referred to as:
a) – an expansion in demand where quantity demanded rises due to a fall
in price.
b) – a contraction in demand where quantity demanded falls due to a rise
in price.
The relationship between demand and price can be shown in a diagram and is
referred to as a demand curve.
(Note: For such graphs we plot quantity along the horizontal axis and price
on the vertical axis. This may seem the wrong way round to you as we are
arguing here that demand depends on price and we normally have the
dependent variable on the vertical axis. However, this is the accepted
approach for economics.)
Market demand shows the total amount of effective demand from all the
consumers in a market. It is an aggregate, like the supply curve for an industry.
Conditions of demand:
Any change in one or more of the conditions of demand will create shifts in the
demand curve itself.
a) If the shift in the demand curve is outward, to the right, such a shift is
called an increase/rise in demand.
b) If the shift in the demand curve is inward, to the left, such a shift is
called a decrease/fall in demand.
A good example of this was the rapid rise in demand for fidget spinners
seen in 2017 followed by a decline as people’s attention moved
elsewhere. Tastes, of course, can be manipulated by advertising and
producers to try to ‘create’ markets, particularly for ostentatious goods,
for example, air conditioners which our ancestors survived perfectly well
without. Some goods are in seasonal demand (e.g. cooked meat) even
though they are available all year round, because tastes change (i.e.
more salads are consumed in the summer).
In the analysis of how the demand and supply model works, the
distinctions between increase/decrease in demand and
expansion/contraction in demand are very important.
Remember:
The formula can be applied either at one point on the demand curve or over
part (arc) of it. It is critical that percentage or proportional changes are used
rather than absolute ones.
Definitions:
There are two ways of calculating PED using the 'arc method'. Both of these
methods are examinable.
Note that the value of price elasticity of demand will change as you move along
the length of the straight demand curve.
A normal demand curve will always slope downwards from left to right
indicating that a price rise will lead to a contraction in demand and a price fall
will lead to an expansion in demand
Factors that influence PED:
There are several factors which determine the price elasticity of demand:
c) Necessities: The demand for vital goods such as sugar, milk and bread
tend to be stable and inelastic; conversely luxury items such as foreign
skiing holidays are likely to be fairly elastic in demand. It is interesting to
note that improvements in living standards push certain commodities
such as televisions from the luxury to the necessity category.
The PED can also be calculated by examining total revenue. This method is
most useful to business people.
Conversely, if total revenue falls after a price cut, then the demand is inelastic;
and after a price rise it is elastic. If total revenue remains unchanged, then the
demand is of unitary elasticity.
Supply:
A supply curve shows how much producers would be willing and able to offer
for sale, at different prices, over a given period of time.
An increase in supply:
Factors of production:
c) Enterprise: This is another human resource but refers to the role played
by the organiser of production, including risk-taking, organising and
decision making.
Therefore, the value of the price elasticity of supply (PES) is always positive.
a) Time. Supply tends to be more elastic in the long run. Production plans
can be varied and firms can react to price changes. In some industries,
notably agriculture, supply is fixed in the short run and thus perfectly
inelastic. However, in manufacturing, supply is more adaptable.
Equilibrium:
Now we have looked at demand and supply in detail, let us consider how the
price mechanism sets a price.
The way to see how market forces achieve equilibrium is to consider what
happens if the price is too high or too low:
The graph shows the intended demand and planned supply at a set of prices. It
is only at price P where demand and supply are the same. If the demand of
consumers and the supply plans of sellers correspond, then the market is
deemed to be in equilibrium.
Only at output Q and price P are the plans of both sellers and buyers realised.
Thus, Q is the equilibrium quantity and P is the equilibrium price in this
market.
For instance, at price P1, consumers only want Q1 output but producers are
making Q2 output available. There is a surplus of supply, the excess supply
being the difference between the Q1 and Q2 output levels.
This will be reflected in the short term by retailers having unwanted goods,
returns made to manufacturers, reduced orders and some products being
thrown away and so suppliers may be prepared to accept lower prices than P1
for their goods.
Conversely, at a price of P2, the quantity demanded, Q2, will exceed the
quantity supplied, Q3. There will be a shortage of supply (Q2 – Q3),
demonstrating the excess demand.
This will be reflected in the short term by retailers having empty shelves,
queues and increased orders. Furthermore, there may be high second-hand
values, for example on eBay. The supplier will respond by increasing
prices to reduce the shortage.
This excess demand will thus lead to a rise in the market price, and demand
will contract and supply will expand until equilibrium is reached at price P.
a) Supply of and demand for money gives an equilibrium price that can be
interpreted as the level of interest rates in an economy.
Note that if we had drawn the diagram with steeper supply (and demand
curves), then the price fluctuations would have been greater. Thus the more
inelastic the demand and supply of a good are, the greater will be price
volatility when either demand or supply shifts.
The longer-term effects of these changes in the market depend upon the
reactions of the consumers and producers. The consumers may adjust their
preferences and producers may reconsider their production plans. The impact
of the latter on supply depends upon the length of the production period.
