Becker Et Al (2024) Religion and Growth
Becker Et Al (2024) Religion and Growth
JANUARY 2024
[email protected]
www.rfberlin.com
Abstract
We use the elements of a macroeconomic production function—physical capital,
human capital, labor, and technology—together with standard growth models to
frame the role of religion in economic growth. Unifying a growing literature, we
argue that religion can enhance or impinge upon economic growth through all four
elements because it shapes individual preferences, societal norms, and institutions.
Religion affects physical capital accumulation by influencing thrift and financial
development. It affects human capital through both religious and secular education.
It affects population and labor by influencing work effort, fertility, and the
demographic transition. And it affects total factor productivity by constraining or
unleashing technological change and through rituals, legal institutions, political
economy, and conflict. Synthesizing a disjoint literature in this way opens many
interesting directions for future research.
16 December 2023
*
We thank the editors Steven Durlauf and David Romer, Jean-Paul Carvalho, Timur Kuran, Felipe Valencia Caicedo,
and four anonymous referees for thoughtful comments. All errors are our own. The contribution of Woessmann is part
of German Science Foundation project CRC TRR 190.
†
Becker: Monash University and University of Warwick; CAGE, CEH@ANU, CEPR, CESifo, CReAM, IZA, ROA,
Rockwool Foundation Berlin, and SoDa Labs; [email protected]. Rubin: Chapman University;
[email protected]. Woessmann: University of Munich, ifo Institute; Hoover Institution, Stanford University;
CESifo, IZA, and CAGE; [email protected].
1. Introduction
Why some countries are rich and some are poor is among the most important issues studied by
economists and is central to the literature on economic growth and development (e.g., Smith 1776;
Easterlin 1981; Landes 1998; Hall and Jones 1999; Jones 2016; Koyama and Rubin 2022). On the
theoretical front, the neoclassical growth model independently developed by Solow (1956) and
Swan (1956) suggested that the accumulation of physical capital led to transitional growth whereas
long-run growth was ultimately driven by technological advances, which were taken as exogenous.
In his Nobel-prize winning contribution to endogenous growth theory, Romer (1990) emphasized
that technological change is the result of efforts by researchers and entrepreneurs who respond to
economic incentives. These efforts are affected by factors such as education and basic research
funding which ultimately influence an economy’s long-run trajectory. In a unified growth theory,
Galor (2011) stressed that during most of human existence, technological progress was offset by
population growth, and living standards were near subsistence. An escape from this Malthusian
trap required a fertility transition that was facilitated by a technology-induced increase in the return
to human capital, opening a perspective to understand the transition to modern growth.
Yet, for all the insights this literature provides into the causes of economic growth, it does not
provide broad coverage of one of the most ubiquitous social phenomena: religion. 1 The subject
indices of the Handbook of Economic Growth refer to coverage of “religion” (or “relig*”) on only
three of 1822 pages in volume 1 (2005) and four of 1070 pages in volume 2 (2014). 2 It is puzzling
why this is the case. In the past two decades, a large literature has emerged showing many ways
in which religion affects various elements that either enhance or impinge upon economic growth,
both historically and in the present, and both in rich and poor countries. In most societies, religion
plays some role in determining nearly every input into growth models—physical capital, human
capital, population/labor, and technology. What is the growth literature missing by ignoring the
role of religion? Can religious differences over time and space help explain differences in growth?
1
There are notable exceptions. For instance, Barro and McCleary (2003) present cross-country regressions connecting
various aspects of religion to growth. The robustness of these results is questioned by Durlauf, Kourtellos, and Tan
(2012).
2
Similarly, Temple’s (1999) survey of empirical growth research does not mention religion at all, only briefly referring
to cultural barriers to growth.
1
In this paper, we provide a framework for conceptualizing the ways in which religion can affect
economic growth. 3 We propose to incorporate the role of religion into existing growth models that
build on a standard macroeconomic production function, consistent with much of the existing
growth literature. Central to our framework is the idea that religion is a key determinant of the
inputs considered in these models. It is not our intention to simply survey the literature on the
economics of religion. Nor is it our intention to provide a laundry list of the role each major religion
has played for economic outcomes. Instead, we attempt to organize various studies of different
denominations, historical periods, and geographic locations to highlight the aggregate effect of
religion on economic growth.
We focus on how different aspects of religion, religious practice, religious institutions, and
religious doctrine impinge on inputs into different growth models by shaping preferences, norms,
values, laws, and institutions. First, we consider the role that religion plays in the accumulation of
physical capital, building on the neoclassical setup used in the Solow-Swan model. Various
studies, dating back to those of Max Weber, have connected religion to thrift, saving, and financial
development—important components of capital accumulation that vary across societies and over
time. Taken in aggregate, they reveal a role for religion in physical capital formation, or lack
thereof, across historical and modern societies. Second, we cover the role of religion for growth
through the accumulation of human capital in light of augmented neoclassical models and
endogenous growth models. Religion has been shown to exert both positive and negative effects
on human capital development, particularly through its role in secular and religious education.
Human capital is therefore a key mechanism through which religion indirectly affects economic
growth. Third, our framework covers the role that religion plays in influencing the amount of labor
available in productive activities. Religion might influence labor-force participation by
encouraging or discouraging work effort. Lower population growth tends to allow for faster
economic growth in the transition to a higher steady-state level of per-capita income. Unified
growth theory sheds light on the role that religion plays in allowing societies to escape the
demographic trap by affecting fertility. Fourth, leaning on endogenous growth models, the
3
Following the typical usage in social sciences, we think of religion as “any shared set of beliefs, activities, and
institutions premised upon faith in supernatural forces” (Iannaccone 1998), although it may not be necessary to
associate religion with the supernatural. For instance, Confucianism is often considered a religion although it is largely
disinterested in the supernatural, but in fact the idea of celestial wisdom and the worship (in practice) of Confucius as
a “god” of culture in many temples speak at least to religious elements. We follow the definition including the
supernatural association because it aligns with most studies of religion and growth in the social sciences.
2
framework explores the role that religion plays in technological change. Some religious doctrines
actively discourage innovation, while in other cases the link between religion and innovation is
indirect (for instance, through education or political economy). The framework also considers
various additional roles that religion plays in affecting total factor productivity by shaping rituals,
norms, legal institutions, political economy, state development, and conflict.
This framework allows us to unify a relatively disjoint literature connecting religion to several
aspects relevant for economic growth. We incorporate recent works in the economics of religion
which reveal microeconomic consequences of religious behavior, often in specific contexts. The
authors of many of these studies answer narrow questions with a high degree of precision. By
construction—and due to the incentives faced in publishing in top-tier social-science journals—
such studies at most hint at their implications for economic growth, and many do not even do this.
This is appropriate in studies of specific consequences of religious behavior or institutions.
However, it does not mean that such studies tell us little about broader economic growth. When
taken in aggregate, they paint a clear picture of just how important religion can be for economic
growth. Our primary goal in writing this article is to provide a framework that aggregates these
studies in a coherent fashion, thereby revealing the importance of various religious practices,
doctrines, and institutions for macro phenomena.
By providing a framework for understanding the many pathways through which religion
augments or impedes economic growth, we hope to underscore to economists interested in growth
the potential importance of religion for the very phenomena in which they are interested. The
literature in the economics of religion suggests that we need to move beyond the conventional
inputs into growth models, because religion is a “deeper” determinant that can affect these inputs
in various—and sometimes nonobvious—ways. On the converse, another central goal of this
article is to reveal to economists and political scientists interested in religion how the aggregation
of their works has advanced what we know about the process of economic growth. Such insights
are often not obvious from reading individual articles. Only in aggregate is the impact clear.
Such a unifying framework has not been provided before, differentiating this article from
previous surveys that overviewed various aspects of the economics of religion. The surveys of
Iannaccone (1998) and Iyer (2016) provide general overviews of the literature on the economics
of religion at different points in time, focusing on how religious groups and institutions work and
the resulting economic implications. Two other recent surveys cover specific religions: Kuran
3
(2018) on the economics of Islam and Becker, Pfaff, and Rubin (2016) on the Protestant
Reformation. Our recent handbook chapter (Becker, Rubin, and Woessmann 2021) surveys the
role that the three Abrahamic religions have played in economic history, confined to phenomena
prior to World War II. While there is natural overlap of the present article with each of these
surveys, it differs from all of them in two important ways. First, the existing surveys are not
concerned with growth per se. They thus do not provide a framework to think about how various
features of religion aggregate to contribute to growth and how the individual works combine to
tell a broader story on economic growth. As a consequence, they also do not cover many of the
works that we cover here. Second, by contrast, the existing surveys cover works on the effects of
religion on non-growth-related outcomes, on determinants of religious behavior, and on other
aspects of the economics of religion that are unrelated to growth such as the economics of doctrine
and the industrial organization of religious institutions—neither of which is the topic of our article.
While our focus on economic growth provides many insights for the process of economic
development, it makes sense to delineate the concepts of growth and development. We think of
growth as a change in the aggregate output of an economy—be it in initially rich or poor
countries—as covered by the factors featured in standard growth models. This is distinct from the
modern literature on economic development, which is often conceived as relating to the economics
of “developing” or “poor” countries. While we cover any part of this literature that relates to the
growth of these countries, the multiple aspects of religion in developing countries that do not
directly provide insight into the countries’ growth processes are beyond our scope. For example,
we do not cover how religion affects behaviors of poor people in developing countries if these
behaviors are not central to macroeconomic growth. This unfortunately means that papers on the
developing world are under-represented in this survey, as most of the economics literature on
religion in these countries studies development, not growth, outcomes. 4
Relatedly, the process of economic development is sometimes conceived as a multi-faceted
process that is not just about growth of aggregate output, but also about the fundamental
transformation of an economy (Kuznets 1966). This encompasses its sectoral structure, its
demography and economic geography, and the entire social and institutional setup. Again, we
4
Examples of recent work on religion and development outcomes include papers on Ghana (Auriol et al. 2020), India
(Menon and McQueeney 2020), transition economies (Popova 2014), and Brazil (Cavalcanti et al. 2022).
4
cover work in this broader field to the extent that these transformations are a crucial ingredient for
aggregate economies to grow.
Finally, this article focuses on the various ways that religion affects economic growth and not
the reverse pathway. Such works, most prominently on the secularization hypothesis (which sees
economic growth as a potential cause of the decline in religiosity in the West), is the subject of a
large literature in the social sciences and was covered extensively in previous surveys by
Iannaccone (1998) and Iyer (2016). Secularization, of course, may affect economic growth through
various channels including education, innovation, and labor productivity, and we cover these
effects of secularization on inputs of growth models. 5
There are two important limitations in the coverage of our survey. First, our coverage of
religions outside the three Abrahamic faiths is regrettably limited, which is owed to the focus in
existing research. 6 Second, our treatment falls short of a systematic coverage of every possible
influence of religion on the different growth inputs, which is inevitable as many possible channels
have not been addressed in existing work. Instead, we aim to cover the research that exists within
established frameworks for studying growth.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 lays out the overall conceptual framework which
builds on existing growth models. Section 3 discusses the role of religion in physical capital
accumulation, Section 4 the role of religion in human capital accumulation, Section 5 the
connection of religion with population and labor, and Section 6 the role of religion in total factor
productivity. Section 7 concludes with some overall lessons learned on the role of religion in
economic growth and a discussion of open questions that provide fruitful avenues for future
research in this rapidly growing field.
5
For instance, Strulik (2016) studies the link between secularization and long-run growth by introducing religious
identity choice in an endogenous growth model. A secular identity allows an individual to derive more pleasure from
consumption than religious individuals, leading secular individuals to work harder and to save more in order to
experience this pleasure from consumption. In line with increased consumerism in a secularizing society, shop-
opening times on Sundays have been liberated (Gruber and Hungerman 2008).
6
We conjecture that many of the highlighted patterns apply to religions more generally. We hope that this survey will
inspire specialists in Asia, Africa, Latin America, and elsewhere to research the similarities and differences.
5
2. Conceptual Framework
The key proposition of this article is that religion can affect economic growth through various
channels. To frame our discussion, we use a canonical macroeconomic production function that
expresses output (Y) at time t as a function of a set of intermediate input factors:
As is common in growth research, we consider four groups of inputs: physical capital (K), labor
(L), and human capital per worker (h) as factors of production plus total factor productivity (A)
which depicts how the production factors are transformed into output. Although this is in no way
obligatory, for concreteness we can think of a standard functional form of the Cobb-Douglas shape:
where the production elasticities of physical capital (α) and human-capital-augmented labor (1–α)
are constrained to sum to 1—implying constant returns to scale—and where productivity augments
both of these factors.
The central notion in this article is that religion is related to each of the four elements of the
production function and, as such, has effects on growth through each of these four channels.
Modern growth theory tends to consider the indicated elements of the production function as
“proximate” determinants of growth (e.g., Romer 2019; Ashraf and Weil, forthcoming). These
proximate determinants are explained by “deeper” or “fundamental” determinants, which may
include aspects such as geography, institutions, and culture (e.g., Acemoglu, Johnson, and
Robinson 2005; Spolaore and Wacziarg 2013; Mokyr 2016; Koyama and Rubin 2022). It is our
contention that as a crucial aspect of culture, religion is one of the many “fundamental”
determinants of each of the four inputs.
Conceptually, we think of the role of religion—the shared set of beliefs, activities, and
institutions—in two primary ways. First, religion affects individual preferences. By its very nature,
religion can have a bearing on individuals’ altruism, reciprocity, trust, patience, risk-taking, and
other preferences. These preferences directly enter the utility function and thus steer economic
decisions and behavior. Future-oriented preferences such as patience and risk-taking will have a
bearing on the willingness to save and on educational efforts. Similarly, religion affects people’s
(work) ethic and motivation.
6
Second, religion also shapes the rules and regulations that embed and constrain societal
interaction. These come in two kinds. On the one hand, religion defines many norms and values—
such as rules on family, fertility, or openness to (technological) change—often in informal ways
that govern people’s actions. On the other hand, religion sets formal rules, laws, and institutions—
such as restrictions on interest or the authorization of specific forms of corporate organization and
market exchange—and affects state development by legitimating political leadership. As both
individual preferences and societal norms have to be conveyed, religious education can take on a
particular role in passing the role of religion on from generation to generation. Religion can also
have unintended side effects. For example, when Martin Luther urged his followers to educate
their children so that they could read God’s word in the bible, he probably had no intention to build
economically relevant human capital.
We further develop the relation of religion with each of the four elements of the
macroeconomic production function in the first sub-section of each of the following four sections.
Many of the discussed papers fit directly into the structure as they clearly focus on the effect of
religion on one of the four elements. Some papers tend to cover more than one element or treat the
reduced-form effect of religion on growth more generally, and we will discuss them in the
respective section where they fit best in our view.
In the production framework of equation (2), the accumulation of physical capital (K) is related to
increases in output. In a basic capital accumulation equation, capital in period t is the sum of the
previous period’s capital and investment (I), minus depreciation (D):
7
Investment is central for capital accumulation in the long run; without investment, the capital stock
eventually depreciates. In the Solow-Swan neoclassical model, higher investment rates lead to
higher physical capital and higher output per worker. Thus, an increase in the investment rate leads
to economic growth in the transition from one steady state to another.
As investment requires one to forgo consumption, any act of investment corresponds to an act
of saving. Therefore, in the neoclassical model, differences in saving rates have a direct bearing
on steady-state output. Furthermore, the development of financial institutions that intermediate
between savers and investors can have an impact on the amount of resources that are available for
investment in a society.
When depicting the role of religion in capital accumulation, it is useful to break investment
motives down into two components: investment motivated by extrinsic (xt) and intrinsic (nt)
incentives to save:
Extrinsic incentives include the rate of return, risk, the availability of financial institutions,
property rights, etc. Obviously, there are many roots of these incentives that have nothing to do
with religion. However, religion plays a role in shaping these incentives by shaping norms and
institutions that set the rules of the game. Examples include usury laws, restrictions on certain
types of investments, and Islamic finance.
Religion also affects intrinsic incentives to save. The most famous example was given by Max
Weber, who viewed thriftiness as a peculiarly Protestant trait (see McCleary and Barro 2019, ch.
3, for a recent summary). To the extent that religion impacts individuals’ intertemporal preferences
such as patience and risk-taking, it has a bearing on saving, investment, and growth.
We start with what is probably the first major social-science argument that connects religious
belief to economic development: the Weber (1904/05) thesis of a Protestant Ethic. Weber argued
that Protestants are characterized by their own distinct ethic which influences their economic
behaviors. His study was motivated by the observation that in Baden (a state in southwest
Germany) Protestants earned more than Catholics. While Protestants in Baden were mostly
Lutheran, Weber’s focus was on ascetic forms of Protestantism such as Calvinism or Methodism.
8
Weber (1904/05, p. 118) quotes John Wesley (1703-1791), the founding father of Methodism, “as
a motto for everything” that aligns with Weber’s view: “For religion must necessarily produce
both industry and frugality, and these cannot but produce riches.” In the German original Weber
quotes the English words “industry” (which he translates as “Arbeitsamkeit”) and “frugality”
(which he translates as “Sparsamkeit”). In the literature, “work effort” is commonly used to capture
the hard work allegedly put in by ascetic Protestants, and “thrift” is commonly used as the re-
translation of Weber’s German word “Sparsamkeit”.
Paying particular attention to Calvinism, Weber (1904/05, p. 56) describes predestination as
Calvinism’s most characteristic doctrine: that only some human beings are chosen to be saved
from damnation, the choice being predetermined by God. Calvinists could not be certain whether
they are among the elect, but success in a calling came to be regarded as a sign of being one of the
elect. Work effort and thrift could be pathways to success.
