Mismanaged Trade - Strategic Policy and The Semiconductor - Kenneth S Flamm - Washington, D - C, District of Columbia, 1996 - Washington, D - C - 9780815717355 - Anna'
Mismanaged Trade - Strategic Policy and The Semiconductor - Kenneth S Flamm - Washington, D - C, District of Columbia, 1996 - Washington, D - C - 9780815717355 - Anna'
TRADE?
KENNETH FLAMM
MISMANAGED
TRADE?
Strategic Policy
and the
Semiconductor Industry
987654321
The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of the
American National Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for
Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1984.
Board of Trustees
Honorary Trustees
Since 1959 the United States and Japan have repeatedly negotiated with
one another to resolve disputes involving trade in semiconductors. During
these four decades the American and Japanese chip industries have been
reluctant pioneers, cutting their way through a forest of issues created by
the unique conditions of high-technology trade and investment. The new
directions explored by the two countries’ policymakers evolved into the
1986 U.S.-Japan Semiconductor Trade Arrangement. Today, as that ex¬
periment and its 1991 successor agreement are about to expire, the
United States and Japan seem poised to again change course.
In this study Kenneth Flamm analyzes the public policy issues raised
during these years of friction over semiconductor trade. Motivated by
strategic economic and national security rationales, both the United
States and Japan pursued policies designed to advance their industrial
objectives. Policy conflicts occurred over trade, technology, development,
investment, and antitrust enforcement as Japan’s microelectronics indus¬
try caught up with its American competitors and pulled ahead in some
areas. U.S. short-range tactics sometimes undercut long-term goals. The
author concludes that over the long term improved trade rules and
strengthened enforcement mechanisms must be developed to ensure open
and competitive international markets for semiconductors. Effective so¬
lutions for trade in semiconductors will undoubtedly be applicable to
other industries and ultimately may serve as the model for further
strengthening the more general multilateral trading system codified in
the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.
The author is grateful to Dan Hutcheson, F. M. Scherer, and Michael
Smith for the detailed comments they made on the first draft of this study.
Extensive comments received from Daryl Hatano, Thomas Howell, Matt
IX
X FOREWORD
Rohde, John Steinbruner, Makoto Sumita, and Alan Wolff also greatly
improved this book, as did comments from Bill Finan, Gary Hufbauer,
Peter Reiss, Gary Saxonhouse, Carl Shapiro, Jack Triplett, and Philip
Webre on articles based on this research. Executives in U.S., European,
and Japanese electronics companies were generous with their time and
extraordinarily helpful when they spoke with the author as he went about
researching this book, as were many government officials in the United
States, Japan, and the European Community. The author is also grateful
to Japan’s Ministry of International Trade and Industry and Ministry of
Finance for their financial and logistical support of short stays at the
Tokyo research institutes associated with those ministries and their help
in arranging interviews with Japanese government and industry officials.
The author thanks the Rockefeller Brothers Fund and the John D.
and Catherine T. MacArthur Foundation for their financial support of
this study.
First-rate research assistance was provided by Yuko Iida Frost and
Kaori Nakajima. Michael Treadway and James Schneider edited the man¬
uscript. Melanie Allen, Ian Campbell, Cynthia Iglesias, and Andrew
Solomon verified its factual content. Kris McDevitt and Ann Ziegler
provided staff assistance. Ellen Garshick proofread the pages and Julia
Petrakis compiled the index.
The views expressed in this book are those of the author and should
not be ascribed to the persons or organizations whose assistance is ac¬
knowledged or to the trustees, officers, or other staff members of the
Brookings Institution.
MICHAEL H. ARMACOST
President
May 1996
Washington, D.C
Contents
1. Introduction 1
Challenges for Public Policy 1
Technology and Industrial Structure in Semiconductors 7
International Competition in Semiconductors 18
Strategic Policy in the United States 27
xi
xn CONTENTS
Index 461
Tables
1-1. Share of Worldwide R&D Expenditures and Employment for
U.S.-Based Companies and Their Majority-Owned Foreign
Affiliates, by Parent’s Industry, 1989 14
1-2. Capital Costs of a Typical Semiconductor Wafer Fabrication
Facility, Mid-1970s-Early 1990s 16
1-3. Domestic R&D Expenditures and Employment by U.S.-Based
Companies and Their Majority-Owned Foreign Affiliates as
Shares of Worldwide Totals by Parent’s Industry, 1989 19
1-4. World Market Shares of Merchant and Captive Semiconductor
Manufacturers, by Region Where Headquartered, Selected
Years, 1981-93 20
1-5. U.S. Government Shares of Total R&D Funding,
by Industry, 1989 28
1-6. U.S. Industrial Consumption of Semiconductors,
by Consuming Sector, Selected Years, 1963-87 35
xiv CONTENTS
Figures
1-1. Year-to-Year Changes in DRAM Prices, 1972-89 10
1-2. U.S. Semiconductor and Electronic Component Company
R&D as Share of Sales and Japanese Company IC R&D as
Share of Semiconductor Sales, 1976-94 12
1-3. U.S. Company Semiconductor Plant and Equipment
Investment and Japanese Company IC Plant and Equipment
Investment as Share of Semiconductor Sales, 1976-94 15
1-4. World Market Shares of Merchant Semiconductor Companies,
by Region, 1970-95 22
1-5. U.S. Share of Combined U.S. and Japanese Semiconductor
Industrial Employment, Value Added, and Sales, 1968-93 23
1- 6. Federal Government Share of U.S. Electronic Components
R&D Expenditures, 1972-92 29
2- 1. Output of Transistors and Diodes by Japanese Manufacturers,
September 1954-March 1956 46
2-2. Volume of U.S. Transistor Production, by Type, 1955-65 50
2-3. Value of U.S. Transistor Production, by Type, 1955-65 51
2-4. Import Shares of Japanese Semiconductor Consumption,
1966-94 62
2-5. Japanese Tax Incentives and Subsidized Lending for
Electronics Development, and Investment in Electronics by
Major Companies, 1961-71 65
2-6. Japanese R&D Subsidies for Electronics Development, and
R&D in Electronics by Major Companies, 1961-71 67
2-7. Japanese Consumption of Integrated Circuits and Import
Market Share, 1968-74 78
2-8. Major Results of the Japanese VLSI Project, 1975-90 101
2-9. Expenditures on VLSI Project and Subsequent Cooperative
Research, by Category, 1976-86 103
2-10. Linkages within VLSI Industrial System 104
2-11. Public and Private Funding of VLSI R&D Association,
1976-86 112
4-1. Errors in MITI Forecasts of DRAM Production, Quarterly,
1986-88, and Semiannually, 1987-94 198
4-2. Errors in MITI Forecasts of Japanese EPROM Production,
Quarterly, 1986-88, and Semiannually, 1987-94 199
4-3. Year-to-Year Changes in Fisher Ideal Price Indexes for DRAMs
and EPROMs, 1972-89 210
xvi CONTENTS
'
MISMANAGED
TRADE?
CHAPTER ONE
Introduction
1
2 INTRODUCTION
U.S. firms’ sales of semiconductor chips in 1990 were $19 billion (out of
a worldwide industry total of $50 billion), compared with $200 billion in
American motor vehicle shipments. And aside from the semiconductor
industry itself, the only segments of U.S. industry to take an active
interest in semiconductor trade policy were the computer and commu¬
nications equipment sectors, the chief users of the products most affected
by the negotiations.
Despite the lack of notice, the discussions carried out behind closed
doors in government offices near the White House were anything but a
minor sideshow. As in other high-technology sectors, where global com¬
petition had mainly pitted American and Japanese companies against
one another, bilateral agreements between these two nations were his¬
torically the model for expanded arrangements as other countries’ market
presence grows.
By 1996, stakes that were already big had grown larger. Global semi¬
conductor sales in 1995 had soared to $150 billion, now more than 20
percent of world vehicle sales. Forecasts predicted that by 2000, global
chip sales would amount to 40 percent of global motor vehicle sales.1
Increasingly, able new competitors in East Asia—particularly Korea and
Taiwan—had emerged as major new players in the global chip industry,
pushing past European companies in their share of the global market in
1994. As negotiators from Washington and Tokyo convened their trade
talks, corporate and political leaders in Seoul, Taipei, and the capitals of
Europe made little effort to disguise their intense interest in the pro¬
ceedings. Today’s bilateral precedents were clearly likely to shape to¬
morrow’s multilateral system.
Precedent-setting features of the semiconductor pacts have already
been mimicked in other sectoral trade negotiations. The semiconductor
agreements’ market share target for foreign sales in the Japanese chip
market, widely hailed as a step toward “managed trade” by both sup¬
porters and opponents, was acknowledged by American government of¬
ficials to be the inspiration for a 1992 bilateral agreement setting quan¬
titative targets for increased sales of U.S.-made auto parts in the
Japanese market.2 More recently, apparent success in achieving market
they also realize that, as recent experience shows, that is the only way to deal with Ja¬
pan. . . . ‘We knew we had to pattern this agreement after the semiconductor agreement,’
said an official in the Commerce Department. ‘But we could not appear to be agreeing to
specific numbers.’
The Japanese know that, too, and, eager to make Mr. Bush’s trip a success, the Gov¬
ernment here spent the last few weeks cajoling and arm-twisting to force Japanese auto¬
makers to once again revise plans to increase their imports. Because the announcements
came from the companies, not the Government, the United States was able to argue that
such ‘unilateral’ proposals from Japanese companies did not amount to managed trade.”
David E. Sanger, “Bush in Japan; A Trade Mission Ends in Tension as the ‘Big Eight’ of
Autos Meet,” New York Times, January 10, 1992, p. Al.
3. Bob Davis, “Economy: Clinton Team to Suggest Import Goals for Japan as Trade
Talks Approach,” Wall Street Journal, May 20, 1993, pp. A2, All.
4. The 1993 GATT Agreement skirted the margins of this issue by explicitly permitting
government subsidies of up to 75 percent of basic research conducted by industry and up
to 50 percent of applied R&D costs through development of the first prototype. “World
4 INTRODUCTION
Second, how must the world trading system be adapted to deal with
the presence—or absence—of accepted norms for competitive behavior
among high-technology firms, and for relations with their home govern¬
ments? How much cooperation or collusion among nominally competitive
firms, possibly mediated or coordinated by government, can be tolerated
without making the idea of a competitive marketplace meaningless? In¬
vestments in high technology, if successful, create (at least temporarily)
some element of monopoly power based on a firm’s proprietary control
over unique technological assets. What will be the ground rules for com¬
petition in global markets that must, virtually by definition, stray far from
the textbook vision of perfect competition?
How these issues are settled will shape the world trading system for
decades to come. Given its central importance, one might presume that
thinking through the outlines of a coherent policy would be an overriding
concern of U.S. trade policymaking. But this has not always been the
case. The semiconductor industry has been simmering—or perhaps stew¬
ing—on the front burner of trade policy for over three decades. Instead
of writing down a recipe, however, rapidly changing shifts of American
trade policymakers have simply tossed additional ingredients into the pot,
often ignoring the outcomes of their predecessors’ experiments. Instead
of drawing operational guidance from a long-term strategy and vision,
American policy has largely been devised in terms of short-run tactics to
fix the irritant of the moment on an industry-by-industry, case-by-case
basis.
This study analyzes how thirty years of fierce international economic
competition, and high-stakes political intervention, came to lock the
American and Japanese chip industries onto their current course as re¬
luctant pioneers of a new high-technology world order. For it is no acci¬
dent that semiconductors have historically been at the cutting edge of
trade friction in high-technology industries. There are three reasons why
this has been so. First, semiconductors are an extreme example of a
product undergoing rapid and sustained technical innovation, showcasing
the distinctive features of high-technology industries that make them
both economically important, and a challenge to the international trading
system. Second, from the start, semiconductor companies fixed their gaze
on a global market, producing a sharp and sustained international com-
Trade Talks: The Uruguay Round’s Key Results,” Wall Street Journal, December 15, 1993,
p. A6.
INTRODUCTION 5
5. See figure 1-1 and Jack E. Triplett, “Price and Technological Change in a Capital
Good: A Survey of Research on Computers,” in Dale W. Jorgenson and Ralph Landau,
eds., Technology and Capital Formation (MIT Press, 1989), pp. 127-214.
8 INTRODUCTION
cessors has been limited by clock speed and the distances between transistors on a chip.
High-performance computer processor chips are now often crammed as full of circuit
elements as the densest memory chips, and the manufacturing technology used by the
makers of the most advanced microprocessors is as demanding as that used in leading-edge
memories.
8. See M. P. Lepselter and S. M. Sze, “DRAM Pricing Trends—The -it Rule,” IEEE
Circuits and Devices Magazine (January 1985), p. 53.
10 INTRODUCTION
dinary decline in price was more than a fanciful phrase.9 One DRAM
price index in common use within the industry, the aggregate price per
bit of memory sold, fell at a compound annual rate of 31 percent from
1977 to 1988. Over the entire 1974-89 period, the compound rate of
quarterly decline in average cost per bit was 10.6 percent, equivalent to
an annual rate of 36.1 percent. Another, technically superior index of
DRAM price is a so-called Fisher Ideal price index. It more accurately
measures the effects of price declines and shows a drop closer to 34
percent a year from 1977 to 1988.10 A trend line fit to an annual Fisher
Ideal price index, whose changes are depicted in figure 1-1, over the
1971-89 period, shows a long-term decline of about 42 percent a year.
9. Consulting firm Dataquest’s quarterly estimates of average selling prices and quan¬
tities sold for all types of DRAMs were used to construct these measures.
10. Average price per bit is calculated by dividing aggregate sales revenues by total bits
sold for all generations of chip. Even if prices remained absolutely constant for each type
of chip from one period to the next, the average price per bit would change as a consequence
of shifts in demand from one type of chip to another. In essence, price per bit is a weighted
average of chip prices, where the weights vary across any two periods being compared.
The Fisher Ideal index, in contrast, uses identical weights in the two periods compared,
thus avoiding confusion of the effects of price changes with shifts in usage from one
generation to another. See chapter 5 for further details.
INTRODUCTION 11
Other types of memory chips show only slightly less rapid declines in
price. One study found a Fisher Ideal price index for all memory chips
declining at an annual rate of almost 33 percent from 1977 to 1988.”
Interestingly, the long-term decline in DRAM prices is even more
rapid if the period of extraordinary rise of chip prices after 1986, when
the STA was signed, is excluded. Figure 1-1 shows how unusual the
annual rates of change in DRAM prices after 1986 were: for the first time
in the history of the industry, a substantial price increase was registered
in 1988, and declines far smaller than historical norms were recorded in
1987 and 1989. How the STA might have been related to this slowing of
the historical rate of price decline in DRAMs is an important subject
explored in detail in this study.
A corollary to the rapid improvement in manufacturing technology
that made these dramatic price declines possible has been an equally
torrid pace for the introduction of new products. Even in the late 1950s,
for example, more than half of all new types of transistors introduced
were obsolete within two years; roughly the same life span applied to
chips used in computer systems in the mid-1970s.12 At IBM, memory
products historically had about a one-year lifetime.13 Nor does innovation
appear to have slowed—one analysis shows new generations of DRAMs
in the late 1980s being introduced at roughly the same rapid pace ob¬
served in the 1970s.14
Technological Intensity
11. See Ellen R. Dulberger, “Sources of Price Decline in Computer Processors: Se¬
lected Electronic Components,” in Murray F. Foss, Marilyn E. Manser, and Allan H.
Young, eds., Price Measurements and Their Uses (University of Chicago Press and National
Bureau of Economic Research, 1993), table 3.6.
12. See John E. Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology .The Case of Semicon¬
ductors (Brookings, 1971), p. 83; and Douglas W. Webbink, Economic Report on the
Semiconductor Industry: A Survey of Structure, Conduct and Performance (Federal Trade
Commission, 1977), p. 131.
13. William E. Harding, “Semiconductor Manufacturing in IBM, 1957 to the Present:
A Perspective,” IBM Journal of Research and Development, vol. 25 (September 1981),
p. 653.
14. M. Therese Flaherty and Kathryn S. H. Huang, “The Myth of the Shortening
Product Life Cycle,” Harvard Business School, May 1988.
12 INTRODUCTION
Percent
Source: MITI IC R&D as percent of semiconductor sales was estimated by taking the IC R&D-to-sales ratio from
the MITI survey and adjusting to reflect aggregate value of semiconductor production versus IC production from
MITI industrial production statistics. Semiconductor Industry Association, SIA 1995 Annual Databook: Review of
Global and U.S. Semiconductor Competitive Trends, 1978-1994 (San Jose, Calif.: Technicon Analytic Research,
1995), p. 40; Thomas R. Howell and others. The Microelectronics Race: The Impact of Government Policy on
International Competition (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1988), pp. 218-19; National Science Foundation, Research and
Development in Industry: 1982, NSF 84-325 (Arlington, Va., 1984), 1988, NSF 90-319 (1990), 1991, NSF 94-325 (1994)
and unpublished MITI surveys of twelve Japanese IC companies.
a. Members of the Semiconductor Industry Association (merchant producers only).
b. Twelve Japanese semiconductor companies surveyed by the Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI).
c. Total funds for R&D as a share of net domestic sales by U.S. electronic component companies.
d. Company funds for R&D as a share of net domestic sales by U.S. electronic component companies.
15. The National Science Foundation’s data on industrial R&D spending show domestic
R&D as a share of domestic sales, which is a misleading basis for cross-industry compari¬
sons when substantial research, or significant sales, take place within overseas affiliates and
the share of overseas affiliates varies substantially from industry to industry.
16. Although there are important examples of “fabless” chip companies, which do no
manufacturing and instead have their designs produced in outside fabrication facilities under
contract, these firms account for a relatively small share of industry output. The most
prominent examples are microprocessor and computer peripheral systems design specialists
such as Cyrix, Chips and Technologies, Weitek, and Cirrus Logic, and might arguably be
14 INTRODUCTION
Scale Economies
designated as specialized computer peripheral producers (where the entire system just
happens to be incorporated into a single chip or set of chips), rather than producers of
standard semiconductor components. The blurring of lines between systems producers and
semiconductor component manufacturers is an important topic addressed later.
INTRODUCTION 15
Figure 1-3. U.S. Company Semiconductor Plant and Equipment
Investment and Japanese Company IC Plant and Equipment Investment
as Share of Semiconductor Sales, 1976-94a
Percent
stant. Thus the larger the sales base, the lower the average unit cost of
production.
These economies of scale in the use of the outcomes of R&D have
created a constant pressure for manufacturers to seek out the widest
possible market for their products to maximize the return on their rela¬
tively fixed R&D investments. As a consequence, the industry has been
unrelentingly international in focus right from the start. Major producers
quickly turned to foreign markets in their quest for a larger sales base.
U.S. companies surged into Europe in the late 1960s and, after overcom¬
ing numerous obstacles, into Japan in the 1970s and 1980s.
Another important source of scale economies in semiconductor pro¬
duction has been the capital-intensive nature of the chip manufacturing
process. Both American and Japanese companies have typically plowed
from 10 to 20 percent of their sales into new plant and equipment invest¬
ment, year after year. Figure 1-3 shows that in the early 1980s, one of the
16 INTRODUCTION
17. See Reese M. Reynolds and Don R. Strom, “CEM: Process Latitude in a Bottle,”
Semiconductor International (October 1989), pp. 122-29. These figures refer to a state-of-
the-art facility for manufacturing a high-volume, mass-produced product. Facilities invest¬
ments relative to other costs would be substantially lower for a smaller facility used in
producing smaller volumes of more specialized products. Unit manufacturing cost would
also be a smaller share of product price for such more specialized, noncommodity products.
INTRODUCTION 17
Learning Economies
18. The world record for bringing a new chip plant on line appears to be held by NMB
Semiconductor, a defunct Japanese company, which claimed that it took only nine months
to go from initial groundbreaking on a new fabrication facility to initial production of 256K
DRAMs in 1985. See Larry Waller, “DRAM Users and Makers: Shotgun Marriages Kick
In,” Electronics (November 1988), pp. 29-30.
19. Robert N. Noyce, “Microelectronics,” Scientific American, September 1977, p. 67.
18 INTRODUCTION
20. Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Direct Investment Abroad: 1989 Benchmark
Survey, Final Results (U.S. Department of Commerce, October 1992). Observe first that
firms primarily producing semiconductors almost certainly account for the overwhelming
share of output of multinational electronic component producers. Output of U.S. electronic
component factories was about $60 billion in 1989; domestic and export sales by R&D-
performing U.S. electronic component companies were about $53 billion. U.S. semicon¬
ductor sales accounted for 43 percent of electronic component output; sales of multinational
electronic component home offices amounted to 42 percent of sales of R&D-performing
electronic component companies. Since virtually all significant semiconductor producers
operate foreign affiliates, one may infer that statistics on the populations of U.S. multina¬
tional electronic component firms and statistics on U.S. semiconductor companies are
largely describing the same group.
Since parent-firm sales by U.S. electronic component makers operating as multination¬
als (in the Commerce Department benchmark survey) amounted to well under half of
domestic sales by all R&D-performing U.S. electronic component makers (in the NSF
INTRODUCTION 19
survey) in 1989, there were clearly a large number of American electronic component
companies selling almost exclusively to the domestic market, including the large U.S.
defense market. About half of electronic component output is active (vacuum tubes and
semiconductors) and passive (resistors and capacitors) components. The balance is coils
and transformers, connectors, printed circuit boards, miscellaneous parts, modules, and
circuit assemblies.
20 INTRODUCTION
North America
Merchant 46.9 33.1 30.3 32.4
Captive 17.0 12.1 9.4 7.0
IBM 9.4 7.4 6.5 4.5
Europe 7.4 9.6 10.9 8.7
Japan 26.6 42.1 44.2 42.6
Rest of world 2.1 3.1 5.1 9.4
Memorandum:
IBM share of North American
captive production 55.2 60.9 68.9 65.5
IBM purchase/world market n.a. 1.5 n.a. 0.9
IBM share of world production 9.4 7.4 6.5 4.5
Source: Integrated Circuit Engineering, Status 1982, Mid-Term 1988, Status 1991, Status 1994: A Report on the
Integrated Circuit Industry (Scottsdale, Ariz.), pp. 1-10.
n.a. Not available,
a. Estimated.
21. The decline in the share of American captive production in world output during
the 1980s reflects several factors: systems companies shutting down high-cost internal chip
fabrication lines, rapid growth in merchant sales by companies such as Intel, and shifts in
strategy leading captive producers to sell their chips on the open market as well. Until the
late 1980s, when it began to sell its semiconductor products in significant volume, AT&T
was the second largest captive producer in the United States; today it is classified as a
merchant producer. Since 1991 IBM has aggressively begun to seek sales of its semicon¬
ductor output on the open market. See IBM, Annual Report, 1991 (Armonk, N.Y., 1991).
22. See Integrated Circuit Engineering, Status 1992: A Report on the Integrated Circuit
Industry (Scottsdale, Ariz., 1992), pp. 2-14 to 2-17, 2-32, 3-6.
23. Integrated Circuit Engineering, Status 1994: A Report on the Integrated Circuit
Industry (Scottsdale, Ariz., 1994), pp. 1-14, 3-6.
22 INTRODUCTION
Percent
Sources: Dataquest unpublished historical estimates; Industry and Trade Strategies, The U.S. Electronics Industry
Complex, report to the U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Analysis (Berkeley, Calif., October 1988), table 2;
Dataquest, "Worldwide Semiconductor Market Grew 40 Percent in 1995,” press release (January 1996); and "World¬
wide Semiconductor Market Grew by 28 percent in 1994,” press release (January 1995).
regions where the output is produced rather than the corporate nation¬
ality of the producer.24 U.S. census data on factory shipments include
Japanese firms’ production in the United States, which, although still
modest, increased significantly in the late 1980s.
