219 - The Richebacher Letter - July 1991, Nobody To Finance The U.S. Recovery
219 - The Richebacher Letter - July 1991, Nobody To Finance The U.S. Recovery
KURT RICHEBACHER
EngUsh Correspondents: Frankfurt
) Hahn Capital Partners IRe.
CANADA
GERMANY
As amatter of fact, the intensity and length of a crisis depend largely on the resistance which the
banking structure is or is not able to otTer. An illiquid structure leads to a crash which a liquid
one not only avoids for itself, but may actually soften for the rest of the community, by being able
to 'come to the rescue'."
HIGHLIGHTS
In trying to assess the future 'course of the U.S. currency it is essential to distinguish between
two,
sometimes highly-divergent, sets of forces: long-term secular developments and medium-term
cyclical fluctuations around the secular trend.
In our view, it's all too obvious that the U.S. dollar is in a long-term
downtrend. The decline,
though, has taken place in waves that are clearly linked to the ups
-) cycle.
and downs of the U.S. business
Again we see shades of 1989 only with one little difference: The same economists who didn't see
any recession approaching in 1989-90, now claim that the U.S. downturn is already over.
Irrespective of the odd statisticalup-tick, our view about the U.S. economy's u.nderlying
weakness
remains unchanged. Every single fundamental monetary, financial and economic indicator speaks
against any possibility of a sustained, strong, re_covery from recession.
The great theme that-has served to boost the dollar is scaremongering about Germany excessive -
unification costs and associated fiscal and monetary- policies are supposed to drag down the
German economy and extolling a certain U.S. rebound. We have come across many silly
-
The credit crunch in the U.s. has turned into a credit deadlock. Bank credit growth, including
bank investments, has been virtually zero.
What, then, is driving the stock market? It definitely isn't excess liquidity in the monetary
sense,
as so many Wall Street gurus like to assert.
)
The chronic compression of profit margins in the U.S. suggests that
any recovery might quickly
run into rising inflation as businesses try to improve their profit margins.
2
Viewing the television screens showing rolling Yugoslavian tanks and reading the bullish reports
about the U.S. economy and the dollar, somehow it all appeared so familiar. Suddenly, it struck us.
Heck, it's June-July 1989 all over again bristling tanks and bustling dollar euphoria.
. . .
guns and
. .
giddiness.
Almost exactly to the day two years ago the end of June 1989
-
A shipowner there had invited us to discuss the currency situation. The U.S. dollar was soaring then
against the D-mark just as today. He had bought a ship payable in dollars and didn't know whether
Late in the evening, watching the television newscast, we saw tanks rolling through the streets, just
as today. However, it was nowhere near the German border, but far away in Tiananmen Square,
Bejing.. Nevertheless, the "infant lemmings" an expression borrowed from Mr.. Denis Healey,
-
meaning the young men who dominate currency trading nowadays revelled in their usual "safe
-
haven" catch-phrase, pushing the dollar toward DM 2.00 just as today. Highly bullish forecasts
targeting.DM 2.40 and 180 Yen were rampant until September 1989, just before the dollar's descent
started.
Apart from the ubiquitous IIsafe haven" standby, a number of other slogans contributed to the mid-
1989.dollar surge: a soft landing add resilient U.S. econonúc growth, an improving U.S. trade
b~ance, the expectation of a permanently tighter U.S. monetary policy relative to that of the \
Bundesbank and the Bank of Japan, falling U.S. inflation and last but not least how could we
~ )
forget -
the PPP mantra (Purchasing Power Parity). A typical headline of September 1989 read as
follows: The Dollar Powering its Way to Purchasing Parity.
As always, dollar bullishness was a reflection of the optimism on the U.S. economy; its improving
fundamentals versus underlying bearishness about economic growth and inflation in Europe.
After the wild currency gyrations of June-September, during which the dollar briefly hit a peak of
DM 2.04 despite heavy U.S. and Japanese interventions, it swiftly sagged toward DM 1..70 by year-
end 1989. What followed was a grinding decline to OM 1.44 by early February this year.
What was it that so thoroughly deflated he dollar's heady steam of mid-1989? Simply, all the
assumptions underlying the move proved to be glaringly wrong. fu reality, the U.S. economy was
weakening not strengthening
-
easing by the Fed.. Europe, on the other hand, was on the verge of a boom in tandem with a
progressive monetary tightening. Instead of rising to the expected DM 2.40, these two sets of forces
acted together to push the dollar to a new post-war low of DM 1.44. Again, the predominating rule
of currency markets prevailed: namely, that the dollar falls when the U.S. economy weakens relative
to Europe.