In a national account framework, saving is the mirror image of investment. The literature
focuses on measures of attitudes towards thriftiness, saving, and wealth. While the Weberian focus
is on Protestantism, the broader empirical question is whether denominational differences in
attitudes towards thriftiness may give rise to differences in saving behavior which in turn influence
capital accumulation and growth. Using data from the World Values Survey (WVS), Guiso,
Sapienza, and Zingales (2003) show that individuals who were raised religiously are more likely
to consider it “important that children be encouraged to learn at home ‘thrift, saving money and
things’.” Yet, when looking at specific denominations in the present day, Catholics and Protestants
are roughly equally likely to support thriftiness but support it more strongly than Jews, Muslims,
Hindus, Buddhists, and “Others”. While the fact that Protestants do not put more emphasis on
thriftiness than Catholics is at odds with Weber’s thesis (which, to be fair, was put forth over a
century ago), the fact that there are differences across religious groups is consistent with a role for
religion in thriftiness. Relatedly, Andersen et al. (2017) focus on the Cistercians, a Catholic order
present in many parts of medieval Europe, which Weber (1904/05, p. 72) himself singled out as
encompassing values with a clear antecedent to the Protestant ethic. If the Cistercians had an
impact on cultural values of the population around them, those values may have been passed on
over generations. Using the same WVS question, Andersen et al. find that respondents in European
regions that historically had Cistercian monasteries do indeed consider it important that children
learn thrift, which influences their economic behavior as adults.
9
Weber suggested that Protestantism might have led to an “accumulation of capital through
ascetic compulsion to save” (Weber 1905, p. 191). Alaoui and Sandroni (2018) look at the link
between ascetic compulsion to accumulate wealth in secular Protestantism and the Calvinist
teaching of predestination, as proposed by Weber, from a theoretical standpoint. The ascetic
compulsion to save can be modeled as a direct utility from owning wealth, above and beyond
wealth’s instrumental value in procuring consumption and other benefits. The Calvinist teaching
of predestination can be thought of as inducing a strict preference for early resolution of
uncertainty about God’s grace (during one’s lifetime instead of afterlife). The authors show an
exact equivalence between the two classes of utility functions, thereby providing a foundation for
the use of direct preferences for wealth in empirical work. Looking at Prussia, the largest state in
the 19th-century German Empire, Kersting, Wohnsiedler, and Wolf (2020) do not, however, find
differences in savings per capita and in the number of savings banks across counties with a
Protestant versus Catholic majority. This is again inconsistent with systematic differences in
saving behaviors between Catholics and Protestants.
While the work described so far has looked at the population at large, Baxamusa and Jalal
(2016) analyze corporate decisions taken by American CEOs depending on their religious
denomination. Firms with Catholic CEOs invest less than firms with Protestant CEOs, and the
decisions of Catholic CEOs are associated with lower firm value. The authors attribute this to
denomination-specific personal preferences of CEOs.
The takeaway from the empirical literature that tests aspects of the Weber thesis relating to
denominational differences in saving, thriftiness, and wealth is rather mixed. While Protestants
have been found to be thriftier in some contexts, those results do not apply universally, and—in
line with Weber’s own work—Protestants are by no means the first group displaying an “ethic” of
thriftiness. Weber’s legacy is still significant as he has stimulated generations of social scientists
to explore the link between religion and economics more broadly and beyond simple Protestant-
Catholic comparisons.
The capacity of individuals to invest in physical capital is also determined by the development of
the financial sector which matches saving to investment. We cover two leading applications of
how religion affects financial development and thereby broader growth trajectories: the role of
10
restrictions on interest in Christianity and Islam (Section 3.3.1) and rules on finance and
corporations in Islam (Section 3.3.2).
7
There are several Qur’anic passages addressing the sinfulness of riba—a pre-Islamic practice in which a loan’s
principal was doubled and redoubled when the debtor was unable to pay (Rahman 1964). Muslims quickly equated
riba with interest of any kind, although the Qu’ran is silent on such transactions.
11
tantamount to a loan at interest, with the interest being the difference between the two prices
(Rubin 2011). Similar stratagems were widely used in Europe and the Middle East to evade interest
restrictions.
Despite these workarounds, the literature points to two mechanisms how interest restrictions
mattered for growth: path dependence and institutional formation. In Western Europe, secular
authorities began to permit moderate interest in the 12th and 13th centuries as commerce began to
flow more rapidly and merchants sought relief from interest restrictions. The Church was slow to
catch up and continued its campaign against usury (Noonan 1957). Meanwhile, openly lending at
interest remained prohibited in most Muslim polities unless some sort of stratagem (hila) were
employed, although such restrictions were eased (though not eliminated) in the Ottoman Empire
(Rubin 2011; Kuran and Rubin 2018). In other words, both intrinsic and extrinsic motivation to
openly lend at interest was stifled in the Middle East.
Usury laws had a significant impact on the development of financial and banking institutions
across Western Europe and the Middle East. Rubin (2010) argues that differences in bills of
exchange (debt instruments) arising from differences in usury restrictions incentivized Europeans,
but not Middle Easterners, to expand operations interregionally. Such expansion was exemplified
by the Medici bank, whose hub-and-spoke system gave it access to most of the financial centers
of Europe (de Roover 1963). A similar expansion did not happen in the Middle East, where
partnerships remained small and of limited duration (Kuran 2005, 2011). More generally, recent
research indicates that where access to interest-bearing loans in the past was limited, there still
tends to be less access to credit in the present. Such lack of credit access has clear negative
consequences for growth (King and Levine 1993; Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales 2004). Grosjean
(2011) tests the impact of past financial access to present-day finance by studying within-country
variation in Ottoman rule in six countries in Southeastern Europe that were partly ruled by the
Ottomans from the 14th through 20th centuries. She finds that those regions that fell under Ottoman
rule have 10 percent less bank penetration in the present across countries and 4 percent less
penetration within country. Walker (2020) provides evidence that such historical differences may
have also affected the propensity to save in the present. Employing a lab-in-the-field experiment
and a regression discontinuity across an old Ottoman-Habsburg border in Romania, she finds that
people living on the Habsburg side have greater access to banks and save significantly more, which
allows them to smooth consumption when faced with negative shocks.
12
Usury restrictions also shaped the development of financial institutions in medieval and early
modern Europe. For instance, in the 15th century, the Church accepted the validity of Monte di
Pietà, a “pious” institution that lent at low rates and was supposed to be an act of charity and make
no profit. Originally meant to compete with Jewish lenders on the Italian peninsula, the Monti
quickly developed features such as charging interest, accepting deposits, and remunerating
deposits that formed the basis for modern banking in Italy. Pascali (2016) finds that cities with a
Monte di Pietà during the Renaissance have significantly greater access to credit and higher
banking branch density in the present and consequently have higher GDP per capita and aggregate
productivity. Historical intrinsic and extrinsic motivations to lend for investment can thus become
institutionalized over time and result in more growth than in places where such motivations were
historically absent.
13
Islamic law may have had an even greater dampening effect on investment in large commercial
and financial enterprises. Until the 19th century, Islamic partnerships remained small (generally
involving no more than two or three people) and lasted for a short duration (Kuran 2005). This
meant that opportunities for capital investment were inherently limited by the legal and
organizational infrastructure available to prospective merchants. Kuran (2005, 2011) explains that
the relative size and duration of partnerships was not due to the “unchangeable” nature of Islamic
law. However, the fact that Islamic law dominated commercial activity meant that there was
relatively little demand for legal changes that would have supported larger and more durable
enterprises.
According to Kuran (2005, 2011), two aspects of Islamic law stifled incentives to invest in
larger enterprises: partnership and inheritance law. The relevant feature of partnership law was
that partnerships were forced to disband upon the death or incapacitation of a partner. This was
also a feature of the commenda partnership commonly employed in medieval Italian commerce.
Yet, unlike Italian partnerships, Islamic partnerships did not ultimately evolve into larger, more
durable partnerships capable of attracting more investment. Kuran points to inheritance law as a
key difference between the two regions. It was straightforward for the heirs of a recently deceased
or incapacitated partner to reconstitute an Islamic partnership and reap the proceeds of an
uninterrupted venture. However, Islamic inheritance law laid out a pre-specified split among many
heirs. If any one of the heirs were in a bind and needed the assets, they could force the dissolution
of the partnership. This could in turn lead to significant losses, especially when goods were in
transit or had to be sold at below-market prices. Kuran argues that this dampened demand for large
and long-lasting ventures in the first place. Hence, the type of financial evolution that happened in
Europe—which ultimately resulted in the advent of tradable shares, limited liability, the corporate
form, and a host of other innovations that increased incentives for the capital-rich to invest—never
emerged indigenously in the Middle East.
While Islamic inheritance law may have reduced demand for larger and more durable
commercial organizations, it was possible to circumvent. Yet, as Kuran (2001, 2011) notes, one of
the primary means of circumvention, the waqf, also played a role in retarding long-run capital
investment and economic growth in the Middle East. The waqf was an Islamic trust typically meant
to endow local public goods such as a madrasa (school), mosque, water fountain, or hospital. Waqf
endowments could be used to circumvent Islamic inheritance law. A wealthy Muslim could choose
14
an heir by endowing a waqf and appointing the heir to administer it, with a handsome salary that
would keep family assets consolidated. This practice greatly restricted the capacity of the heir to
invest their assets, most of which were tied up in the waqf. By law, a waqf had to serve a purpose
as dictated by its founder which could not be changed after the founders’ death. Hence, if
investment opportunities arose that were not in the founding deed (even if unforeseeable at the
time of founding), waqf assets could not be used on such a purpose. Kuran views this as a key
mechanism through which the waqf dampened long-run economic growth in the Middle East.
A related innovation that facilitated investment in the Ottoman Empire was the cash waqf. In
contrast to the traditional waqf which funded an immovable object, the cash waqf—which was
formed to lend money—by construction funded a movable object. Moreover, it earned income by
lending at interest, typically via legally-approved mechanisms. This caused immense controversy
for at least a century after their initial spread in the 15th-16th centuries. Ultimately, their legality
was approved on the basis that they were so widespread and improved the welfare of the people
(Mandaville 1979, pp. 297-98; Imber 1997, pp. 144-45). The cash waqf served as a substitute for
banks, although they were more rigid and limited in purpose. As part of the waqf system, they
were mandated to have a pre-specified purpose that could not be altered. This meant that most cash
waqfs could not take on the type of activities typical of banking such as accepting deposits,
branching out to meet demand, or even adjusting interest rates to market conditions. Hence,
although the cash waqf was the organizational form most likely to transition into something akin
to modern banking, it never did. The first Middle Eastern banks were formed in the mid-19th
century with British and French capital.
It was not until the 20th century that an “Islamic banking” system emerged distinct from the
type of banking found in the West. Now a $2 trillion industry, the Islamic banking system, although
in many respects similar to the Western banking system, has many unique elements. Interest-based
contracts are replaced with similar debt contracts that do not explicitly charge interest. In theory,
excessive risk-taking is avoided via risk-sharing contracts involving a symmetrical risk/return
among participants. There must be some material object underlying transactions, meaning that
options and derivatives are banned. Islamic banking also prohibits sinful transactions (e.g., those
related to pork, alcohol, or gambling) (Khan 2010). There is much debate regarding how different
the Islamic banking system is from conventional banking (Hassan and Aliyu 2018). Some argue
that Islamic banking is de facto Western banking with some de jure appeals to Islamic principles,
15
especially partnerships (Kuran 2004a, Khan 2010). Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Merrouche (2013)
qualify this argument, noting that while there is little difference in business orientation between
Islamic and conventional banks, the former tend to be better capitalized and have higher asset
quality. 8 This allowed them to survive the 2008 financial crisis in a better position than the average
conventional bank. Likewise, Islamic banks tend to be more efficient on net (reflecting high
managerial quality) but less efficient in the type of services provided (Johnes, Izzeldin, and Pappas
2014). Islamic loans also have a significantly lower default rate than conventional loans, especially
during Ramadan, perhaps suggesting a religious motive to avoid default (Baele, Farooq, and
Ongena 2014). For these reasons, Islamic banking has become an important vehicle for attracting
investment in Muslim-majority countries. It follows that the presence and depth of Islamic banking
has been found to be positively associated with economic growth (Imam and Kpodar 2016).
Overall, there are many clear examples of episodes where religion affected economic growth
by promoting or hindering the accumulation of physical capital. These worked both through
particular preferences for saving among religious populations and through regulations and
institutions that governed the financing of investments.
4. Human Capital
This section addresses many of the ways in which religion affects economic growth through its
effects on the accumulation of human capital. We begin by discussing the role of religion for
human capital accumulation in the contexts of augmented neoclassical models and endogenous
growth models, as well as the role of religious education (Section 4.1). We then survey several
literatures that highlight different aspects of how religions help or hinder economic growth through
religious education (Section 4.2) and secular education (Section 4.3).
Religions often directly affect both the religious and secular education of their followers. Growth
models tend to depict the effects of investment in secular education: labor can be augmented by
8
This analysis is supported by Khediri, Charfeddine, and Youssef (2015) who find that Islamic banks are, on average,
more profitable, liquid, and capitalized than conventional banks in Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) countries over
the period 2003-2010. Similarly, Mollah et al. (2017) find that Islamic banks achieve greater performance through
greater risk-taking and are more capitalized than conventional banks.
16
investment in human capital. There are three main classes of growth models that emphasize distinct
mechanisms through which human capital may affect economic growth.
First, in neoclassical growth models that are augmented to account for the accumulation of
human capital (Mankiw, Romer, and Weil 1992), human capital (ht) is modelled as another
production factor that can be accumulated (see equation (2)). Educational investments augment
the labor force, and the added aggregate economic inputs move the economy to a new higher
steady-state level of aggregate output. 9
Second, endogenous growth models stress the role of human capital in increasing the
innovative capacity of the economy through developing new ideas and new technologies (e.g.,
Lucas 1988; Romer 1990; Aghion and Howitt 1998). In these models, technological change is
determined by economic forces within the model that make technology (Tt)—a crucial ingredient
of total factor productivity (At) in equation (2) that will be discussed further in Section 6—
dependent on human capital:
Third, and relatedly, models of technological diffusion stress that human capital can facilitate
the transmission of knowledge needed to implement new technologies devised by others (e.g.,
Nelson and Phelps 1966). In this perspective, human capital can help countries increase their total
factor productivity by helping to adopt new technologies from abroad.
Religion may affect human capital in ways consistent with all three frameworks. Economically
valuable skills can be accumulated through informal learning (it), e.g., in apprenticeships or on the
job, and formal education (et):
Religion can affect both types of human capital accumulation. On the one hand, religion can affect
informal skill formation (e.g., through the Protestant ethic), although the literature does not place
9
A similar point can be made for health investments: health as one form of human capital plays a role in the context
of augmentation of the labor force (e.g., Weil 2014), but less directly so for innovation or technological diffusion.
Recent work shows that religion can affect mental health, especially with respect to depression in adolescents
(Fruehwirth, Iyer, and Zhang 2019) and suicide (Becker and Woessmann 2018). Religion can also affect physical
health behavior such as alcohol consumption which in turn may affect productivity (Fletcher and Kumar 2014). The
bulk of work on the link between religion and health has been in medical journals (see, e.g., Koenig (2012)’s meta-
study of religion, spirituality, and health). In line with the focus in the economics literature, this section focuses on the
linkages between religion, education, and growth.
17
great weight on this mechanism. On the other hand, a frequently studied mechanism is that religion
may affect the accumulation of secular education.
Religion can affect both the quantity of education and its content. Religious denominations
have often been the original providers of formal schooling, extending the reach and duration of
education (Ramirez and Boli 1987; West and Woessmann 2010). The content taught can load
directly on human capital, as in the case of economically relevant knowledge and skills such as
literacy (even if the aim is to read holy texts) and norms of thrift. This is in line with Mokyr’s
(2002, p. 284) concept of “useful knowledge”, which he describes as “the equipment we use in our
game against nature.” But the content of religious education can also lower the economic usability
of education—and potentially enough to more than offset any positive effect on the quantity of
education. This may be the case when the content taught in religious schools is focused on instilling
knowledge of religious doctrine and acts of group cohesion more than on conveying knowledge
and skills that are also commercially and financially useful. The content of religious education
may thus substitute for secular education, but it may also encourage secular education (Chiswick
2014, Chapter 4). We separate our following overview of the role of religion for growth through
human capital along the lines of religious and secular education.
We cover three literatures, each focused on one of the three Abrahamic religions, that highlight
the role of religious education in economic growth: Islamic education in medieval and modern
times (Section 4.2.1), the role of (mostly Christian) religious education during industrialization
(Section 4.2.2), and the choice of religious over secular education among Ultra-Orthodox Jews
(Section 4.2.3).
4.2.1 Islamic Education, Scientific vs. Religious Knowledge, and Economic Growth
For centuries following the spread of Islam, education and science in the Islamic world were at the
world’s frontier. During the “Islamic Golden Age” (roughly 7th-10th centuries), educational
institutions, especially at higher levels, were largely secular, not religious. This favored the
production of works on science relative to those on religion. Beginning in the 12th century,
however, works on religious topics became predominant at the expense of works related to science.
These trends are documented in detail in Chaney (2023), who shows that scientific works fell in
both absolute terms and, even more so, relative to Europe. He finds a clear trend break in the
18
proportion of authors affiliated with madrasas in the 11th century, just as madrasas were beginning
to spread. In this telling, religious and secular education are substitutes, at least at higher levels of
education.