More interestingly, the data show that the share of semiconductor
value added within U.S. factories, despite a decrease through 1989, still
greatly exceeded the share of U.S. factory sales. Since 1989 the U.S.
share of value added has risen sharply and now exceeds that of Japanese
factories, but U.S. factory shipments remained stagnant at under 40
percent of the binational total. Materials consumption in the United
States, which probably more or less tracks wafer fabrication activity,
declined even more steeply than the U.S. share of shipments. What these
figures seem to show is that Japanese output is mainly concentrated in
24. I use official U.S. and Japanese manufacturing census data to construct these series.
Note that the U.S. concept of value added corresponds to the Japanese concept of gross
value added. (Japan also reports “plain” value added net of depreciation.)
INTRODUCTION 23
Figure 1-5. U.S. Share of Combined U.S. and Japanese Semiconductor
Industrial Employment, Value Added, and Sales, 1968-93
Percent
Sources: See figure 1-4; MITI, Census of Manufacturers, various years; and Bureau of the Census, Annual Survey
of Manufactures, 1993.
25. See, for example, Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology, p. 27, who shows
Japanese firms trailing slightly behind most European firms in imitating major semicon¬
ductor innovations of the 1950s, but ahead of the Europeans (although still behind the
United States) in the 1960s.
26. The standard source for this history is Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology.
27. See Kenneth Flamm, Targeting the Computer: Government Support and Interna¬
tional Competition (Brookings, 1987), chap. 4, and Flamm, Creating the Computer: Gov¬
ernment, Industry, and High Technology (Brookings, 1988), pp. 13-19. In the 1950s and
early 1960s, military purchases also accounted for the bulk of sales of the most technolog¬
ically advanced computers.
INTRODUCTION 25
and complex question that cannot be explored here.29 In brief, the basic
European strategy from the late 1960s on was to protect national markets
with high tariff walls, then select “national champion” firms who were
given favored treatment within the protected national market (generally
receiving both direct subsidies and preferences in government procure¬
ment).30 The major reasons for failure in the case of semiconductors were
twofold: first, their sheltering from competition in the open market often
meant that the European firms felt lessened pressure to stay technologi¬
cally abreast in a rapidly changing marketplace; second, misguided and
failed policies in the computer sector obstructed the development of a
dynamic upstream market for chips used in computers like the one that
was driving the IC industry in the United States.
Indeed, attempts to protect the European semiconductor and com¬
puter industries from imports created a vicious circle of sorts. High tariffs
and high costs for imported semiconductors meant higher prices—and
diminished sales—for European computer systems makers in both na¬
tional and global markets. Diminished computer sales meant a smaller
demand for locally produced semiconductors to be used in those com¬
puter systems. A weaker national semiconductor industry meant greater
political pressure for protection, and so on. This apparent contradiction
between protecting a chip industry and fostering a competitive, chip¬
using computer industry downstream is not unique to Europe, of course;
it became a major source of division within the U.S. electronics industry
in the late 1980s, after the Semiconductor Trade Arrangement was
signed.
Because European chip manufacturers are largely vertically integrated
divisions within electronics systems companies, this inherent policy con-
29. For a detailed analysis in computers, see Flamm, Targeting the Computer, chap. 5,
and Creating the Computer, chap. 5.
30. See Giovanni Dosi, Industrial Adjustment and Policy, vol. 2: Technical Change and
Survival: Europe’s Semiconductor Industry (Sussex, U.K.: University of Sussex, 1981), pp.
26-41; and Malerba, Semiconductor Business, 1985, pp. 129-31, 188-200, for concise dis¬
cussions of the pattern of government funding for European semiconductor companies in
the late 1960s and 1970s. Although the United States, Japan, and Canada virtually elimi¬
nated all tariffs on semiconductors in 1985 on a most-favored-nation basis, the European
Community continued to maintain a steep 14 percent duty on integrated circuits. In late
1995 the European Union agreed to slash semiconductor duties beginning in 1996. Tariffs
greater than 7 percent were to be cut to 7 percent and those less than 7 percent were to be
abolished. See “Europe to Cut Duties on Semiconductors,” Electronic Engineering Times
(December 18, 1995), p. 20.
INTRODUCTION 27
flict was internalized within the European electronics firms. The solution
chosen was to protect the domestic chip market, but to permit free
investment within Europe by foreign producers. In that way, access to
semiconductor technology developed abroad could be maintained and
some degree of protection granted to the domestic industry, yet enough
domestic competition preserved over the long run to ensure that prices
eventually approached costs. Only a mildly negative effect on the com¬
puter industry would be felt, to the extent that foreign producers of the
latest, most proprietary technology might be able to discriminate on price
in the European market, behind the shelter of tariff and other barriers
impeding chip imports. But for mature products, with multiple sources
of supply, competition within the European market would eventually
drive prices down.
The strategy contrasted markedly with that adopted in Japan, which
built formidable walls around its domestic chip market, blocking both
trade and investment, and strictly regulated the terms under which for¬
eign technology could be imported. Another vital difference in Japanese
policy seems to have been that Japan did not focus its promotional efforts
on a single national champion, but instead chose to actively foster com¬
petition at home within the ranks of its sheltered domestic producers
(while simultaneously promoting cooperation in R&D). As will be seen,
this policy of maintaining competition within the domestic market was
successfully defended by government bureaucrats against pressure from
Japanese politicians to organize a national semiconductor champion. In
both Japan and Europe—and increasingly in the United States—the
driving force behind national support programs in semiconductors was
the view that this sector was somehow strategic.
31. The government share is considerably smaller (about 10 percent; see figure 1-6) if
all R&D-performing electronic component companies (that is, those with no foreign affil¬
iates as well as those with them) are included. Virtually all significant U.S. semiconductor
makers have foreign affiliates, however, and the multinational segment of the electronic
components industry provides the more relevant comparison.
INTRODUCTION 29
Percent
Source: Author's calculations based on National Science Foundation, Selected Data on Research and Development
in Industry: 1992 (Arlington, Va., 1994), tables SD-3, SD-4, SD-6, SD-7, SD-8, SD-9; National Science Foundation,
Research and Development in Industry: 1988 (1990), tables B-4, B-7, B-11, B-18, B-19.
a. Mid-1970s data are not available.
Furthermore, the trend has clearly been downward over time, so that
semiconductors today benefit less from federal R&D funding than in the
past. Figure 1-6 shows the decline of the government share in funding of
the U.S. electronic component industry’s domestic R&D from levels
approaching 40 percent in the mid-1970s. The significance of these figures
is that the semiconductor industry—in the United States, as well as
overseas—has long been, and continues to be the focus of intense gov¬
ernment involvement, with the power to shape competitive outcomes.
A brief consideration of the history of that involvement suggests that
until fairly recently the motivation for U.S. government support in semi¬
conductors was strategic only in the least economically interesting sense
of the word, that is, driven primarily by national security concerns. Gov¬
ernment’s initial involvement with semiconductor technology had oc¬
curred during World War II as an effort to improve the reliability of
30 INTRODUCTION
32. See Ernest Braun and Stuart Macdonald, Revolution in Miniature: The History and
Impact of Semiconductor Electronics, 2d ed. (Cambridge University Press), 1982, pp. 226-
30. Some of the experiments undertaken at Purdue University as part of this effort were
so similar to the later experiments undertaken at Bell Labs that resulted in the invention
of the transistor that some have speculated that the transistor might have been invented
years earlier if the Purdue researchers had been searching for amplification effects. See
Richard R. Nelson, “The Link Between Science and Invention: the Case of the Transistor,”
in National Bureau of Economic Research, The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity:
Economic and Social Factors (Princeton University Press, 1962), pp. 549-86; and Thomas
J. Misa, “Military Needs, Commercial Realities, and the Development of the Transistor,
1948-1958,” in Merrit Roe Smith, ed., Military Enterprise and Technological Change: Per¬
spectives on the American Experience (MIT Press, 1985), pp. 256-57.
33. After the war the Signal Corps also sponsored development of a photolithographic
process for creating resistors and capacitors on ceramic substrates at the National Bureau
of Standards and the Centralab division of the Globe Union Corporation for use in min¬
iaturized proximity fuses. The basic photolithographic techniques later used in the manu¬
facture of integrated circuits were derived from this technology. Jack S. Kilby, coinventor
of the integrated circuit, had worked on this technology before moving on to Texas Instru¬
ments. See Kilby, “Invention of the Integrated Circuit,” IEEE Transactions on Electron
Devices, vol. ED-23 (July 1976), pp. 648-54.
The National Bureau of Standards and the Signal Corps also worked together on the
research programs that led to the development of printed circuit boards and wave soldering
techniques, which were to revolutionize electronics manufacture. As late as 1961, half of
INTRODUCTION 31
scale Signal Corps funding of transistor research at Bell in 1950 had risen
to 20 percent of total funding by 1952, and 50 percent of transistor work
by 1953, and stayed at that level through 1955.34 About 25 percent of Bell
Labs’ semiconductor research budget over the period 1949-58 was funded
by defense contracts, and all of the early production of Western Electric,
the Bell System’s manufacturing affiliate, went to military shipments.35
After 1955 the Signal Corps began to fund semiconductor research
and fundamental development at companies other than the Bell Labs
(adding RCA and Pacific Semiconductor to the list in 1955), and in 1956
it doubled the size of the R&D effort to an average of $1 million a year.
Even greater funding went into engineering development (“fundamental
development” left off at the prototype stage, while “engineering devel¬
opment” created efficient and economic mass production technology).
Army transistor engineering development contracts over the 1952-64 pe¬
riod amounted to $50 million, averaging $4 million annually.36 The en¬
gineering development effort also jumped sharply in 1956—in that year
alone, $15 million in contracts was appropriated, with funds flowing to
virtually every semiconductor company in the United States.37
The occasion for the sharp increase in R&D funding in 1956 was a
breakthrough in transistor manufacturing technology. In late 1955, influ¬
enced by an ongoing antitrust suit brought by the U.S. Justice Depart¬
ment, Bell Labs had permitted the transfer of its “diffusion process”
technology to other companies. This technology, invented at Bell, with a
the value of U.S. shipments of printed circuit boards went to military users. See S. F.
Danko, “Printed Circuits and Microelectronics,” Proceedings of the Institute of Radio and
Electronic Engineers, vol. 50 (May 1962), pp. 937-38, 941; and Misa, “Military Needs,”
pp. 263-64.
34. Misa, “Military Needs,” p. 273.
35. Indeed, the first practical application of the transistor in laboratory equipment was
undertaken by Bell for the navy in 1949. The first use of transistors in a computerlike digital
circuit was in a gating matrix built at Bell Labs that same year as part of a “simulated
warfare” computer. The first transistorized computer built in the United States and the
early development of the power transistor were funded at Bell by the air force. C. A.
Warren, B. McMillan, and B. D. Holbrook, “Military Systems Engineering and Research,”
in M. D. Fagen, edA History of Engineering and Science in the Bell System: National
Service in War and Peace (1925-1975) (Murray Hill: Bell Telephone Laboratories, 1978),
pp. 617-48; and W. S. Brown, B. D. Holbrook, and M. D. Mcllroy, “Computer Science,”
in S. Millman, ed., A History of Engineering and Science in the Bell System: Communica¬
tions Sciences (1925-1980) (Indianapolis: AT&T Bell Laboratories, 1984), pp. 351-98. See
also Richard C. Levin, “The Semiconductor Industry,” in Richard R. Nelson, ed., Govern¬
ment and Technical Progress: A Cross-Industry Analysis (Pergamon, 1982), p. 26.
36. Misa, “Military Needs,” pp. 275-76.
37. Misa, “Military Needs,” p. 282.
32 INTRODUCTION
large share of the cost borne by the Signal Corps, made possible a great
improvement in performance (in particular, the ability to deal with high-
frequency signals) over the first crude point-contact transistors, and later
generations of junction transistors.38 With the rapid adoption of produc¬
tion technology for diffused base transistors by the U.S. industry, the
Signal Corps had reason to spread its research largesse much more
widely, as it pursued the development of high-performance transistors.
In its quest for new high-performance products, the military was partic¬
ularly inclined to take a chance on new firms: in 1959, for example, new
firms (those with no background in the older vacuum tube business)
accounted for 69 percent of military sales, compared with a 63 percent
share of all semiconductor sales.39
The military influence was pervasive. In 1958 and 1959, for example,
the federal government was directly funding about 25 and 23 percent,
respectively, of the R&D (excluding engineering development contracts)
undertaken within the U.S. semiconductor industry.40 If university and
federal laboratory work were factored in, along with engineering devel¬
opment funds, and indirect R&D funding embedded in contracts to
procure new devices at premium prices, that figure would have been
much higher: a congressional committee report estimated that the federal
38. See Misa, “Military Needs,” p. 281; and Tilton, International Diffusion of Tech¬
nology, p. 76. The early point-contact transistors were manufactured by attaching two
metal wires to the surface of a piece of germanium semiconductor. These devices were very
sensitive to environmental factors, had high noise levels, worked only at low frequencies,
and could be used only in low-power applications. Point-contact transistors were superseded
by so-called junction transistors in the early 1950s, which worked by creating junctions
between regions of semiconductor materials treated with impurities. The two principal
methods of creating junction transistors involved adding the impurity while growing a single
silicon crystal (grown junction transistors) or melting silicon materials already treated with
impurities into one another (alloy junction transistors). Although they improved the con¬
trollability of semiconductor characteristics, junction transistors still operated only at low
frequencies. The diffusion process worked by exposing a semiconductor substrate to a
carefully controlled atmosphere of heated, gaseous impurities, which diffused into the
surface of the substrate. Very precise control of the composition and thickness of the
impurities in the silicon could thus be achieved, and the operating frequencies of the new
transistors so produced jumped by two orders of magnitude.
39. Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology, p. 91.
40. See Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology, pp. 93-94. Tilton stresses that
formal R&D contracts were concentrated in older, established electronics firms, but it is
clear that substantial government funding flowed into research at newer companies. New
entrant Texas Instruments, for example, had about half of its $30 million in R&D spending
for 1959—-which compares with $70 million shown for the entire U.S. semiconductor in¬
dustry in 1959 by Tilton’s sources—contributed by the government. “Business Week Re¬
ports on: Semiconductors,” Business Week, March 26, 1960, pp. 92-108.
INTRODUCTION 33
Flamm, Creating the Computer, pp. 15-19, 92-94,119-20, 122-23, and Targeting the Com¬
puter, pp. 49-51. See also Misa, “Military Needs,” p. 282, note 59.
47. Note that much of the output of “communications equipment” historically went to
military customers. Also, the rapid increase of semiconductor consumption within the
business services sector in the 1980s probably reflected the explosive growth in demand for
standardized microprocessor memory chips integrated into computer systems by value-add
resellers and computer retailers and probably should be considered a subset of demand for
chips used in computers.
48. See Norman J. Asher and Leland D. Strom, “The Role of the Department of
Defense in the Development of Integrated Circuits,” IDA paper P-1271, Arlington, Va.:
Institute for Defense Analyses, pp. 1-7.
49. In 1962, for example, all ICs produced were used in defense systems. That share
fell to 85 percent in 1964, 53 percent by 1966, and 37 percent by 1968. See Tilton, Inter¬
national Diffusion of Technology, table 4-8.
INTRODUCTION 35
Scientific and measuring instruments 2.1 1.8 1.5 2.4 2.1 10.3
Optical and photo 0.3 0.5 4.9 8.3 13.7 8.8
Misc. manufacturing 0.0 0.4 0.5 0.2 0.3 1.0
Transportation and warehousing 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.3 0.3 0.4
Communications services 0.0 1.4 1.9 4.0 7.5 9.1
missile.50 Awarded in 1960, the contract for this D37 computer—the first
built using ICs—alone accounted for about one-fifth of industry sales in
1965.51 ICs were not shipped in commercial computers until 1965, four
years after the first D37 rolled off the production line.
From 1959 through the late 1960s, military and space contracts pow¬
ered a surge in American IC production. The guidance computer for the
50. Texas Instruments engineers put 94 percent of the computer’s electronics on a set
of thirteen custom-designed integrated circuits. See Richard C. Platzek and Jack S. Kilby,
“Custom-Integrated Circuits—A Military Computer Application,” Proceedings of the IFIP
Congress 65, vol. 2 (Washington: Spartan Books, 1965), pp. 425-26.
51. Asher and Strom, “Role of the Department of Defense,” p. 21.
36 INTRODUCTION
Federal funding
Federal Company as percent
Period funding funding Total of total
early 1980s, climbed back into the 10 percent range in the late 1980s
(table 1-8). However, this number—based on direct sales of chips to
government and to primary and subcontractors building government sys¬
tems—significantly understates government’s total (direct and indirect
purchases) share of the semiconductor market. A calculation using an
input-output table to estimate the semiconductor content of commercial
equipment procured by the government suggests that in the mid-1980s,
purchases by defense agencies alone—direct and indirect—accounted for
over one-quarter of U.S. semiconductor shipments.55
A significant change, however, had occurred in the relationship be¬
tween the military and the semiconductor industry. Whereas in the 1960s
defense systems had ridden at the leading edge of semiconductor tech¬
nology, by the late 1970s they trailed far behind the standard set in a
booming commercial market.56 Perceiving a threat, the military proposed
a program designed to push the technological frontier in semiconductors
and close the gap between military and commercial electronics. The huge
and costly effort, known as VHSIC, the Very High Speed Integrated
Circuit program, accomplished neither objective, but in the process it set
the stage for an important shift in the articulation of objectives for gov¬
ernment investments in semiconductor technology.
55. Computer runs from the Defense Economic Impact Modeling System (DEIMS)
input-output model estimated that defense spending accounted for $274 million in direct
and $3,791 million in indirect consumption of semiconductors in 1986, about 26 percent of
U.S. shipments in that year. See Directorate for Information, Operations, and Reports,
Department of Defense, Projected Defense Purchases, Detail by Industry and State, Cal¬
endar Year 1986 through 1991 (1987), p. 51, and Calendar Year 1991-1997, p. 58. The DEIMS
model shows $66 million in direct and $3,447 million in indirect sales in 1985 (about 21
percent of U.S. shipments) and $206 million and $3,906 million in 1991 (just under 20
percent of U.S. shipments).
56. See John A. Alic and others, Beyond Spinoff: Military and Commercial Technolo¬
gies in a Changing World (Harvard Business School Press, 1992), p. 269, for a perceptive
analysis of this shift.
38 INTRODUCTION
For the first time, the potential impact of an R&D program in im¬
proving the competitiveness of the American industry, although not a
primary goal of Defense Department planners, played an important role
in building political support for the program. The strategic objectives of
U.S. policies affecting semiconductor technology had begun to swing
away from the purely military considerations of the cold war and toward
economic conceptions of a strategic industry or policy. This swing was to
pick up momentum rapidly throughout the 1980s, breaking through an
important political and ideological barrier in 1987 with the formation of
the Sematech (semiconductor manufacturing technology) consortium, a
large-scale R&D effort with explicitly commercial objectives.
Conceived in a moment of crisis for the semiconductor industry, during
the initial months of the Semiconductor Trade Arrangement, Sematech
marked an extraordinary shift in policy for an American administration
for which government intervention was ideological anathema. Although
framed in terms of national security, the Sematech initiative was clearly
intended primarily to improve the health of a broad base of U.S. com¬
mercial semiconductor manufacturers (many of whom also supplied the
Department of Defense). Together with the market share targets accom¬
panying the STA, Sematech constituted a truly radical change in Amer¬
ican policy toward its high-technology industries.
What had brought all this about was the extraordinary development
of the Japanese semiconductor industry in the previous decade. For the
first time, an American postwar high-technology success story—the sem¬
iconductor industry—stood at the brink of decisive competitive defeat at
the hands of a foreign competitor. How this came to be (for the most
part, within the space of a single decade), and how policy responses
articulated in terms of strategic arguments were to become a staple of
American economic debate, is—it shall be argued—one of the most
important episodes in the economic history of the postwar international
system.
CHAPTER TWO
New Competition:
The Japanese Ascent
in Semiconductors
Japanese companies have worked for over forty years to master lead¬
ing edge semiconductor technology. Through the mid-1970s these enter¬
prises lagged several steps behind the pioneering American firms that
had founded the industry. But in less than a decade, by the mid-1980s,
the mantle of overall leadership in semiconductor manufacturing (al¬
though not in design) had clearly passed to Japanese producers, and this
development was accompanied by profound shifts in the marketplace.
The pattern of Japanese investments in semiconductor technology in
many respects resembled that observed in computers.1 As they did in
computers, government laboratories took the first steps in semiconductor
R&D in the early 1950s (although unlike in computers it was small Jap¬
anese firms who rushed the new components to market, embedded in
innovative consumer electronics products). During the 1960s high trade
barriers were put in place, shielding the domestic market. As the private
sector took on more of the burden of technology development, the gov¬
ernment labs shifted toward more long-term projects. As in computers,
a large amount of government aid in the mid-1970s (following the infusion
1. For more details see Kenneth Flamm, Creating the Computer: Government, Industry,
and High Technology (Brookings, 1988), chap. 6; and Targeting the Computer: Government
Support and International Competition (Brookings, 1987), chap. 5.
39
40 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
First Steps
5. For example, two prominent semiconductor technologists left NTT to join Sanyo and
Nippon Electric Corporation in 1957; a senior semiconductor specialist left MITI’s ETL to
join Sony Corporation in 1961. Nearly thirty semiconductor researchers left the NTT labs
in 1962. See Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp. 282-84.
A historically significant research program in semiconductors was also launched at
Tohoku University about this time; Tohoku to this day remains a major academic resource
for the Japanese semiconductor industry.
6. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 286.
7. Under the auspices of a 1949 Joint Services contract to develop transistors for defense
applications, a five-day symposium was convened in September 1951 by Bell Labs and
Western Electric, the manufacturing arm of American Telephone and Telegraph Company
(AT&T), to disseminate information to the military and their contractors, including indus¬
trial and university representatives. Representatives of twenty-two American universities
and eighty-six other American companies attended. Two individuals affiliated with foreign
firms, serving in their governments’ technical liaison offices to U.S. government agencies,
attended this meeting: one came from International Standard Electric, in England, and the
other from the French subsidiary of ITT Corporation.
A second symposium, explicitly designed to teach “the art and science of transistor
technology, theory, and practice as it was known” to commercial licensees was held in April
1952. Representatives of a grand total of thirty-seven firms are known to have either
attended the 1952 Bell Labs technology transfer symposium or signed licensing agreements
with the Bell Labs by the end of 1952. Eleven of these firms were foreign (twelve if one
counts ITT as a foreign-based firm—ITT was U.S.-owned and headquartered but sold its
products in foreign markets). Five were British (Automatic Telephone and Electric, British
Thomson-Houston, General Electric, Pye, and English Electric), four were German (Sie¬
mens and Halske, Telefunken Gesellschaft, Felton and Guilleaume Carlfswerk, and Brush,
an American affiliate of Intermetall), one was Dutch (N.V. Philips), and one Swedish (L.
M. Ericsson). In addition, representatives of three European subsidiaries of ITT attended
the eight-day April 1952 symposium: Laboratoire Centrale de Telecommunications
(France), Standard Telephones and Cables (Britain), and Siiddeutsche Apparatfabrik (Ger¬
many). See F. M. Smits, ed., A History of Engineering and Science in the Bell System, vol.