We thought it'd be instructive to recall that episode of 1989 simply because the arguments fuelling
the new "bull run" of the dollar this year are almost a carbon copy. There is only one little
)
Currencies and Credit Markets \ July 1991
3
~
,) difference: The same economists who didn't see any recession approaching in 1989-90, now claim
that the downturn is already ave'r. Besides, they assert," the recession, though short and shallow, did
have wonderful curative effects for the U.S. economy, particularly for inflation, as well as the trade
deficit and the U.S. dollar.
In trying to assess the future course of the U.S. currency it is essential to distinguish between two,
sometimes highly-divergent, sets of forces: long-term secular developments and medium-term cyclical
fluctuations around the secular trend.
I
In our view, it's all too obvious that the U.S. dollar is in a long-term downtrend. The decline,
J though, has taken place in waves that are clearly linked with the U.S. business cycle. often We have
l explained that the dollar tends to be strong when the U.S. economy pulls out of recession ahead of
I Continental Europe, especially so when accompanied by a fmn monetary policy. Conversely, the
~. dollar has always weakened during u.s. business-cycle downswings.
I Looking at the long-run fluctuations of the dollar, the dollar made new lows against the D-mark every
successive cycle both declining highs and lower lows. The low in the late 1970s was marked at
-
~ The downward tendency of the dollar has probably been greatly understated considering that it always
Î)
~
,~
~
garneredmassive central bank support during its critical phases. The extent 9f this support can be
measured by the increase in dollar reserves held by foreign central banks with the Federal Reserve.
Between the end of 1985 and early 1991 foreign-held reserves rose from $121 billion to $286 billion.
Just how low would the dollar be without the benefit of the central banks' safety net?
During the dollar's surge of 1989, it was widely argued that superior prospects for U.S. inflation and
trade balances particular, relative to Japan and Germany
-
A substantial improvement in U.S. trade has occurred, but the inflation petformance has turned out
to be a great disappointment. Even while the U.S. economy has progressively weakened since 1988,
the inflation rate has persistently risen.
. . . ABOUT INFLATION
More recently, both the u.s. trade and inflation pictures have improved more markedly while
Germany, on the other hand, shows rising inflation -
possibly rea~hing or exceeding 4% coupled-
~\
view. The salient point is that these economists misrepresent the time-limited effects of plain cyclical }
influences as new sustainable long-term trends.
Apparently, we are not alone in observing this deception as the following quote from Samuel Brittan
in the Financial Times of London reveals: "There is indeed more than a 50-50 chance that for a few
months from this autumn, headline German inflation rates may exceed headline British rates. One
cringes in advance at the way in which the more partisan British tabloids will celebrate. But this
completely artificial crossover.will reflect nothing more than the different cyclical
positions of the two
economies, plus the deficiencies of the British Retail Price Index, which produce wild gyrations
around the underlying inflation rate."
By all appearances, U.S. inflation is stuck around 5%. That's the highest level since 1982, showing
aslow but steady uptrend ever since 1986.
In our view, despite the almost unanimous optimism over U.S. inflation prospects, there is at least
one compelling reason for pessimism: that is the savage compression of corporate profit margins
from a peak of 7% in 1985 to barely 3.5% recently. That profit squeeze, by the way, 'well predates
the start of recession. Quoting Keynes: "Cheapness which means the ruin of the producer is one of
the greatest economic disasters which
can possibly occur."
The chronic compression of profit margins in the U.S. suggests that any recovery might quickly ron
into rising inflation as businesses try to improve their profit margins.
The bottom line is that domestic demand growth in Europe and Japan has outstripped U.S. domestic
demand growth ever since 1987. During 1988 to 1990, domestic demand for all industrial countries
overall (excluding the U.S.) increase4 by 13% against only 5.5% for the United States. More
recently, the greatest contrast is between
Germany where domestic demand growth has accelerated
to 5% and higher while U.S. domestic demand has been shrinking at an annual rate of 5%.
As a
matter of fact, it is
rather scary to think that both the United States and Britain still have
substantial trade deficits in the depth of recession. Recession is not a lasting substitute for lacking
competitiveness.
COMPETITIVENESS IN PERSPECTIVE
One glance at Table I on the next page puts the international competitiveness debate into sharp focus.
It shows the cumulative move of prices, wage rates, productivity and unit labour costs for Britain,
)
Currencies and Credit Markets \ July 1991
5
() Germany
Purchasing
and the
Power Parity, pales
last five years. The pet theory obsessing Anglo-Saxon economists,
u.s. during the
when one puts these sharply diverging performances into perspective.
Is that too harsh of an assessment? Just for fun, can you recall the comments several years back
when the United States and Britain had soaring trade deficits and Germany was sporting a soaring
surplus? The media and analysts then extolled these deficits as virtuous emblems of economic
dynamism while German surpluses were decried as the sorry symptom of "euro-sclerosistl. The
conclusion, of course, was the same as now: the dollar and the pound should therefore be strong and
the D-mark should be weak.