A transition from secular to religious educational content impinged on economic growth in
part due to the role that human capital accumulation plays in technological progress. Technological
progress unlocked the keys to riches in the West (Mokyr 1990, 2009; Koyama and Rubin 2022,
ch. 7-8). But there was nothing inherently inimical to technological development in Islam. For
centuries following the spread of Islam, the Islamic world was far ahead of Europe, and possibly
ahead of China, in scientific and technological output (Huff 2017). The tide only began to turn in
the 11th century. With the rise of madrasas, human capital still played an important role in the
region, but it was not the type of “useful knowledge” Mokyr (2002) views as central to economic
development. For instance, Talbani (1996, p. 71) notes that a characteristic of madrasa education
was that “Qur’anic verses emphasizing research, inquiry, and contemplation about the nature of
the world were interpreted so that scientific aspects of these matters were ignored and theological
implications were emphasized.” Still, in many parts of the world madrasas are not a central
component of religious education. For instance, Andrabi et al. (2006) find that in present-day
Pakistan madrasa enrollment makes up less than one percent of overall school enrollment, despite
Islam and religious legitimacy being important to daily and political life.
Historically, there was wide variation in the provision of secular and religious schools
throughout the Muslim world. One of the key distinctions between these types of schools, in terms
of “useful” knowledge, was the degree to which they taught basic literacy and numeracy. For
instance, in early-20th century British India, Hindu literacy rates were typically higher than Muslim
literacy rates, particularly in places with large Muslim populations. Chaudhary and Rubin (2011)
explain this outcome via the historical demand for religious legitimacy in highly Muslim areas.
They find that districts that had a more recent collapse of Muslim political rule had better funded
religious schools, which were not as good at promoting literacy as were secular state schools. In a
follow-up study on the Princely States (i.e., the parts of British India not directly controlled by the
British), Chaudhary and Rubin (2016) find that Hindus in Muslim-ruled states had lower literacy
than in Hindu-ruled states, but there were no literacy differences for Muslims. This is consistent
with their theory that Muslim rulers channeled more resources into religious schools, which
provided legitimacy for the rulers and were excludable by religion. In modern India, the state began
19
to liberalize in 1991. Iyer (2018) finds that religious (Hindu, Muslim, and Christian) organizations
have filled the gaps left by the state, especially for those left behind, by providing health and
education services. The context under which people are able to access such services matters.
Recent evidence from democratic India finds that districts which received Muslim political
representation had better health and educational outcomes for Muslim children (Bhalotra et al.
2014). Thus, different political environments—democratic or autocratic—can yield opposite
predictions on the connection between the religious identity of political elites and educational
outcomes.
In Muslim-majority countries, the tension between religious and secular education has been of
acute policy relevance in the last century. In Egypt, the government undertook a series of reforms
following independence to transform traditional primary schools to become more secular and
modern. Prior to the reforms, the Christian minority was overrepresented in higher paying
occupations, in large part because they had an educational advantage. Admittance into secondary
education required secular primary education, which was mostly limited to elites. Saleh (2015)
finds that the reforms imposed by the Egyptian government in the early 1950s, which permitted
graduates of religious primary schools (kuttabs) to attend higher-level schools, positively impacted
educational and labor-market outcomes for Muslims but not for Christians, helping shrink the gap
between the two groups.
Yet, the growth in secular and religious schooling has had mixed results with respect to
economic growth in the Islamic world. In the 20th century, reforms expanding public, compulsory
education took place in Turkey, Egypt, Tunisia, and Iran, among others (Gulesci and Meyersson
2015). In Turkey, a 1998 law increased the years of compulsory schooling in secular schools.
Gulesci and Meyersson (2015) find that this reform resulted in one more year of schooling for
women but had no significant effect on labor-force participation or early fertility, two further
inputs into growth models (see Section 5). 10 On the other hand, Berman and Stepanyan (2004) find
that returns to education are lower, and fertility is higher, for graduates of Muslim schools in
Indonesia, Bangladesh, India, Cote D’Ivoire, and Pakistan.
One reason for these mixed results is that there have been unanticipated consequences of
expanded secular education in the Muslim world. For instance, Indonesia implemented a massive
10
Studying the same law, Cesur and Mocan (2018) also find that the reforms resulted in a decrease in female religiosity
and propensity to vote for Islamic parties. However, it had no effect on male religiosity or voting propensity.
20
expansion of public secular education in the 1970s. Bazzi, Hilmy, and Marx (2023) find that while
these reforms decreased attendance in Islamic primary schools, the reforms ultimately increased
demand for secondary schooling, which religious schools were able to absorb. These reforms,
which intended to increase national identity at the expense of religious identity, therefore had the
opposite effect. In Egypt, Binzel and Carvalho (2017) show that improved secular education
increased the occupational expectations of the educated middle class. When this did not come to
fruition, many highly educated Egyptians turned to religious movements, some extreme, to cope
with failing to reach their reference point. These movements (e.g., the Muslim Brotherhood) have
played a key role in Egyptian politics since the mid-1980s. Similarly, Sakalli (2019) finds that the
Turkish education reforms cited above triggered a religious backlash. Following the expansion in
secular schooling, residents in highly religious areas were less likely to send their children to
secular schools in order to better promote their religious identity.
Christian-Muslim educational differences have persisted in Africa. Bauer, Platas, and
Weinstein (2022) document that areas governed by Islamic states in the pre-colonial period
experience fewer years of education, and lower density of nightlights, in the contemporary period
in comparison to areas governed by traditional or Christian kingdoms or stateless areas. They
explain these results by the location of missionaries and weak penetration of the colonial
administration, rather than by the influence of Islamic beliefs. Alesina et al. (2023) find that
African Christians have greater intergenerational economic mobility than Muslims. This is in large
part due to Christians being more likely to move to high-mobility regions, where educational and
economic opportunities are more plentiful. Like some of the studies cited above, the Christian-
Muslim educational gap is greatest in areas with large Muslim communities, largely due to lower
emigration rates among Muslims to higher mobility regions.
21
generally see Section 4.3.3). It may also be associated with pro-social and pro-commerce norms
such as trust and thriftiness (see Section 3.2). On the other hand, religious education might hamper
industrialization for two reasons. First, industrial technologies alter human’s relationship with the
physical world, and this may be contradictory to religious beliefs (Mokyr 1990; more generally
see Section 6.2). For instance, Mokyr (2011) suggests that the relative paucity of Jewish innovation
prior to 1850—in spite of relatively high levels of human capital—resulted from traditional Jewish
beliefs, which were unfavorable to scientific innovation and industrial capitalism. Such beliefs are
strengthened via religious education. Second, religious education may crowd out secular
education, as was the case in various points in Islamic history (see Section 4.2.1). Crowd-out may
occur through competition for instructional hours. In addition, reductions in religious schooling
can lead to reduced religiosity which may in turn lower the demand for religious education for the
next generation (Becker, Nagler, and Woessmann 2017; Arold, Woessmann, and Zierow 2022).
Central to the process of industrialization is innovation. Bénabou, Ticchi, and Vindigni (2022)
provide a theoretical link between religion and scientific innovation via political economy. They
assume that scientific discoveries can erode religious beliefs. The state may therefore block the
spread of scientific innovations when the society is particularly religious and religious authorities
are part of the ruling coalition. In other words, a society’s (religious) culture and its institutions
can interact to suppress efficiency-enhancing outcomes (Mokyr 2016). One long-run strategy for
making this equilibrium impervious to shocks is via state investment in religious education
(Iyigun, Rubin, and Seror 2021). Bénabou, Ticchi, and Vindigni (2022) provide empirical support
for this prediction, showing that religiosity (measured by surveys) is negatively correlated with
innovation as measured by patents. The prediction is also supported by Lecce, Ogliari, and
Squicciarini (2021), who find that scientists were less likely to be born in more religious parts of
19th-century France. Their results suggest that religious education is a major channel, as people
born in less religious places tended to acquire more scientific human capital early in their life. This
was largely due to the scientific curriculum being weaker in religious schools than in secular
schools.
While many innovations of the First Industrial Revolution were not based on scientific
principles (with the famous exception of the steam engine) and required mechanical skill more
than scientific knowledge (Mokyr 2009), there was no longer a disconnect between innovation and
science during the Second Industrial Revolution. Beginning around 1870 and located across
22
Western Europe and North America, this period of rapid industrial change was built on the
scientific knowledge base of humanity (Mokyr 1990, 2002; Koyama and Rubin 2022, pp. 180-
183). Technology became skill-intensive, requiring a more technically-skilled workforce to
operate and repair the new machinery. Squicciarini (2020) shows that in 19th-century France,
secular schools responded with a curriculum more conducive to attaining technical skills. Catholic
schools, on the other hand, were much slower to adopt a technical curriculum; in fact, in many
places the emphasis on religious education increased in conjunction with a conservative,
antiscientific program. 11 Squicciarini finds that this had numerous long-term consequences for
local levels of industrialization and industrial employment, though only during the Second
Industrial Revolution (and not before). 12
For follower countries, the fruits of industrialization came from adoption. Liang (2010) argues
that Confucian ethics such as the importance of study and academic qualifications may not have
been conducive to being leaders of capitalist and technological development, but they were highly
conducive to being followers. This, in turn, helps explain the catch-up growth undertaken by the
Asian Tigers in the 20th century and China and parts of Southeast Asia in the 21st century.
Similarly, Dong and Zhang (2023) find that the Confucian emphasis on human capital (due to
needing to know the Confucian classics to pass the imperial examination system) spurred the rise
of modern science in China in the 21st century, as the number of jinshi (highest degree holder) is
related to the presence of modern schools. Chen, Kung, and Ma (2020) also find a persistent effect
relating the density of jinshi to modern years of schooling.
11
The opposition of the Catholic church to the secular mass state school systems that emerged in most Western
societies during the second half of the 19th century led to the establishment of large private Catholic school sectors in
Catholic countries that allowed for religious education; this is well characterized by the slogan propagated by the
Catholic bishops in the US in 1884, “every Catholic child in a Catholic school” (West and Woessmann 2010).
12
Consistent with these findings is the broader result of Andersen and Bentzen (2022) that cities across Europe
inhabited by more religious individuals, proxied by the frequency of religious first names, grew more slowly than
other cities.
23
men attend yeshiva until they are around 40. This poses a puzzle: why do Ultra-Orthodox men
spend so much time attaining religious education, when the secular returns are so low? Similar to
the cases of Islam and of Catholicism, Ultra-Orthodox religious education has mostly been found
to be substitutable for secular education and labor-market opportunities. Works on this topic are
consistent with canonical models in the economics of religion, such as Iannaccone (1992), which
argue that costly actions (from the perspective of secular income) can strengthen the religious
group. The vitality of Ultra-Orthodox communities may therefore benefit from religious education,
even if their members suffer economically.
Such actions have clear implications for economic growth. In the model sketched out above,
human capital decreases with Ultra-Orthodox religious education when the latter substitutes for
secular education. Berman (2000) addresses the puzzle that this “costly” form of education is
ubiquitous among Israeli Ultra-Orthodox Jews. Since Ultra-Orthodox Jews provide attractive
services such as social insurance to fellow members, they must find a way to exclude potential free
riders. Iannaccone argued that religious groups do this by imposing costly and observable
requirements for members—sacrifices or stigmatized actions that negatively affect secular
opportunities. By requiring males to attend yeshiva well into their prime earning years, Ultra-
Orthodox norms impose a significant wage penalty. Berman argues that this penalty is the price of
admission into Ultra-Orthodox Judaism: it reflects a strong commitment to the group, keeping
group vitality high and maintaining a high level of intragroup public goods. 13 Likewise, Berman
argues that intragroup subsidies to women lower their relative real wage in the labor market,
encouraging them to increase their time spent on household activities including child-rearing. This
helps explain why the Ultra-Orthodox fertility rate remains much higher than for non-Ultra-
Orthodox Jews.
Ultra-Orthodox Judaism emerged in the context of Jewish emancipation in the late-19th
century, which opened labor-market doors to Jews that were previously shut. Why would a group
respond to such a change with a set of restrictions that limited their ability to take advantage of
these new opportunities? Carvalho and Koyama (2016) answer this question with a model focusing
on a time-money tradeoff: religious communities can either choose to be affluent (with little time
and effort spent on religious activities) or poor but with much time and effort spent on religious
13
A similar mechanism was proposed by Abramitzky (2008) to explain why adverse selection and free riding were
typically not issues for Israeli kibbutzim, despite their sharing of resources and promotion of economic equality.
24
activities. A community’s response will largely depend on the labor-market conditions it faces.
Where there are significant economic opportunities, there will be more incentive to choose the
affluent path; where opportunities are fewer, the poorer path with greater religious vitality is more
attractive. Hence, Jews located in Eastern Europe, where economic opportunities were worse than
in Germany, were more likely to become Ultra-Orthodox. These norms persisted even after labor-
market conditions improved in the 20th century.
The bifurcation between Reform and Ultra-Orthodox Jews also sheds light on the interaction
between religious education and religious identity. Carvalho, Koyama, and Sacks (2017) present a
model in which formal education is a means of both transmitting human capital as well as cultural
values (as in Bisin and Verdier 2000, 2001). Mainstream education, which transmits the values of
the majority group, may therefore be harmful to minority groups. According to this theory, groups
like Ultra-Orthodox Jews, whose cultural distance is far from the mainstream, respond to
increasing returns to education by investing less in education. This in turn reinforces intragroup
cohesion, as in Iannaccone (1992) and Berman (2000). In the context of our growth model, the
substitutability between mainstream and religious education entails negative economic returns to
religious education for Ultra-Orthodox Jews, yet there is still an equilibrium in which they acquire
a substantial amount of religious education. These cultural norms persist via education and
marriage markets, thereby limiting Ultra-Orthodox assimilation within the majority communities
at the expense of their economic growth.
In short, the canonical models of the economics of religion help explain why Ultra-Orthodox
Jews attain such high levels of religious education at the expense of secular education, even though
the latter has much higher economic returns. Combined with the above insights regarding Islamic
education and industrialization, this literature suggests that growth will stagnate where i) religious
education is a substitute for secular education and ii) an equilibrium exists in which part of the
population desires religious education despite its lower secular returns.
This section overviews many of the ways in which religion has contributed to economic growth
by augmenting incentives to accumulate secular, economically useful education. The covered
topics include the roles of Jewish education for occupational specialization (Section 4.3.1),
25
Christian orders (Section 4.3.2), the Protestant Reformation (Section 4.3.3), Christian missionaries
(Section 4.3.4), and religious diasporas (Section 4.3.5).
14
See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_Jewish_Nobel_laureates.
26
their children’s education comparatively more because their family derived direct utility from their
education. The key point is that Jewish specialization in high-skilled jobs was the result of an intra-
Jewish battle in the first century CE giving way to religious norms focusing on human capital
acquisition and not external factors (discrimination, persecution) set by non-Jews.
The Jewish educational advantage over Christian majorities has been documented in many
contexts. For instance, Jews put on trial in Spain during the times of the Inquisition (1478-1834)
had higher numeracy (measured by lower rates of age-heaping) than Catholics on trial (Juif, Baten,
and Pérez-Artés 2020). Jews also stand out in their educational achievement in modern times (Pew
Research Center 2016): their average years of schooling is 13.4 years, well ahead of Christians
(9.3 years), Buddhists (7.9 years), Muslims (5.6 years), and Hindus (5.6 years).
Quite closely linked is European Jewish specialization in high-skilled occupations. In 19th-
century Prussia, Jews were over-represented in banking, a skill-intensive occupation in which Jews
were historically strongly represented (Becker and Pascali 2019). In the Middle Ages, the Catholic
Church’s usury ban for Christians (see Section 3.3.1) was a key factor for the Jewish specialization
in banking, but education was a condition sine qua non for Jews to be able to fill that market niche.
The Protestant Reformation brought about Christian competition, because in Protestant areas,
Luther’s and Calvin’s teaching was more tolerant of Christian activity in this sector. Becker and
Pascali (2019) show that the legacy of Jewish banking specialization continued, especially in
Catholic areas. Similarly, Jewish economic specialization may have facilitated greater market
access for cities with Jewish communities. Johnson and Koyama (2017) find that, from 1750-1850,
cities with Jewish communities grew 30-50 percent faster than cities without Jews, with the most
plausible mechanism being that they were better able to take advantage of the growth in market
access that happened across Europe in this period.
The Jewish case highlights that certain religious doctrines may instill norms in their believers
that put a particular emphasis on secular education. The accumulated human capital in turn is a
key driver of economic growth among the religious community, as indicated by occupations in
higher paying sectors such as banking and academia.
27
transcription of religious texts. Monasteries were thus central places of medieval literature,
education, and science, preserving the knowledge of antiquity. They often contained substantial
libraries (e.g., Mary 1953), as documented by the 1170 dictum of Godfrey of St. Barbe-en-Auge,
“a monastery without a library is like a fortress without an armory” (Migne 1855, col. 845A). The
human capital handed down in Christian orders thus particularly emphasized literacy, although the
seven liberal arts taught in monastic schools included logic, math, and astronomy.
In the early Middle Ages, monasteries were the prime centers of book production in Western
Europe. Buringh and van Zanden (2009) show that monasteries were major sources of both the
supply and demand for books during large parts of the Middle Ages. Their analysis indicates that
the church and its institutions shaped book production until the 11th-12th centuries, and universities
and urban lay demand took over as leading factors only afterwards.
At least three aspects of the human capital accumulation in medieval Christian orders suggest
that its impact on economic growth may have been quite limited, especially beyond monastic
development itself. First, literacy was mostly restricted to monks and very seldomly spread beyond
the walls of the monasteries towards the general population. This meant that its use in economic
production, commerce, and initiative was limited. Second, with its focus on religious texts, their
knowledge had a strong focus on religious content and only occasionally referred to scientific or
economically valuable knowledge. Third, outreach was limited by the fact that most works were
written in Latin.