42 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Instead, it was small Japanese companies, not the giants, who took
the lead with the new technology. The first company to produce a working
transistor was Kobe Kogyo, a small machinery producer,8 whose tech¬
nology chief had come to the United States in 1951 and been introduced
to the new device during visits to RCA and the Bell Labs. A bootleg
research project was started on his return. By the spring of 1952 an
experimental transistor had been built and the needed technology ac¬
quired and licensed from RCA. Hitachi and Toshiba signed licensing
agreements with RCA in that same year. Because of cross-licensing ar¬
rangements between Bell and RCA then in effect, a separate license
from Bell was not required in order to use the basic Bell patents.9 Indeed,
use of patented transistor concepts was initially cheaper via the RCA
channel: the Bell Labs required a $25,000 advance toward future royal¬
ties in exchange for patent rights, while RCA did not.10
RCA’s licensing of its electronic componentry in 1952 was followed by
the transfer of its monochrome television system to its Japanese partners
in 1953.11 RCA was willing to not only sell patent rights, but also actively
transfer know-how. To service its Japanese licensees RCA set up a Tokyo
engineering facility in 1954.12 In 1960 RCA expanded its presence to
include a Japanese research laboratory.13 In 1962 RCA sold rights to its
6: Electronics Technology (1925-75) (Murray Hill: AT&T Bell Laboratories, 1985) pp. 28-
29); Thomas J. Misa, “Military Needs, Commercial Realities, and the Development of the
Transistor, 1948-58,” in Merritt Roe Smith, ed.. Military Enterprise and Technological
Change: Perspectives on the American Experience (MIT Press, 1987), pp. 267-68. Foreign
licensing and seminar participation have been established from unpublished lists contained
in communications from D. S. Hochheiser, AT&T Archives, June 1990 and February 1991;
also John E. Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology: The Case of Semiconductors
(Brookings, 1971), pp. 102, 104, 106. Attendance records for the 1952 symposium may not
be absolutely complete; the only surviving historical record of participation is a series of
group pictures of attendees.
8. Its name had been changed from the Kawanishi Machine Manufacturing Company.
See Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 75.
9. See Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology, p. 77.
10. See William F. E. Long, “Price and Nonprice Practices Under the Uncertain Con¬
ditions of Rapidly Improving Technologies—A Case Study,” Ph.D. dissertation. Depart¬
ment of Economics, George Washington University, June 1967, pp. 24-25. However, pay¬
ment of the $25,000 to Bell entitled early licensees to attend the important April 1952
symposium in which detailed transistor know-how was transferred to them. See also “Busi¬
ness Week Reports On: Semiconductors,” Business Week, March 26, 1960, pp. 93-94.
11. See U.S. Tariff Commission, Television Receivers and Certain Parts Thereof, TC
publication No. 436 (1971), p. 13.
12. See Jack Baranson, The Japanese Challenge to U.S. Industry (Lexington Books,
1981), p. 40.
13. See “RCA Prepares to Open Far East Research Lab,” Electronics, July 24, 1960,
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 43
p. 11. The initial focus of its Japanese research effort was on basic studies of solid state
phenomena.
14. See U.S. Tariff Commission, Telephone Receivers and Certain Parts Thereof, p. 13.
Heavy and Chemical Industries News Agency, Foreign Investments in Japan, 2d ed. (Tokyo,
1967), chap. 5, shows virtually every major Japanese manufacturer of television receivers
and parts signing licensing and technical assistance contracts with RCA in the color tele¬
vision area in 1962.
15. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 97.
16. Ibuka’s contacts were instrumental in initial sales of voltmeters and broadcast
equipment to Japan Broadcasting (NHK), Japan National Railways, and other government
agencies in the early years of the company. See Nick Lyons, The Sony Vision (Crown,
1976), p. 14.
17. See Merton J. Peck and Shuji Tamura, “Technology,” in Hugh Patrick and Henry
Rosovsky, eds., Asia’s New Giant: How the Japanese Economy Works (Brookings, 1976),
p. 535.
44 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
in that year.18 MITI was later to use its control over technological tie-ups
to obstruct entry into the market by other Japanese firms.19
Many early concerns over patent rights were to become moot in 1956.
In that year AT&T signed a consent decree with the U.S. Department
of Justice that required all existing AT&T, Bell Labs, and Western Elec¬
tric transistor patents to be licensed free of charge to all interested do¬
mestic companies. Since Bell Labs had essentially dominated technology
development up to that point, this had the effect of placing the main¬
stream transistor technology of the day—junction transistors—into the
public domain.20
In other respects as well, U.S. semiconductor technologists were rel¬
atively open about permitting Japanese engineers unencumbered access
to their technology in the 1950s and 1960s. One individual posted at a
Japanese trading company’s New York office, for example, estimates that
he made arrangements for visits by approximately 3,000 Japanese elec¬
tronics engineers during a three-year assignment.21 Japanese researchers
also were given free access to American semiconductor research confer¬
ences, and came in large numbers.22 The methods some of these Japanese
visitors used to gather information may have contributed to a certain
degree of resentment visible in later years on the American side.23
engineers involved in the project and so obtained the needed know-how. In another in¬
stance, a former Toshiba researcher described how, forbidden to take notes while visiting a
New York office, he would feign a need to go to the bathroom, where he would write
important points down. He did this so often that those with him thought he had a stomach
ailment. See NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 1, pp. 264-76, which contains material
from this series of NHK documentaries.
24. One of Kobe Kogyo’s engineers, Leo Esaki, moved from Kobe Kogyo to Sony in
1955, where he was to discover the tunnel diode, which earned him a Nobel Prize in 1973
and became Japan’s first significant technical contribution to semiconductor technology.
46 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Transistors Diodes
80,000
50,000
40,000
20,000
Source: Twenty-Year History of the Electronics Industry (Tokyo: Dempa Publications, 1968), p. 110.
a. Manufacturers are Toshiba, Sony, Kobe Kogyo, Hitachi, and NEC. Mitsubishi, Fuji Tsushin, and Matsushita
were engaged in experimental research only.
b. Begins with sale of Sony transistor radios.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 47
Output
Percent of Percent of
United Japanese transistors Japanese transistor
Year States Japan used in radios radios exported
1957 29 6 67 n.a.
1958 47 27 67 n.a.
1959 82 87 55 77
1960 128 140 48 70
1961 191 180 41 67
1962 240 232 34 76
25. These figures are reported in Tilton, International Diffusion of Technology, p. 144.
Japan’s lag in high-performance transistor technology for use in industrial applications
(such as communications equipment) was apparent in an internal battle that took place
within NEC, when it made a decision to support the construction of production facilities
for transistors. Research staff favored the use of indigenously developed transistor tech¬
nology, while manufacturing engineers advocated the use of more advanced American
transistor technology. A bitter conflict was ended in 1957, when NEC’s chairman chose to
go with the American technology. The episode is detailed in Nakagawa, Semiconductor
Development in Japan, pp. 91-93.
48 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
26. See Long, “Price and Nonprice Practices,” pp. 30-36. For a description of the
different techniques, see chapter 1, note 39 of this volume.
27. Takahashi writes that an improved version of a Sony transistor was selected for the
computer (the ETL Mark III) design, but the official history of computer development at
the ETL notes that point-contact transistors imported from the United States were actually
used. See Osamu Ishii, “Research and Development on Information Processing Technology
at Electrotechnical Laboratory: A Historical Review,” vol. 45 (1981), p. 315 [contract
translation by IBRD]; and Shigeru Takahashi, “Early Transistor Computers in Japan,”
Annals of the History of Computing, vol. 8 (April 1986), p. 146.
28. Takahashi, “Early Transistor Computers in Japan,” p. 149; Ishii, “Research and
Development on Information Processing Technology,” p. 315.
29. See Flamm, Creating the Computer, pp. 175-76.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 49
30. As part of its 1956 consent decree, AT&T had agreed to license all existing patents
royalty-free to any domestic company, and not to sell semiconductors in commercial markets
(that is, excluding defense and space applications).
31. On Japanese consumer electronics exports see “Japan Boosts TV Set Output,”
Electronics, February 26,1960, p. 48; “Japanese TV Sets Arriving This Week,” Electronics,
April 29, 1960, p. 32; “Sales and Imports of Radio-TV Rise,” Electronics, May 19, 1961,
p. 12; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Domestic Commerce, The U.S. Con¬
sumer Electronics Industry (1975), pp. 8-9, 11. On calculators see U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of Domestic Commerce, The Impact of Electronics on the U.S. Cal¬
culator Industry, 1965 to 1974 (November 1975), pp. 13-15,44; and Badiul Alam Majumdar,
Innovations, Product Developments, and Technology Transfers: An Empirical Study of
Dynamic Competitive Advantage, The Case of Electronic Calculators (University Press of
America, 1982), chap. 5.
50 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Percent
100
80
60
40
20
0
1955 1960 1965
which they were incorporated. There was a sharp decline in the share of
transistors for consumer applications (mainly germanium for most of this
period) in U.S. output, in terms of both value and quantity; this decline
coincided with the Japanese push into consumer electronics exports that
began after 1957.
Relatively more of U.S. output shifted into higher performance tran¬
sistor types used in industrial applications, especially the recently intro¬
duced silicon transistors.32 Rapidly declining costs made the new silicon
32. Over this period the principal performance difference between transistors for the
consumer market and those for the industrial market was the ability to operate at high
frequencies. Transistors made using grown or alloy junction technology generally operated
at low frequencies, while transistors manufactured using newer diffused base techniques
operated at much higher frequencies. Virtually all consumer applications required only
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 51
Figure 2-3. Value of U.S. Transistor Production, by Type, 1955-65
Percent
transistors more attractive for low-end applications over time, and some
resurgence by American producers in the market for consumer-use tran¬
sistors was evident by the mid-1960s. In a pattern that was to recur later,
the United States passed Japan in transistor output in the early 1960s as
demand shifted to more technically advanced silicon transistors. Japan
then raced to catch up in the new technology, ultimately surpassing the
United States again in total transistors produced in the late 1960s. This
phenomenon—of new technology providing the basis for improved com¬
petitive performance by American producers vis-a-vis foreign rivals man-
33. The Electronics Industry Promotion Law (Denshinho) was actually preceded by a
Law on Temporary Measures for the Promotion of Specified Manufacturing Industries in
1956, which, like the 1957 electronics law, provided for low-interest loans from the Japan
Development Bank (JDB) for investments in modernization and technology within selected
industrial sectors. Machine tools, auto parts, and other basic machinery were among the
nonelectronic sectors enjoying favored access to JDB capital. From 1956 through 1960
slightly less than 10.6 billion yen in loans was extended to these sectors. This compares
with 2.2 billion yen in loans to the consumer electronics sector granted over the seven years
from 1957 through 1963.
The Specified Manufacturing Industries Law was renewed in 1961 and again in 1966,
expiring in 1971. The Small Business Finance Corporation (SBFC) joined the JDB in
providing subsidized credit to the machinery industry, with loans extended by these two
institutions amounting to 53.8 billion yen over 1961-65, and 48.9 billion yen over 1966-70.
In 1964 the electronics law was extended for another seven years. Loans over this period
amounted to 12.1 billion yen, with the bulk of the funds going into electronic components.
In 1971 the electronics and machinery industry laws were combined into a single mea-
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 53
sure, the Law on Temporary Measures for the Promotion of Specified Electronics Industries
and Specified Machinery Industries (Kidenho). Over the seven years through 1977, the
electronics industry received approximately 20 percent of some 70.6 billion yen in loans
under the new law. In 1978 this measure was revised and extended as the Law on Temporary
Measures for the Promotion of Specified Machinery and Information Industries (Kijoho).
Loans from the SBFC and the JDB amounted to approximately 11 billion yen per year,
with approximately 80 percent going into electronics.
See Seiritsu Ogura and Naoyuki Yoshino, “The Tax System and the Fiscal Investment
and Loan Program,” in Ryutaro Komiya, Masahiro Okuno, and Kotaro Suzumura, eds.,
Industrial Policy of Japan (Academic Press, 1988), pp. 147-48.
34. The 1957 Denshinho law was extended in 1964, then followed by the 1971 Kidenho
law, which in turn was followed by the 1978 Kijoho (see the previous note.) Although the
Kijoho expired in 1985, another law, the Josokuho (established in 1960, amended to include
many new provisions for investment subsidies, and reenacted in 1986) provides legal au¬
thority for many of the sorts of subsidies to the computer and semiconductor industries
granted under the Kijoho. All recent JDB investments in information technology and
related industries, for example, have been made under the framework of the Josokuho.
See Japan Electronic Computer Corporation (JECC), Computer Notes (Tokyo, 1989), pp.
62-63 (in Japanese).
35. See Koji Shinjo, “The Computer Industry,” p. 342; and Ogura and Yoshino, “The
Tax System,” in Komiya and others, eds., Industrial Policy of Japan, p. 147.
36. See Komiya, “Introduction,” in Komiya and others, eds., Industrial Policy of Japan,
54 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
(JDB), and later from its sister institutions, for initial production and
subsequent capacity expansion in specified products.37 The third type of
support provided additional JDB loans and special depreciation breaks
where “industrial rationalization”—that is, improvements in quality or
production technology—was desirable.38 The law also authorized selec¬
tive exemption from the antimonopoly law, allowing MITI to establish
research and production cartels.39
Although semiconductor-related R&D and production rationalization
were thus supported virtually from the start, the resources applied to
these ends were clearly quite small.40 All electronics-related R&D sub¬
sidies averaged a little over 230 million yen (just under $650,000) per
year during the seven-year period ending in fiscal 1963. Similarly, JDB
loans to the electronics industry accounted for an annual average of
324 million yen (about $900,000) over the same period.41 As previously
remarked, funding mainly went into consumer electronics—only a small
portion of these funds was applied to semiconductors.
In contrast, subsidized JDB loans to other machinery industries auth¬
orized by similar legislation amounted to over 2 billion yen per year over
1956-60, and almost 11 billion yen annually over 1961-65. Thus, the
“temporary measures” of 1957 initially led to only minimal new subsidies
for semiconductors. More important, perhaps, was the rigorous policy of
37. It is frequently argued that, in addition to the funds themselves, and the signal to
invest in the promoted sector provided to highly regulated private financial institutions
(which was quite significant in the capital-short Japanese economy of the 1960s, but less so
in the late 1970s and 1980s) or the direct subsidy element in loans at below-market rates,
these funds provided an implicit government guarantee for private sector loans to these
sectors.
38. This discussion follows Shinjo, “The Computer Industry,” p. 342.
39. MITI is reported to have used this law to block entry into semiconductors by some
Japanese latecomers, including Sanyo Electric. See Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development
in Japan, pp. 101-03.
The authority to sanction legal cartels in electronics was not often invoked. Over the
years 1957-70 some six legal “rationalization” cartels were established under the auspices
of the Electronics Industry Promotion Law: three over the period 1964-66 and three over
the period 1969-70. This compares with some 114 established in machinery under the
machinery promotion law over the same period. See Yutaka Kosai, “The Reconstruction
Period,” in Komiya and others, eds., Industrial Policy of Japan, p. 47.
40. Categories of products that were promoted, and the years over which the support
extended, are shown in Badiul A. Majumdar, “Industrial Policy in Action: The Case of the
Electronics Industry in Japan,” Columbia Journal of World Business, vol. 23 (Fall 1988),
pp. 27-29.
41. Majumdar, “Industrial Policy in Action,” p. 30-31.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 55
42. See Motoshige Itoh and Kazuharu Kiyono, “Foreign Trade and Direct Investment,”
in Komiya and others, eds., Industrial Policy of Japan, pp. 147, 160.
43. Other elements included the Export Trade Control Law (ETCL), the Import Trade
Control Law (ITCL), and the rules of the “Standard Method of Payments” governing
imports. On the operation of these measures, see Lawrence Krause and Sueo Sekiguchi,
“Japan and the World Economy,” in Patrick and Rosovsky, eds., Asia’s New Giant, pp.
411-27, 451-52; Mark Mason, American Multinationals and Japan: The Political Economy
of Japanese Capital Controls, 1899-1980 (Harvard University Press, 1992), pp. 159-61; and
Dennis J. Encarnation, Rivals Beyond Trade: America versus Japan in Global Competition
(Cornell University Press, 1992), pp. 46-50.
44. On the mechanics of how this system was used, see Mason, American Multinationals
and Japan, pp. 154-61; Encarnation, Rivals Beyond Trade, pp. 47-50.
45. See Terutomo Ozawa, Japan's Technological Challenge to the West, 1950-1974: Mo¬
tivation and Accomplishment (MIT Press, 1974), pp. 16-24, 52—66; and Peck and Tamura,
“Technology,” 544-58.
56 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
the foreign exchange control system had evolved into a broad system of
MITI-administered import quotas. Mounting foreign criticism led to Ja¬
pan’s first steps toward trade liberalization at the end of the 1950s, when
257 commodities, covering 44 percent of all Japanese imports, were first
freed from licensing requirements.46 The 1960 program of Trade and
Exchange Liberalization Guidelines initially considered selected elec¬
tronics items for liberalization, but MITI later withdrew electronics goods
from the list of items to be liberalized.47
Tight control over foreign imports of and investment in semiconductors
was maintained throughout the 1950s and early 1960s. The limitations on
investment were particularly important in ICs, products that often re¬
quired considerable technical support from manufacturers. Without a
local subsidiary to provide that support to customers or distributors, an
effective sales effort was difficult, if not impossible.
In 1962, for example, Robert N. Noyce, then one of the key technical
figures at Fairchild Semiconductor and co-inventor (with Jack S. Kilby of
Texas Instruments) of the integrated circuit, visited Japan to arrange an
investment in a local production facility and discuss the sale of licenses
to use Fairchild’s key patents to Japanese firms.48 (Together, the TI and
Fairchild patents were the key intellectual properties at the center of the
emerging IC market.)
Noyce, and Fairchild, were completely outmaneuvered in their initial
foray into the Japanese market. MITI flatly refused to permit Fairchild
to invest in its own Japanese factory. Frustrated, Noyce then contacted
an NEC executive he had met in the United States at a defense semicon¬
ductor conference,49 complained about MITI’s reaction, and set about
negotiating with NEC over patent rights. Informed of the need for NEC
to secure approval of the terms from MITI, Fairchild was pressured to
reduce its royalties and fees; only later did the U.S. company discover
46. Krause and Sekiguchi, “Japan and the World Economy,” p. 414.
47. See “Japanese Put Off Freeing Electronics Imports,” Electronics, July 8, 1960,
p. 11. The initial, “temporary” delay of three years was to stretch into sixteen years;
quantitative restrictions were not completely removed from electronics imports until 1976.
48. This episode is described in Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan,
pp. 135-40.
49. Noyce apparently met Mr. Naganuma, the NEC executive, at a conference de¬
scribed in NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 2, pp. 253-56: the U.S. Navy-sponsored
Semiconductor Devices Research Conference, held in Boulder, Colorado. Although the
conference was closed to the general public, some foreign engineers including Naganuma
were allowed to attend.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 57
that NEC’s own president also chaired the MITI licensing approval ad¬
visory committee responsible for this decision!50
A deal was finally struck in 1963. Noyce negotiated an exclusive license
with NEC for patent rights in the Japanese market. The agreement so
completely transferred the Japanese rights to Fairchild’s IC technology
to NEC that it was later used to block attempts by Fairchild to set up a
Japanese sales office. NEC also charged other Japanese companies for
their use of covered technologies. It was a poor deal for Fairchild, but it
reflected the then-prevailing climate for foreign investors in Japan. That
same year, TI began its attempt to enter the Japanese market, and took
a much tougher bargaining stance. But TI was not to gain even a small
degree of access to the Japanese market until half a decade later, in 1968,
after an exhausting battle.
Through 1963 only seven foreign semiconductor producers had been
permitted to invest in the Japanese market, in all cases through joint
ventures in which they held a minority interest, and in all cases with
extensive transfer of technical know-how a part of the deal. Four of these
ventures were broad tie-ups in electrical equipment and electronics,
which also covered semiconductors. Over the period from 1952 through
1962 the Dutch company Philips NV had acquired a 35 percent interest
in Matsushita Electronics, the semiconductor-producing affiliate of Mat¬
sushita.51 From 1953 to 1960 ITT’s International Standard Electric sub¬
sidiary had increased its holdings in NEC to 17.7 percent. General Electric
(GE) had built up a 5.6 percent interest in Toshiba from 1953 to 1959.52
Three new ventures were exclusively concerned with semiconductors.
From 1957 to 1961 International Rectifier had established a 39 percent
stake in Nippon International Rectifier. In 1961 Raytheon Company had
invested in New Japan Radio, a semiconductor-producing joint venture
with Japan Radio (Raytheon’s share had increased to 33 percent by 1963).
In 1962 Mitsubishi TRW (with a 20 percent stake held by TRW Incor¬
porated, and another 20 percent held by Pacific Semiconductor) and
50. See Mason, American Multinationals and Japan, pp. 196, 325. Mason’s account is
based on interviews with Noyce and then-executive vice president of Fairchild, Richard
Hodgson.
51. This equity was finally sold back to Matsushita in 1993. See Douglas R. Sease,
“Abreast of the Market: With Confusing Results for 1st Quarter, It Isn’t Surprising the
Market Is Stalled,” Wall Street Journal, May 3, 1993, p. Cl.
52. See Heavy and Chemical Industry News Agency, Foreign Investment in Japan,
pp. 375, 377.
58 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
53. See Heavy and Chemical Industry News Agency, Foreign Investments in Japan,
chap. 5. See also Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD),
Electronic Components, Gaps in Technology (Paris, 1968), p. 186.
54. Mason, American Multinationals in Japan, p. 176.
55. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp. 125-27. TI then reportedly
joined other U.S. semiconductor producers in petitioning for restrictions on Japanese
transistor imports, in what appears to have been the first trade policy initiative taken by
the U.S. chip industry (discussed in chapter 3).
56. More details and an analysis of this episode may be found in Flamm, Creating the
Computer, pp. 180-82; Mason, American Multinationals in Japan, pp. 187-91; and Marie
Anchordoguy, Computers Inc.: Japan’s Challenge to IBM (Harvard University Press, 1989),
pp. 22-24.
57. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 154.
58. The most complete account of this affair from the American side may be found in
Mason, American Multinationals in Japan, pp. 176-87. Mason was given access to the TI
corporate archives in preparing his research.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 59
59. It is interesting to note that in Mason’s account from the U.S. perspective (Amer¬
ican Multinationals in Japan, p. 180) the Japanese industry is portrayed as pressuring MITI
to resist TI’s demands. In Nakagawa’s version (Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp.
154-66), told from a Japanese perspective, MITI is credited with having a long-range vision
of a competitive threat that the domestic industry did not yet see, and organizing an industry
all too prone to cutting individual deals on the side with TI. According to Nakagawa,
Hitachi, Mitsubishi, and Toshiba all held secret talks with TI. According to Mason
(p. 323), Matsushita attempted to cut its own deal through Philips, which had an equity
share in (as noted above) and extensive cross-licensing arrangements with Matsushita
Electronics.
60. See Flamm, Creating the Computer, chap. 6.
61. The project spent a total of 1.126 billion yen, of which 787 million yen was provided
by the participating companies (NEC, Fujitsu, and Oki). The Computer Technology Re¬
search Association in which these companies joined together as members was not actually
dissolved until 1973. Thirty Year History of Mining and Manufacturing Industry Technology
Research Associations (Tokyo: Japan Industry Technology Promotion Association, 1991),
p. 70. See also Shinjo, “The Computer Industry,” p. 343.
60 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
62. Actually, the IBM computers did not use true “monolithic” (that is, etched from a
single piece of silicon) ICs. Discrete semiconductor components were instead bonded to a
ceramic substrate to form so-called hybrid ICs. Although competitors were to soon intro¬
duce computers using true monolithic ICs, the IBM System 360 line nonetheless marked a
significant step forward in the sophistication of components used in commercial computers.
63. See Martin Fransman, The Market and Beyond: Cooperation and Competition in
Information Technology Development in the Japanese System (Cambridge University Press,
1992); and Charles Cohen, “Japanese Components Men Stress Integrated Circuits and
Diodes,” Electronics, May 4,1962, pp. 20-21. Mitsubishi brashly announced the availability
of a complete line of ICs in 1961 but was unable to produce a functioning complete circuit
until 1964. See Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp. 130-35; NHK, Elec¬
tronics-Based Nation, vol. 3, pp. 83-93.