)
/
Many Wall Street and City of London economists operate with two different sets of economic
theorems one for their own economies and another one for non-English-speaking countries. As
-
long as inflation accelerated in Britain and the United States, this was interpreted as being bullish for
their two respective curr~ncies on the ~sumption that it would necessitate higher interest rates. Now,
as inflation rises in Germany, another set of economics applies, of course, supporting a bearish stance
on the D-mark.
One of the worst aspects of the U.S. economic develop'ment, no doubt, is the collapse of net fixed
capital investment in manufacturing. For good reasons, Wall Street has treated this severe problem
just like any other with silence. But to our boundless astonishment, we have now learned from an
-
article by the chief economist of Morgan Stanley, Stephen Roach, that record-low investment is not
only non-problem but rather a blessing. He writes: "The anaemic pace of capital formation in the
a
1980s means that, going into this recession, businesses did not make the classic mistake of bringing
new plants on line precisely when the economy was about to hit the skids.... For you "double-dippers"
[forecasters of a second economic down-leg], capital spending does not seem to be a leading suspect
that might prompt another leg down in the current recession." Simply paraphrased, because industry
investment is already at low levels, investment cannot fall further.
Unfortunately, anaemic manufacturing investment transcends this recent cycle and has already lasted
)
Currencies and Credit Markets \ July 1991
6
Nevertheless, the
great theme that has served to spread
doom and gloom about
excessive unification costs Germany is that
and associated fIscal and
monetary policies will drag down the
economy while the U.S. rebounds. We German
have come across
them all. many theories in our life. This one beats
_._n_O"T""'F"".....;--.'. .......'....,....:~7"~~~
..,;;t
..:.....:-=-:~
7
) inflation against the background of ån already booming West Germany, such resources must be
withdrawn or "crowded out" from somewhere else.
Right from the beginning, it has been eminently clear that the natural and prime target for such
a
"crowding out" in favour of unification would have to be Germany's huge export surplus. Neither
domestic consumption nor domestic investment need to be bridled. Rather, the resources tied up in
producing the export surplus had to be redirected towards the domestic market.
What was it that implemented this rapid, whopping resource transfer? It was a combination of three
things: tight money, a soaring budget deficit and a highly responsive German investor who massively
switched his new investments from foreign to German bonds. Considering the speed and the scale
of the operation, we can only say that is has proved to be a smashing success.
Fuelled by an mvestment boom- in the West and by consumer demand in the East, the West German
economy has continued to boom with an inflation rate well below that of other countries mired in
1991 rose
deep recession. Compared with the last quarter of 1990, real GNP in the rrrst quarter of
at an annual rate of 10%.
But what about the economic collapse and depression in East Germany? For the time being, no
though real incomes have been
doubt, soaring unemployment and uncertainty cause human duress
boosted. But the economic and financial problems are manageable when seen against the nation's
t:: huge pool of capital reserves, thanks to high savings and investments. Even the pessimists agree that
in the longer-run, unification will unleash new economic energies for Germany as
a whole. When
From what we hear and read from competent people, we would say that an upturn in East Germany
should be under way by early next year at the latest. Then, we think, good news items will increase
relative to the incidence of negative articles. Some research institutes expect that industrial
production will bottom this autumn and then rise by 10% annually between 1992 and 1995. That
1990 and an expected 20% in 1991.
compares with a decline of 13% in
So far, services are the main pillars of growth, especially so financial services, retail trade and
communication. Already, available telephone lines have been quadrupled. Later this year, as
institutional obstacles are overcome, many and varied incentive and pr~motion programs should
trigger off a considerable upswing in corporate and public investment. A
double-digit growth rate
is considered a realistic possibility as of 1992.
is
reasonable to expect a temporary inflation-peak of 4% to 4.5%, a rate which intolerable for
tightening by the
Germany. If inflation were to rise that high, further measures of monetary
Bundesbank would be a virtual certainty, whatever the economic situation. At the very least, there's
no hope of any relaxation in any monetary policy.
~)-_._~
t - .
\
Currencies and Credit Markets July 1991
.
8
--l
~r/
; I
. :
.
4 . .
: "
,
~ . . . . I
-t ." . I I . .
,,,
:
:
.
:
3 . ".
.
. ,
IIIIi
.. .
.. ".'
:
:
2 ;
II
. .
I
';< .
. ,
I:
I ·
.
:
1 : ~
-11 I:
. .
..
. . .
'I'
: f
:
ø
:
~I
:
It seems to us that most economists put too much emphasis on incremental growth percentages,
completely disregarding economic levels. If German GNP growth were to slow to 3% in 1991 from
4.6% in 1990, or even to 0% growth later in the year for that matter, it would still be at boom levels.