Still, there are exceptions where the human capital impact of medieval orders reached beyond
monastic walls. Most notably, early modern development in the Netherlands has been linked to
the stimulation of human capital by a religious community, the Brethren of the Common Life.
Founded in the late 14th century in Deventer, the Brethren wanted Christians to read the bible and
other religious texts. They thus distributed vernacular religious texts, founded schools, and
produced books. Akçomak, Webbink, and ter Weel (2016) argue that this creation of human capital
among the general public was the foundation for the Netherlands’ early economic development.
They show that Dutch cities with a presence of the Brethren had higher levels of book production
in 1470-1500 and had higher literacy rates in 1600. They further show that cities with Brethren
presence had higher population growth in 1400-1560. With their outreach to the broader
population, the religious community of the Brethren thus initiated economic growth through broad-
based human capital accumulation.
28
4.3.3 The Protestant Reformation and Human Capital Development
The Protestant Reformation brought an important change with respect to human capital: rather
than limiting literacy and learnedness to monks and clergymen (who read the gospel to the
congregation in Latin during mass), leading Protestant reformers demanded that all Christians
should be able to read the word of God themselves. Martin Luther famously translated the bible
into vernacular German. From the very beginning, Luther also preached that every town should
have a school for boys and for girls so that every child could learn to read the bible. Much like the
case of Jewish education (see Section 4.3.1), this religiously-induced literacy could also act as
economically useful human capital, laying the foundation for later growth. Thus, as an alternative
to Weber’s Protestant ethic (see Sections 3.2 and 5.2) as an explanation for the Protestant economic
advantage over Catholics, Becker and Woessmann (2009) suggest a human capital theory of
Protestant economic history: the desire for Protestants to read the bible led to a spurt of literacy in
the overall population that had long-run implications for economic growth.
Luther made his case for the importance of schooling to both political authorities and the
general public, initiating a shift in educational norms at both levels. Leading reformers like Philipp
Melanchthon regularly traveled to the different Protestant territories for visitations to verify the
implementation of school ordinances, which earned him the honorary title of Praeceptor
Germaniae (teacher of the Germans) (Rupp 1996). By preaching to parents to send their children
for instruction, Luther and his fellow reformers also tried to initiate preferences for schooling
among the people. Luther’s theology advanced a “universal priesthood of all believers” against
priestly injunctions, which required universal basic education.
Empirically, Protestantism led to substantially higher levels of education to an extent that may
account for most if not all the Protestant economic advantage over Catholics at Weber’s time.
Becker and Woessmann (2009) exploit the initial concentric dispersion of the Reformation in 19th-
century Prussia to use distance to Wittenberg as an instrument for Protestantism. They find that
Protestantism had a substantial effect on literacy and measures of income and economic
modernization. In their analysis, the Protestant lead in literacy was large enough to account for
practically the entire gap in economic prosperity, leaving little scope for independent effects of the
factors emphasized by the Weber thesis. Becker and Woessmann (2009) also show that
Protestantism was significantly associated with both higher literacy and higher per-capita GDP
across countries in 1900, suggesting that the human capital explanation may generalize beyond
29
Prussia. In fact, by 1900 all Protestant-majority countries had virtually universal literacy, but no
Catholic-majority country did.
Luther’s quest for girls’ as well as boys’ education meant that Protestantism also furthered
gender equality in education. Becker and Woessmann (2008) show that Protestantism significantly
lowered the gender gap in elementary school enrollment in 19th-century Prussia. They also
document that Prussia virtually reached gender parity in elementary education by the second half
of the 19th century, and Protestantism reduced the gender gap in literacy among the adult
population in 1871. In a cross-country analysis, Protestantism is also associated with higher
educational gender parity indexes in 1970.
The Protestant-Catholic difference in human capital may be particularly pronounced in
relatively conservative milieus. Boppart et al. (2013) suggest that the denominational effect on
education may be mediated by other sociocultural characteristics. Using data for Swiss districts at
the end of the 19th century, they find that Protestant districts have higher educational spending per
student and better educational performance on pedagogical exams of conscripts. Results are most
pronounced in districts that voted against three referenda that aimed to introduce progressive
legislation, whereas the Protestant-Catholic difference tends to be weaker in more progressive
districts (which partly reflects that progressive views may be endogenous to the population’s
education).
While the educational impact of Protestantism was particularly pronounced for literacy, it also
extended to other cognitive skills. In the setting of late-19th century Switzerland, Boppart,
Falkinger, and Grossmann (2014) make use of pedagogical exam grades of conscripts in reading,
essay writing, numeracy, and history. They find that the positive effect of Protestantism was
particularly pronounced in reading, consistent with the hypothesis that Protestants stressed bible
reading. At the same time, there is a significant Protestant lead also in the other subjects, which
the authors attribute to a higher Protestant motivation to develop cognitive skills.
An important aspect of the human capital effect of the Protestant Reformation was that it
replaced Latin with vernaculars in printed texts. Binzel, Link, and Ramachandran (2023) argue
that the vernacularization of printing facilitated the spread and subsequent production of
knowledge in the broader population. Drawing on data on books across European cities between
the mid-15th and late-16th century, they show that the Reformation was related to a strong increase
in printing in the vernacular, first on religious texts and then also on non-religious texts, which
30
also spread beyond Protestant cities in due course. The authors also show that vernacular printing
is associated with an increased number of births of famous creatives and innovators as well as
higher population growth in subsequent centuries.
The Protestant-Catholic divide was further amplified by the fact that during the Counter-
Reformation, the Catholic church censored the printing of books deemed in conflict with Catholic
doctrine, thereby holding back the diffusion of knowledge and retarding growth. In response to the
challenges that the newly emerging Protestantism posed to its monopoly, the Catholic church
issued indexes of forbidden books that censored the printing and diffusion of Protestant writers
and other conflicting texts. Becker, Pino, and Vidal-Robert (2021) use data on censored books
across European cities to show that Catholic censorship was effective in reducing the printing of
forbidden authors. In addition, defiant cities that printed indexed books were more attractive to
famous people, a measure of upper-tail human capital.
31
the missionary effect on education is positively mediated by use of the printing press. Alesina et
al. (2021) stress that Christian missions may have long-run effects on education by influencing
educational mobility across generations. They find that Christian—most robustly, Protestant—
missions are among the strongest correlates of intergenerational mobility in educational attainment
across African regions. Outside of Africa, Bai and Kung (2015) stress that Protestant missionaries
erected schools and hospitals in China. Although converting only a tiny fraction of the population,
the missionary conversion had substantial effects on human capital and, thereby, on urbanization.
Protestant missions also had a lasting effect on education in India (Lankina and Getachew 2012),
particularly for women and for missions with higher female presence (Calvi, Hoehn-Velasco, and
Mantovanelli 2022).
Some Catholic orders also emphasized education (see Section 4.3.2), and where Catholic
missionaries did so, they also had a positive long-run effect on education and growth. In various
settings, the Catholic order of the Jesuits—a spearhead of the Counter-Reformation—had a strong
emphasis on educating children. Valencia Caicedo (2019) argues that Jesuit missions played a
leading role in the education of the indigenous population in the Guaraní area in modern-day
Argentina, Brazil, and Paraguay. He shows that former Jesuit presence has a persistent positive
effect on literacy, educational attainment, and income today. In contrast to Jesuit missions,
Catholic missions of the Franciscan order—which did not emphasize education in the Guaraní
area—had no long-term effects. Waldinger (2017) finds the opposite effect for Mexico. She argues
that in colonial Mexico, the educational efforts of the Jesuit order were mostly restricted to colonial
elites in cities rather than the masses. By contrast, the Mendicant orders such as the Franciscans,
which were committed to the poor, were strongly active in educating the native population,
particularly in rural areas. Her results show that the historical presence of Mendicant missions has
a persistent positive effect on literacy and education in Mexico today, whereas Jesuits missions do
not. Thus, the effects of the different Catholic missionary orders appear to strongly depend on the
extent to which they emphasized education of the broad native population.
In colonial Benin, Catholic missionaries founded the first regional schools. Wantchekon,
Novta, and Klašnja (2015) show that attending these schools had significant positive effects on
individual living standards, and the positive effects extend to the next generation—both to the
original students’ descendants and to the descendants of other people in the same villages who did
not attend the schools. In India, Castelló-Climent, Chaudhary, and Mukhopadhyay (2018) argue
32
that Catholic missionaries were instrumental in opening Catholic colleges but had limited lasting
influence otherwise. Their results indicate that historical Catholic missionaries had a positive effect
on higher education today which raises economic growth as proxied by night light density.
33
substantial positive effects on the productivity of textile manufactories in Prussia a century later
(see also Section 6.2 on the transfer of technology).
Religious groups who are forced to migrate can also affect the destination country by spreading
specific norms. Miho, Jarotschkin, and Zhuravskaya (2023) study the deportation of German
Protestants and Chechen Muslims—who they argue had very different gender norms—from the
western to the eastern parts of the Soviet Union by Stalin during World War II. Cohorts of the
native population who went to school when the deportees arrived had higher female higher-
education attainment in destinations with more Protestant compared to Muslim deportees.
Similarly, the share of Protestant deportees is positively related to various measures of gender
equality such as labor-force participation and to the native population’s attitudes towards the role
of women today.
Overall, an array of historical and modern episodes, particularly from Judaism and Christianity,
shows that religion can spur long-run growth by promoting human capital, accounting for several
transitions from stagnation to growth. A central aspect is whether a specific religion puts greater
emphasis on secular or religious content in education. At the peril of over-generalization, it seems
that secular content often took precedence in early Islam, mainstream Judaism, and Protestantism,
whereas religious content often took precedence in later Islam, Ultra-Orthodox Judaism, and
historical mass Catholicism. It is an important open question under which conditions one takes
precedence over the other, and under which conditions religious education may further rather than
retard economic outcomes.
34
5.1 Religion, Population, and Economic Growth
Growth models differ in the extent to which population and labor affect growth. In the standard
Solow-Swan model, the size of the labor force (input factor L in equation (2)) is effectively treated
as synonymous with population size. In that model, an increase in the population growth rate raises
the growth rate of aggregate output but has no permanent effect on the growth rate of per-capita
output, ultimately lowering the steady-state level of per-capita output. By contrast, in endogenous
growth models where growth is a function of ideas and the creation of ideas is a function of the
number of researchers, growth depends positively on the size or growth rate of the population
(Jones 2022).
Religion can affect the development of the population and the labor force in various ways. For
one thing, religion may affect effective labor input because the preferences and ethical values it
conveys can impact work at the intensive margin. For example, Weber’s Protestant work ethic
hypothesis implies that believers provide additional labor input. But time spent on religious
practices may also take away from time available for work (e.g., McCleary and Barro 2019).
It has often been argued that religion played an important role in the demographic transition
and in the escape from the Malthusian trap that is used to describe the pre-modern economy. The
demographic transition occurred when nations moved from a “high birth rate, high death rate”
regime to a “low birth rate, low death rate” regime. This occurred first in France in the 18th century
and then in other European nations in the 19th century. Other parts of the world followed in the
20th century. Unified growth theory attempts to explain this demographic transition and its
consequences for growth. At its core is the child quantity-quality tradeoff, whereby parents choose
between the number of children and the amount they can invest in each child (Galor 2011). An
increase in the demand for skills—e.g., through the advent of better but more skill-intensive
technologies—can thus trigger a decline in fertility which sets the demographic transition in
motion.
Similarly, religion may impede or accelerate the onset of the demographic transition and
subsequent growth dynamics by affecting fertility behavior in at least three ways (Iyer 2002, pp.
30ff). First, the ‘pure religion effect’ hypothesis posits that religions adopt positions on the moral
acceptability of birth control and abortion or norms about ‘desired’ family size. Second, the
‘characteristics’ hypothesis attributes differential fertility to socio-economic differences between
religious groups. In particular, the minority status of a religious group might push it towards
35
procreating more to secure its future. Third, discrimination in the form of differential access to
services such as health and family planning can indirectly affect fertility outcomes (see Iyer 2002
for the case of India).
Work effort is the second main part of the Weber thesis (see Section 3.2 for its first part, thrift).
Developing a specific ethic to work hard, thereby increasing effective labor inputs, should give
rise to increased economic output during the transition to a new steady state. The Protestant work
ethic is one example of how religions develop specific ideas about the importance of work in their
followers’ lives. 15
Papers that test Weber’s Protestant Ethic or related hypotheses about a link between religion
and work ethic tend to look at work effort in conjunction with thriftiness (see Section 3.2). For
instance, Andersen et al. (2017) use items in the European Values Survey (EVS) on whether
valuing “hard work” is an important trait for children to learn at home. Their focus is on the long-
run effect of the historic presence of Cistercians as a Catholic order whose cultural traits resemble
those ascribed to Protestants. They find that in European regions with historic presence of
Cistercians, parents place greater value on hard work as a trait to instill in children.
Staying closer to the original Weber thesis by directly comparing Protestants to Catholics and
looking at Weber’s home country Germany, Spenkuch (2017) draws on the historical variation in
Protestantism in the aftermath of the Peace of Augsburg (1555) where the principle “whose rule,
his religion” was established. Modern-day Germany essentially still displays the same religious
majorities as roughly 400 years ago. Results suggest that historical Protestantism is associated with
longer working hours, but not higher hourly wages, in the present. This finding is consistent with
a cultural values-based interpretation, as in the Weber thesis. Basten and Betz (2013) find similar
results for Switzerland, employing a spatial discontinuity in the cantons of Vaud and Fribourg
created by a 16th-century split between Catholicism and Reformed (Calvinist) Protestantism.
Looking at preferences expressed in modern referenda, they find that Protestant support for
increasing leisure time is about 13.5 percentage points lower than in Catholic electorates, in line
with the Weber thesis.
15
For instance, Sharabi (2017) compares the work ethic among Jews and Muslims in Israel.
36
A Protestant “work ethic” also plays a prominent, albeit indirect, role in the work of Cantoni
(2015). Looking at city growth over the years 1300-1900 in Protestant versus Catholic cities in the
German lands, he expects Malthusian forces to entail that urban productivity advantages translate
into faster city growth. Cantoni (2015, p. 570) argues that “if Protestantism did indeed increase the
productivity of urban dwellers—by providing them with a peculiar ‘work ethic’ …—this should
translate into larger city sizes.” Yet, his results show that Protestant cities did not grow faster than
Catholic cities, inconsistent with a prominent role for a Protestant work ethic at the city level.
Overall, the empirical evidence for the Weber thesis is mixed. While in some contexts there is
evidence for denominational differences in work effort (or thrift) between Protestants and
Catholics, or between different types of Protestantism, this finding is by no means universal.
Religious norms can influence work effort and thereby effective labor inputs. But it seems that
empirically, work ethic is not necessarily the most influential factor in the link between religion
and growth.
The role of religion in fertility, demographic development, and population growth has been studied
in various settings. In particular, researchers have looked at the demographic transition—a shift
from high to low birth and death rates—which played a central role in the escape from the
Malthusian trap. As such, it has been central to theories of long-run growth (Galor 2011; Koyama
and Rubin 2022, ch. 5). It is important to note that both the quantity and quality of children are
endogenous variables in the quantity-quality (Q-Q) model of unified growth theory. Galor (2011)
argues that the cleanest evidence for a child Q-Q tradeoff is the response to a change in the price
of fertility (e.g., cost of contraception) or in the price of child quality (e.g., cost of education).
Even before the demographic transition, there is evidence for the existence of a child Q-Q
tradeoff. In their analysis of 19th-century Prussia, Becker, Cinnirella, and Woessmann (2010) use
exogenous variation in the price of child quality triggered by the Protestant Reformation’s
fostering of public schools. Their results show that the religion-induced increase in investment in
child quality, measured by education in 1849, does indeed decrease fertility. They also show that
education in 1849 predicts the fertility transition in 1880-1905. To the extent that demographic
transition was key in the transition to modern growth, this provides evidence for religious roots of
the differential timing of this transition. In fact, a child Q-Q tradeoff existed even earlier, in 1816
37
(Becker, Cinnirella, and Woessmann 2012). In short, there is a tradeoff between a generally
procreational stance and investment in education in both Protestant and Catholic denominations,
but the different emphasis on the importance of education triggered different fertility responses.
A direct analysis of the link between religion and fertility is provided by Becker and Cinnirella
(2020), who use municipality-level variation across roughly 50,000 locations in Prussia in 1871.
Using only within-county variation, they show that fertility rates are lower the larger the share of
Protestants (and Jews) in a location.
It is not always differences between religious groups that drive differences in inputs to
economic growth; such differences may also result from people turning away from religion. Blanc
(2023) shows that the process of secularization that started earlier in France than anywhere else is
the key driver of France’s earlier start of the demographic transition. Blanc (2023) draws on
genealogical records to document fertility levels across French départements. To proxy for
religiosity, he uses the share of clergymen who did not take the oath on the secular French Republic
in 1791 (known as refractory clergy). Individuals born in places with refractory clergy have more
children. The various works on the demographic transition thus suggest that different religious
groups show different fertility behavior in this crucial phase, indicating that religion likely played
a relevant role in the transition from stagnation to modern growth.
Religious health practices constitute another cause of demographic differences across religious
groups. Botticini, Eckstein, and Vaturi (2019) document that over the period from 1500 to 1930,
Jews in central and eastern Europe had birth rates that were about the same as those of non-Jews,
but infant and child mortality among Jews was much lower and accounted for the main difference
in Jewish versus non-Jewish natural population growth. The reason they suggest was that the
Talmudic teaching on breastfeeding affected women’s behaviors that enhanced children’s well-
being. The Talmud advises mothers to breastfeed their infants immediately following birth and
requires 24 months of breastfeeding. The rabbis also allowed mechanical contraception during
lactation to preserve the mother’s ability to nurse, which directly reduced fertility by preventing a
rapid succession of newborns. Such rules were not common among Christian communities and,
according to the authors, explain the higher survival rate of Jewish infants.