Generally, the longer the production period, and the more inelastic the supply
is, the more unstable price will tend to be.
Introduction:
Public goods:
As a result, a market for this type of goods does not exist and so must be
provided by the state.
Externalities:
Externalities are social costs or benefits that are not automatically included in
the supply and demand curves for a product or service. Social costs arising
from production and consumption of a good or service are described as
negative externalities and social benefits as positive externalities.
Supply and demand curves only take into account private costs and benefits,
i.e. the costs that accrue directly to the supplier or the benefits that accrue
directly to the consumer.
Externalities:
An externality occurs when the costs or benefits of an economic action are not
borne or received by the instigator. Externalities are, therefore, the spill-over
effects of production and consumption which affect society as a whole rather
than just the individual producers or consumers.
c) Calculate social costs. These would indicate the true cost to society of
production to incorporate into decision making. However, externalities
are very difficult to calculate as they are not always attributable, for
example noise, and their impact is not universally identical.
Despite the many measures to deal with externalities, the issue of achieving
the socially optimal level of production remains unresolved.
Merit goods:
One way of looking at merit goods is in terms of externalities. Merit goods are
characterised by external social benefits (i.e. positive externalities) in
consumption or by lack of knowledge of the private benefits in consumption.
This would lead to under consumption of such services and health and
education.
Moreover, merit goods are also ones that it is generally agreed should be
available to all, irrespective of the ability to pay. Thus, governments often
provide health and education services even though, unlike public goods, these
can be provided by the market.
Thus, merit goods may be underprovided by the market because of
Note: some consumers possess the means and the willingness to buy merit
goods, such as education and healthcare
Furthermore, the private sector often provides alternatives, although these are
often seen as ‘different’, or even superior goods/services, for example, private
school education, private health schemes. In the case of state-provided merit
goods, economies of scale can often be achieved, so the cost of education per
student is about three times cheaper in the state sector than in the private
sector, for example.
Demerit goods:
As markets have become more heavily concentrated among fewer firms more
controls have been applied to restrictive trade practices and pricing. The
economic justifications for such a policy are fairly clear.
Scope of regulation:
There may be occasions when the equilibrium price established by the market
forces of demand and supply may not be the most desirable price. With such
cases the government might wish to set prices above or below the market
equilibrium price.
Minimum price:
To be effective legal minimum prices must be above the current market price.
If the government sets a minimum price above the equilibrium price (often
called a price floor), there will be a surplus of supply created.
In the diagram this surplus is the difference between Q2 and Q1.
If this minimum price was applied in the labour market it would be known as a
minimum wage and the surplus would be the equivalent of unemployment,
which would be a waste of a factor of production.
For example, direct payments provide farmers with a steady income and
reward. Left to the mercy of the market, they would be unlikely to be able to
invest in improvements to productivity, food safety or environmental
protection. CAP ensures that Europeans have stable food supplies at
reasonable prices. Increasingly, CAP is used to protect the rural environment.
Farmers get more if they sign up to agro-environmental commitments – using
fewer chemicals, leaving boundaries uncultivated, maintaining ponds, trees,
hedges and protecting wildlife.
a) Excess supply
b) Misallocation of resources
c) Waste of resources. Note: Alternative approaches to protect farmers
include
d) the use of deficiency payments, where farmers are paid the difference
between a legislatively set target price and the lower national average
market price during a specified time
e) payments of subsidies to farmers, effectively reducing their costs.
Maximum price:
In the housing market this may lead to fewer apartments for rent as
landowners develop office blocks rather than residential houses.
For example, a larger firm may be able to gain greater discounts when
purchasing raw materials.
Diseconomies can arise as a firm grows very large. These often reflect the
difficulty of communicating within a large organisation, together with a decline
in management control
If such economies exist, then firms will need to achieve 'critical mass' in order
to be competitive on cost. The low costs that result allow the firm to set its
prices below those of smaller competitors and can act as a serious barrier to
new firms trying to enter the industry.
Obtaining such scale of production can result from organic growth and/or
acquisition. While this results in larger firms, it often means fewer firms in the
market as well.
However, the firm should not simply grow for growth’s sake as diseconomies
of scale will erode its cost advantage.
The existence of significant economies of scale can be expected to lead to:
a) costs and therefore prices falling as firms increase their scale of output
b) barriers to entry for newer smaller firms; and
c) industries dominated by a small number of large firms.
When the advantages of expanding the scale of operation accrue to just one
firm, these economies are termed internal. They can be obtained in one plant,
belonging to a firm, or across the whole company. The main internal
economies are as follows:
There may be a pool of skilled labour which is available, and this may lower
training costs for a firm. Specialised training may be provided locally in
accordance with the industry’s needs. This might be provided by a training
board to which firms contribute to gain access to the available expertise.
Diseconomies of scale:
These exist when the average cost rises with increased production. If they are
specific to one firm they are categorised as internal.
However, there may also be general disadvantages which afflict all firms as
the scale of the industry grows.