64. However, Mitsubishi’s early IC effort was driven by contracts from the Japan Self
Defense Agency to downsize communications equipment. NHK, Electronics-Based Nation,
vol. 3, p. 92.
65. Yasuo Tarui, “Japan Seeks Its Own Route to Improved IC Techniques,” Electronics,
December 13, 1965, pp. 90-98. The funds were made available to the “big six” of the
Japanese computer industry: Fujitsu, Hitachi, Toshiba, NEC, Oki, and Mitsubishi.
66. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 158.
67. “Onward and Upward,” Electronics, October 3, 1966, p. 257.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 61
68. The five Japanese companies were Toko, Nippon Chemical Condensor, Koden Elec¬
tronics, Pioneer Electronics, and Alps Electric. See Tarui, “Japan Seeks Its Own Route,”
p. 91. Jacobs owned 25 percent of the venture’s equity and received additional compensation
for technical assistance. See Heavy and Chemical Industries News Agency, Foreign Invest¬
ments in Japan, 2d ed., pp. 48, 372.
69. See “Onward and Upward,” pp. 257-58.
70. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 280. By late 1966 only NEC,
Kyodo Electronic Laboratories, and Fujitsu were producing ICs (in small quantities);
Hitachi and Toshiba had just completed manufacturing facilities. “Onward and Upward,”
pp. 257-58.
71. “Onward and Upward,” pp. 257-58.
72. In figure 2-4, IC exports from the United States by captive producers such as IBM
and the U.S. affiliates of Japanese companies (growing rapidly since the 1980s) are counted
as imports, while production by Japanese affiliates of U.S. companies, such as TI, IBM,
and Motorola, are counted as domestic output.
73. For more detailed references to MITI projects in computer technology development
and their outcomes over this period, see Flamm, Creating the Computer, pp. 184-92.
62 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Percent
Sources: Pre-1970 measures of IC production from Machinery Promotion Association Economic Research Institute,
Japan-US Semiconductor Industry Research Survey (Tokyo, 1980), p. 114. Post-1970 production data from Research
and Statistics Department. MIT1, Yearbook of Machinery Statistics, various years. Import data from Japan Tariff
Association, Japan Exports and Imports, Commodity by Country (Tokyo, various years). Import share of consumption
is defined as value of imports divided by apparent consumption (Value of production plus value of imports less value
of exports). Hybrids were not a separate category in trade data until 1989. Hybrids are excluded in production data
only.
a. April 1966: ban on foreign ICs with more than 34 circuit elements.
b. September 1970: Liberalization of ICs with less than 100 elements.
c. Late 1971: MITI crackdown on LSI IC import licenses.
d. 1973: removal of licensing of ICs with less than 200 elements.
e. December 25, 1974: liberalization of IC imports with more than 200 elements.
f. 1975: liberalization of computer ICs.
g. U.S.-Japan Semiconductor Trade Arrangement.
74. Yasuo Tarui, “ICs in Japan—a CloseupElectronics, May 13, 1968, p. 106. Al¬
though there is no exact definition, medium-scale integration (MSI) generally is taken to
mean ICs with up to 1,000 circuit elements, while very large scale integration (VLSI) devices
have up to 100,000 circuit elements.
75. MITI’s ETL, which directed the project, developed a metal oxide semiconductor
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 63
(MOS) device structure known as the diffusion self-aligned (DSA) circuit, which producers
used extensively in following years. The first Japanese IC memory, a 144-bit static random
access memory (RAM) chip, was developed by ETL and manufactured by NEC in 1968.
An electron beam exposure system was developed in cooperation with JEOL, now the top
supplier of electron beam production equipment to the semiconductor industry. This system
was the very first such machine developed by JEOL; the second and third systems built
were shipped to Sanyo and Toshiba. A step-and-repeat photolithographic system using laser
alignment was built by Nikon for ETL as part of this project. This design was later used in
the very first commercial wafer stepper system built by Nikon, which was to become a top
supplier of such machines to IC makers a decade later. Author’s interview with Yasuo Tarui,
director of the MITI VLSI project, March 18, 1992; Osamu Ishii, “Research and Devel¬
opment”; and Machinery Promotion Association Economic Research Institute, Japan-U.S.
Semiconductor Research Survey (Tokyo, 1980), p. 30.
76. See Flamm, Creating the Computer, pp. 189-90, notes 43-44.
77. See note 34.
78. These statistics capture only lending to industry under the Electronics Industry
Promotion Law and exclude funds borrowed under the auspices of other measures.
s: ^ §
o
2 §
s: sc in
d ■se.
«0 r^ <u
<N g I'
cl .5 3 ^
to -*2 E
« 2 3 -«
3 2
U CO
o 55
53
u.
3 os
o >s
^ ?
■o 3
= T3
, ^ vd
O v. SC
§ 2 •
go —
a . cn SO
J5 ^ a-
. \6 d m 2 o O'
s c in
(N
•—
w 5—
£ S 2
i^I
' ^ ca
Table 2-2. FILP Loans to Japanese Machinery and Electronics Industries, 1956-84
“ CD “
i g ■§
&
* Q§.£
f. Lending was mainly to auto parts manufacturers (within machinery) and integrated circuit producers (within electronics).
P^.g.
«U E
cs
cn (N , «
: 5 : : (N r-
r- :Q
- 3 .
cS't*
«- C O
y
E a !
2 ^1
M S3 !
2 a: •
CL O
I31 cn o vo o 00 iJ
I c d i-H ^-H d (N 00 :
^ a
a> «-
§-e;
d. A major proportion of this lending went to electronic components manufacturers.
^ <
— c
h On (N
e. Japan Development Bank lending specifically budgeted for electronics.
(N VO E I1
<N <n d d JS S'
e9 vo
■O ^
c. Period saw a rapid increase in loans to auto parts manufacturers.
c ^ >%
CS flj a> TJ
> o
E.S. _ t-
_C 3
<l> jr
o
00
</5
o
CO -E
X LT a. o
c2
H 22
'f
£P « oo (N
D oo •-s s<u
■o 2 3
£ s
*
• d
°°.
ov (N
.c
H "! <u -Sr "E
> o ^
rrs sa
<U
VC
: Cl
« 2 «
‘o
0)
O ^
3 “^ u.- £3
o
Cl
is
sf 1
S® •E c<u <*-o
15 $ X) -,-3 O
3 £ 3
Q. «2
— CO
(#i
U.
o 0-
CO O § £
C. T33
o
-C vo f— ^
*E
vj QJ '— o
d m
in
oo VO in C -o ^ 3 a.
C/5 fc-
*5 m CO CO
i= s
i< S » ^
"c <U O c
3 S o -J5
C
<u £^ 9- <u
^ C
^
<u
>5 cE jj
a -C O -o 1) 1> /) Ci.w 3 ^
O
VO
cn IX)
VO vo
o
r-
O
r-
GO
NO
o r-
r-
^ ^ C
00
■^3 i
l i
i ii i i
i 1 8^-:^ §
3 >,CC f- J
•2 vO i-H vo '-t OV i-H 00
l! iX) IX) vo vo vO s VO r- r- o .VJ O'
co
CQ On
Ov On Ov
’“H
Ov On Ov
t-H
Ov On
i-H
Ov " 2S
CL
d.
CL
^
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 65
Billions of yen
Sources: Electronic Industry Almanac, 1975 (Tokyo: Dempa Publications, 1974), p. 176; and Machinery Promotion
Association Economic Research Institute, Japan-US Semiconductor Industry Research Survey, pp. 98, 119.
55 percent),79 the tax benefits would also have been quite large. However,
this special depreciation was spread over all qualifying electronics-related
investments (including the computer industry), not just ICs—unfortu¬
nately, further disaggregation is not possible.
Figure 2-5 also compares JDB loans in electronics with investment in
IC facilities. Again, subsidized loans are relatively large in relation to
investments. Like the special tax breaks, the JDB loans also went to
electronics firms making products other than ICs, but we do know that
the largest share of the funding after 1964 did go to IC producers. Also,
since the JDB was not the only public lender to the industry under the
auspices of the Electronics Industry Promotion Law, other relevant sub¬
sidized loans are not being captured in this figure.
In contrast to depreciation benefits and loan subsidies, MITI R&D
subsidies to electronics under the Electronics Industry Promotion Law
were much less important. Figure 2-6 compares all electronics R&D
subsidies with IC-related R&D spending by major Japanese producers.
If it is recalled that significant R&D subsidies in semiconductors began
only after 1965, it is clear that these monies could not have been partic¬
ularly large in relation to spending levels within the industry. However,
these R&D subsidies capture only MITI monies spent under the Elec¬
tronics Industry Promotion Law—they do not cover large-scale national
R&D projects, internal funding of the ETL, or funding provided under
other statutes. Nonetheless, it is probably reasonable to suggest that for
semiconductors in the 1960s, in the aggregate, tax breaks and subsidized
loans, and not R&D subsidies, were the most significant instrument for
MITI’s promotion of the semiconductor industry.
In fact, R&D subsidies in semiconductors seem to have been focused
on relatively narrow themes, and principally on supporting national pol¬
icy in computers. But while the big ticket semiconductor R&D projects
were in digital ICs and were clearly designed to strengthen the Japanese
computer industry, now at the center of MITI’s electronics strategy, some
resources went into ICs oriented toward other applications. Analog cir¬
cuits for use in communications and consumer electronics were funded
at Fujitsu, Toshiba, Hitachi, Shiba Electric, Nippon Columbia, NEC,
Matsushita, and Toyo Communication Equipment in the latter part of
the 1960s.80 A MITI-funded consortium of five television manufacturers,
79. See Ogura and Yoshino. “Tax System and the Fiscal Investment and Loan Pro¬
gram,” p. 126.
80. Tarui, "ICs in Japan," p. 103.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 67
Billions of yen
81. The joint research group included Osaka Onkyo, Hayakawa Electric (later renamed
Sharp), Matsushita Electric, Mitsubishi Electric, Sanyo Electric, Elna-Fox Electronics,
Hoshi Electric, Kobe Industrial, Matsuo Electric, Murata Manufacturing, Nichicon Capac¬
itor, Sodensha, and Osaka University. See Eizi Sugata and Tashihiko Namekawa, “Inte¬
grated Circuits for Television Receivers,” IEEE Spectrum, May 1969, p. 74.
82. “Japan: LSI Calculator,” Electronics, November 11, 1968, p. 307.
68 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
calculator chips for its LSI research.83 This push into calculators, indeed,
was integral to the next major twist in the saga of Japanese semiconductor
development.
Just as the Japanese electronics industry was faced with new and po¬
tentially devastating changes in its global competitive environment, Texas
Instruments’ stalled 1964 application to enter the Japanese market flared
up into a hot dispute. Tensions had escalated in mid-1965 when TI’s
Japanese investment applications were published, some five years after
their initial filing.84 All Japanese semiconductor producers opted to op¬
pose the TI application, and the “patent war” began in earnest. But
whereas most Japanese chip makers were apparently willing to make
some sort of deal, NEC—armed with its exclusive Japanese rights to the
Fairchild IC patents—opted for an aggressive legal counterattack in
Japan.
By 1966, however, Japanese firms had begun to eye the United States
as a market for a new generation of consumer electronic products con¬
taining ICs. In the fall of 1966, after beginning shipments of a new radio
containing ICs, Sony was forced to discontinue sales by the threat of
patent infringement suits from TI.85 In that same year, Hayakawa Electric
(Sharp) began to mass-produce calculators.86 The product appeared to
have enormous export potential but would be vulnerable to legal attack
83. Mitsubishi decided, however, not to commercialize these experimental chips, and
Sharp began to talk to foreign suppliers. The linkups with foreign suppliers of LSI
chip sets for calculators are described below. “Japan: LSI Calculator,” p. 308; and NHK,
Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 3, p. 233.
84. Full patent rights were not granted to TI until 1989 (although some limited patent
rights were approved in 1977). Andy Zipser, “Texas Instruments Gets Japanese Patent;
Analysts See Sizable Addition to Revenue,” Wall Street Journal, November 22, 1989,
p. 1A.
85. Mason, American Multinationals in Japan, pp. 183-84.
86. Sharp’s entry into calculators was closely linked to MITI policy. In the early 1960s
Sharp had actually developed a prototype transistorized computer system but, on advice
from MITI, decided not to enter the business. MITI instead had suggested that Sharp make
smaller products using digital logic designs that could be mass-produced. By 1964 Sharp
had developed its first transistorized calculator. Commercialization of desktop calculators
was encouraged with subsidized loans in 1964-65; further investments in production facil¬
ities for calculators using ICs were made eligible for subsidized loans and special deprecia¬
tion benefits from 1966 to 1970. See NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 3, pp. 129-39;
and Majumdar, “Industrial Policy in Action,” pp. 28-29.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 69
in the United States, where TI’s IC patents were recognized. These fears
were realized when TI warned Sharp about patent violations in 1967.
MITI, alarmed by the threat to exports, finally responded to TI in
August 1966 on its 1964 application for a Japanese affiliate. MITI offered
to permit an equal partnership with a Japanese firm, provided that TI
also agreed to license its patents to Japanese companies at reasonable
rates and accept MITI restrictions on its output in the first three years
of production.87 TI turned down the offer. MITI nonetheless reportedly
began to work on persuading NEC to drop its adamant opposition to the
TI patents, and the agency secretly began to search for a possible Japa¬
nese joint venture partner for TI.88
Mitsubishi, supplier of the ICs used in the Sharp calculator (and the
largest producer of calculator ICs in Japan), was extremely concerned,
and the company sent a team to Texas to seek a solution to the Sharp-TI
patent conflict.89 Mitsubishi was particularly interested in a solution in¬
volving some manufacturing tie-up with TI because of its own weakness
in leading edge semiconductor technology compared with other Japanese
semiconductor producers.90 Mitsubishi made some new and interesting
proposals to TI and offered advice on negotiations with MITI, fully
expecting that it would emerge with a new relationship with TI.91
At this point, however, MITI intervened. Rather than simply continue
the exchange with Mitsubishi, TI’s negotiating team in Tokyo was asked
to speak with other Japanese companies. Sony soon came forward with
a proposal for a temporary 50-50 joint venture under TI control, to be
converted into a wholly owned affiliate at a later date, in exchange for
giving Japanese firms the license to use the TI patent portfolio. MITI
quickly agreed to go along with the Sony proposal. Mitsubishi was
shocked to learn it had been unceremoniously dumped; from the TI
perspective, it was all rather mysterious.92
tial boost in the mid-1960s.96 By 1969 imports accounted for less than a
quarter of apparent Japanese IC consumption (see figure 2-4). But as it
had before, rapid technological change was to again threaten these gains
in domestic makers’ market share.
Calculator sales had expanded rapidly in the late 1960s, and continued
development of this product led to the next major crisis for the struggling
Japanese semiconductor industry. In the late 1960s the technological focus
was on replacing the relatively large number of chips in current models
with a much small number of more highly integrated LSI chips. In the
United States the production technology for LSI had developed rapidly,
and American semiconductor manufacturers were sweeping world mar¬
kets with low-cost LSI products.
Japanese semiconductor producers initially had a great deal of diffi¬
culty mastering LSI technology; they were also strapped financially by
the cost of investing in the whole new generation of production facilities
required to produce the more advanced chips. An advanced fabrication
technology, MOS (metal oxide semiconductor) technology, was also be¬
coming important in the manufacture of LSI chips, but the production
process for MOS devices was very demanding. Japanese chip makers
lagged well behind American companies in mastering it.97 The costs of
using patents owned by American chip makers put Japanese producers
at a further competitive disadvantage, forced to pay about 10 percent of
sales as royalties to their American competitors.98
96. My account in this section for the most part closely follows those of Nakagawa,
Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp. 190-205, and NHK, Electronics-Based Nation,
vol. 3, pp. 264-316, which are only available in Japanese.
A radically different Japanese view of the strength and behavior of Japanese semicon¬
ductor companies at the time of the “calculator wars” of the late 1960s and early 1970s has
also appeared in the English-language literature. Note, in particular, the view expressed
by Takuo Sugano (University of Tokyo) and Michiyuki Uenohara (NEC): “the Japanese
coauthors assert that Japanese companies were ready sooner than the Americans to under¬
take large-scale commercial production of MOS ICs. NEC foresaw a potential mass market
for the desk-top calculator, and, in cooperation with Hayakawa (the predecessor of Sharp),
developed calculators using MOS ICs. They completed a commercial model in 1966, and
the success of this venture helped to establish the practicality of the MOS IC.” Michiyuki
Uenohara, Takuo Sugano, John G. Linvill, and Franklin B. Weinstein, “Background,” in
Daniel I. Okimoto and others, eds., Competitive Edge: The Semiconductor Industry in the
U.S. and Japan (Stanford University Press, 1984), p. 15.
97. See, for example, NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 3, p. 311; U.S. Department
of Commerce, Global Market Survey: Electronic Components (1974), pp. 5-6, 81-82;
Franco Malerba, The Semiconductor Business: The Economics of Rapid Growth and De¬
cline (Frances Pinter, 1985), pp. 100-02, 151-52.
98. “IC Makers Shaken at the Dawn of IC Liberalization: Request for 7 Billion Yen
72 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Subsidy and the Rush to Establish Their Own Technology for Mass Production,“ Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, April 18, 1973.
99. A famous story often told in Japan relates how the chief executive of Sharp visited
the United States in 1968 to work out an arrangement for an American chip company to
supply MOS LSI chips needed in its new calculator designs. He visited eleven manufactur¬
ers, including Fairchild, TI, Motorola, AMI, National Semiconductor, RCA, Philco, and
Sylvania. All rejected his proposal, because the volumes he required were too high for
their current capacity, which was largely tied up with defense production. Finally, just as
he was leaving the United States, executives at North American Rockwell had him paged
at the Los Angeles airport, to tell him they had reconsidered their initial decision to reject
his request and would work with him. The details of this story may be found in Nakagawa,
Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 192; NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 3,
p. 264. The Rockwell-Sharp collaboration was to continue well into the early 1970s. See
“How to Cut a Pocket Calculator in Half,” Electronics, February 1, 1971, p. 104. Other
Japanese calculator makers quickly followed Sharp in striking deals with American chip
suppliers. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 192.
100. Machinery Promotion Association Economic Research Institute, Japan-U.S. Sem¬
iconductor Industry Research Survey, p. 30.
101. See Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, p. 195; NHK, Electronics-
Based Nation, vol. 3, pp. 264-316.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 73
102. Arthur Erikson and Charles Cohen, “Japanese Electronics Firms Search Out New
Markets to Pierce Economic Fog,” Electronics, November 22, 1971, p. 132.
103. See NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 3, pp. 318-21; and Robert N. Noyce and
Marcian E. Hoff Jr., “A History of Microprocessor Development at Intel,” IEEE Micro,
vol. 1 (February 1981), pp. 9-13.
104. “Cheap IC Selling by U.S. Firms Posing Problem; Dumping Mooted,” Japan
Economic Journal, September 29, 1970, as excerpted in Semiconductor Industry Associa¬
tion (SIA), Japanese Protection and Promotion of the Semiconductor Industry: Japanese
Laws, Government and Industry Documents, and Press Reports Relating to Japan’s Pro¬
motion of Its Semiconductor Industry, 1967-85 (Washington: Dewey, Ballantine, Bushby,
Palmer and Wood, 1985).
105. Similar devastation in the market for standard logic occurred in Europe, where
this was the period of the so-called logic wars. A price war broke out among American
chip makers, inflicting a severe blow to European producers struggling to stay abreast of
their American competition. See Malerba, The Semiconductor Business, pp. 110-19.
74 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
In the latter part of 1970 MITI and the Ministry of Finance launched
informal investigations of possible American dumping of ICs in Japan.
The intent was apparently to put pressure on American producers to
mute unwanted price competition with Japanese manufacturers; officials
suggested to reporters that a “dumping charge may rise to the surface if
the cheap sale of ICs continues further.”106 The tough talk apparently had
little effect on the hardheaded Americans; within months a continuing
“low price offensive” by the American producers had forced Japanese
producers to cut back production of these chips by 20 percent.107 By early
1972 MITI was even floating the idea of a rationalization cartel covering
logic ICs with fewer than 100 elements, but this apparently went no¬
where.108
Meanwhile, even at the protected high end of the market—for highly
integrated calculator LSI chips—product-starved Japanese calculator
manufacturers braved MITI’s wrath and red tape and fought for the right
to import needed inputs. The issue, quite simply, was survival. U.S. IC
manufacturers had crammed all the electronics for a calculator onto a
single chip, and these new products had revolutionized the economics of
the calculator business. Advances in ICs and reductions in the number
of components used, not the wages of workers assembling hundreds of
discrete components, became the key to competitive success. New Amer¬
ican players, including some U.S. chip makers, even reentered the elec¬
tronic calculator business, basing their designs on the revolutionary new
chips now hitting the market, and substantially reduced the share of the
American market captured by calculator imports.109
Chip prices dropped precipitously in the U.S. market, under the pres¬
sure of aggressive competition. The fierce competition was also exported
across the Pacific. From spring 1970 to early 1971, the prices of imported
calculator LSI chips dropped by half.110
by U.S. Makers,” Japan Economic Journal, January 5, 1971 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese
Protection).
111. NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, p. 311; U.S. Department of Commerce, Global
Market Survey, Electronic Components, p. 82. Large investments in upgrading plants to
produce CMOS (complementary metal oxide silicon) ICs were undertaken by most Japanese
producers in 1972 and 1973. “IC Makers Shaken.”
112. NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 3, p. 311 (author’s trans.).
113. On the other hand, Mitsubishi, which was working with Sharp to manufacture ICs
for a MITI-funded calculator project, actually declined to move to commercial production.
See note 83.
114. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp. 196-97 (author’s trans.).
115. For example, note the evaluations of the semiconductor makers’ problems found
in Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp. 198-200, and U.S. Department
of Commerce, Global Market Survey, Electronic Components, pp. 81-82. The Nihon Keizai
Shimbun commented in 1973 that “it is estimated to take at least 2 to 3 years” for Japanese
companies to come up with the technology needed to compete with U.S. IC producers.
“IC Makers Shaken.”
76 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
1971
Sales 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 (estimate)
Inside
company 230 984 4,860 14,576 24,780 28,223
Outside
company 380 2,120 5,847 11,008 16,172 20,951
Total 610 3,104 10,707 25,584 40,952 49,174
Inside
sales (percent) 37.7 31.7 45.4 57.0 60.5 57.4
Outside
sales (percent) 62.3 68.3 54.6 43.0 39.5 42.6
Source: Machinery Promotion Association Economic Research Institution, Japan-U.S. Semiconductor Industry
Research Survey, p. 124.
116. Erikson and Cohen, “Japanese Electronics Firms,” pp. 125, 132.
117. NHK, Electronics-Based, Nation, vol. 3, p. 18.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 77
company import a product deemed vital to its future. When the first
prototype of the Intel design arrived in Tokyo, it took over a month for
it to clear customs at Haneda airport.118
Less typical was the experience of Texas Instruments Japan, which in
1971, consummating its secret 1968 bargain with MITI and Sony, was
transformed into the only wholly owned affiliate of an American semi¬
conductor maker inside the Japanese market. In that same year TI Japan
began shipping a one-chip calculator IC that sold like hotcakes—at its
peak, 300,000 units per month.119 Although ostensibly perched comfort¬
ably behind the protective walls thrown up around the Japanese market,
TI continued to fight a silent guerrilla war against the bureaucracy. In
1972, for example, a top Japanese executive quit Mitsubishi and was
recruited by TI. Shortly before he was to be hired, he was approached
by MITI and warned that, if he joined TI, MITI “would act accord¬
ingly.”120 Heeding these warnings, he and others in his group joined
another Japanese company.