Differential teachings on the acceptability of contraceptive devices to regulate fertility are
another important difference between religious groups. The Catholic Church discourages the use
of condoms whereas Protestant churches usually do not. This has both a potential direct effect on
38
fertility levels and a potential influence on mortality risk stemming from sexually transmitted
diseases like HIV (Cagé and Rueda 2020). Religious differences in mortality have also played a
major role in Durkheim’s (1897) classic work on suicide, with suicide rates in Protestant areas far
exceeding those in Catholic areas in 19th-century Prussia (Becker and Woessmann 2018).
Overall, the empirical work clearly shows that religion is an underlying driver of differences
in fertility and mortality and thus in demographic development. Historically, religious
differences—as well as secularization—influenced the demographic transition, a turning point in
history and an essential condition for sustained growth.
As highlighted in equation (5) and covered in Section 4, technological change will partly depend
on human capital. This section covers those aspects of the nexus between religion, technological
development, and macroeconomic efficiency that are not necessarily mediated through human
capital.
The key innovation of endogenous growth models such as Romer (1990) and Aghion and
Howitt (1998) is the endogenization of technological change. Apart from investment in research
and development, technological change depends on the creativity of the population and its
39
openness to develop new technologies or adopt them from abroad. In general, available technology
is the sum of previous technology, new technology produced domestically (∆𝑇𝑇𝑡𝑡𝑑𝑑 ) and new
technology adopted from elsewhere (∆𝑇𝑇𝑡𝑡𝑎𝑎 ):
Religions can affect new technology produced domestically for material reasons (i.e., valuing
the returns to new technology), but also for spiritual or ideological reasons, as technology requires
altering human’s relationship with the natural world (Mokyr 1990). In particular, religious beliefs
may affect both the understanding of how technologies work in a scientific sense and the
willingness to abandon traditional but outdated technologies for new ones. In a similar way, the
willingness to adopt new technologies can be affected by religion, as documented in the differential
use of the newly emerging printing press during the Protestant Reformation (Rubin 2014). When
individuals can choose between an intuitive-believing and a reflective-analytical reasoning style,
a decline in religiosity can lead to an increased willingness to engage in reflective-analytical
reasoning, higher productivity in research and development, and increased TFP growth (Herzer
and Strulik 2020).
Beyond technology in the narrow sense, TFP is shaped more broadly by political, legal, and
economic institutions. To the extent that religions shape individual preferences and values such as
trust and openness to change, they will affect TFP by framing the efficiency of market interactions.
In various ways, religions also impinge on economic institutions such as customs of taxation and
commercial law. In many places, religious rituals, politics, and laws shape not only economic
institutions, but also the state and development of societal institutions and norms more broadly. In
addition, political economy models suggest that religion is often used for political legitimation.
Religions can also incite conflict or call for tolerance between and within countries, affecting both
the ability to produce and the extent to which economic agents can engage in interpersonal
exchange. We will cover each of these aspects in turn.
We start with the impact of religion on technological change. Technological change is the central
feature of modern growth (Mokyr 1990, 2009; Koyama and Rubin 2022, ch. 8). In Section 4
(particularly Section 4.2.2), we focused on the interaction between religion and education as inputs
40
into endogenous growth models, primarily via technology. Here we are interested in the direct
nexus between religion and technology, absent the education link.
There are several avenues through which religion can play a positive role in domestic
technological development and technology adoption. In the medieval period, monastic houses
throughout Europe were the primary places where technical knowledge, books, and informal
learning were preserved. In the 17th and 18th centuries, Jesuits acted as central conduits through
which technical knowledge was passed between Europe and China (Ma 2021; Davids 2013, ch.
3). Religious minorities also brought technologies with them when they were persecuted (see also
Section 4.3.5). For instance, Protestants fleeing Spanish-controlled Belgium during the Eighty
Years’ War (1568-1648) settled in the Netherlands, bringing their knowledge of fine draperies
with them. It therefore may not be religion but religious tolerance that facilitates technological
progress. Cinnirella and Streb (2018) test this hypothesis in the context of the Second Industrial
Revolution. They find that in late-19th century Prussia, those cities that had greater religious
toleration (as measured by the presence of different denominations) had greater patenting activity.
Relatedly, Hornung (2019) shows that in the setting of 18th-century Berlin, greater religious
diversity—brought about by the persecuted religious minority groups of Jews, Huguenots, and
Bohemian Hussites—increased the utilization of loom technology in textile production.
Religion can also have a negative impact on the spread of technology. The Catholic Church’s
condemnation of Galileo and the anti-Darwinism of the early 20th century are leading examples.
In the 21st century, religious groups have successfully pushed for limitations on embryonic stem-
cell research. In Islam, Naghavi (2019) argues that a relative lack of intellectual property rights
has impeded technological development. Historically, scientific production dropped dramatically
in the Islamic world in the 11th and 12th centuries as the rise of the madrasas shifted learning from
secular to religious topics (Chaney 2023; see Section 4.2.1). Waqf-funded religious education in
madrasas played a particularly important role in limiting scientific production, as curricula were
not always adjustable and waqf deeds often limited education to Islamic sciences and not rational
sciences (Huff 2017, ch. 5; see Sections 3.3.2 and 4.2.1). The theory proposed by Bénabou, Ticchi,
and Vindigni (2022) helps explain this negative connection between religion and technology,
suggesting that scientific discoveries can erode religious beliefs (see Section 4.2.2). This is also
true of technologies, especially those that transform nature or threaten the veracity of religious
doctrine (e.g., evolution).
41
Political economy considerations likewise contribute to religious restrictions on technology.
Seror (2018) suggests that economic prohibitions may be promoted by religious authorities when
it improves their political bargaining power. This is especially true for conservative clerics, since
prohibitions can increase resentment towards religious minorities (who take up occupations using
the prohibited technology), in turn giving more political power to conservatives at the expense of
their more moderate peers.
For some technologies, religious authorities stand to lose rents should adoption become
widespread. Technology prohibitions can therefore occur when religious authorities are powerful
enough—via their role in legitimating the state—to prevent the spread of the new technology. This
was the case, for instance, with the Ottoman prohibition on the movable type printing press. As
documented by Coşgel, Miceli, and Rubin (2012), who employ a similar political economy model,
the Ottomans prohibited printing in the Arabic script for nearly 250 years after learning of
Gutenberg’s invention (from the 1480s until 1727). 16 A key reason was that the printed word
threatened the monopoly the religious establishment held on intellectual activities. As long as the
top religious authorities played a key role in legitimating the state, the sultan enacted a ban on
printing in the Arabic script in order to protect the rents of religious authorities. It was only after
the power of religious authorities diminished that these restrictions were relaxed.
In sum, there are several ways that religion can impact domestic technological change and
technology adoption. Religion affects the former via religious beliefs and tolerance, whereas it
affects the latter through political economy and missionary activity.
This section covers various additional aspects (besides technological change) of how religion
affects the efficiency of an economy, including the role of rituals in shaping cultural norms and
institutions (Section 6.3.1), religious politics and law (Section 6.3.2), the legitimation of states
(Section 6.3.3), and religious conflict and tolerance (Section 6.3.4).
16
Religious minorities in the Ottoman Empire were permitted to print, so long as the language did not use the Arabic
script (e.g., Greek, Hebrew).
42
growing literature reveals how such rituals can impinge on economic growth via “residual factors”
that affect total factor productivity.
One particularly important religious ritual that affects around 1.8 billion people is the fasting
associated with the Muslim observance of Ramadan. As one of the five pillars of Islam, observant
Muslims are supposed to fast from sunrise to sunset. Social scientists have found that this ritual
has varied socio-economic consequences, many of which have implications for productivity and
growth. Campante and Yanagizawa-Drott (2015) find that places with longer Ramadan fasting
(because they are closer to the equator or Ramadan takes place in summer) have lower output
growth but higher subjective well-being. They rationalize these findings with an Iannaccone
(1992)-style club good model. If greater fasting restrictions screen out less committed members,
happiness should be greater for those who are in the club. Such a sacrifice has economic
consequences since it comes with reduced productivity—places with longer Ramadan fasting have
lower GDP per worker.
There are several other consequences of Ramadan. Although Ramadan observance is not
required for pregnant women, it is the norm in many parts of the world. This can have damaging
consequences for the fetus and for physical and mental development. Almond, Mazumder, and
van Ewijk (2015) find that students who were exposed to Ramadan while in utero have lower test
performance years later, and Majid (2015) finds that these effects last throughout life. On the other
hand, Hornung, Schwerdt, and Strazzeri (2023) show that Muslim students exposed to longer
fasting hours during Ramadan have higher test scores; they argue that Ramadan improves learning
outcomes by facilitating the formation of social capital.
Religious rituals can substitute time away from economically productive activities. For
instance, Montero and Yang (2022) find that Catholic patron saint day festivals in Mexico, which
occur for many days at different times of the year, have a negative effect on local economic
development and household income when they coincide with the agricultural planting or
harvesting months. The most likely mechanism is that these festivals lower agricultural
productivity: during the festivals, households are time- and liquidity-constrained, limiting their
agricultural activities. Religious festivals can also crowd out agricultural financial investments and
encourage communities to plant at non-optimal times.
Religious norms and rules such as marriage practices can also affect the importance of kinship
networks and thereby the mode of economic cooperation and exchange. In the case of Europe,
43
Schulz et al. (2019) and Henrich (2020) argue that the Catholic Church’s medieval ban on cousin
marriage—a key mechanism binding together kin groups—undermined extensive kin networks.
Instead of emphasizing in-group loyalty, places with deeper Catholic influence became more
individualistic and exchange became more impersonal. Such characteristics are essential for
modern economic exchange; when relegated to the kin group, there are significant limits to how
much exchange can occur. Moreover, impersonal trust affects financial development. Chen, Ma,
and Sinclair (2022) show that Chinese financial development was delayed due to the importance
of kin-group social insurance; because members of the same kin group were expected to provide
for each other in times of need, there was less pressure for more impersonal forms of lending to
arise. Schulz (2022) also finds an important political consequence of weakened kin groups: places
with greater historical exposure to the Catholic Church have weaker kin-group norms and thus
higher levels of civicness, which facilitates higher levels of political participation.
Religion affects cooperation and norm enforcement in several other ways. One well-known
example is the caste system, which proscribes all sorts of socio-economic injunctions on Hindus.
One consequence of this system is that it shapes in-group versus out-group norms of cooperation.
Hoff, Kshetramade, and Fehr (2011) find that those at the bottom of the caste hierarchy are less
willing to punish members of their own caste because repression experiences reduce their
capability for altruistic third-party punishment. This negatively affects their ability to sustain
cooperation with those outside of their caste.
Some rituals can affect economic decision-making by altering beliefs in how others act. This
is particularly true for traditional religions, where beliefs in spells and curses are common. Butinda
et al. (2023) study the willingness to pay for religious protection rituals of beer sellers in the
Democratic Republic of Congo who fear theft and confiscation and thus understock their
inventory. Butinda et al. run a field experiment offering a protection ritual to some of the beer
sellers. Among those who have the ritual performed for them, those who believe in its efficacy
increase their inventory to a level closer to optimal (i.e., fewer stock-outs and greater profits).
These results suggest that rituals can have a positive impact on inputs into economic growth
regardless of whether the rituals are effective or not.
Another example for the relevance of second-order beliefs comes from Taoist beliefs about
marriage matching. Ciscato, Do, and Nguyen (2023) show that in Vietnam auspicious beliefs about
marriage fortune based on birth-year matches derived from Taoist astrology affect not only
44
marriage matching, but also positively impact income and children’s educational outcomes. A
likely mechanism is that auspicious matches receive higher transfers from extended family when
hit by shocks, and auspicious couples believe that their relatives believe that auspicious couples
are luckier.
In summary, religious rituals and norms can be an important residual factor affecting
productivity and growth—in both positive and negative ways. Rituals can encourage and sustain
hard work, cooperation with outsiders, and the provision of social insurance to co-religionists. On
the other hand, they can encourage and sustain dangerous, unproductive, or costly actions that
reduce the productivity of the religious group.
45
Ultimately, this permitted religious minorities in the empire (mostly Greeks, Armenians, and Jews)
to pull ahead of Muslims in commercial affairs (Kuran 2004b).
Even in states in which religious law is not predominant, religious politics can play an
important role in determining a society’s productive capacity. This can be the case in democracies
that contain religious parties or autocracies that depend on religious authorities for legitimation
(see Section 6.3.3). One important development in the last half century has been the rise of
Islamism and Islamic political parties. 17 In Indonesia, Bazzi, Koehler-Derrick, and Marx (2020)
find that a significant rise in assets transferred into waqf in the 1960s (to avoid state expropriation)
led to increased political power for local religious authorities via increased investment in religious
schools and mosques. Over time, this led to a rise in conservative, Islamist ideology in places most
affected by waqf transfers and, ultimately, to increased electoral support for Islamic parties and
the adoption of sharia laws. Those areas with greater waqf endowments also had lower agricultural
productivity, which was likely due to the inflexibility of waqf endowments. In Turkey, religious
parties have been on the rise since the 1990s, with the Islamist AKP winning the presidency in
2002. At the local level, this has led to more pro-Islamic policies, including the removal of
headscarf bans. Corekcioglu (2021) shows that towns with Islamist mayors were more likely to
eliminate headscarf bans, which in turn increased employment for observant Muslim women.
Religion is intertwined with politics in the US, as well, with significant implications for
economic growth. In recent decades, there has been a rise of “faith-based” initiatives promoted by
religious conservatives. These initiatives authorized faith-based offices and task forces to bridge
the gap between local governance and the faith-based community. Bentzen and Sperling (2020)
find that places with more faith-based initiatives have more faith-based organizations and churches
after the onset of the initiative. One area where this impinges on economic growth is attitudes
towards women. McKenzie and Rouse (2013) find that among the US white population,
conservative Christianity is associated with less egalitarian views on gender (although this is not
the case for the Latino or black populations who are on average more religious). The rise in US
faith-based initiatives thus increased skepticism towards women working in the labor market and
receiving education, resulting in greater gender gaps in employment and education.
17
There is a large literature in political science on the causes of the rise of Islamic parties. See Grewal et al. (2019)
for a nice overview. We do not review this literature here because we focus on works that directly relate religious
politics with economic growth.
46
Religion can also affect voters’ political preferences, which can in turn influence political
outcomes that affect growth. In addition to direct preference effects on political majorities, charity
provision is one mechanism through which this can happen. Huber and Stanig (2011) theorize that
privately provided charity can create voting cleavages among charity recipients, some of whom
receive charity from the state and others from religious institutions. This in turn allows for
coalitions to emerge (as in the modern US Republican Party) between the rich and “religious poor”
that favor low taxes and limited redistribution. They also find that these coalitions only emerge
when there is weak state financial support of religion. Stegmueller (2013) finds a similar result in
the context of Western Europe: to gain support for anti-redistributive policies, political parties
strategically bundle them with conservative Christian social policies. Gaskins, Golder, and Siegel
(2013) argue that increases in inequality lead to both greater religious participation and increased
economic conservativism among the poor (but not the rich).
In sum, there are numerous channels through which religious law, religious political parties,
and religious preferences impinge on political outcomes. These can in turn affect total factor
productivity through several channels such as restrictions on female labor-force participation,
redistribution by the state, the perpetuation of inefficient institutions, and productivity in sectors
affected by religious regulations.
47
these legitimating arrangements include increased city growth, public good investment, and
technology adoption, all of which are key components of growth models.
Many countries have state religions, which have several economic implications (McCleary and
Barro 2019, ch. 5). As Barro and McCleary (2005, p. 1332) note, “state monopoly over religion
has probably been the single most important form of state monopoly in existence.” They find that
state control of religion tends to persist: by far the best predictor of state religion is whether the
nation had a state religion in the past. Bentzen and Gokmen (2023) find that such persistence has
very deep roots. Their analysis suggests that religion became institutionalized in states which used
divine legitimation long in the past, and those states still have more institutionalized religion today
and are more likely to be autocratic. While nations with state religions do not always adhere to the
constitutional clauses promoting one religion over another (Fox and Flores 2009), the presence of
a state religion is indicative of how the state legitimates rule.
How and when the state uses religious legitimation varies across time and place. For instance,
Gill (1998) argues that, in Latin America, the strategy used by autocrats of legitimating rule with
the Catholic Church depends on the degree of religious competition. This in turn has implications
for how much the state can use its coercive power to suppress potentially subversive organizations.
Coşgel and Miceli (2009) also find that religious competition affects whether the state finds it
optimal to take control of religion. They argue that under monopolistic settings, religion can more
effectively legitimate the state and thus lower the costs of tax collection. 18
In the Islamic world, religion has played a role in politics since Muhammad and the First Four
caliphs. Rubin (2017) argues that an equilibrium emerged in which religious legitimation was
effective and thus frequently used by political authorities. This in turn meant that religious
authorities received policy concessions. In fact, Blaydes, Grimmer, and McQueen (2018) find that
medieval advice texts to rulers began to emphasize religion in the Middle East precisely when
religious authorities began to obtain power independent of the state around the 11th century.
Meanwhile, religion began to be de-emphasized in Christian advice texts in the late medieval
period, as religious authorities were losing their capacity to legitimate rule. According to Rubin,
this meant that religious authorities gained a greater seat at the political bargaining table in the
18
Coşgel et al. (2018) qualify this finding empirically, noting that while monopolization of religion does lead to less
secularization, this result is reversed if the ruler is of a different religion than most of the population. In this case, a
monopolized religious market can have a delegitimating effect.