By contrast, if U.S. domestic demand increases 2% after falling almost 5% at an annual rate over the
last two quarters, it would still be at recessionary levels, although not as low as before. Obviously,
these different absolute levels of economic activity must also have differing implications for interest
rates.
The central question for the world economy and world financial and currency markets is whether
there will be solid and sustained recovery in the U.S. economy. Irrespective of the odd statistical up-
ticks, our view remains unchanged. Immutably, unquestionably, every single fundamental monetary,
financial and economic indicator speaks against any possibility of such a recovery.
The potential for a sustained, strong recovery from recession depends on two all-important processes
:..1\-....
_f'....-..'.
V
Currencies and Credit Markets \ July 1991
L
","J"
-...-:"""
~
-)
GERMANY: GNP GROWTH
(Year-over-year, percent change)
6
~ . . . . . , .
. . . . .
q , . . . . . .
"'
f . .
:) r .
. . r . . .
2 . . . . , .
1 . .
. . '.
ø
I I 1
1
1'9~ 986 1 SJB'7 199 1999 1
'90 991
Source: Datastream
in the monetary and fmancial sphere: sufficient money creation by the banking system and business
) reliquefication. Neither is in evidence.
As elucidated in the last letter, overall liquidity and money supply growth is determined by the
expansion of bank lending and bank investments. No other fm"ancial intermediary shares this ability
of the banks to create liquidity. That's why the banks hold the key to money supply growth.
Many econonùsts, though, have the bright notion that the U.S. banking
system has become redundant,
arguing that its role has been superseded by other fmancial intermediaries. The fact is that an
expansion of financial assets say for insurance companies or pensions funds
-
doesn't add a núte -
to the money supply. These intermediaries can only shift money. They cannot create money.
Lately, talk about credit crunch has waned. However, the banking figures actually show that it's
a
getting worse and worse, not bener. The credit crunch has turned into a credit deadlock. Bank credit
p )
/
rTP
10
)
U..S.. OOMESTIC F1NANCIAL STATISTICS: LOANS AND SECURITIES
(BIUlons of dollars, all ngureS annualized)
ferocious squeeze of 1980-82. What, then, is driving the stock market? It definitely
isn't excess
liquidity in the
monetary sense, as so many Wall Street gums like to assert.
Measured in terms of the sky-high stock market prices, corporate health seems to be
at its most hale
ever never mind that mundane things like corporate liquidity and profit margins have hardly
ever been
.;'-).~""
'..
Currencies and Credit Markets \ July 1991
I~-
11
To be sure, year -
falling
liquidity has shown a deteriorating trend ever since 1988 as
As matter of fact, U.S. corporate
a
external financing coincided with declining internal fmancing. In 1988, total net new internal and
$548 billion. By the fourth quarter of 1990, this figure declined to
external fmancing amounted to
$421 billion at an annual rate. The frrst quarter of this year didn't see any improvement.
A significant cause of this shrinkage in corporate liquidity has been the fact that U.S. corporations
spite of declining profits. In 1989, dividend payments of $80.5
have boosted dividend payments in
billion compared to ato $68.8 billion in undistributed profits. In the first quarter of this year,
þ ) dividend payments ballooned to a level of $115 billion while undistributed
profits from domestic
CONCLUSIONS
The
The real estate crisis that destroye<i the S&L's has caught up with the
commercial banks.
undeniably stark. Between 1980 and 1991, U.S. banks
statistics displayed in the table on page 10 are
have increased their real estate loans from $262 billion to $854 billion. That compares to an increase
$32648 billion to $626.5 billion.
in commercial and industrial loans from
billion in 1990, and at an annual rate of $166 billion in the first quarter of 1991.
Meanwhile, more and more problems are bubbling up in insurances companies and pensions funds.
With all these crumbling fmancial edifices, we ask ourselves, who will fmance the U.S. recovery?
The answer is nobody.
The structural problems afflicting the U.S. economy alone are sufficient to support our negative long-
term outlook on the U.S. economy. Previous letters have analyzed these structural factors in detail,
including underinvestment, low savings, overconsumpti~n, high unproductive debt, to name a
few.
The spreading financial problems, in isolation, have serious negative implications and are sufficient
to block the U.S. economy all on their own. Adding the structural and financial problems into the
same brew makes the situation all the more intractable. Try as we might, we see no potential for a
sustainable U.S. recovery.
AnDual Subscription Rates: 12 Issues. Europe: srr. 600.00. Subscribers outside of Europe: $US 400.00
Please Inquire for multiple subscriptions.
Reproduction oj pIU't 0/ tit. 41Ullysú is ollly penniltød when the $OlU"Ce is $Iaúd.