Billions of yen
121. Author’s trans. The NEC executive went on to blame the quality problem on
cheap offshore assembly of these ICs in Southeast Asia: too much emphasis on cost, too
little attention to quality control. Interestingly, no Japanese semiconductor user is quoted
as supporting this version of events. Indeed, one user interviewed by Nakagawa describes
the lesson taught over this period as being that a certain minimum amount had to be
purchased from domestic chip makers, but notes that even this left Japanese semiconductor
producers unhappy. Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan, pp. 197, 203-04.
But NEC had its own quality problems with LSI, according to other accounts in this
same volume. After copying Rockwell chips as a last resort, NEC finally managed to
develop its own ten-chip LSI calculator kit, but was unable to sell it. When a Japanese
calculator producer finally tried to use it, the NEC LSI chips were found to be defective.
Ibid., pp. 199-200.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 79
if the liberalization were delayed, and U.S. officials publicly complained before the OECD.
“Liberalization of Electronic Computers and ICs Generally Decided; MITI to Hasten
Implementation Measures,” Asahi Shimbun, March 1, 1973; “Industrial Circles’ Plan Out
of Question—Liberalization of Electronic Computers, Eberle Expresses Strong Dissatis¬
faction,” Sankei Shimbun, March 27,1973; and “Import Liberalization during 1975; Cabinet
Decision on Electronic Computers Expected Today,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, June 15, 1973
(all excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection).
125. “Industrial Circles’ Plan Out of Question—Liberalization of Electronic Com¬
puter; Eberle Expresses Strong Dissatisfaction,” Sankei Shimbun, March 27, 1973 (ex¬
cerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection).
126. Japan had accepted Article XI of the GATT in 1963 and Article VIII of the Articles
of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in 1964, and had joined the
OECD in 1964. A three-year phased program calling for removal of some quantitative
restrictions and partial capital liberalization had been introduced in 1968, and a further
phased liberalization of trade and foreign investment was announced in 1971. See Krause
and Sekiguchi, “Japan and the World Economy,” pp. 425-30; and Itoh and Kiyono, “For¬
eign Trade and Direct Investment,” pp. 164-66.
127. “Contents of MITI Views on Electronic Computer Industry,” Asahi Shimbun, July
13, 1971 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection).
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 81
128. The name alluded to the view that IBM’s System 370 was only half a generation
more advanced than its so-called third-generation System 360. For further details, see
Flamm, Creating the Computer, pp. 193-95; Targeting the Computer, pp. 135-36.
129. The Fujitsu-FIitachi research association spent a total of 88 billion yen over the
1972-76 period, of which 61 billion yen was contributed by the companies. In addition,
another 67 billion yen (entirely contributed by the companies) was spent over the 1975-81
period. See Thirty-Year History, p. 77; Flamm, Creating the Computer, pp. 194-95.
130. The total budget for the research association was 22.2 billion yen over fiscal 1972-
76, plus 3.4 billion yen over an additional period extending through fiscal 1981. A govern¬
ment subsidy was only granted during the first period. Thirty-Year History, p. 79.
131. The research association’s total budget was 60.5 billion yen from 1972 through
82 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
fiscal year 1976; 19.5 billion yen was spent over an “additional development” period from
1977 through fiscal 1981. Thirty-Year History, p. 78.
132. Thirty-Year History, p. 78.
133. A call by MITI Minister Yasuhiro Nakasone for “promotion of further tieup than
the present three groups” in early 1973, for example, was explained to reporters by MITI
officials to mean that these firms “cannot stand competition with the huge manufacturers
of the United States, unless they deepen mutual tieup in commonization of the software
and in taking shares in production and joint development of peripheral apparatus, and
unless they either unified into a home-production manufacturer like Britain’s ICL in the
future or are concentrated at least into a group for specific purposes (Oki-Mitsubishi) and
an alignment of electronic computers proper (remaining four companies). Explaining the
Minister’s statement of the 7th to the press, a MITI leader said, ‘For the present, this does
not necessarily mean unification of industry circles, but the emphasis of the administrative
guidance lies in promoting tieup among the three groups.’ ” “Cooperation in Concentration
Sought—Statement by MITI Minister,” Asahi Shimbun, March 8, 1973 (excerpted in SIA,
Japanese Protection).
134. NEC was the first Japanese company to announce a commercial sixteen-bit micro¬
processor, in 1978. Machinery Promotion Association Economic Research Institute,
“Japan-U.S. Semiconductor Industry Research Survey,” p. 30.
135. See Electrotechnical Laboratory, Pattern Information Processing System: National
Research and Development Program, 1978 (Tokyo, 1978), pp. 27-30; and Ishii, “Research
and Development on Information Processing Technology.”
136. These are my estimates derived from graphs found in ETL, Pattern Information
Processing System, p. 5. This compares with total spending of 17.4 billion yen over the years
1971-78.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 83
137. ETL, Pattern Information Processing System, pp. 3, 5. The research themes (and
contractors) in devices and materials were semiconductor lasers (NEC, Toshiba), reversible
photosensitive materials (Sanyo, Fujitsu, Konishiroku), spatial modulation devices (Hita¬
chi, Matsushita, Hoya Glass), magnetic bubble domain devices (Hitachi, Hitachi Metal,
NEC, Tohoku Metal), and large-scale integrated circuits (Toshiba, Hitachi, NEC).
138. The chronology given in Machinery Promotion Association Economic Research
Institute, “Japan-U.S. Semiconductor Industry Research Survey,” p. 31, shows NEC as the
first company to sell a 16K DRAM, in March 1977. On Toshiba’s commercialization of its
PIPS microprocessor technology, see Hajime Iizuka, ’’Design and Implementation of a
Microprocessing Unit with a Flexible Architecture,” in T. Kitagawa, ed., Computer Science
and Technologies, 1982 (Tokyo and Amsterdam: Ohm and North-Holland, 1982), pp.
22-38.
139. Import quotas on ICs with 200 elements or fewer were removed in 1973. U.S.
Department of Commerce, Global Market Survey: Export Opportunities for Electronics
Industry Production and Test Equipment (GPO, 1974), p. 69.
140. “MITI Envisages Establishment of Joint Firm of Makers for Blueprinting ICs,”
Japan Economic Journal, August 3, 1971 (excerpted in SI A, Japanese Protection).
84 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
141. Nihon Kogyo Shimbun, January 8, 1972 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection).
142. A news report on the proposal, considered within Japan’s Electronics Industry
Association, specifically notes that “trying to find out which maker is superior in technology
stands to be difficult owing to the swift pace of technology in this field. As such, [industry
quarters] felt that reaching a conclusion on such aspects was going to take some time.”
“Electronics Industry Plans Cartel for Types of Products Using IC,” Japan Economic
Journal, December 14, 1971 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection). By March 1972 the
idea of a special Kidenho cartel had been abandoned, with firms disagreeing over how to
determine which producer would manufacture what types of ICs, and the four top compa¬
nies resisting the cartelization of more advanced chips. “Cartel Controlling IC Production
Types Will be Difficult to Implement for FY1972,” Nikkan Kogyo Shimbun, March 23, 1972.
143. ‘“Cooperation in Concentration Sought,’ Strengthening of Tieup among Three
Groups—MITI Policy,” Mainichi Shimbun, March 8, 1973 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese
Protection).
144. “Will Not Carry Out Another Reorganization—Electronic Computer Industry
Circles,“ Nihon Keizai Shimbun, March 8, 1973 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection).
145. “IC Makers Shaken.”
146. “MITI Heading toward Reorganization of IC Enterprises; Adjustment of Produc-
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 85
tion Fields Planned for Six Exporter Firms in Preparation of Liberalization,” Nihon Keizai
Shimbun, March 15, 1973 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection).
147. “IC Industry Circles Shocked; Caught Between U.S. Offensive and Liberaliza¬
tion,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, June 15, 1973; and “IC Industry Reorganization Adjusting
Production Areas,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, June 15, 1973, p. 6 (both in SIA, Japanese
Protection).
148. “IC Industry Circles Desire Establishment of Legislative Measures by Govern¬
ment—Prevention of Selling at Low Price,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, June 16, 1973 (ex¬
cerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection).
149. “Three Electronic Computer Groups Strengthening Tie-Up, Planning on Joint
Development of ICs and Mutual Supply of Equipment,” Nihon Kogyo Shimbun, June 25,
1973 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection). NEC and Toshiba apparently did do joint
R&D, whereas Hitachi and Fujitsu apparently did not. An official history of Japanese
technology research associations notes that in the NEC-Toshiba grouping, an R&D section
was established “in each member firm, which independently and jointly (partially) pursued
its assigned topic.” In the Ultra Advanced Computer Development Technology Research
Association (the Fujitsu-Hitachi grouping), in contrast, a research system was established
“within each company and engaged in a topic assigned to each.” Thirty-Year History, pp.
77-78.
150. “IC Industry Looks to the Government for Aid; Is It Quick Remedy or Only
86 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Narrow Escape?” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, November 5, 1973; “IC Subsidies to be Granted
to 8 Companies; Mitsubishi-Oki and Fujitsu-Sharp-Kyodo Electronic Groups Come to
Fore; Hitachi, Toshiba, and Japan Electric to Carry Out Unilateral Development,” Nihon
Kogyo Shimbun, November 29, 1973 (both excerpted in SI A, Japanese Protection). One of
the joint development efforts was the work on NMOS LSI, carried out by Mitsubishi and
Oki; the other was development of multipurpose linear ICs for use in industrial applications,
jointly undertaken by Fujitsu, Sharp, and Kyodo Denshi Gijutsu Lab. See Computer White
Paper, 1974 Edition, p. 22.
151. “MITI expects that groups of companies engaging in joint development will main¬
tain their cooperative structure in other fields henceforth without sticking to those kinds of
items which became the objects of a subsidy.” “IC Industry Circles to Make Every Possible
Effort for Development of Technology; Subsidy Amounting to 1.8 Billion Yen for Fiscal
1974 to be Given Shortly to Eight Companies, Including Hitachi and Toshiba,” Nikkan
Kogyo Shimbun, March 20, 1974. See also “IC Subsidies to be Granted,” Nihon Kogyo
Shimbun, November 29,1973; and “Joint Development for IC New Model Becomes Active;
Mitsubishi-Oki; Fujitsu-Sharp, etc.,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 6,1974 (all excerpted
in SI A, Japanese Protection).
152. Mitsubishi and Oki were already cooperating on development of ICs for use in
computers as part of their participation in the 3.5 generation program. Joint work on their
IC promotion subsidy project—development of an NMOS microprocessor LSI—was to be
divided, with Mitsubishi developing the LSI chip itself and Oki the low-cost package. Nihon
Kogyo Shimbun, February 19, 1974 (excerpted in SI A, Japanese Protection).
153. Nihon Kogyo Shimbun, February 19,1974; and “IC Industry Circles to Make Every
Possible Effort for Development of Technology; Subsidy Amounting to 1.8 Billion Yen for
Fiscal 1974 to Be Given Shortly to Eight Companies, Including Hitachi and Toshiba,”
Nikkan Kogyo Shimbun, March 20, 1974 (both excerpted in SI A, Japanese Protection).
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 87
Electronic computers
Major components 8/4/1974“ 12/11/1975“ 12/24/1975 7/1/1974
Peripheral device 7/1/1974 7/1/1974 7/1/1974 7/1/1974
Memory or terminal 8/4/1974 12/11/1975 12/24/1975 7/1/1974
Other partsb 8/4/1974 12/11/1975 2/1/1972 7/1/1974
Other components 8/4/1974 12/11/1975 12/24/1975 7/1/1974
c
Software 12/1/1974 4/1/1976 7/1/1974
Integrated circuits
Fewer than 100 8/4/1971“ 12/1/1974“ 9/1/1970 6/1/1968
Fewer than 200 8/4/1971 12/1/1974 4/19/1973 6/1/1968
More than 200 8/4/1971 12/1/1974 12/25/1974 6/1/1968
Source: Kenneth Flamm, Targeting the Computer: Government Support and International Competition (Brookings,
1987), p. 254; and MITI Machinery and Information Industry Bureau, Current Condition of the Electronics Industry
(Tokyo, September 1985), p. 8 (in Japanese).
a. Including integrated circuits for computer.
b. Input device, output device, communications control, and so forth.
c. No quotas applied.
Even before it had become clear that political pressure was finally
about to succeed in pushing open the door into the Japanese market,
American semiconductor firms had begun to position themselves for the
big event. Fairchild (in 1969) and National Semiconductor (before 1972)
had attempted an end run around investment restrictions by setting up
wholly owned manufacturing affiliates in U.S.-occupied Okinawa, where
the investment regime was more liberal than on the main islands of Japan.
The companies were gambling that, when Okinawa reverted to Japan in
1972, they would be permitted to retain their wholly owned Okinawa
manufacturing affiliates (despite a legal maximum of 50 percent foreign
ownership in IC manufacturing affiliates after the initial round of liber¬
alization in 1971) and achieve unhindered access to the Japanese mar¬
ket. 158 The bet failed to pay off. National was forced to close its operation,
while Fairchild was compelled to enter into an ill-starred 50 percent joint
venture with TDK Electronics, which finally closed in 1977 after years of
problems.
159. This account of Motorola’s experiences is drawn from Mason, American Multi¬
nationals in Japan, pp. 220-31; National Research Council, U.S.-Japan Strategic Alliances
in the Semiconductor Industry: Technology, Transfer, Competition, and Public Policy (Wash¬
ington: National Academy Press, 1992), pp. 91-101; David B. Yoffie and John Coleman,
“Motorola and Japan (A),” Harvard Business School case 9-388-056 1987, rev. 1989.
160. Both Toko and Alps had lost assets in semiconductor manufacturing when Kyodo
Electronics Laboratories, the startup founded as a joint venture by American Bernard
Jacobs and seven Japanese companies in 1964, disappeared in the mid-1970s.
161. Japan Electronics Almanac 1983 (Tokyo: Dempa Publications, 1983), p. 202.
90 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Until the early 1980s, when it became the subject of protracted trade
negotiations between the United States and Japan, NTT’s procurement
was effectively closed to non-Japanese suppliers.164 Indeed, even many
Japanese suppliers were frozen out of NTT contracts, which for the most
part went to a small group of favored companies, the so-called “Den-
Den” family of suppliers. Within this small group, an even smaller group
of four principal suppliers—NEC, Fujitsu, Hitachi, and Oki—received
the bulk of the NTT contracts. In 1968, for example, these four firms
accounted for 70 percent of NTT’s procurement.165 This share was to
decline over the next decade, but remained around 50 percent in the
early 1980s.166
NTT’s support for Japanese electronics manufacturers has been or¬
ganized quite differently from that provided by MITI. NTT’s large inter¬
nal research laboratories conducted basic research and transferred the
results of that research to selected suppliers. The transfer of technology
typically occurred through joint projects with suppliers to develop equip¬
ment using new technology, and through the exchange of technical per¬
sonnel between supplier companies and the NTT laboratories.167 Support
for R&D by its suppliers has not taken the form of contract R&D per¬
formed by these companies for NTT.168 Instead, funding for supplier
R&D has been structured as a part of development and procurement
164. Indeed, the president of NTT’s widely quoted response to some of these foreign
pressures was to declare that “the only thing we could consider buying overseas would be
[telephone] poles and mops.” “High Technology Gateway: Foreigners Demand a Piece of
NTT’s $3 Billion Market,” Business Week, August 9, 1982, pp. 40-44.
165. Anchordoguy, Computers Inc., p. 42, citing a Japanese study.
166. See U.S. International Trade Commission, Foreign Industrial Targeting and Its
Effects on U.S. Industries, Phase I: Japan (Washington, 1983), p. 152; and “High Tech¬
nology Gateway,” pp. 42, 44. Data in these sources show NEC, Fujitsu, Oki, and Hitachi
accounting for between 42 and 49 percent of NTT’s purchases over the years 1980-82.
Companies affiliated with NEC and the Sumitomo trading group (to which NEC belongs)
account for another 5 percent of NTT procurement, pushing the big four share above
50 percent. In 1981 NEC was the largest single supplier, accounting for about 20 percent
(25 percent with other Sumitomo group affiliates added on) of NTT purchases. Fujitsu
accounted for about 13 percent of purchases, Oki 7 to 8 percent, and Hitachi 6 to 7 percent.
167. Kozo Yamamura, “Joint Research and Antitrust: Japanese vs. American Strate¬
gies,” in Hugh Patrick, ed., Japan’s High Technology Industries: Lessons and Limitations
of Industrial Policy (University of Washington Press, 1986), p. 194; and Jon Sigurdson,
Industry and State Partnership in Japan: The Very Large Scale Integrated Circuits (VLSI)
Project (Lund, Sweden: Research Policy Institute, 1986), p. 100.
168. Published R&D survey statistics, for example, confirm that only relatively small
amounts could have been paid out to external organizations for contract R&D in the 1970s
and 1980s. See Flamm, Targeting the Computer, p. 139, note 19.
92 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
contracts for new equipment.169 Patents resulting from these joint devel¬
opment projects have generally been jointly owned by NTT and the
company concerned, so that companies have been free to use technolo¬
gies developed with NTT assistance.170
NTT’s early role in Japanese transistor R&D (it boasts of having built
the first Japanese germanium transistor, in 1952) as well as the manner
in which significant know-how was transferred to the private sector has
already been noted. NTT largely focused its semiconductor research
through the mid-1960s on the conservative goal of improving transistors
used in transmission systems. In the late 1960s, however, NTT began
research on electronic switching. Its first studies of the use of ICs were
not undertaken until 1965, when a project to design a family of IC logic
chips for use in switching systems was begun.171
Within the large semiconductor makers, all of which were Den-Den
family suppliers, development—and procurement—of ICs used in NTT
equipment were of considerable importance. In 1968, for example, NEC
had three lines of advanced digital ICs under development: one for “a
government-sponsored, large scale integration project” (presumably the
LSI component of MITI’s Very High Speed Computer System national
R&D project), another for use in NTT’s electronic telephone exchanges,
and a third for use in its next-generation advanced computer systems.172
Five Japanese manufacturers—Hitachi, Toshiba, NEC, Mitsubishi, and
Fujitsu—worked on ICs for use in NTT’s “DEX 2” electronic switching
system, developed in 1969. Experience on this project is credited by
Japanese semiconductor producers with being especially important
in establishing rigorous quality and reliability standards for domestic
products.173
Through the 1960s, though, NTT put little emphasis on support for
the Japanese electronics industry beyond its relatively narrow interest in
169. Ira C. Magaziner and Thomas M. Hout, Japanese Industrial Policy (Berkeley:
Institute of International Studies, University of California, Berkeley, 1980), pp. 107-08;
and Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership.
170. Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership; and Yamamura, “Joint Research and
Antitrust.”
171. Watanabe, “Electrical Communications Laboratories,” p. 4.
172. See Tarui, “ICs in Japan,” p. 105. The NTT logic design, known as controlled
saturation logic (CSL), was used in its D-10 electronic switching system. See Watanabe,
“Electrical Communications Laboratories,” p. 4.
173. NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 4, p. 14.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 93
was chosen as the vehicle for creating and testing the new process tech¬
nologies.178 The program met its goals: by 1977 a 64K DRAM had been
produced and significant progress made in photolithographic, X-ray, and
electron beam systems used to manufacture integrated circuits.179 By that
time, however, the NTT effort was no longer the only such program, or
even the largest one, on the scene.
own separate ways with their shares of the IC research subsidies.180 Com¬
plicating matters further from MITI’s perspective was NTT’s increasing
interest in computers and computer-related ICs, which historically had
been MITI’s responsibility.
When news of the double-barreled IBM-AT&T technological threat
from America hit Japan in 1974-75, important voices within the Japanese
industrial system clamored for action. NTT advanced further into MITI
territory with the announcement of its 1975 VLSI program. The industry
begged for huge new subsidies but was opposed by fiscal conservatives
within the government. Powerful groups within the LDP repeated their
call for a single Japanese national computer champion.181
Whether MITI was serving as a buffer between the conflicting interests
of LDP politicians and the private sector, or the bureaucrats were “mere
puppets for important political interests,” or “the politicians were really
only ‘cheering squads’ (oendan) for the bureaucratic armies” will prob¬
ably forever remain a topic for vigorous debate among students of Japa¬
nese political economy.182 Whatever the reality, a three-sided negotiation
among MITI, the electronics companies, and LDP politicians took place.
A compromise, brokered by the former head of the Dietmen’s League
for Promotion of the Information Industry, was struck, giving the industry
a large subsidy for VLSI research.183 In exchange, the firms would recon-
180. Fujitsu, however, did join a cooperative effort with two electronics companies not
involved in computer production, Sharp and Kyodo Electronics Laboratories. Also, al¬
though not a formal part of the IC subsidy program, a certain amount of cooperation in
R&D appears to have gone on between Hitachi and Fujitsu through their Nippon Periph¬
erals joint venture, and between NEC and Toshiba through their NTIS joint venture
company.
181. The account given below draws heavily upon Masato Hashizume, “Tracing the
VLSI Research,” in VLSI Technology Research Association, VLSI Technology Research
Association: Retrospective, pp. 80-87. Hashizume, a former section chief from the elec¬
tronics industry division of MITI, was appointed head councilor of the VLSI Research
Association. See also NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 4, pp. 358-61.
182. These different views of the Japanese political system are marvelously exposited
in Chalmers Johnson, “MITI, MPT, and the Telecom Wars: How Japan Makes Policy
for High Technology,” in Chalmers Johnson, Laura D’Andrea Tyson, and John Zysman,
eds.. Politics and Productivity: The Real Story of Why Japan Works (Ballinger, 1989), pp.
197-200.
183. The little-known Dietmen’s League for Promotion of the Information Industry
had earlier consulted with MITI when the original 1973-74 IC R&D subsidies, and addi¬
tional assistance for the computer industry, had been negotiated. See “MITI Informally
Decides on Liberalization Countermeasures Expenses—Electronic Computers: 43 Billion
Yen for Three Years: Aid to Be Extended for Development of New Models: Total Amount
96 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
figure themselves into just two private industry laboratories for the pur¬
poses of the subsidy and do a significant amount of R&D jointly in a
single common facility.
The research effort was organized around five companies: Fujitsu,
Hitachi, Toshiba, NEC, and Mitsubishi. (Both Toshiba and Oki dropped
out of mainframe computer manufacture in the mid-1970s, but only Oki,
technically and financially the weakest of these companies, was excluded
from the project.184) Technical personnel from MITI’s ETL were put in
charge of the common facility, dubbed the VLSI Joint Laboratory, which
gathered personnel from all five private sector participants and the ETL.
NTIS, the NEC-Toshiba joint venture formed in 1971, which already had
established a joint research laboratory system, became one of the two
participating private laboratories. A new entity known as Computer De¬
velopment Laboratories (CDL), with Fujitsu, Hitachi, and Mitsubishi as
participants, was created as the second industry laboratory.185 The entire
project was budgeted at 74 billion yen ($236 million), to be spent from
1976 to 1979; of that total MITI was to contribute 40 percent. The overall
objective of the program was to develop the technologies needed to
manufacture a 1M DRAM, or the equivalent, by 1985.186
Quite simply, this was by far the largest infusion of R&D subsidies
ever received by the Japanese semiconductor industry, in both absolute
and relative terms. The VLSI project accounted for almost 40 percent
(over 50 percent if the NTT projects are counted as well) of Japan’s
of Subsidies to Reach 77.1 Billion Yen,” Sankei Shimbun, August 14, 1973 (excerpted in
SI A, Japanese Protection).