48
Middle East as their power to legitimate rule rose. For example, in a study of medieval Egypt
where rulers relied heavily on religious authorities for legitimacy, Chaney (2013) finds that
religious authorities gained political power and were less likely to be removed when the Nile River
was either too high (flood) or low (drought). Such weather conditions placed political authorities
in a precarious position, thus increasing their desire to establish their legitimacy. As a result, the
bargaining power of the religious establishment was greatest at these times, and they were able to
extract the most from the state.
Such arrangements could have serious consequences for economic growth. The most direct
consequence is that policies that hamper economic growth persist even after it becomes clear that
they stifle growth. Two examples with substantial impact on growth in the Middle East are
restrictions on taking interest (which is widely thought to be banned by the Qur’an) and
prohibitions on printing in the Arabic script which would have threatened the monopoly of the
religious establishment over intellectual pursuits (Rubin 2017). According to Rubin, the most
important effect of religious legitimation in the Islamic world is that it kept economic elites outside
of the ruling coalition. With little voice, these elites could not advocate for policies that benefited
themselves and, incidentally, economic growth.
Other political economy phenomena have been deemed important for the relative economic
stagnation of the Middle East. One related to religious legitimation was proposed by Blaydes and
Chaney (2013), who argued that Muslim rulers had fewer constraints on their rule than Europeans
because the former had access to slave soldiers. This meant that Muslim rulers did not need to
negotiate with other powerful elites, and thus institutions like parliaments never formed until after
colonization. By contrast, European rulers were constrained by powerful lords whom they relied
upon for military service, and these lords ultimately institutionalized their power in parliaments.
Bisin et al. (2023) present a model in which political authorities only devolve political power (as
European rulers did) when the returns from religious legitimacy are sufficiently low. They reason
that there are benefits to a ruler to voluntarily constrain their own power—greater tax collection,
more local law and order—but these benefits are only worth it when the ruler has weak access to
other sources of power such as religious legitimacy. These insights can help explain the divergent
political and economic trajectories of Western Europe and the Middle East.
In Europe, the Protestant Reformation brought a sea change in how rule was legitimated, with
significant consequences for growth. Rulers that adopted the Reformation lost one of their
49
historical sources of legitimacy in the Catholic Church. Greif and Rubin (2023) and Rubin (2017)
argue that the Reformation encouraged Protestant rulers to turn to parliaments for legitimacy.
Protestant rulers were no longer able to rely on the Catholic Church to legitimate their claims to
rule, and Protestant churches were a weak substitute. Parliaments were the natural alternative, as
they were pre-existing forums where elites met to negotiate with the crown. This had important
implications for economic growth. In England and the Dutch Republic, which became the world’s
leading economies soon after their reformations, parliamentary power grew substantially in the
16th and 17th centuries. This led to the enactment of many pro-growth statutes, including those
related to transportation, enclosures, land reclamation, and property rights (Rubin 2017). Cantoni,
Dittmar, and Yuchtman (2018) argue that state administration became more secular in the Holy
Roman Empire because Protestant rulers no longer sought legitimacy from the Church. They find
that Protestant university students increasingly majored in law rather than theology, seeking jobs
in government administration. Religious competition also encouraged Protestant towns to adopt
church ordinances, which expanded local welfare provision and public education. Dittmar and
Meisenzahl (2020) find that this induced those with elite human capital to move to Protestant cities,
which in turn caused them to grow faster and become more human capital intensive by 1800. Thus,
throughout Europe the Reformation had a secularizing effect that ended up promoting growth.
Another outcome through which religion and political economy interact is the development of
the state itself. For instance, late-medieval city states were among the first places in Europe to
move away from autocratic governance. Belloc, Drago, and Galbiati (2016) show that earthquakes
slowed this transition, but only in places that were ruled by religious authorities. They reason that
earthquakes were viewed as signs from God, and religious authorities had a comparative advantage
in interpreting them as such. This allowed religious authorities to maintain their autocratic powers,
which tended to retard economic growth. More generally, a large literature attributes Europe’s
eventual economic growth to its fragmentation following the collapse of the Holy Roman Empire
(Ko, Koyama, and Sng 2018; Scheidel 2019). Grzymala-Busse (2023) argues that the Church
played a role in this fragmentation. It benefited the Church when none of the European powers
were too large, so it played the powers off against each other, never allowing any one state to
become too powerful. The Church could do this because it had the “wealth, spiritual authority, and
expertise to fundamentally mold politics” (Grzymala-Busse 2020, p. 20). With little access to
50
coercive power, the papacy instead shaped states via doctrine, law, and administrative innovations.
Though unintended, these innovations would play a key role in Europe’s eventual economic rise.
In summary, an important mechanism through which religion affects economic growth, both
historically and today, is political economy. Religious authorities can use their spiritual power to
legitimate the state, which in turn allows them to influence policy. This can have far-reaching (and
unintended) consequences for economic growth, affecting patterns of trade, human capital
development, and productivity.
51
anti-Semitism in Germany. Their analysis begins with the Black Death, a plausibly exogenous
shock that precipitated anti-Semitic views, as Jews were blamed for the plague (e.g., through
poisoned wells). They find that places that had medieval pogroms against Jews still harbored anti-
Semitic sentiments in the 20th century, as seen in Nazi vote shares and attacks on synagogues. The
persistence of these cultural traits is much weaker in places with greater access to trade.
These results have serious implications for economic growth. D’Acunto, Prokopczuk, and
Weber (2019) find that financial development in the present day is low in German counties with
high levels of anti-Semitism. Although savings are similar across German counties, those with an
anti-Semitic past invest less in stocks, have fewer bank deposits, and are less likely to get a
mortgage. These results are likely due to the historical specialization of Jews in financial services,
which fed anti-Semitic tropes of Jews being stock-market manipulators and avaricious
moneylenders.
At the root of many persecutions are political economy considerations. Political legitimacy is
a key component in how a state is run and how an economy grows (Section 6.3.3). Religious
persecutions can be a means to obtain legitimacy. Johnson and Koyama (2019) argue that Jews
and other minorities (e.g., Roma, “witches”) in medieval Europe were tolerated only when
societies were relatively stable. Since rulers relied on religious legitimacy, they could improve
their religious bona fides by persecuting religious minorities in times of instability. Oster (2004)
finds that witchcraft trials were particularly prominent during periods of bad weather when
scapegoats were needed for crop failures. Likewise, Miguel (2005) finds that extreme rainfall
shocks lead to increased murder of elderly women deemed as “witches” in Tanzania, possibly
because of their relatively low labor productivity. The presence of witchcraft is also associated
with several inputs of economic growth functions. Gershman (2022) finds that beliefs in witchcraft
are negatively associated with markers of creative culture, innovative activity, social capital, and
trust, while there is an inverted-U shape relationship between witchcraft beliefs and standard
measures of economic well-being. 19
Political economy considerations also contributed to the persecution of medieval Jews, who
were more likely to be persecuted during unseasonably cold weather years (Anderson, Johnson,
19
The negative relationship between witchcraft beliefs and social capital—both for those holding beliefs and those
engaging with people who hold these beliefs—has also been found in Gershman (2016) and Le Rossignol, Lowes,
and Nunn (2022).
52
and Koyama 2017). It was particularly in weak states—those in which authorities were not secure
in their rule—that such persecutions were most likely to occur. A similar mechanism is proposed
by Ticku, Shrivastava, and Iyer (2023) to explain Muslim desecration of Hindu temples in South
Asia. They find that desecrations were much more likely to occur during large weather
fluctuations. Iyer (2018) argues that Indian regions with greater inequality are more susceptible to
religious violence because it causes politicians to exploit economic grievances by raising religious
hostility. In Eastern Europe, Grosfeld, Sakalli, and Zhuravskaya (2020) find that anti-Jewish
pogroms were more likely to happen in the Pale of Settlement between 1800 and 1927 when
economic shocks and political turmoil occurred at the same time. Unlike the analyses of
Voigtländer and Voth (2012) and Johnson and Koyama (2019), they find little evidence of Jews
simply being scapegoated. Instead, they argue that Jewish moneylenders were quick to demand
repayment during periods of turmoil because debtors were unable to commit to paying back their
loans. This led to ethnic and religious violence and persecution.
Several studies seek to understand the consequences of religious intolerance and persecution.
The Holocaust stands out as the deadliest religious persecution of the 20th century. Acemoglu,
Hassan, and Robinson (2011) find that those Russian cities which had the most intense experience
with the Holocaust grew less throughout the 20th century and continue to have lower population
and greater Communist vote shares after the collapse of the Soviet Union. They argue that this was
due to a substantial thinning-out of the middle class, as Russian Jews were primarily engaged in
white-collar occupations prior to the Holocaust.
In contrast to the detrimental impact of religious persecution, inter-religious economic activity
can often have a positive effect on growth. Religious tolerance and diversity can spur technological
advancement (Section 6.2). Economic complementarities between religious groups can also foster
dependence and trust, thus lowering animosity or a predilection to persecute. In India, Jha (2013)
studies how historical economic complementarities between Hindus and Muslims can mitigate
hostilities between the two groups in subsequent centuries. Such complementarities were
particularly stark in port towns, where Muslim traders dominated in the medieval period. Jha
argues that this encouraged the formation of institutions that supported inter-religious exchange
and helped mitigate Hindu-Muslim riots in the 19th and 20th centuries. 20
20
Mitra and Ray (2014) present an alternative theory of Hindu-Muslim violence. They argue that an increase in income
for a religious group makes violence against that group more likely to be framed as religious. This allows all members
53
For as long as there has been religion, there has been religious intolerance and persecution.
This can have a dampening effect on economic growth through expulsions of productive religious
minorities, reduced use of financial services, increased presence of extractive institutions, negative
attitudes towards female education and employment, and much more. Exposure to individuals
from other religions can help mitigate intolerance and inter-religious conflict, which remains a
significant hurdle to economic growth.
7. Conclusions
The important insights generated over the past couple of decades by the literatures on the
economics of religion and the economics of growth have mostly been disjoined. While the popular
media often makes broad-brush connections between specific religions and particularly successful
or detrimental growth episodes, modern economic analysis mostly shies away from such
connections. This may partly be true because many of the recent advancements in the economics
of religion, in particular as far as they are concerned with present-day analysis, tend to take a
microeconomic rather than macroeconomic perspective. In fact, a key feature of most of the
economics of religion studies that we cover is that they do not aim to contribute to the literature
on economic growth and thus mostly do not make an explicit connection of their findings to
growth.
We hope that our synthesis, with its structure (and, in parts, reinterpretation) along the lines of
the elements of the macroeconomic production function, will not only help to better understand
the important bearing of religion for growth, but also to initiate future work directly focused on
the topic and to better place future work in the growth perspective. While many areas remain
underexplored, we think that a few general conclusions on the relevance and nature of the impact
of religion on growth and its various channels can be drawn based on our synthesis.
There is clear evidence that religion affected growth through promoting or hindering the
accumulation of physical capital during various episodes across time and space. Restrictions on
interest in Christianity and Islam, as well various elements of Islamic finance, are key examples
of how religion affects financial development, with consequences for the matching of saving to
capital investment. While there is some indication that—as argued by Max Weber—a Protestant
of the other religion to be targeted. They argue that the motivations for violence may be either economic (i.e.,
appropriation) or resentment.
54
ethic may have furthered thrift and saving in some contexts, the overall evidence on this channel
is mixed.
Evidence also abounds that religion affects growth by influencing human capital. Many
historical and modern examples, particularly from Judaism and Protestantism, show that religious
norms, practices, and institutions—often inadvertently—led to a substantial accumulation of
secular education in the mass population. By contrast, when religious content takes precedence
over secular education, it often substitutes away from the generation of economically useful
knowledge. Changes in Islamic education, Catholic resistance to the industrialization, and Ultra-
Orthodox Judaism pose examples where religious education impeded long-run growth.
Religion can also affect growth through its impact on population and labor. Religious norms
(and their decline) affect fertility and health-related mortality, thereby speeding up or holding back
the demographic transition, which was essential for the transition from Malthusian stagnation to
modern growth. By contrast, while relevant for denominational differences in some contexts,
religious differences in work effort and thus effective labor input empirically do not seem to be
the most influential factor linking religion to growth.
One of the most important channels of the role of religion for growth appears to be the shaping
of norms and institutions that impact total factor productivity. Numerous empirical examples from
all major world religions exemplify how religions can impact state development, policies, the
emergence of growth-promoting institutions, and technological change. A key mechanism is the
role of religion in legitimating political power. But religions also impact macroeconomic
productivity through rituals, laws, the choice between inter-religious persecution or tolerance, and
the suppression of innovations that threaten the traditional order.
As will have become painfully clear from our synthesis, there are also many obvious holes in
our understanding of the link between religion and growth, which we think of as highly fruitful
directions for future research. Most notably, among the “Big Five” world religions—Buddhism,
Christianity, Hinduism, Islam, and Judaism—the available economics literature is clearly overly
weighted towards the three Abrahamic religions and notably short of reliable insights from
Buddhism and Hinduism. The same is true for other religions such as Taoism or—to the extent
that it can be considered as a religion—Confucianism. Similarly, little research comparable to the
studies covered here has focused on the growth implications of indigenous religions and of
alternative spiritual movements. More research on non-Abrahamic religions could provide
55
fundamental insight into some of the most important questions in the economics of growth, such
as why certain economies pulled ahead at certain points in time, why others caught up with those
at the frontier (e.g., the Asian “tiger economies”), why some economies started to emerge in recent
decades (e.g., some BRICS economies), and why others are still lagging behind (e.g., South Asia,
sub-Saharan Africa).
The synthesized evidence on religion and education has uncovered a crucial distinction
between educational content that builds economically valuable skills and content that does not.
Research uncovering systematic reasons why religious content or secular education takes
precedence over the other in specific contexts would clearly further our understanding of the
human capital channel of the effect of religion on growth. Similarly, religious education can act
either as a substitute for or complement to secular education in promoting growth-enhancing traits,
and it is not well studied when and why one emerges rather than the other.
It also seems that the growth implications of the decline in religion and religiosity in some
modern societies are a relatively understudied topic compared to inter-religious differences. There
is evidence that secularization and a turn away from religiosity may have been an important factor
for the very first demographic transition in France. Similar mechanisms may have relevance for
the development of the other elements of the macroeconomic production function.
There is also little rigorous work on the role of religion in the sustainability of long-run growth.
Some growth depends on the depletion of natural resources, which are obviously finite. Different
forms of growth will also have different implications for climate change. Religions, and
particularly religious values, may be relevant for the choices of individuals and societies in this
respect.
56
References
Abramitzky, Ran. 2008. “The Limits of Equality: Insights from the Israeli Kibbutz.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 123(3): 1111–59.
Acemoglu, Daron, Tarek A. Hassan, and James A. Robinson. 2011. “Social Structure and
Development: A Legacy of the Holocaust in Russia.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(2):
895–946.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005. “Institutions as a Fundamental
Cause of Long-Run Growth.” In: Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of
Economic Growth. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Volume 1A, Chapter 6, pp. 385–472.
Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 1998. Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
Akçomak, İ Semih, Dinand Webbink, Bas ter Weel. 2016. “Why Did the Netherlands Develop So
Early? The Legacy of the Brethren of the Common Life.” Economic Journal 126(593): 821–
60.
Alaoui, Larbi, and Alvaro Sandroni. 2018. “Predestination and the Protestant Ethic.” Journal of
the European Economic Association 16(1): 45–76.
Alesina, Alberto, Arnaud Devleeschauwer, William Easterly, Sergio Kurlat, and Romain
Wacziarg. 2003. “Fractionalization.” Journal of Economic Growth 8(2): 155–194.
Alesina, Alberto, Sebastian Hohmann, Stelios Michalopoulos, and Elias Papaioannou. 2021.
“Intergenerational Mobility in Africa.” Econometrica 89(1): 1–35.
Alesina, Alberto, Sebastian Hohmann, Stelios Michalopoulos, and Elias Papaioannou. 2023.
“Religion and Educational Mobility in Africa.” Nature 618: 134–143.
Almond, Douglas, Bhashkar Mazumder, and Reyn van Ewijk. 2015. “In Utero Ramadan Exposure
and Children’s Academic Performance.” Economic Journal 125(589): 1501–33.
Andersen, Lars Harhoff, and Jeanet Bentzen. 2022. “In the Name of God! Religiosity and the
Transition to Modern Growth.” CEPR Discussion Paper 16938.
Andersen, Thomas Barnebeck, Jeanet Bentzen, Carl-Johan Dalgaard, and Paul Sharp. 2017. “Pre-
Reformation Roots of the Protestant Ethic.” Economic Journal 127(604): 1756–93.
Anderson, Robert Warren, Noel D. Johnson, and Mark Koyama. 2017. “Jewish Persecutions and
Weather Shocks: 1100–1800.” Economic Journal 127(602): 924–58.
Andrabi, Tahir, Jishnu Das, Asim Ijaz Khwaja, and Tristan Zajonc. 2006. “Religious School
Enrollment in Pakistan: A Look at the Data.” Comparative Education Review 50(3): 446–477.
Arold, Benjamin W., Ludger Woessmann, and Larissa Zierow. 2022. “Can Schools Change
Religious Attitudes? Evidence from German State Reforms of Compulsory Religious
Education.” CESifo Working Paper 9504.
Ashraf, Quamrul H., and David N. Weil. Forthcoming. Economic Growth, 4th edition. London:
Routledge, Taylor and Francis.
Auriol, Emmanuelle, Julie Lassebie, Amma Panin, Eva Raiber, and Paul Seabright. 2020. “God
Insures those who Pay? Formal Insurance and Religious Offerings in Ghana.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 135(4): 1799–1848.
Baele, Lieven, Moazzam Farooq, and Steven Ongena. 2014. “Of Religion and Redemption:
Evidence from Default on Islamic Loans.” Journal of Banking and Finance 44: 141–159.
57
Bai, Ying, and James Kai-sing Kung. 2015. “Diffusing Knowledge while Spreading God’s
Message: Protestantism and Economic Prosperity in China, 1840–1920.” Journal of the
European Economic Association 13(4): 669–98.
Barro, Robert J., and Rachel M. McCleary. 2003. “Religion and Economic Growth across
Countries.” American Sociological Review 68(5): 760–81.
Barro, Robert J., and Rachel M. McCleary. 2005. “Which Countries Have State Religions?”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 120(4): 1331–70.
Basten, Christoph, and Frank Betz. 2013. “Beyond Work Ethic: Religion, Individual, and Political
Preferences.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 5(3): 67–91.
Bauer, Vincent, Melina R. Platas, and Jeremy M. Weinstein. 2022. “Legacies of Islamic Rule in
Africa: Colonial Responses and Contemporary Development.” World Development 152:
105750.
Baxamusa, Mufaddal, and Abu Jalal. 2016. “CEO’s Religious Affiliation and Managerial
Conservatism.” Financial Management 45(1): 67–104.
Bazzi, Samuel, Masyhur Hilmy, and Benjamin Marx. 2023. “Religion, Education, and the State.”
Working Paper.
Bazzi, Samuel, Gabriel Koehler-Derrick, and Benjamin Marx. 2020. “The Institutional
Foundations of Religious Politics: Evidence from Indonesia.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
135 (2): 845–911.
Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ouarda Merrouche. 2013. “Islamic vs. Conventional
Banking: Business Model, Efficiency and Stability.” Journal of Banking and Finance 37(2):
433–47.
Becker, Sascha O., and Francesco Cinnirella. 2020. “Prussia Disaggregated: The Demography of
its Universe of Localities in 1871.” Journal of Demographic Economics 86(3): 259–90.
Becker, Sascha O., Francesco Cinnirella, and Ludger Woessmann. 2010. “The Trade-Off between
Fertility and Education: Evidence from before the Demographic Transition.” Journal of
Economic Growth 15(3): 177–204.
Becker, Sascha O., Francesco Cinnirella, and Ludger Woessmann. 2012. “The Effect of
Investment in Children’s Education on Fertility in 1816 Prussia.” Cliometrica 6(1): 29-44.
Becker, Sascha O., Erik Hornung, and Ludger Woessmann. 2011. “Education and Catch-up in the
Industrial Revolution.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3(3): 92–126.
Becker, Sascha O. Markus Nagler, and Ludger Woessmann. 2017. “Education and Religious
Participation: City-level Evidence from Germany’s Secularization Period 1890–1930.”
Journal of Economic Growth 22: 273–311.
Becker, Sascha O., and Luigi Pascali. 2019. “Religion, Division of Labor and Conflict: Anti-
Semitism in German Regions over 600 Years.” American Economic Review 109(5): 1764–
1804.
Becker, Sascha O., Steven Pfaff, and Jared Rubin. 2016. “Causes and Consequences of the
Protestant Reformation.” Explorations in Economic History 62: 1–25.
Becker, Sascha O., Francisco Pino, and Jordi Vidal-Robert. 2021. “Freedom of the Press? Catholic
Censorship during the Counter- Reformation.” CEPR Discussion Paper 16092.
58
Becker, Sascha O., Jared Rubin, and Ludger Woessmann. 2021. “Religion in Economic History:
A Survey.” In: Alberto Bisin and Giovanni Federico (eds.), Handbook of Historical
Economics, Chapter 20. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Becker, Sascha O., and Ludger Woessmann. 2008. “Luther and the Girls: Religious Denomination
and the Female Education Gap in 19th Century Prussia.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics
110(4): 777–805.
Becker, Sascha O., and Ludger Woessmann. 2009. “Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory
of Protestant Economic History.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(2): 531–96.
Becker, Sascha O., and Ludger Woessmann. 2018. “Social Cohesion, Religious Beliefs, and the
Effect of Protestantism on Suicide.” Review of Economics and Statistics 100(3): 377–91.
Belloc, Marianna, Francesco Drago, and Roberto Galbiati. 2016. “Earthquakes, Religion, and
Transition to Self–Government in Italian Cities.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(4):
1875–1926.
Bénabou, Roland, Davide Ticchi, and Andrea Vindigni. 2022. “Forbidden Fruits: The Political
Economy of Science, Religion, and Growth.” Review of Economic Studies 89(4): 1785–1832.
Bentzen, Jeanet and Gunes Gokmen. 2023. “The Power of Religion.” Journal of Economic Growth
28(1): 45–78.
Bentzen, Jeanet and Lena Sperling. 2020. “God Politics: Religion, Attitudes, and Outcomes.”
CEPR Discussion Paper 37664.
Berman, Eli, 2000. “Sect, Subsidy, and Sacrifice: An Economist’s View of Ultra–Orthodox Jews.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3): 905–53.
Berman, Eli, and Ara Stepanyan. 2004. “How Many Radical Islamists? Indirect Evidence from
Five Countries.” Working Paper.
Bhalotra, Sonia, Irma Clots-Figueras, Guilhem Cassan, and Lakshmi Iyer. 2014. “Religion,
Politician Identity and Development Outcomes: Evidence from India.” Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization 104: 4–17.
Binzel, Christine, and Jean‐Paul Carvalho. 2017. “Education, Social Mobility and Religious
Movements: The Islamic Revival in Egypt.” Economic Journal 127(607): 2553–80.
Binzel, Christine, Andreas Link and Rajesh Ramachandran. 2023. “The Protestant Reformation
and Language Choice in the Holy Roman Empire.” CEPR Discussion Paper 17818.
Bisin, Alberto, Jared Rubin, Avner Seror, and Thierry Verdier. 2023. “Culture, Institutions, and
the Long Divergence.” Journal of Economic Growth, forthcoming.
Bisin, Alberto, and Thierry Verdier. 2000. “‘Beyond the Melting Pot’: Cultural Transmission,
Marriage, and the Evolution of Ethnic and Religious Traits.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
115(3): 955–88.
Bisin, Alberto, and Thierry Verdier. 2001. “The Economics of Cultural Transmission and the
Dynamics of Preferences.” Journal of Economic Theory 97(2): 298–319.
Blanc, Guillaume. 2023. “The Cultural Origins of the Demographic Transition in France.”
Working Paper.
Blaydes, Lisa, and Eric Chaney. 2013. “The Feudal Revolution and Europe’s Rise: Political
Divergence of the Christian West and the Muslim World before 1500 CE.” American Political
Science Review 107(1): 16–34.
59
Blaydes, Lisa, Justin Grimmer, and Alison McQueen. 2018. “Mirrors for Princes and Sultans:
Advice on the Art of Governance in the Medieval Christian and Islamic Worlds.” Journal of
Politics 80(4): 1150–67.
Boppart, Timo, Josef Falkinger, and Volker Grossmann. 2014. “Protestantism and Education:
Reading (the Bible) and other Skills.” Economic Inquiry 52(2): 874–95.
Boppart, Timo, Josef Falkinger, Volker Grossmann, Ulrich Woitek, and Gabriela Wüthrich. 2013.
“Under Which Conditions Does Religion Affect Educational Outcomes?” Explorations in
Economic History 50(2): 242–66.
Botticini, Maristella, and Zvi Eckstein. 2005. “Jewish Occupational Selection: Education,
Restrictions, or Minorities?” Journal of Economic History 65(4): 922–48.
Botticini, Maristella, and Zvi Eckstein. 2007. “From Farmers to Merchants, Conversions and
Diaspora: Human Capital and Jewish History.” Journal of the European Economic Association
5(5): 885–926.
Botticini, Maristella, Zvi Eckstein, and Anat Vaturi. 2019. “Child Care and Human Development:
Insights from Jewish History in Central and Eastern Europe, 1500–1930.” Economic Journal
129(623): 2637–90.
Buringh, Eltjo, and Jan Luiten van Zanden. 2009. “Charting the “Rise of the West”: Manuscripts
and Printed Books in Europe, a Long-term Perspective from the Sixth through Eighteenth
Centuries.” Journal of Economic History 69(2): 409–45.
Butinda, Lewis Dunia, Aimable Amani Lameke, Nathan Nunn, Max Posch, and Raul Sanchez de
la Sierra. 2023. “On the Importance of African Traditional Religion for Economic Behavior.”
NBER Working Paper 31430.
Cagé, Julia, and Valeria Rueda. 2016. “The Long-Term Effects of the Printing Press in sub-
Saharan Africa.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 8(3): 69–99.
Cagé, Julia, and Valeria Rueda. 2020. “Sex and the Mission: The Conflicting Effects of Early
Christian Missions on HIV in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Journal of Demographic Economics 86(3):
213–257.
Calvi, Rossella, Lauren Hoehn-Velasco, and Federico G. Mantovanelli. 2022. “The Protestant
Legacy: Missions, Gender, and Human Capital in India.” Journal of Human Resources 57(6):
1946-1980.
Campante, Filipe, and David Yanagizawa-Drott. 2015. “Does Religion Affect Economic Growth
and Happiness? Evidence from Ramadan.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 130(2): 615–58.
Cantoni, Davide. 2015. “The Economic Effects of the Protestant Reformation: Testing the Weber
Hypothesis in the German Lands.” Journal of the European Economic Association 13(4): 561–
98.
Cantoni, Davide, Jeremiah Dittmar, and Noam Yuchtman. 2018. “Religious Competition and
Reallocation: The Political Economy of Secularization in the Protestant Reformation.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 133(4): 2037–96.
Carvalho, Jean-Paul and Mark Koyama. 2016. “Jewish Emancipation and Schism: Economic
Development and Religious Change.” Journal of Comparative Economics 44(3): 562–84.
Carvalho, Jean-Paul, Mark Koyama, and Michael Sacks. 2017. “Education, Identity and
Community: Lessons from Jewish Emancipation.” Public Choice 171(1): 119–43.
60
Castelló-Climent, Amparo, Latika Chaudhary, and Abhiroop Mukhopadhyay. 2018. “Higher
Education and Prosperity: From Catholic Missionaries to Luminosity in India.” Economic
Journal 128(616): 3039–75.
Cavalcanti, Tiago, Sriya Iyer, Christopher Rauh, Christian Roerig, and Maryam Vaziri. 2022. “A
City of God: Afterlife Beliefs and Job Support in Brazil.” CEPR Discussion Paper 17719.
Cesur, Resul, and Naci Mocan. 2018. “Education, Religion, and Voter Preference in a Muslim
Country.” Journal of Population Economics 31(1): 1–44.
Chaney, Eric. 2013. “Revolt on the Nile: Economic Shocks, Religion, and Political Power.”
Econometrica 81(5): 2033–53.
Chaney, Eric. 2023. “Religion and the Rise and Fall of Islamic Science.” Working Paper.
Chaudhary, Latika, and Jared Rubin. 2011. “Reading, Writing, and Religion: Institutions and
Human Capital Formation.” Journal of Comparative Economics 39(1): 17–33.
Chaudhary, Latika, and Jared Rubin. 2016. “Religious Identity and the Provision of Public Goods:
Evidence from the Indian Princely States.” Journal of Comparative Economics 44(3): 461–83.
Chen, Ting, James Kai-sing Kung, and Chicheng Ma. 2020. “Long Live Keju! The Persistent
Effects of China’s Civil Examination System.” Economic Journal 130(631): 2030–2064.
Chen, Zhiwu, Chicheng Ma, and Andrew Sinclair. 2022. “Banking on the Confucian Clan: Why
China Developed Financial Markets So Late?” Economic Journal 132(644): 1378–1413.
Chiswick, Carmel. 2014. Judaism in Transition: How Economic Choices Shape Religious
Tradition. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Cinnirella, Francesco and Jochen Streb. 2018. “Religious Tolerance as Engine of Innovation.”
CESifo Working Paper 6797.
Ciscato, Edoardo, Quoc-Anh Do, and Kieu-Trang Nguyen. 2023. “Astrology and Matrimony:
Social Reinforcement of Religious Beliefs on Marriage Matching in Vietnam.” Working Paper.
Corekcioglu, Gozde. 2021. “Unveiling the Effects of a Headscarf Ban: Evidence from Municipal
Jobs in Turkey.” Journal of Comparative Economics 49(2): 382–404.
Coşgel, Metin M., and Boğac Ergene. 2014. “Dispute Resolution in Ottoman Courts: A
Quantitative Analysis of Litigations in Eighteenth Century Kastamonu.” Social Science
History 38(1&2): 183–202.
Coşgel, Metin M., Matthew Histen, Thomas J. Miceli, Sadullah Yıldırım. 2018. “State and
Religion over Time.” Journal of Comparative Economics 46(1): 20–34.
Coşgel, Metin M. and Thomas J. Miceli. 2009. “State and Religion.” Journal of Comparative
Economics 37: 402–416.
Coşgel, Metin M., Thomas J. Miceli, and Jared Rubin. 2012. “The Political Economy of Mass
Printing: Legitimacy, Revolt, and Technology Change in the Ottoman Empire.” Journal of
Comparative Economics 40(3): 357–71.
D’Acunto, Francesco, Marcel Prokopczuk, and Michael Weber. 2019. “Historical Antisemitism,
Ethnic Specialization, and Financial Development.” Review of Economic Studies 86(3): 1170–
1206.
Davids, Karel. 2013. Religion, Technology, and the Great and Little Divergences: China and
Europe Compared, C. 700–1800, vol. 32. Leiden: Brill.
61
De Roover, Raymond. 1963. The Rise and Decline of the Medici Bank: 1397–1494. New York:
W.W. Norton.
Dittmar, Jeremiah, and Ralf Meisenzahl. 2020. “Public Goods Institutions, Human Capital, and
Growth: Evidence from German History.” Review of Economic Studies 87(2): 959–96.
Dong, Baomin, and Yu Zhang. 2023. “Confucianism and Science.” Explorations in Economic
History: 101517.
Durkheim, Émile. 1897. Le suicide: étude de sociologie. Paris: Félix Alcan. (Suicide: A Study in
Sociology, trans. John A. Spaulding and George Simpson. Glencoe, The Free Press, 1951.)
Durlauf, Steven N., Andros Kourtellos, and Chih Ming Tan. 2012. “Is God in the Details? A
Reexamination of the Role of Religion in Economic Growth.” Journal of Applied
Econometrics 27(7): 1059–75.
Easterlin, Richard A. 1981. “Why Isn’t the Whole World Developed?” Journal of Economic
History 41(1): 1–19.
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 1997. “Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic
Divisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1203–50.
Fletcher, Jason, and Sanjeev Kumar. 2014. “Religion and Risky Health Behaviors among U.S.
Adolescents and Adults.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 104 (C): 123–140.
Fox, Jonathan, and Deborah Flores. 2009. “Religions, Constitutions, and the State: A Cross–
National Study.” Journal of Politics 71(4): 1499–1513.
Fruehwirth, Jane, Sriya Iyer, and Anwen Zhang. 2019. “Religion and Depression in Adolescence.”
Journal of Political Economy 127 (3): 1178–1209.
Gallego, Francisco A., and Robert Woodberry. 2010. “Christian Missionaries and Education in
Former African Colonies: How Competition Mattered.” Journal of African Economics 19(3):
294–329.
Galor, Oded. 2011. Unified Growth Theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Gaskins, Ben, Matt Golder, and David A. Siegel. 2013. “Religious Participation and Economic
Conservatism.” American Journal of Political Science 57(4): 823–40.
Gershman, Boris. 2016. “Witchcraft Beliefs and the Erosion of Social Capital: Evidence from Sub-
Saharan Africa and Beyond.” Journal of Development Economics 120: 182–208.
Gershman, Boris. 2022. “Witchcraft Beliefs Around the World: An Exploratory Analysis.” PLoS
ONE 17(11): e0276872.
Gill, Anthony. 1998. Rendering Unto Caesar: The Catholic Church and the State in Latin
America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Greif, Avner, and Jared Rubin. 2023. “Endogenous Political Legitimacy: The Tudor Roots of
England’s Constitutional Governance.” ESI Working Paper 23-01.
Grewal, Sharan, Amaney A. Jamal, Tarek Masoud, and Elizabeth R. Nugent. 2019. “Poverty and
Divine Rewards: The Electoral Advantage of Islamist Political Parties.” American Journal of
Political Science 63(4): 859–74.
Grosfeld, Irena, Seyhun Orcan Sakalli, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya. 2020. “Middleman Minorities
and Ethnic Violence: Anti-Jewish Pogroms in the Russian Empire.” Review of Economic
Studies 87(1): 289–342.
62
Grosjean, Pauline. 2011. “Long Term Institutional Persistence: Ottoman Rule and Financial
Development in the Regions of Europe.” Journal of Comparative Economics 39: 1–16.
Gruber, Jonathan, and Daniel M. Hungerman. 2008. “The Church Versus the Mall: What Happens
When Religion Faces Increased Secular Competition?” Quarterly Journal of Economics
123(2): 831–862.
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2020. “Beyond War and Contracts: The Medieval and Religious Roots of
the European State.” Annual Review of Political Science 23: 19–36.
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2023. Sacred Foundations: The Religious and Medieval Roots of the
European State. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2003. “People’s Opium? Religion and Economic
Attitudes.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50: 225–282.