184. Various explanations have been advanced as to why Oki got dropped and not
Mitsubishi. The most common explanation is that Oki was simply too technologically
inferior. See “Responding to Criticism of the Closed Nature, Complete Opening of Super
LSI Patents of NTT,” Keizai Sangyo, February 8, 1980 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protec¬
tion)-, and Anchordoguy, Computers Inc., pp. 140-41, quoting MITI sources. Other reports
suggest that OKI’s close technical ties with American computer maker Sperry Rand through
their Oki-Univac joint venture were a factor. See “Computer Industry Seen Revamped;
Joint VLSI Development Agreed,” Japan Economic Review, August 15, 1975 (excerpted in
SIA, Japanese Protection). Oki was reportedly given 64K DRAM technology by NTT to
compensate for its exclusion. Other firms outside the NTT VLSI project, including Toshiba,
Mitsubishi, and Matsushita, also reportedly lobbied for access to the NTT work. See
“Responding to Criticism.”
185. Mitsubishi was the weakest company in terms of its level of IC technology. Author’s
interview with Yasuo Tarui, March 1992. Its presence in CDL probably posed little threat,
then, to either Fujitsu or Hitachi. Also, Anchordoguy, Computers Inc., p. 140, cites a
popular Japanese history of the period as suggesting that Fujitsu saw this as a chance to
penetrate the Mitsubishi keiretsu grouping’s large computer market.
186. Nishi, “The Japanese Semiconductor Industry,” p. 5.
to O 3
+ £
d f' r~ oo
rt¬ no i/t m
E S>< a
* &"• = “
c"> S O ■f'
g
^3
s: 2-I S i
§ -o
£ O >N C
<n
&* 31 £ 53 ™
'c: .E oo
Q t 1L no iri u-> r- oo o j= r-
3i cj —
“3 <&, m o ic oo Q. CQ
N to 't N
OS 3 b 2 8S ^
U a 5 * ■i ^
a §
I = f2 2
a y 5 .2 li «
-3 3) • CL
+ ^ d m oo d d rf o —< >/n ro
R b-
O -t H Ol
s t-H oo Tt d no d m ri io OO N oi H 6 o\ t:rl
<D © £ rf d d cn ro m d d
no a O ^ g = §.
On 3 8^5
£ c oc
^ ij
r9
•" Ss-S a
•kj f- NO r'l ro oo M O 1; h Oi 2-st i
^ C NO On rt O On
3 o o 3 oo
rf d
■t 6 o oi —5 d' (3 id VO d N Ol O
t-H {N} T-H r-H
o a " o g ^
?>
c C.'i'
& O *J
£ s c
ri ^
to
I?
3 y q r- r- r- s-S
OS .2
ts Q
£ fc *8 &o ts
o s
vd id id
'O VO vO vO 'vO id id
52 1/5
b CJ
!<
I
Q is S *o «
u j c a
3 a> O O
^3^00
QS Sp ^3 § liu
S£ C % O MU O
a Q s5wP
S o « E
K aS
00 C''; © iO
3
"3 g. ri h oo id *0Sujo
£ c oo o in ov
CN (N t—i
<n
r-
so
Q & os
H -C)>N
C w “I
« j tso
"3 P =
CD ^ P£ . 2
S 1
5 2 h E
3 T3 M
c/5 e W)
S? - £- = 6
H Tf f\] (N
Q £ B litf-B
°8 «,
't ’t On 00
CO 00 Os iO
ca E .2 V5 c
<u o o w 3
3 o; c/joOC1*-
W l r^i CO ,
O
U ^
£5 *; g
■Cl
3 3 I -■§=,■§
3 © ^
*T-«>
*»A o p poop oooo ooooo
8 ^
-2 BS dH
r--
~3 O W
^ rt- ^t- Ht (N CO IO ID o o o in in e x> n- , S
til j£
< E-
5H 3 32
s oo.£
y s;
& ^ s t-H iO O oooo oooo ooooo J« |< i
o ^ 2 «r g
Sg
JiQ 3 oi it! o m in r- Ov O O in in <n in o oo iD E
rs -
o y o'
On ^
O'
NO IT)
r-
t? K (N n *o oo O' N OO Hrt^-00^
<3 ta (N N n in P -H 3-1
' O M k
3 O' M
c ^
J- - 00 ■ ' c
U O' O £ Urc «j
c — no o o. DO DO
(U <U
O CL . <u X) -O
in >> ' <S) /-S - c 00
■ yN „
. <U UJ E E On
^ « W —
Cd os:
Ov
r- 2S O DO 60 E
0) I EU £ S £
i: o
s CO in iO r- 00 Oi o tH (N m rl* in iO 00 Ov iO
iO VO VO vO vO VO VO r- r- r- r- r- r- r^
3 X)
Ov Ov Ov Ov Ov
£ Ci
t-H
ON
t-H
Oi
t-H
Oi
T-H
Oi
t-H
Oi
T-H
Oi
t-H
Ov
t-H
Ov
t-H
Ov
*-H t-H T-H
Ov
t-H t-H, t-H
Ov
T-H t-H
Ov
t-H c Cuj (2
98 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
national IC R&D effort in the late 1970s (table 2-5).187 In addition to the
subsidies shown in table 2-5, in-kind contributions of personnel and
equipment from MITI’s own lab worth 500 million to 1 billion yen,
exemptions from tariffs on machinery and equipment worth about
550 million yen, and reductions in taxes on fixed capital further aug¬
mented government support for the VLSI project.188
There is a virtual consensus in Japan that the effort was an exceedingly
important boost to Japanese semiconductor technology and played a key
role in making Japanese firms leaders in semiconductor manufacturing in
the 1980s.189 Certainly, tangible progress in DRAM manufacturing, in
particular, followed in the wake of the VLSI projects. The first 16K
187. My figures suggest that the VLSI project was a smaller fraction of overall IC R&D
than does a widely cited calculation by Ryuhei Wakasugi, because I am using revised MITI
statistics that increased estimates of private IC R&D in 1979. See “Research and Devel¬
opment and Innovations in High Technology Industry: The Case of the Semiconductor
Industry,” Japanese Economic Studies, vol. 17 (Fall 1988), p. 15.
188. Inoue, “VLSI Technology Research Association,” p. 63.
189. Typical appreciations are the following: “the most successful among [technology
research cooperatives] has been the VLSI Technological Research Cooperative. The reason
that it has been assessed as a success is, first, that there have been achievements in regard
to technologies that are common throughout the semiconductor industry as a whole. . . .
Second, there has been an efficient interfirm transfer of the common technologies.” Wak¬
asugi, “Research and Development,” pp. 18-19.
“Consequently, the VLSI Program contributed greatly to the Japanese semiconductor
industry both directly, in terms of its research and development achievement, and indirectly
by building a new culture for R&D planning and collaboration.” Nishi, “The Japanese
Semiconductor Industry,” p. 126.
“Today there exists a consensus that the VLSI Project in Japan, established in 1976 as
an engineering research association, had an exceptional success in promoting technological
development. . . . The project resulted in firmly raising the level of VLSI manufacturing
technology of the five participating companies. . . . This is a contributing factor for the
increasing shares taken by these companies in the world market for memory circuits.
However, the VLSI project also had a profound effect on companies outside the group of
5 companies; today Matsushita has become a major actor in the field.
Furthermore, the project similarly raised the technical level of two major groups of
supporting companies ... not only have Japanese VLSI companies established themselves
among the world leaders but its crystal and VLSI equipment manufacturers have also
established themselves in the top league.” Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership, pp.
62-63.
“In the middle of the 1980s, Japanese companies caught up with their U.S. counterparts,
and had stayed in a dominant position in the memory chip market represented by 4M
DRAM and 16M DRAM until the beginning of the 1990s. It is well known that the ‘VLSI
Research Association’ assisted by MITI contributed to the success of the Japanese semi¬
conductor industry during this period to a great extent.” Ryo Sakamoto, “Will the Japanese
Version of ‘Sematech’ Save the Japanese Semiconductor Industry?” Foresight (November
1995), pp. 94-95.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 99
DRAM, introduced by the U.S. producer Intel in 1976, kicked off four
generations of DRAMs, through the 1M chip introduced in the mid-
1980s, in which the focus for innovation was on perfecting manufacturing
technology with which to squeeze a well-understood physical design into
ever smaller spaces.190 Improvements in manufacturing technology were
precisely the focus of the VLSI projects, and they provided an entry
point for Japanese manufacturers into world semiconductor markets.
Beginning in 1978, after the completion of the first NTT VLSI project,
the first significant innovations in DRAM design and manufacturing from
Japanese companies (from both NTT and project participant NEC) were
publicly unveiled, in the form of the first prototype 64K DRAMs. The
success of the first NTT project paved the way for a second 20-billion-
yen ($95 million) three-year project, ending in 1980.191 In the next gen¬
eration of DRAM, the 256K chip (appearing in 1980), Japanese compa¬
nies (again NTT and NEC) were even to take the lead as the first world¬
wide to unveil the new product. These new 256K DRAM designs, in
fact, were directly linked to the results of the VLSI projects.192 From
that generation on, Japanese producers clearly dominated the introduc¬
tion of new product and process technologies in DRAM manufacture.193
As the first large-scale experiment in which rival companies’ engineers
actually worked together in the same laboratories, the MITI VLSI pro¬
gram’s apparent success also made it the model for even more intensive
experiments with joint research, in Japan and abroad. However, recent
revisionist assessments of the VLSI project in the West have argued for
two qualifications. First, in assessing the project’s technological accom¬
plishments, it has been suggested that the “Japanese did not appear to
have made any major breakthroughs. In most areas, [an American VLSI
expert interviewed] felt that the Japanese had simply extended their tech¬
nology in ways comparable to developments that had already occurred in
the United States.”194
Second, it has been argued that in the VLSI project, as in previous
cooperative research programs sponsored by the Japanese government,
there was “very little research cooperation between the participating
Japanese companies, at least insofar as this refers to the joint generation
and sharing of technological knowledge ”195 Both of these points merit
some brief consideration.
194. Uenohara and others, “Background,” in Okimoto and others, Competitive Edge,
pp. 38-39, also cited prominently in Fransman, The Market and Beyond, p. 84. It should
be noted that this assessment was made before the VLSI effort had actually ended. As will
be documented below, although the government subsidy ended in 1979, the companies
involved continued in a “private sector edition” of the project, using private funds only,
from 1980 to 1986, to further develop and commercialize the results of the initial, subsidized
project. Neither Okimoto and others nor Fransman seem even to be aware that the coop¬
erative effort extended beyond 1979.
195. Fransman, The Market and Beyond, p. 58.
Figure 2-8. Major Results of the Japanese VLSI Project, 1975-90
Direct drawing
>
O'
o
O
102 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
In the view of the former director of the VLSI Project’s Joint Research
Laboratory, the four most important achievements of the program were
advances in electron beam machines (used to indirectly etch patterns for,
and directly write, circuit features on silicon chips); optical “steppers”
(photolithographic machines used to imprint patterns on chips); the tech¬
nology used to grow single silicon crystals, then slice and polish the silicon
wafers used in chip making; and techniques used to characterize and
measure silicon crystals.196 Another project participant’s list of major
research areas shows six topics in semiconductor manufacturing pro¬
cesses, three in materials, three in design and testing, two in packaging,
and four in particular device structures.197
Consistent with all these lists is the central thesis of the most detailed
published study of the VLSI project: that the most visible, concrete
effects of the program were in creating technical information flows be¬
tween Japanese equipment and materials suppliers and IC producers.198
It was in the manufacturing infrastructure for the Japanese semiconductor
industry that the most important advances appear to have occurred.
This is evident to some extent in the way the VLSI project’s budget
was spent. Figure 2-9 breaks out expenditure by the VLSI Technology
Research Association over the four years of the subsidized MITI project,
as well as seven additional years of wholly privately funded cooperative
research that continued the project after 1979 (this point is elaborated
below). Expenditure on facilities, materials, and procurement contracts
averaged about 70 percent of the project’s cost over the years 1976-79.
Yasuo Tarui, the project’s leader, estimates that 30 to 40 percent and
perhaps even more of the project’s budget went into the development of
new equipment.199 Another study estimates that a quarter to a third of
the project’s funding was spent on the purchase of the most advanced
semiconductor manufacturing equipment available in the United
States.200
Ironically, the most direct evidence for the link between the VLSI
project and Japanese semiconductor technology shows up in the com¬
mercial activities of firms that were not even members of the VLSI proj¬
ect. These equipment and materials firms cooperated and subcontracted
with the formal project participants to produce advanced materials and
equipment that had not previously been available to the Japanese indus¬
try (figure 2-10).201 The importance of these linkages is visible in the
subsequent success of Japanese equipment and materials suppliers in
global markets with products utilizing their VLSI project experience.
201. This figure, from Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership, p. 120, is also partly
reproduced in Fumio Kodama, Analyzing Japanese High Technologies: the Techno-Para¬
digm Shift (London: Pinter Publishers, 1991), p. 89.
104 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
DAI- USHIO
RICOH
NIPPON DENKI
VLSI
PROJECT
JOINT
LABS - TOPPAN
TOSHIBA
LITHO
T. MACH. TOSHIBA I.
T. SEIKI
TOKUDA CANON -1
TOK.DK. LITHO
ASIA E. II. KYOCERA
NIKON
FUJITSU LITHO
NGK-SPARK
III.
DISCO
SHINKAWA
ULVAC
CRYSTAL JEOL
NIHON SHINKU
TOKYO ELECTRIC
ANELVA
HITACHI SHIN ETSU ANDO
HITACHI WAFER
HANDOTAI
KOKUSAI-
DENKI
OSAKA
TESTING
TITANIUM
TOKYO
OHKA
ETL
NTT TAKEDA
LABS RIKEN
NHK
SHARP KDD KOKUSAI
SANYO DENKI
Source: Jon Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership in Japan: The Very Large Scale Integrated Circuits (VLSI)
Project (Lund, Sweden: Research Policy Institute, 1986), p. 120.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 105
202. Presentation of John Poate prepared for a National Research Council seminar,
“Advanced Processing of Electronic Materials in the United States and Japan,” Washing¬
ton, June 4, 1986. In 1985 Nikon had 35 percent of the global optical lithography equipment
market, and Canon 17 percent. The leading American producer, GCA (Geophysics Cor¬
poration of America), had 30 percent of the market. In 1981 GCA had sold 73 percent of
wafer steppers shipped globally. See also Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership, pp.
86-93; Jay S. Stowsky, “Weak Links, Strong Bonds: U.S.-Japanese Competition in Semi¬
conductor Production Equipment,” in Johnson and others, Politics and Productivity, p. 263;
and “VLSI Projection Aligner by Canon,” Electronic News, November 8, 1978, p. 28.
203. See John Hataye, “Toshiba Machine to Market E-Beam Pattern Generator,” Elec¬
tronic News, July 24, 1978, p. 42.
204. Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership, pp. 93-105, 120; and Stowsky, “Weak
Links,” pp. 265, 268-69.
205. See John Hataye, “Japan Equip. Firms Eye Exports to U.S.,” Electronic News,
December 3, 1979, p. 20; and U.S. Department of Commerce, A Competitive Assessment
of the U.S. Semiconductor Manufacturing Equipment Industry (1985), p. 4.
106 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
The VLSI project was the first case in which a MITI-supported re¬
search association set up its own, independent joint laboratory to under¬
take research, and the first to mix within a common space researchers
from the different participating companies. Its success provided the im¬
petus for later initiatives to establish joint industry R&D facilities.
However, it has rightly been pointed out that perhaps 15 percent of
the project’s total budget was spent within the joint R&D laboratory,
with the remainder expended within the two company-run joint research
programs and the individual companies, under the direction of the VLSI
Technology Research Association.209 Actually, the share of the work car¬
ried out by the joint lab may have fallen below even this low number; as
table 2-6 suggests, personnel in the joint lab as a share of the project’s
total personnel dropped rapidly from 18 to 11 percent over the four-year
life of the project. Furthermore, the topics pursued within the joint lab
were specifically chosen to be “common” and “basic” technologies far
removed from actual commercial device development.210
Even within these constraints, organizational walls between different
research groups in the joint lab were erected to protect perceived pro¬
prietary interests: Hitachi, Fujitsu, and Toshiba, for example, were re¬
luctant to have their researchers work with other companies in the area
of lithography equipment because each of these companies had active
commercial efforts under way for these products. As a result, each of
these companies’ researchers were segregated within their own compet¬
ing lithography laboratory within the overall joint lab, joined by research¬
ers from NEC and Mitsubishi (who were not in direct competition) but
not the other companies.211 One breakdown of a group of patent appli¬
cations resulting from the project shows only 16 percent of these patents
involving researchers from more than one company.212 Given these facts,
one revisionist critique has argued that there was limited joint generation
and sharing of knowledge within the VLSI project.213
28.7
CN cn
ON nC
CN (N
NO oc o oc
CN r-
23.0
CN GO O ’—1
o r- o in oo tj- 00 CN
-H r-H ^H (N r- CN in
oo oo m
24.5
On r- oo
oo ri h O' o in o cn o o
NO m in
no
oo
I
^h cn o
23.3
NO
On oo no c o in © cn 00 cn
i—( r-H r-H CN r- CN in
22.1
r- CN On
^ (N) CO NO r- O c^ 00 CN CN
CN r—< r-H r-H NO cn
-O
Source: VLSI Technology Research Association, History of the VLSI Research Association (Tokyo 1991), pp. 39, 56, 62.
r- oo in o
20.3
in On no
in
CN
r-i <n in NO
NO
cn -h oo
<n
r-H
c
c
o in o NO 00 GO © CN cn
17.4
£ o o cn 'Tf 00 cn o r-H 00
<n r-H r-H r-H NO r—H r-H m m
$
in in CN CN
«L N- N- N- N-
e
o
0
On O O O
o
o <N in
N-
in
N-
CN
"xf
CN
>2
^2
-c
O o o o
0
« 00
m
oo
cn
O r-
o
<u
fti
Co <n o o o O O O o
0
cn
r-H r-H r-H r-H
CN CN NO NO
L
£ .£
£
J9
o T3
T3
<D
©
s«. <U <D
<3
-s; O
O
o
CO cj
O O co
to
to
to 03
NO C3 CO
I JD<& C a
-o 03
<N cS C
—
NTIS
Q- CL
JD ■J P jo E
P
1 1
3 C
S
h
£ o
aj o U rG cn E
o p Q
Q o PJ o H o
I u
£ ‘o
UfclSu Z H Z u
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 109
214. See Akira Goto and Ryuhei Wakasugi, “Technology Policy,” in Komiya and others,
Industrial Policy of Japan, pp. 198-99.
215. Ishii, “Research and Development on Information Processing Technology.”
216. Tarui, “Japan Seeks Its Own Route,” pp. 90-91.
110 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
217. Fransman, The Market and Beyond, p. 81. Fransman also describes some research
actually conducted jointly by the two laboratory groupings, but he minimizes its impor¬
tance.
218. NHK, Electronics-Based Nation, vol. 4, p. 358; Sakakibara, “Organization and
Innovation,” pp. 21-22; Sigurdson, Industry and State Partnership, pp. 50—51; and author’s
interview with Yasuo Tarui, March 1992.
219. Inoue, “The VLSI Research Association,” p. 68.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 111
220. Ross A. Young, Silicon Sumo: V.S.-Japan Competition and Industrial Policy in
the Semiconductor Equipment Industry (Austin: University of Texas IC2 Institute, 1994),
pp. 185-88. Propelled by these new systems, Canon and Nikon turned the tables on industry
leader GCA. From a 10 percent share of the world stepper market in 1980, they jumped to
80 percent by the end of the decade. U.S. stepper makers’ share dropped to 10 percent,
and GCA, which invented the stepper, went out of business in 1992. Young, p. 99.
221. In fact, Fransman, The Market and Beyond, p. 52, notes how important it was for
“cross-fertilization” of ideas for engineers from the two rivals to sit down and work together
on research in the joint venture.
222. Anchordoguy, Computers Inc., p. 144.
223. See “VLSI Research Group Is Going to Halt Activities at End of March,” Japan
112 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
Billions of yen
the VLSI project for another seven years, funded entirely out of its own
monies, to continue development and commercialization of semiconduc¬
tor manufacturing technologies first explored under the subsidized pro¬
gram.224 Figure 2-11 shows the scale of the original and the additional
funding (the latter amounted to about 60 billion yen, or 50 percent more
than the companies’ contribution to the original program).225 Companies
clearly must have found their joint research through CDL and NTIS, and
Economic Journal (March 1980, excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection)-, and Sakakibara,
“Organization and Innovation,” pp. 12-14.
224. See “Super LSI Volume Production 3-Year Plan, 10 Billion Yen Invested in First
Year,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, July 31, 1980 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese Protection)-, and
unpublished slides for presentation of Yoshio Nishi, “VLSI Technology Perspective,” World
Bank, China Electronics Seminar, October 22, 1987.
225. The VLSI project’s government funding was actually given in the form of a “con¬
ditioned loan” with an obligation to pay back the subsidy if profits were earned on the
technologies and products developed. From 1983 to 1987 the companies actually paid back
some 8.5 billion yen to the government (out of a MITI subsidy of 28.6 billion yen). Inoue,
“The VLSI Research Association,” p. 63.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 113
226. CDL and NTIS were participants in the MITI-sponsored Next Generation Basic
Computer Technology program, which carried out research in the areas of software, com¬
puter processing of language, and computer peripherals (but not ICs).
227. See Izuo Hayashi, Masahiro Hiano, and Yoshifumi Katayama, “Collaborative
Semiconductor Research in Japan,” Proceedings of the IEEE, vol. 77 (September 1989),
pp. 1431-32.
ON CO 00 _
03 vO VO co
cd cd 03 °o o (N in 00 m
d d d (N o o o d o CO o
(N 00 _: 00 CO (N (N
■^t cd cd r- 3 rxj o cd o NO in
d d (N c d d o (N o
in 03 03 03 03 03 cd cd
•^f d p: co
On C © d d d d d d d
I
On
cd CO t—' r- 03 03 03 03 cd 03 cd
tt co oo
d d d d d d d d
£
'-•-A
o
03 00 NO CO •
03 r- (N o 03 03 03 (N ^ cd cd
d d d d O c d d
2
• »*y
c
o
•*■<» o cd
O 03 cd 03 03 T-H cd cd
<L>
*^» d d d d d d d
O c
o
ON Tt 03
03 oo m 03 03 03 03 cd 03 cd
d d d d d d d d d
^3
>-*
Q
*^««»
r- on 03 03 03 03 cd cd 03 03
ft: tj- r- iT)
»3 d d d d d d d d
s
a
v
®o
o
co m
<N 00
Tt 03 03 03 cd cd cd 03
ft, co
d d d d d d d
Q
°8
a;
s T3 ON
co
r- in
in Tf 03 03 cd 03 cd 03 cd 03
o <L>
d d d d d d d d
<0 *3
s^ 0)
a Cu
■3 “
c 'is
<u C. u
Cv <D C/5
OJ
C/5
£
<D
U |1 I C
o
Lq o o C/5 C
cc — Q. U g Wh
o § >, 3 <D <D -3
03
. C/5
<L> - 1/3 Cl td £ c/5 > -a “
C s o
I*-*- C/5
^o vs 5s s« <n
op ^
'O C y
o
■C c <u
cu
”
Cl
0)
^
^ -S
c o gc g - <u ■4—> <D
!- O
CL Z3 •5b w o 5/5 • W) u y T3 ~ 1 2 2
Qc/> 03 c jf <c
0) o g ’S c « « a Ed.-
^ <U o o '5 - > 0>3c^
S 79 >%.s £
1— ■2 g
^ 03-3
5/5 > _C
(u o
<=« P 03 c/5 W-
■§11
r--' <u c -c g *C "c O (Ui > ^ cd
i Ot * a..<£ o = o cd e -a 8 II
■g 2 I
-n «« (U
<N — 03 C/5 'o
u £ a cd C
03 O -C 00 s o i 8 C ^
_0> c o 00 CL U s cd
s -a o C
XJ 3 3 o
■lo GO o -gc j s Z
e2 CQ Z
r- o <N co O 00 vC (—>
vO (N O o CO On in o
ri
O'
9-
o
c
E
cJ
'<•
i
o (N o cd — U 3
1-H CO O' ^
'd'
f' o S
—' c2 J=
O (N £ -u
cd co O (N oo ^d" O r-
Td- cf O r- CO CO ON On
d in
^d- S 2W
dll
O'
1
Cd 03 cd
co o <N oo o (N oo
o r- CO in ON _
d d d co . - o U)
O c
Vj *r
i C; O
*3 g
dg9
03 03 cd
co O (N 00 o VO
TJ- o CO in in
d d d
in
CO
03 cd cd
co o <N 00 o in
^d- o r- CO 00 t>
d d d 00 o vd I P SJ
00 CNl I ON
(N on
<—•
vo S'
Q- \£5
CO a. *
cd os cd
co O (N 00 o co
rj- o vo "d- 00
d d d C1-— sr
r-
<N 'C"5
t- ^
O ^
03 03 cd
co o
o
CN ^ 00 av
t— <V
. >s “>
d d d a5 ^
C 1^ o
VO
(N a.^ >NfO
CN
oo S 5
ON ^ O TO
- bS M
9?.!; 5
q ° o r- 3 N! ^ Q
03 03 cd cd cd cd cd oo o CO
*dt w
d d d d d d c
CO
<N s.i'5.-
3 co
kj «s C33
O On O '« 1)
03 03 cd cd cd cd cd
VO
o On O | "fN>s 1/93 3
d d d d d d d in
ON cd <L < fflco
f2
3< ?9§ .22
Q. > - t
a. Average annual funding levels for multiyear projects.
K S O w
o 3
G O >, O H
b. OEIC is optoelectronic integrated circuit project.
<U
in c g 0-
os cd U cd cd cd cd On o o. u =
d d G d d d d VO <N 3 C E 3
2 o n) «J
_o VO
o V -a E
in fli W t.
o £7 > w O
£
o u.u T3
•- a
2 T3
c
3 U ® t5
CL
-C
CJ Q £ “X5 ^ IU
t-M
cd tU 0)
G
<D
o>
C/5 G u PC
a q 3 00
e
5 a D o 0> *c
PC G
O "5
c -v > V
u g 4
C ^
O — NO 2
G cS g e ’P o cd cd OX) G T3 iz H •
O
£ s 2 3
^ £ u cj 03 cd PC U S
S3 S
CL Lh
at
u c/5 _ .
P “2 E T3 £ c E js •« cd CJ
’> T3 T c O O a, s_✓
G G .> c c 5 o C/5 Cd
r O G OX) c S> S l;
<D 5 3 p bG (j o U
G “ I
G
O
_ _
H-* d -g oo c u- OX) 5 u S5 m
.22 cd cd C “ c G
0)
£
C/<u5 £
<U ~ V 43
O ■6 <u I £. | «
T3 .£
£ <u
C/5
G G "3
« g • 3
<u
u
s- O
■*->
O <2
0
<u
v a -
o
s « o 2 «5 G
G
c2 -o G
G G
o <L> e E E H o a M—<
X 43
c/5cd <D
^ o jr c c
W PH
>
U
G
co O < <L) Q.
P
!« 1- •§ S
GO CQ Z s S aaS
116 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
focusing more on devices and device structures, and less on the manu¬
facturing process (although, as described earlier, some important pieces
of manufacturing equipment—testers and etching equipment—came out
of the program).228 The scale of the overall program was substantially
smaller than MITI’s, however, since firms were not required to match
NTT’s investment in R&D.
In 1978 NTT began a second three-year VLSI program, this time
focusing on development of a 256K DRAM, and like the first program
budgeted at 20 billion yen.229 By early 1980 NTT had announced a 256K
DRAM prototype.230 Yet a third NTT VLSI program was begun in the
fall of 1981, this time targeting 1M DRAMs and computer-aided design
systems for use in designing future generations of ICs.231 In this third
project, membership was extended beyond the three core members—
Fujitsu, Hitachi, and NEC—to Toshiba. Technology transfer from and
procurement of 256K DRAMs by NTT gave the Japanese semiconductor
makers an early boost in 256K DRAM production in the mid-1980s.232
NTT spending on R&D involves a substantial component of joint
research with other companies. Table 2-8, based on data reported by
Kodama, shows that about 28 percent of patent applications jointly filed
by NTT and its suppliers over the 1980-86 period involved two or more
of NTT’s suppliers.
By the mid-1980s NTT, through its relationships with its suppliers, had
quietly become the largest source of quasi-public subsidies to the Japa¬
nese semiconductor industry. An AT&T semiconductor technologist has
estimated, on the basis of his visits to NTT in the mid-1980s, that about
22 percent of all NTT R&D staff were working on semiconductor tech¬
nology in 1985, suggesting an internal 1988 R&D expenditure of about
228. Author’s interview with Yasuo Tarui, March 1992; Sigurdson, Industry and State
Partnership, p. 58; and unpublished slide from Nishi presentation, 1987.
229. “Responding to Criticism of the Closed Nature, Complete Opening of Super LSI
Patents of NTT,” Nihon Keizai Sangyo, February 8, 1980 (excerpted in SIA, Japanese
Protection).
230. See note 190.
231. “NTT Has Accepted Toshiba to Join VLSI Project,” Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun,
October 4, 1982, p. 1.
232. In 1982 NTT began procuring 256K DRAMs in production quantities (hundreds
of thousands) from Hitachi, NEC, and Fujitsu, using design and manufacturing technology
transferred to these firms at no cost. See Jack Robertson, “Japan Cos. Get NTT’s 256K
Skills,” Electronic News, October 11, 1982, p. 8; and Nikkei Shimbun, August 26, 1982,
p. 8.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 117
in 1984. From the privatized NTT emerged a major new, publicly funded
institution investing in information technology. A public battle between
MITI and the Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications in 1984 over
control of Japanese investments in information technology research was
resolved with the establishment of a jointly administered Basic Technol¬
ogy Research Promotion Center in 1985.235 The huge annual dividends
from the government’s remaining one-third share of the equity of the
privatized NTT are funneled into this center, which in turn funds up to
70 percent of joint R&D ventures with private industry. From 1986 to
1990 close to a billion dollars (100 billion yen) of NTT-derived funds were
235. See Johnson, “MITI, MPT, and the Telecom Wars,” pp. 227-30; Teruyuki Inoue,
NTT: A Giant Facing Competition and Division in the Information Age, 4th ed. (Tokyo:
Otsuki Shoten, 1992), pp. 108-14 (in Japanese).
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 119
plowed into this center. The single largest recipient of these subsidies is
the Advanced Telecommunications Research Institute, with a core re¬
search staff mostly made up of personnel sent from NTT. The large
private corporations that participate in the Institute’s projects and fund
the balance of its budget also send researchers to work on these research
efforts, who then serve as the conduit for technology transfer back into
their home organizations.236
MITI’s stance toward the Japanese semiconductor industry also
changed dramatically in the 1980s. The agency lifted formal controls on
semiconductor imports and foreign investment for the most part by 1975,
but some signs that administrative guidance and other barely visible
measures were used to protect domestic producers lingered on through
the remainder of that decade. As late as 1979, for example, American
chip producers still publicly described alleged incidents in which MITI
had forced Japanese customers to cancel orders with American compa¬
nies and switch to Japanese suppliers.237 And one could still see the old
attitudes at work on occasion, even in the 1980s. Perhaps the clearest
example was a MITI initiative, in the early and mid-1980s, to reduce
dependency on foreign supplies of the high-purity silicon used to produce
semiconductors.
Dependence in Silicon
236. Inoue, NTT: A Giant Facing Competition and Division, pp. 108-14.
237. “Dr. Hogan tells of a $7 million order Fairchild got recently from an unnamed
Japanese customer. ‘Our people in Japan gave a party; they were delighted. But one week
later the Japanese customer was on the phone literally crying. MITI, he told us, had forced
the order to go to Hitachi, even though his people felt we were providing a better product.’ ”
John Reason, “Japan’s Electronics Markets: A Pair of Views,” IEEE Spectrum, vol. 16
(June 1979), p. 52.
“Some reported experience implied Japanese government involvement. It was reported
that sales have been cancelled after application to MITI for an import license, and that this
was due to telephone calls received by prospective purchasers asking why they were im¬
porting when essentially comparable domestic products were available.” U.S. International
Trade Commission, Competitive Factors Influencing World Trade in Integrated Circuits
(November 1979), p. 59.
120 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
238. See Toshio Noda, “Processes and Process Developments in Japan,” in Proceedings
of the Flat-Plate Solar Array Project Workshop on Low-Cost Polysilicon for Terrestrial
Photovoltaic Solar-Cell Applications, JPL publication 86-11 (Pasadena, Calif.: Jet Propul¬
sion Laboratory, February 1986), p. 213.
239. Noda, “Processes and Process Developments,” p. 214.
240. For example, to the question, “Do you think it’s possible to use this process to
produce electronic-grade silicon?” Noda of OTC replied, “My understanding is that every¬
one here has a strong interest to see our process applied to produce electronic-grade
material. We would like to see that happen, too.” Noda, “Processes and Process Devel¬
opments,” p. 231.
241. See “Tokuyama Soda’s Polysilicon Business Dept.: Offense with Polycrystalline
Silicon,” Nikkei Sangyo Shimbun, December 18, 1984, p. 6.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 121
dations of the study group report were being implemented, before the
report was even finished, and a full fifteen months before the final report
was published.249 These recommendations included expansion of domes¬
tic production, encouragement of entry by new Japanese producers, ne¬
gotiation of long-term contracts with foreign suppliers, direct investment
in foreign producers, and construction of foreign plants to take advantage
of lower electricity costs. Most of these recommendations were soon
translated into action.
In August 1984 it was announced that poly producer Hi-Silicon (a
joint venture between OTC and Japan Silicon) would double its annual
poly capacity to 1,080 metric tons, and that Tokuyama would also expand
its capacity to 1,000 metric tons. Shortly thereafter it became known in
the Japanese trade press that both Tokuyama and Hi-Silicon were receiv¬
ing subsidized industrial technology promotion loans from the JDB in
connection with these expansions.250 Other Japanese silicon producers
also scheduled capacity expansions in 1984. These expansions continued
even after the silicon market began to turn down in early 1985.
Aside from Tokuyama Soda’s pre-study group entry there was a sub¬
stantial wave of new investment in the silicon business on the part of
Japanese steel companies after the release of this report. Nippon Kokkan
announced its intention to enter the poly business in July 1985.251 The
next month Kawasaki Steel and LSI Logic announced a joint venture to
manufacture wafers.252 Nittetsu Electronics (owned by Nippon Steel) was
willing to talk about its entry into the wafer business, and a technical
link to Hitachi, in the second half of 1985.253
In addition, there was a substantial increase in foreign acquisitions
and investment over this period. SEH and Mitsubishi Metals purchased
substantial equity shares in the U.S. silicon producer Hemlock in 1984,
while the silicon study group was still meeting. Nippon Kokkan pur¬
chased Great Western Silicon from GE in 1985, shortly after the release
249. MITI’s study group was named the High Purity Silicon Issues Study Group (Ko-
jundo Shirikon Mondai Kenkyukai). Its Research Report [Chosa Hokokusho] was published
by the Japan Society of Newer Metals Association, a Tokyo industry association, in March
1985.
250. Rare Metal News, October 24, 1984.
251. See Nihon Keizai Shimbun, July 17, 1985.
252. Avra Wing, “See Japan Challenge to U.S. Wafer Makers,” Electronic News, July
8, 1985, p. 14.
253. See “International Report: Japan,” Solid State Technology, vol. 28 (September
1985), p. 20; and Rare Metal News, January 8, 1986.
THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS 123
254. Indeed, a private antitrust suit (ultimately settled out of court) was brought by
American silicon producer Union Carbide in 1988. It alleged that Japanese silicon producers
had colluded within the MITI-sanctioned study group to exclude U.S. producers from the
Japanese market. See Louise Kehoe, “Japanese Silicon Suppliers Named in Antitrust Suit,”
Financial Times, October 5, 1988; and “Carbide’s Poly Charges Echo DRAM Flap,” Elec¬
tronic News, October 17, 1988.
255. See Noda, “Processes and Process Developments,” p. 231.
256. See Denryoku Jiji Tsushin, January 30, 1985.
124 THE JAPANESE ASCENT IN SEMICONDUCTORS
expected to pave the way for realizing 100% domestic production of solar
batteries, according to industry experts.”257
Aside from occasional episodes like these, however, the most obvious
and visible trappings of protection had clearly been lifted in semiconduc¬
tors. Even complaints about some of the less transparent forms of gov¬
ernment intervention, such as administrative guidance, were to drop
sharply as Japan turned its attentions fully toward global markets. As a
new decade of exports and international competition began in the 1980s,
it was a healthy and self-confident Japanese industry that emerged on the
world scene. On the other side of the Pacific the American industry faced
crisis and self-doubt, as for the first time it confronted a determined,
well-funded, and highly capable foreign competitor.
Summary
The Genesis of an
American Trade Policy in
Semiconductors, 1959-84
127
128 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
1. See “Business Week Reports on: Semiconductors,” Business Week, March 26, 1960,
p. 113.
2. See “Import Study Nears Showdown,” Electronics, November 6, 1959, pp. 32-33;
“Electronics in Japan,” Electronics, May 27, 1960, pp. 99-100; and “Washington Rejects
Transistor Import Quota,” Electronics, June 8, 1962, p. 7.
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 129
sumer electronics division and opposed protection. Foreign Trade and Tariff Proposals,
Pt. 8, Hearings before the House Committee on Ways and Means, 90 Cong. 2 sess. (Gov¬
ernment Printing Office, 1968), p. 3486.
5. “Import Study Nears Showdown,” p. 32.
6. See Dennis J. Encarnation and Mark Mason, “Neither MITI nor America: The
Political Economy of Capital Liberalization in Japan,” International Organization, vol. 44
(Winter 1990), p. 37, for references on this point.
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 131
national economic system since 1945. The delicate balance between the
threats of protection and the open trading system they were intended to
secure (a system placed in jeopardy if threats are transformed into actions
on too wide a scale) fueled policy debates in 1959, as it does today.
On the Japanese side, the response to the campaign for protection in
Washington was to blaze some trails that would become equally well trod
over time. A Japanese delegation traveled to Washington in 1959, where
it stressed that activities in consumer electronics created no threat to
U.S. defense, and that Japanese companies had “no immediate plans to
go after the markets for highly specialized transistors.”7 The delegation
also made clear its willingness to impose voluntary quotas or other ne¬
gotiated arrangements. In the late spring of 1960, in response to contin¬
uing frictions, MITI proceeded to impose quotas and floor prices on
transistor radios exported to the United States.8 The system was contin¬
ued in later years.9
The issue of third-country exports (evasion of quotas by shipping
goods to other countries for reexport to the United States) arose early
on and was dealt with administratively by MITI. By 1961 large quantities
of Japanese transistors were being exported to Hong Kong (clearly by
the same firms whose own exports of transistor radios to the United
States were being limited), where they were then assembled into transis¬
tor radios and exported to the United States. With sales of inexpensive
Japanese transistor radios in the United States undercut by large-scale
imports of even less expensive radios made in Hong Kong, MITI sus¬
pended transistor exports to Hong Kong in May 1962. A system of quan¬
titative limits on transistor exports to Hong Kong was set up a couple of
months later.10
Such export cartels had by then been used for some time in postwar
Japan, initially in textiles, where they dated back to the early 1950s. By
the early 1960s a complex system of legal and administrative measures
permitted—indeed, often encouraged (since moderation of “excessive
competition” was an avowed objective of industrial policy)—the forma¬
tion of both domestic and export cartels, regulating pricing, capacity
investments, or production levels. By the early 1960s, when similar mea¬
sures covering transistor radios and transistors were put into place, the
Japanese government estimated that roughly 30 percent by value of its
exports to the United States were affected by some sort of quantitative
control, on domestic or export price or quantity.* 11
Ultimately, the U.S. producers’ petition to restrict Japanese transistor
imports was rejected in 1962, after a good two and a half years of dis¬
cussion, on relatively narrow national security grounds. The American
semiconductor industry, after an alarming slowdown in 1960-61, was
growing rapidly again, American producers were getting the vast bulk of
the defense business, and capacity seemed adequate to meet any future
surges in demand.12 Although some U.S. producers continued to com¬
plain to Washington that the closed Japanese market was being used as
the base for an export push into the American market, the government’s
attitude was perceived by the Japanese to be that Japan’s concentration
on the consumer market permitted U.S. firms to concentrate their re¬
sources on defense needs, and therefore contributed to national security.
As one Japanese observer later put it, the Japanese were pleased that the
United States, as a technologically advanced nation, could afford such a
fair decision.13
and Japan. The U.K. government threatened to suspend Japanese cotton cloth imports by
the Crown Colony unless the Japanese lifted their export restrictions on transistors. See
“Japanese Transistors Sought by Hong Kong,” Electronics, June 8, 1962, p. 8; and David
Rose, “Hong Kong’s Transistor Radio Exports Soar to 100,000 a Month,” Electronics,
September 28, 1962, p. 24.
11. See Eleanor Hadley, Antitrust in Japan (Princeton University Press, 1970), p. 387.
12. “Washington Rejects Transistor Import Quota,” p. 7.
13. Yasuzo Nakagawa, Semiconductor Development in Japan (Tokyo: Diamond Pub¬
lishing, 1985), pp. 125-27 (in Japanese).
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 133
14. See Electronic Industries Association of Japan, Facts and Figures on the Japanese
Electronics Industry (Tokyo, 1986), p. 34.
15. “Japan Moves to Cut Television Set Surplus,” Electronics, October 14, 1960, p. 11.
16. “Japan Launches Color TV,” Electronics, January 22, 1960, p. 22.
17. See “Japanese Push Color TV Production Plans,” Electronics, July 24, 1960, p. 11.
18. See “Japan Boosts TV Set Output,” Electronics, February 26, 1960, p. 48; and
“Japanese TV Sets Arriving This Week,” Electronics, April 29, 1960, p. 32.
19. Electronics Industries Association of Japan, Facts and Figures, p. 35.
20. See Kozo Yamamura and Jan Vandenberg, “Japan’s Rapid-Growth Policy on Trial:
134 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
The Television Case,” in Kozo Yamamura and Gary R. Saxonhouse, eds., Law and Trade
Issues of the Japanese Economy: American and Japanese Perspectives (University of Wash¬
ington Press, 1986), pp. 259-63; and Brief of Appellants, Zenith Radio Corporation and
National Union Electric Corporation, case nos. 81-2331, 81-2332, 81-2333, United States
Court of Appeals, Third Circuit (Philadelphia: International Printing Company, 1983),
pp. 14-19.
21. Accounts at the time made much of the distinction between price floors and actual
pricing, since “the actual export prices cannot be set because of Japan’s antitrust laws.”
See “Japan Firms Setting Minimum TV Prices,” Electronics, August 2, 1963, p. 7. A fairly
complete discussion of the history of price-setting schemes applied to Japanese TV exports
may be found in Yamamura and Vandenberg, “Japan’s Rapid Growth Policy on Trial,”
pp. 238-70.
22. It is not clear, however, that these cartels always worked well. For example, it is
known that cheating on check prices on television export prices, in the form of under-the-
table rebates to importers, sometimes occurred.
23. In 1974 Zenith Radio Corporation launched a widely publicized antitrust suit
against Japanese television exporters.
24. Brief of Appellants, pp. 20-28; and Yamamura and Vandenberg, “Japan’s Rapid
Growth Policy on Trial,” pp. 262-63. Despite the rule, some U.S. customers managed to
purchase TVs from more than one of the Japanese exporters. A Japanese exporter could
also circumvent the rule by naming as one of the five American purchasers its own U.S.
subsidiary, which would then be free to sell to any U.S. customer. Kenneth G. Elzinga,
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 135
Roughly coinciding with the formation of the TV export cartel was the
development of a domestic cartel to fix prices in the Japanese domestic
color television market.25 In 1964, after the continuing depressed circum¬
stances of the TV industry had triggered a round of severe price cuts in
the domestic market, a web of discussion groups was formed to set retail
prices, rebates, retail and wholesale profit margins, and to discuss such
matters as demand forecasts and bottom prices. Production, inventory,
and shipment data were exchanged and market shares and output quotas
assigned.26 In 1970 six of the companies were found by the Japan Fair
Trade Commission to have broken the antimonopoly law, although they
were also found to have ceased the violations. But various of the groups
associated with this domestic cartel continued to meet after the export
cartel disbanded in 1973. One midlevel group continued to hold monthly
meetings until 1977, and the highest-level group (the Okura Group,
named after the hotel where the presidents of seven top consumer elec¬
tronic producers met to discuss these issues for a variety of electric
appliances) continued to meet through at least 1974.27
The link between the domestic TV cartel and the export cartel has
always been controversial. MITI was clearly involved in the design and
establishment of what was nominally a privately administered export
cartel arrangement and sent representatives to meetings at which actions
were taken to set export prices and foreign market shares. If only because
“The New International Economics Applied: Japanese Televisions and U.S. Consumers,”
Chicago-Kent Law Review, vol. 64, no. 941 (1988), p. 964; and Franklin M. Fisher, “Mat¬
sushita: Myth v. Analysis in the Economics of Predation,” Chicago-Kent Law Review, vol.
64, no. 941 (1988), p. 973.
25. In the 1950s Japanese producers had set up a cartel to regulate prices in black and
white television sets. As David Schwartzman has commented, Japanese TV manufacturers
and distributors created a cartel, the Home Electric Appliances Market Stabilization Coun¬
cil, under the aegis of the Electronic Industries Association of Japan in 1956. This group
set up a series of retail price agreements and enforcement procedures and attempted to
organize production cuts (not fully successfully). In 1957 the Japan Fair Trade Commission
decided that the enforcement procedures violated Japan’s antimonopoly law and ordered
the Market Stabilization Council to halt punitive actions against discounters. (The JFTC
did not, however, rule against price fixing per se or force the council to disband.) See
Schwartzman, The Japanese Television Cartel: A Study Based on Matsushita v. Zenith
(University of Michigan Press, 1993), pp. 77-80.
The considerable evidence unearthed in the 1970 and earlier investigations is also cited
in Yamamura and Vandenberg, “Japan’s Rapid Growth Policy on Trial,” pp. 253-57; Brief
of Appellants, pp. 35-38; and Elzinga, “The New International Economics Applied,”
p. 964.
26. Schwartzman, Japanese Television Cartel, pp. 81-89.
27. Schwartzman, Japanese Television Cartel, pp. 87-89.
136 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
American companies always cut their price even further.”35 Table 3-1,
although it does not control for volume and product mix, shows that unit
costs for a variety of advanced ICs tended to be significantly higher in
Japan in the mid-1970s, while products typically used in consumer elec¬
tronics (linear ICs, display chips) actually tended to be priced below U.S.
levels.