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2004. “Does Local Financial Development
Matter?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(3): 929–969.
Gulesci, Selim, and Erik Meyersson. 2015. “`For the Love of the Republic’: Education,
Secularism, and Empowerment.” Working Paper.
Hall, Robert E., and Charles I. Jones. 1999. “Why do Some Countries Produce So Much More
Output Per Worker than Others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83–116.
Hassan, M. Kabir, and Sirajo Aliyu. 2018. “A Contemporary Survey of Islamic Banking
Literature.” Journal of Financial Stability 34: 12–43.
Henrich, Joseph. 2020. The WEIRDest People in the World: How the West Became
Psychologically Peculiar and Particularly Prosperous. New York: Farrar, Strauss, and
Giroux.
Herzer, Dierk, and Holger Strulik (2020). “Religiosity and Long-Run Productivity Growth.”
Journal of Economics, Management and Religion 1 (1): 2050001.
Hoff, Karla, Mayuresh Kshetramade, and Ernst Fehr. 2011. “Caste and Punishment: The Legacy
of Caste Culture in Norm Enforcement.” Economic Journal 121(556): F449–75.
Hornung, Erik. 2014. “Immigration and the Diffusion of Technology: The Huguenot Diaspora in
Prussia.” American Economic Review 104(1): 84–122.
Hornung, Erik. 2019. “Diasporas, Diversity, and Economic Activity: Evidence from 18th-century
Berlin.” Explorations in Economic History 73: 101261.
Hornung, Erik, Guido Schwerdt, and Maurizio Strazzeri. 2023. “Religious Practice and Student
Performance: Evidence from Ramadan Fasting.” Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization 205: 100–119.
Huber, John D., and Piero Stanig. 2011. “Church-state Separation and Redistribution.” Journal of
Public Economics 95(7-8): 828–836.
Huff, Toby E. 2017. The Rise of Early Modern Science: Islam, China, and the West. 3rd Edition.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Iannaccone, Laurence R. 1992. “Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in Cults, Communes,
and Other Collectives.” Journal of Political Economy 100(2): 271–91.
Iannaccone, Laurence R. 1998. “Introduction to the Economics of Religion.” Journal of Economic
Literature 36(3): 1465–95.
63
Imam, Patrick, and Kangni Kpodar. 2016. “Islamic Banking: Good for Growth?” Economic
Modelling 59: 387–401.
Imber, Colin. 1997. Ebu’s-su’ud: The Islamic Legal Tradition. Stanford: Stanford University
Press.
Iyer, Sriya. 2002. Demography and Religion in India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Iyer, Sriya. 2016. “The New Economics of Religion.” Journal of Economic Literature 54(2): 395–
441.
Iyer, Sriya. 2018. The Economics of Religion in India. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Iyigun, Murat, Jared Rubin, and Avner Seror. 2021. “A Theory of Cultural Revivals.” European
Economic Review 135: 103734.
Jedwab, Remi, Felix Meier zu Selhausen and Alexander Moradi. 2022. “The Economics of
Missionary Expansion: Evidence from Africa and Implications for Development.” Journal of
Economic Growth 27(2): 149–192.
Jha, Saumitra. 2013. “Trade, Institutions, and Ethnic Tolerance: Evidence from South Asia.”
American Political Science Review 107(4): 806–32.
Johnes, Jill, Marwan Izzeldin, and Vasileios Pappas. 2014. “A Comparison of Performance of
Islamic and Conventional Banks 2004–2009.” Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization 103: S93–S107.
Johnson, Noel D., and Mark Koyama. 2017. “Jewish Communities and City Growth in
Preindustrial Europe.” Journal of Development Economics 127: 339–354.
Johnson, Noel D., and Mark Koyama. 2019. Persecution and Toleration: The Long Road to
Religious Freedom. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Jones, Charles I. 2016. “The Facts of Economic Growth.” In: John B. Taylor and Harald Uhlig
(eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Volume 2A, Chapter 1, pp. 3–69.
Jones, Charles I. 2022. “The End of Economic Growth? Unintended Consequences of a Declining
Population.” American Economic Review 112(11): 3489–3527.
Juif, Dácil, Joerg Baten, and Mari Carmen Pérez-Artés. 2020. “Numeracy of Religious Minorities
in Spain and Portugal during the Inquisition Era.” Revista de Historia Economica – Journal of
Iberian and Latin American Economic History 38(1): 147–184.
Kersting, Felix, Iris Wohnsiedler, and Nikolaus Wolf. 2020. “Weber Revisited: The Protestant
Ethic and the Spirit of Nationalism.” Journal of Economic History 80(3): 710-745.
Khan, Feisal. 2010. “How ‘Islamic’ is Islamic Banking?” Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization 76(3): 805–820.
Khediri, Karim Ben, Lanouar Charfeddine, and Slah Ben Youssef. 2015. “Islamic Versus
Conventional Banks in the GCC Countries: A Comparative Study using Classification
Techniques.” Research in International Business and Finance 33: 75–98.
King, Robert G., and Ross Levine. 1993. “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might be Right.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3): 717–737.
Ko, Chiu Yu, Mark Koyama, and Tuan‐Hwee Sng. 2018. “Unified China and Divided Europe.”
International Economic Review 59(1): 285–327.
Koenig, Harold G. 2012. “Religion, Spirituality, and Health: The Research and Clinical
Implications.” ISRN Psychiatry, Article ID 278730.
64
Koyama, Mark, and Jared Rubin. 2022. How the World Became Rich: The Historical Origins of
Economic Growth. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Kuran, Timur. 2001. “The Provision of Public Goods under Islamic Law: Origins, Impact, and
Limitations of the Waqf System.” Law and Society Review 35(4): 841–897.
Kuran, Timur. 2004a. Islam and Mammon: The Economic Predicaments of Islamism. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Kuran, Timur. 2004b. “The Economic Ascent of the Middle East’s Religious Minorities: The Role
of Islamic Legal Pluralism.” Journal of Legal Studies 33: 475–515.
Kuran, Timur. 2005. “The Absence of the Corporation in Islamic Law: Origins and Persistence.”
American Journal of Comparative Law 53: 785–834.
Kuran, Timur. 2011. The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Kuran, Timur. 2018. “Islam and Economic Performance: Historical and Contemporary Links.”
Journal of Economic Literature 56(4): 1292–1359.
Kuran, Timur, and Scott Lustig. 2012. “Judicial Biases in Ottoman Istanbul: Islamic Justice and
its Compatibility with Modern Economic Life.” Journal of Law and Economics 55(3): 631–
66.
Kuran, Timur, and Jared Rubin. 2018. “The Financial Power of the Powerless: Socio-Economic
Status and Interest Rates under Partial Rule of Law.” Economic Journal 128(609): 758–796.
Kuznets, Simon. 1966. Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure, and Spread, New Haven: Yale
University Press.
Landes, David S. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So
Poor. New York: W.W. Norton.
Lankina, Tomila, and Lullit Getachew. 2012. “Mission or Empire, Word or Sword? The Human
Capital Legacy in Postcolonial Democratic Development.” American Journal of Political
Science 56(2): 465-483.
Lecce, Giampaolo, Laura Ogliari, and Mara P. Squicciarini. 2021. “Birth and Migration of
Scientists: Does Religiosity Matter? Evidence from 19th-Century France.” Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization 187: 274–289.
Le Rossignol, Etienne, Sara Lowes, and Nathan Nunn. 2022. “Traditional Supernatural Beliefs
and Prosocial Behavior.” NBER Working Paper 29695.
Liang, Ming-Yih. 2010. “Confucianism and the East Asian Miracle.” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 2(3): 206–234.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 22(1): 3–42.
Ma, Chicheng. 2021. “Knowledge Diffusion and Intellectual Change: When Chinese Literati Met
European Jesuits.” Journal of Economic History 81(4): 1052–1097.
Majid, Muhammad Farhan. 2015. “The Persistent Effects of in utero Nutrition Shocks over the
Life Cycle: Evidence from Ramadan Fasting.” Journal of Development Economics 117: 48–
57.
Mandaville, Jon E. 1979. “Usurious Piety: The Cash Waqf Controversy in the Ottoman Empire.”
International Journal of Middle East Studies 10(3): 289–308.
65
Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of
Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2): 407-437.
Mary, Winifred. 1953. “The Mediaeval Scribe.” Classical Journal 48(6): 207–214.
McCleary, Rachel M., and Robert J. Barro. 2019. The Wealth of Religions: The Political Economy
of Believing and Belonging. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
McKenzie, Brian D., and Stella M. Rouse. 2013. “Shades of Faith: Religious Foundations of
Political Attitudes among African Americans, Latinos, and Whites.” American Journal of
Political Science 57(1): 218–35.
Menon, Nidhiya, and Kathleen McQueeney. 2020. “Christianity and Girl Child Health in India.”
World Development 136: 105109.
Michalopoulos, Stelios, Alireza Naghavi, and Giovanni Prarolo. 2016. “Islam, Inequality and Pre-
industrial Comparative Development.” Journal of Development Economics 120: 86–98.
Migne, Jacques Paul. 1855. Patrologiae. Cursus Completus, Vol. 205. Paris: Imprimerie
Catholique de Migne.
Miguel, Edward. 2005. “Poverty and Witch Killing.” Review of Economic Studies 72(4): 1153–
1172.
Miho, Antonela, Alexandra Jarotschkin, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya. 2023. “Diffusion of Gender
Norms: Evidence from Stalin’s Ethnic Deportations.” Journal of the European Economic
Association, forthcoming.
Mitch, David. 1999. “The Role of Education and Skill in the British Industrial Revolution.” In:
Joel Mokyr (ed.), The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective. Boulder:
Westview. 2nd ed., pp. 241-79.
Mitra, Anirban, and Debraj Ray. 2014. “Implications of an Economic Theory of Conflict: Hindu–
Muslim Violence in India.” Journal of Political Economy 122(4): 719–65.
Mollah, Sabur, M. Kabir Hassan, Omar Al Farooque, and Asma Mobarek. 2017. “The Governance,
Risk-taking, and Performance of Islamic Banks.” Journal of Financial Services Research
51(2): 195–219.
Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 2009. The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700-1850. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 2011. “The Economics of Being Jewish.” Critical Review 23(1-2): 195–206.
Mokyr, Joel. 2016. A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Montalvo, Jose G., and Marta Reynal-Querol. 2003. “Religious Polarization and Economic
Development.” Economics Letters 80(2): 201–210.
Montero, Eduardo, and Dean Yang. 2022. “Religious Festivals and Economic Development:
Evidence from the Timing of Mexican Saint Day Festivals.” American Economic Review
112(10): 3176–3214.
66
Moser, Petra, Alessandra Voena, and Fabian Waldinger. 2014. “German Jewish Émigrés and US
Invention.” American Economic Review 104(10): 3222–55.
Naghavi, Alireza. 2019. “Islam, Trade, and Innovation.” In: Jean-Paul Carvalho, Sriya Iyer, and
Jared Rubin (eds.), Advances in the Economics of Religion. New York: Palgrave Macmillan,
pp. 449–460.
Nelson, Richard R., and Edmund Phelps. 1966. “Investment in Humans, Technology Diffusion
and Economic Growth.” American Economic Review 56(2): 69–75.
Noonan, John T. 1957. The Scholastic Analysis of Usury. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Oster, Emily. 2004. “Witchcraft, Weather and Economic Growth in Renaissance Europe.” Journal
of Economic Perspectives 18(1): 215–228.
Pascali, Luigi. 2016. “Banks and Development: Jewish Communities in the Italian Renaissance
and Current Economic Performance.” Review of Economics and Statistics 98(1): 140–58.
Pew Research Center. 2016. “Religion and Education Around the World.”
Popova, Olga. 2014. “Can Religion Insure against Aggregate Shocks to Happiness? The Case of
Transition Countries.” Journal of Comparative Economics 42(3): 804–818.
Rahman, Fazlur. 1964. “Ribā and Interest.” Islamic Studies 3: 1–43.
Ramirez, Francisco O., and John Boli. 1987. “The Political Construction of Mass Schooling:
European Origins and Worldwide Institutionalization.” Sociology of Education 60(1): 2–17.
Romer, David. 2019. Advanced Macroeconomics. Fifth edition. McGraw-Hill.
Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98(5):
S71-S102.
Rubin, Jared. 2009. “Social Insurance, Commitment, and the Origin of Law: Interest Bans in Early
Christianity.” Journal of Law and Economics 52(4): 761–777.
Rubin, Jared. 2010. “Bills of Exchange, Interest Bans, and Impersonal Exchange in Islam and
Christianity.” Explorations in Economic History 47(2): 213–227.
Rubin, Jared. 2011. “Institutions, the Rise of Commerce, and the Persistence of Laws: Interest
Restrictions in Islam and Christianity.” Economic Journal 121(557): 1310–1339.
Rubin, Jared. 2014. “Printing and Protestants: An Empirical Test of the Role of Printing in the
Reformation.” Review of Economics and Statistics 96(2): 270–286.
Rubin, Jared. 2017. Rulers, Religion, and Riches: Why the West Got Rich and the Middle East did
Not. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Rupp, Horst F. 1996. “Philipp Melanchthon (1497–1560).” Prospects 26(3): 611–621.
Sakalli, Seyhun Orcan. 2019. “Secularization and Religious Backlash: Evidence from Turkey.”
Working Paper.
Saleh, Mohamed. 2015. “The Reluctant Transformation: State Industrialization, Religion, and
Human Capital in Nineteenth-Century Egypt.” Journal of Economic History 75(1): 65–94.
Scheidel, Walter. 2019. Escape from Rome: The Failure of Empire and the Road to Prosperity.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Schulz, Jonathan F. 2022. “Kin Networks and Institutional Development.” Economic Journal
132(647): 2578–2613.
67
Schulz, Jonathan F., Duman Bahrami-Rad, Jonathan P. Beauchamp, and Joseph Henrich. 2019.
“The Church, Intensive Kinship, and Global Psychological Variation.” Science 366(6466).
Seabright, Paul. 2024. The Divine Economy: How Religions Compete for Wealth, Power, and
People. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Seror, Avner. 2018. “A Theory on the Evolution of Religious Norms and Economic Prohibition.”
Journal of Development Economics 134: 416–427.
Sharabi, Moshe. 2017. “Work Ethic among Jews and Muslims: The Effect of Religiosity Degree
and Demographic Factors.” Sociological Perspectives 60(2): 251–268.
Smith, Adam 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: W.
Strahan.
Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 70(1): 65–94.
Spenkuch, Jörg L. 2017. “Religion and Work: Micro Evidence from Contemporary Germany.”
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 135: 193–214.
Spolaore, Enrico, and Romain Wacziarg. 2013. “How Deep Are the Roots of Economic
Development?” Journal of Economic Literature 51(2): 325–69.
Squicciarini, Mara. 2020. “Devotion and Development: Religiosity, Education, and Economic
Progress in 19th-Century France.” American Economic Review 110(11): 3454–3491.
Stegmueller, Daniel. 2013. “Religion and Redistributive Voting in Western Europe.” Journal of
Politics 75(4): 1064–76.
Strulik, Holger. 2016. “Secularization and Long‐Run Economic Growth.” Economic Inquiry
54(1): 177–200.
Swan, Trevor W. 1956. “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation.” Economic Record 32(2):
334–361.
Talbani, Aziz. 1996. “Pedagogy, Power, and Discourse: Transformation of Islamic Education.”
Comparative Education Review 40(1): 66–82.
Temple, Jonathan. 1999. “The New Growth Evidence.” Journal of Economic Literature 37(1):
112–156.
Ticku, Rohit, Anand Shrivastava, and Sriya Iyer. 2023. “Economic Shocks and Religious Conflict
in Medieval India.” CEPR Discussion Paper 17986.
Valencia Caicedo, Felipe. 2019. “The Mission: Human Capital Transmission, Economic
Persistence, and Culture in South America.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 134(1): 507–
556.
Voigtländer, Nico, and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2012. “Persecution Perpetuated: The Medieval
Origins of Anti-Semitic Violence in Nazi Germany.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(3):
1339–92.
Waldinger, Fabian. 2010. “Quality Matters: The Expulsion of Professors and the Consequences
for PhD Student Outcomes in Nazi Germany.” Journal of Political Economy 118(4): 787-831.
Waldinger, Fabian. 2016. “Bombs, Brains, and Science: The Role of Human and Physical Capital
for the Creation of Scientific Knowledge.” Review of Economics and Statistics 98(5): 811-831.
Waldinger, Maria. 2017. “The Long-Run Effects of Missionary Orders in Mexico.” Journal of
Development Economics 127: 355-378.
68
Walker, Sarah. 2020. “Historical Legacies in Savings: Evidence from Romania.” Journal of
Comparative Economics 48(1): 76–99.
Wantchekon, Leonard, Natalija Novta, and Marko Klašnja. 2015. “Education and Human Capital
Externalities: Evidence from Colonial Benin.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 130(2): 703–
757.
Weber, Max. 1904/05. “Die protestantische Ethik und der „Geist“ des Kapitalismus.” Archiv für
Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 20: 1-54 and 21: 1-110. Reprinted in: Gesammelte Auf-
sätze zur Religionssoziologie, 1920: 17-206. [English translation: The Protestant Ethic and the
Spirit of Capitalism, translated by Talcott Parsons, 1930/2001, London: Routledge Classics.]
Weil, David N. 2014. “Health and Economic Growth.” In: Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf
(eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Volume 2B, Chapter 3, pp. 623–
682.
West, Martin R., and Ludger Woessmann. 2010. “‘Every Catholic Child in a Catholic School’:
Historical Resistance to State Schooling, Contemporary Private Competition and Student
Achievement across Countries.” Economic Journal 120(546): F229–255.
69