The SIA’s activity was successful in prodding a Senate subcommittee,
in December 1978, to order the U.S. International Trade Commission
(ITC) to launch an informational investigation into the competitive po¬
sition of the U.S. semiconductor industry.36 By the time the commission’s
report was delivered, at the end of 1979, the forecast threat had mater¬
ialized. Amid a boom in U.S. electronics production, a major shortage
of 16K DRAMs had developed over the summer of 1979.37 Viewing these
shortages as an opportunity, three major Japanese producers—Hitachi,
Fujitsu, and NEC—had plunged into the U.S. market in force. By the
end of the year they had collectively achieved about a 40 percent share
of the U.S. market for 16K DRAMs.38
During the nine-month ITC investigation, the SIA’s evolving theory
of Japanese industrial practices was further elaborated. At an ITC hear¬
ing in San Francisco in May 1979, the SI A for the first time suggested
that the two-tier pricing scenario was actually occurring, notably in sales
of 16K DRAMs.39 Also, apparently for the first time, it was suggested
that, in addition to being an example of what would now be called a
strategic trade policy implemented by the Japanese state, Japanese poli¬
cies contained an explicitly predatory element. Noyce, arguing on behalf
of the SI A at the May hearing, articulated a strategic conception of
the dangers of dependency on foreign suppliers as follows: “Now one
might argue that U.S. consumers benefit from these bargain prices. But
we must realistically ask how long such bargain prices last. Middle East¬
ern oil was a bargain until we became dependent upon it. Similarly,
sooner or later the Japanese losses on high density memories will be
recouped and I submit that it is foolish to assume any long run benefit
to consumers.”40
What is vague in these statements is whether these strategic calcula¬
tions are viewed as being undertaken by the Japanese state, with Japanese
companies passively responding to changes in state policy, or whether the
companies are being accused as active parties to the strategic plan. One
might, for example, conceive of “state predation,” where state subsidies
induce firms to cut prices in order to stimulate exit by foreign rivals.41 At
the time, though, the prevailing conception was one of “Japan, Inc.,”
38. See Lloyd Schwartz, “Mostek Chief: Japan Threatens Industry,” Electronic News,
October 15, 1979, p. 72; and Henry Scott Stokes, “Japan Goal: Lead in Computers,” New
York Times, December 12, 1979, p. Dl. Buoyed by surging demand for computers, even
IBM was reportedly contacting Japanese chip suppliers in search of 16K DRAM supplies.
See John Hataye, “IBM Shopping in Japan for 16K Dynamic RAMs,” Electronic News,
December 24, 1979.
39. See Jim Leeke, “‘Practices Abroad Unfair,’ SIA Says at ITC Hearing,” Electronic
News, June 4, 1979, p. 106.
40. “Statement of Dr. Robert N. Noyce, Vice Chairman of the Board, Intel Corpora¬
tion, on Behalf of the Semiconductor Industry Association,” Hearings before the U.S.
International Trade Commission, San Francisco, May 30, 1979, pp. 21-22.
41. Willig, for example, draws a distinction between “strategic dumping,” which relies
on national policies to protect exporting companies’ home market, in order to gain cost
advantages and create monopoly power for the exporters in importing markets, and “pred¬
atory-pricing dumping,” which is a company strategy to obtain monopoly power in an
importing country’s market. See Robert D. Willig, “The Economic Effects of Antidumping
Policy,” Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris, 1992, pp. 7-8.
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 141
with firms and state joined together in a collective strategic plan. In the
colorful words of one top American executive, it was the “33 companies
in the SI A taking on the sovereign nation of Japan.”42
42. W. J. Sanders, president of Advanced Micro Devices at the time, quoted in Leeke,
‘“Practices Abroad Unfair,’” p. 106.
43. These data were contained in a confidential submission to the ITC dated August
17, 1979, but appear to have been presented later at a hearing of the congressional Joint
Economic Committee in October 1979. See ITC, Competitive Factors Influencing World
Trade in Integrated Circuits, publication 1013 (November 1979), pp. 70-71; and U.S.-
Japanese Trade Relations, Hearing before the Joint Economic Committee, 96 Cong. 1 sess.
(GPO, 1979), pp. 21, 26. Comparisons are further complicated by the fact that DRAMs
are sold on both long-term contracts and on a spot basis, for immediate delivery, and prices
can diverge substantially. It is unclear whether an appropriate spot-to-spot or contract-to-
contract comparison between the two markets was being made.
44. For detailed evidence on the structure of the U.S. semiconductor market, see
Kenneth Flamm, “Measurement of DRAM Prices: Technology and Market Structure,” in
Murray F. Foss, Marilyn E. Manser, and Allan H. Young, eds., Price Measurements and
Their Uses (University of Chicago Press, 1993).
142 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
other contract prices, not with spot prices, and vice versa. Dumping
complaints, historically, have not always drawn these distinctions.
Furthermore, the semiconductor market in Japan has a rather different
structure from that in the United States. For the most part, large chip
manufacturers in Japan sell directly only to sister electronic equipment
divisions of the parent corporation. The vast bulk of external sales to
large customers go through authorized sales agents, while smaller cus¬
tomers are served through secondary sales agents who order product
from the main sales agents. Even smaller quantities are sold on a spot
basis through retailers clustered in selected urban areas, such as Tokyo’s
Akihabara district.45 Prices quoted in Japanese trade sources typically
refer either to prices to large users through main sales agents or to spot
prices in Akihabara. The prices large users pay in Japan are roughly
comparable with U.S. contract prices, whereas U.S. spot prices are most
similar to Akihabara pricing.
The complexities of direct U.S.-Japan price comparisons never be¬
came a major issue, however, because charges of two-tier pricing had a
relatively short life. In the months after the San Francisco hearing, de¬
mand for 16K DRAMs surged, and as prices soared, complaints about
low-priced imports faded away. From mid-1979 until the present day,
charges that U.S. prices for Japanese chip imports were below Japanese
levels ceased to be an important irritant to trade relations.
Instead, complaints that the Japanese were selling below the cost of
production in both markets began to emerge.46 Texas Instruments, the
intent in this development: “Indeed, Intel buys the 16K RAMs from Japan because we
have found that cheaper than to make them ourselves. Now, there is some artificial pricing
in that market. That’s what I’m suggesting.” Senator [Adlai] Stevenson: “Well, that’s what
I’m getting at. Is there? What do you mean by that?” Dr. Noyce: “Up until the San
Francisco hearings, we could buy 16K RAMs in the United States, from Japanese compa¬
nies at lower prices than we were selling the same product for in Japan.” Senator Stevenson:
“Is that artificial pricing or are they just more productive and efficient?” Dr. Noyce: “We
were meeting the market price in Japan. After the ITC hearings in San Francisco, U.S.
prices went up and Japanese prices went down. I think the prices had been artificial there,
but that is a very difficult thing to determine.” Trade and Technology, Part III, Hearings
before the Subcommittee on International Finance of the Senate Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs, 96 Cong. 2 sess. (GPO, 1980), p. 176.
47. “U.S. Semiconductor Firms Disagree on Import Strategy,” Denver Post, March 23,
1980, p. 40.
48. See “Exports of Japanese Semiconductors to US at Low Prices Conspicuous; Half
Price, Too, through Trading Firms; Manufacturers Strengthen Checking of Destinations,”
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, May 24, 1980, p. 6.
49. “NEC Suspends Shipments of RAM Chips to U.S. Market,” Japan Economic
Journal, March 3, 1981; and “Japanese Electronics Firms Delay Plans to Mass-Produce
64-K Chips,” Asian Wall Street Journal Weekly, April 6, 1981, p. 14.
50. See “Japan Firms Plan U.S. Production of Advanced Circuits,” Asian Wall Street
Journal Weekly, May 18, 1981, p. 17; Thomas J. Lueck, “NEC Plans $100 Million U.S.
Plant,” New York Times, June 27, 1981, p. Dl; and “Top Four Japanese IC Makers Expand
U.S. Operations,” Asian Wall Street Journal Weekly, July 13, 1981, p. 15.
144 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
Japanese chip makers had in fact taken their first hesitant steps toward
setting up U.S. production facilities, amid intensifying political criticism,
several years earlier. Among the major Japanese companies, NEC had
been the pioneer in 1978, when it acquired Silicon Valley producer Elec¬
tronic Arrays.51 At least partly in explicit reaction to rising protectionist
sentiment, Fujitsu announced an investment in a San Diego manufactur¬
ing facility in 1979. In that same year Oki Electric opened negotiations
to have some of its products produced in the United States, Hitachi
unveiled plans to use a Dallas facility for semiconductor assembly, and
NEC began shipping U.S.-made chips from its California plant.52
By late 1979 it had become clear that U.S. imports of Japanese chips
had roughly doubled in value, compared with the previous year.53 Amid
an unforeseen boom in demand for chips used in computers, and man¬
ufacturing yield problems on American production lines for 16K
DRAMs, a shortage of DRAMs had developed in the United States.54
Japanese chip makers rushed into that vacuum. In a parallel develop¬
ment, many Japanese semiconductor equipment makers had begun their
first serious probes into the U.S. market. Key production tools developed
in cooperation with the NTT and MITI R&D programs in very large
scale integration—such as the Canon projection alignment system and
the Takeda Riken (later renamed Advantest) high-speed logic tester—
were first offered for sale in the U.S. market in 1979.55 The clearly evident
Japanese thrust into the U.S. semiconductor market provoked a rising
crescendo of political criticism within the United States.56
51. There had been at least two instances of Japanese investments in small American
semiconductor companies earlier in the 1970s: Toyo Electronics (which later changed its
name to Rohm) acquired Exar Integrated Systems in 1972, and Hattori Seiko acquired
Micropower Systems in 1977.
52. John Hataye, “Semicon Makers May Increase Production in U.S.,” Electronic
News, June 11, 1979, p. 24; and “Special Report: Japan is Here to Stay,” Business Week,
December 3, 1979, pp. 81-86.
53. See “Japan IC Exports to U.S. in 8 Months Double to $96M,” Electronic News,
November 19, 1979, p. 58.
54. “Special Report: Can Semiconductors Survive Big Business?” Business Week, De¬
cember 3, 1979, p. 85; and Cheryll A. Barron, “Microelectronics Survey: All That Is
Electronic Does Not Glitter,” Economist, March 1, 1980, pp. 3-4.
55. See John Hataye, “Japan Equip. Firms Eye Exports to U.S.,” Electronic News,
December 3,1979, p. 20. For a discussion of these products’ roots in Japan’s VLSI projects
see chapter 2.
56. For example, see Lloyd Schwartz, “Mostek Chief: Japan Threatens Industry,” Elec-
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 145
tronic News, October 15, 1979, p. 72; Steven Hershberger, “Mostek Chief: Limit Imports
from Japan,” Electronic News, November 19, 1979, p. 42; and Stokes, “Japan Goal: Lead
in Computers,” p. Dl.
57. See Stokes, “Japan Goal: Lead in Computers,” p. Dl.
58. “Can Semiconductors Survive Big Business?” p. 85.
59. Testifying before the U.S. International Trade Commission in 1979, SI A members
argued that “ ‘double’ testing techniques of the Japanese were expensive (‘It is an economic
issue, not a quality issue’) and that they considered this ‘better deal’ given to buyers of
Japanese circuits a type of market penetration technique.” U.S. International Trade Com¬
mission, Competitive Factors Influencing World Trade in Integrated Circuits, USITC publi¬
cation 1013 (November 1979), p. 24. The SIA notes that “To achieve this quality there is a
high dependence on the best available tools and automation. This adds to the capital cost,
but it may pay in the long run through higher yield and higher productivity. Japan, because
of its easier access and lower cost of capital has an inherent advantage.” The International
Microelectronics Challenge: The American Response by the Industry, the Universities, and
the Government (Cupertino, Calif., May 1981), pp. 27-28. See also “Japan Makes Them
Better,” Economist, April 26, 1980, p. 55.
60. See Ray Connally, “Japanese Make Quality-Control Pitch,” Electronics, April 10,
1980, p. 81; and “Japan Makes Them Better,” pp. 55-56.
146 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
Over the next several years American chip makers suffered through a
continuing series of unfavorable quality comparisons with the Japanese
by their customers. Although these assessments showed considerable
improvement relative to the Japanese competition, American chips were
still perceived to lag in quality through the early years of the 1980s.61 A
federal crackdown on fraudulent quality testing and certification practices
in Defense Department chip procurement over 1981-82 did little to help
this perception.62 The American semiconductor industry fought back by
touting its aggressive adoption of improved quality management practices
over this period, and questioning the existence of a quality gap with
Japan to the extent portrayed in customer reports.63 However, at least
some American chip producers, as they point to their current world-class
standards, frankly acknowledge the existence of a significant quality gap
in the early 1980s.64
61. See “U.S. RAMs Improve But Still Lag Japan’s,” Electronic Engineering Times,
November 10, 1980, p. 1; “Xerox Data Uphold HP Contention that Japanese RAMs are
Better,” Electronic Engineering Times, March 2, 1981, pp. 2, 16; Ray Connolly, “Copy
Japanese, U.S. Managers Urged,” Electronics, April 21, 1982, pp. 106-08; Jerry Lyman
and Alfred Rosenblatt, “The Drive for Quality and Reliability, Part 1,” pp. 125-28, and
“Part 3: Users Push for Quality,” pp. 141-43, Electronics, May 19, 1981; “HP, Motorola
Continue the Debate over Quality and its Management,” Electronic Engineering Times,
May 25, 1981, pp. 14-15; and Larry Waller, “Perception Lag Nags U.S. Chip Makers,”
Electronics, April 21, 1982, pp. 42-43.
62. See “A Crackdown on Chip Quality,” Business Week, January 11, 1982, p. 110; and
Marilyn Chase and Jim Drinkhall, “Grand Jury Bores in on the Faulty Testing of U.S.
Defense Gear,” Wall Street Journal, October 4, 1982, p. 1.
63. Waller, “Perception Lag Nags U.S. Chip Makers,” pp. 43-44.
64. Top Intel executive Craig Barrett, for example, was quoted in a 1991 Intel publi¬
cation as saying that, in the early 1980s, “we realized that while we had always been a
leader in technical solutions and product reliability, our product quality levels did not meet
world class standards. After benchmarking against the best manufacturers in the world,
we learned that we had a long way to go to match up.” Katie Woodruff, “Intel’s Journey
to Total Quality,” Intel Microcomputer Solutions (January-February 1991), p. 8.
It is worth contrasting this assessment with the public statements of Intel vice-president
Willard Kauffman in April 1982: “Kauffman, in fact, questions whether any such gap
actually existed to the extent it was perceived by Richard Anderson of Hewlett-Packard
Co.’s Computer Systems division. . . . According to Intel’s Kauffman, the Japanese still
excel in their ‘strategy to market quality. ... We have to sell our quality in the same way.
We have nothing to be ashamed of,’ he emphasizes.” Waller, “Perception Lag Nags U.S.
Chip Makers,” p. 44.
The customer critique of American chip producers’ quality practices in the early 1980s
is implicitly supported by U.S. semiconductor companies’ advertising and marketing liter¬
ature in the late 1980s, which stressed the impact of the adoption of rigorous statistical
process control procedures on defect rates. Advertising by National Semiconductor Cor¬
poration, for example, depicted a decline in defects from 7,800 parts per million (ppm) in
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 147
Organizing a Response
In the spring of 1981 the SIA unveiled its program to combat the
growing competitive threat from abroad. It identified three key areas for
action. One was international in focus: access to foreign markets. The
other two were domestic in nature: greater U.S. stimuli to capital for¬
mation, and increased investment in U.S. R&D and engineering educa¬
tion. Specific goals with respect to market access in Japan included a
reduction of the Japanese tariff on semiconductors from 10 percent to 4.2
percent by April 1982 (rather than in 1987, as scheduled by the Tokyo
Round agreement on multilateral tariff reductions under the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade), and equivalent treatment for U.S. and
domestic companies in Japan (national treatment) in “access to financing
at competitive rates, bureaucratic processing of subsidiary filings with
the government, and ability to recruit top Japanese engineering talent.”
For the first time also, the SIA called on the Japanese government to
create an “affirmative action program” to remedy the effects of past
discriminatory practices against foreign firms.65
Action quickly followed on several of these issues. In May 1981 the
U.S. government announced that it had negotiated the requested reduc¬
tion in Japanese tariff levels.66 Congress passed a 25 percent incremen¬
tal tax credit for R&D in 1981, after the SIA pressed its case for this
measure.67
The industry itself also took concerted action on the research and
education fronts. By late 1981 the SIA had formed the Semiconductor
Research Cooperative, a joint effort to funnel R&D funds into basic
research projects in universities.68 And at Stanford University, with joint
funding from both industry sponsors and the Defense Advanced Re-
1978 to 37 ppm in 1988. National’s vice president for quality and reliability was quoted as
saying that “We feel our ability to produce and supply high-quality, reliable products is
now [author’s emphasis] second-to-none in the industry.” National Semiconductor Corpo¬
ration, National Anthem (1989), p. 7. Similarly, Intel reported a decline in defects from
10,000 ppm in the early 1980s to 200 in 1989, with levels in the 10- to 50-ppm range for
mature products. Woodruff, “Intel’s Journey to Total Quality,” pp. 8-9.
65. Semiconductor Industry Association, The International Microelectronic Challenge,
pp. 22-23.
66. Clyde H. Farnsworth, “U.S. and Japan Plan Cuts in Semiconductor Tariffs,” New
York Times, May 12, 1981, p. Dl.
67. See Andrew Pollack, “Federal Aid Sought for Semiconductors,” New York Times,
May 19, 1981, p. Dl.
68. “Electronics Research Projects,” New York Times, December 27, 1981, p. Dl.
148 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
69. See “Integrated Systems Center Begins Work,” Stanford Observer, February 1982,
p. 1. DARPA also funded more traditional academic research programs at universities,
including the relatively large effort at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT).
See Paul Schindler, “VLSI: Retrieving the Top Spot from Industry,” Technology Review
(January 1983), p. A3, which notes that DARPA funding accounted for $2.7 million of a
$5.1 million budget for the MIT microsystems program.
70. “Control Data’s Push for a Cooperative Chip,” Business Week, April 20, 1981, p.
39; Andrew Pollack, “Singing the Semiconductor Blues,” New York Times, May 24, 1981,
p. F4; Marilyn Chase, “U.S. Electronics Firms Consider Joining in Research Venture to
Counter Japanese,” Wall Street Journal, March 1, 1982, p. 6; Ray Connolly, “Updating
Antitrust Law to Permit Joint R&D,” p. 66, and “U.S. R&D Consortium Takes Shape,”
pp. 97-99, Electronics, March 10, 1982; and William C. Norris, “Cooperative R&D: A
Regional Strategy,” Issues in Science and Technology, vol. 1 (Winter 1985), p. 94.
71. Howard Wolff, “64-K RAM Battle is Murky,” Electronics, September 8, 1981, pp.
89-90; Alan Alper, “Buyers Hedging on Long-Term 64K Pacts Until U.S. Firms Ramp
Up,” Electronic News, February 8, 1982, p. 1; Andrew Pollack, “Japan’s Big Lead in
Memory Chips,” New York Times, February 28, 1982, p. FI; and “A Chance for U.S.
Memories,” Business Week, March 15, 1982, pp. 126-27.
72. See Sabin Russell, “U.S. Suppliers Outnumbered in 64K RAM Competition—for
Now,” Electronic News, August 24, 1981; and “Prices of 64K RAM Drop to One-tenth of
Year Ago,” Japan Economic Journal, September 15, 1981.
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 149
73. Clyde H. Farnsworth, “Japanese Chip Sales Studied,” New York Times, March 5,
1982, p. Dl; John Eckhouse, “Are Japanese Chip-makers ‘Dumping’?” San Francisco
Examiner, March 5,1982; and Bruce Entin, “Motorola Asks Inquiry into Japanese Pricing,”
San Jose News, March 10, 1982. Motorola’s interest in government action came after a
sharply divided SIA reportedly voted down a Motorola proposal to submit a joint anti¬
dumping complaint. See I. M. Destler and Hideo Sato, “U.S.-Japan High Technology
Trade: Politics and Policy,” University of Maryland, School of Public Affairs, August 1986,
p. 38. Motorola executives also were reported to have wanted the government to take the
lead in order to avoid placing itself in an antagonistic position with Hitachi, the top Japanese
producer of 256K DRAMs, with which it had close ties. Richard Wightman, “SIA Split on
64K RAM ‘Dump’ Action; Expect Members to Petition,” Electronic News, March 22,1982,
p. 1.
74. Clyde V Prestowitz Jr., writes of his and Lionel Olmer’s efforts as officials in the
Commerce Department at that time: “Our only tools were bluff and persuasion. Olmer,
who was responsible for administering the antidumping laws, warned MITI officials in
Washington that the Commerce Department might begin to monitor Japanese chip prices.
Our ability to do so was in fact limited, but we hoped to make the Japanese more cautious
by suggesting the possibility.
It worked for a while. The prices of 64K RAMs began to stabilize, as MITI warned
Japanese companies.” Clyde V. Prestowitz Jr., Trading Places: How We Allowed Japan to
Take the Lead (Basic Books, 1988), p. 49.
75. Alan Alper, “See 64K Levels in Line With Demand,” Electronic News, March 15,
1982; and “Justice Department Investigating Japanese 64K RAM Mktg.; Seek Price, Ship¬
ment Data,” Electronic News, August 2, 1982, p. 1.
76. The Japanese trade publication VLSI Report’s timeline of U.S.-Japan trade fric¬
tions, for example, sets February 1982 as the date “MITI instructions on dumping began.”
The Electronic Industries Association of Japan’s official industry handbook, IC Gaido
Bukku, has a timeline also associating February 1982 with the entry “MITI to Japanese
150 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
The very next day, MITI and various Japanese company representa¬
tives officially denied reports of export restraints.79 But U.S. prices were
to continue well above Japanese price levels through early 1983.80
The episode was to take an even more bizarre turn three months later,
in July 1982, when MITI was informed by the U.S. Justice Department
that Japanese producers were being investigated to determine whether a
cartel had been formed to set volume and price levels in the U.S. mar¬
ket.81 (Prices in the United States had continued to hover at almost
double Japanese levels.)82 An NEC spokesman, apparently unfamiliar
industry, no exports that might cause blame for dumping.” See “Japan-U.S. IC Frictions,”
VLSI Report (Tokyo: Press Journal, ca. 1988), p. 62; and Electronic Industries Association
of Japan, IC Gaido Bukku (Tokyo, 1987), p. 62.
77. A. E. Cullison, “Japan Alters Memory Chip Export Policy,” Journal of Commerce,
April 7,1982; and “64K RAM Exports Are Being Held Down by Makers,” Japan Economic
Journal, April 13, 1982.
78. Clyde H. Farnsworth, “Japan to Cut Export of Chips to U.S.,” New York Times,
April 8, 1982, p. Dl.
79. Steve Lohr, “Japanese Deny Any Cut in Chip Exports to U.S.New York Times,
April 9, 1982, p. Dl; see also Associated Press, “Computer Chip Reports ‘Premature,’”
Japan Times, April 10, 1982.
80. Jack Robertson, “Japanese RAM Power,” Electronic News, February 28, 1983.
81. “U.S. Will Probe Japanese Makers of Semiconductors,” Japan Times, July 27, 1982;
Steve Lohr, “6 Japan Concerns Focus of Inquiry,” New York Times, July 27, 1982; “U.S.
Probes Sales of Computer Chips by Six Japan Firms,” Wall Street Journal, July 27, 1982;
“Justice Department Investigating,” p. 1.
82. “U.S. Won’t Indict Japan Semiconductor Makers,” Japan Times, July 30, 1982.
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 151
with U.S. antitrust concepts, responded that “Japanese interests have set
relatively high prices for 64-kilobit RAM chips in the U.S. so as not to
raise suspicions of dumping”!83 Needless to say, the whole sequence of
events left the Japanese somewhat confused. In March, amid loud indus¬
try and Commerce Department complaints about excessively low prices,
Japanese DRAM import prices had suddenly jumped, only to have the
Justice Department announce an investigation of excessively high prices
a short time later.84
A lawyer speaking for the SIA explained the apparent contradiction
as a real-life example of precisely the predatory scenario Robert Noyce
had first warned of back in 1979: “They may have committed violations
of the dumping laws early on, to buy market share, and now they’re
getting the payoff by limiting supplies and raising prices.”85 Noyce himself
even weighed in on the issue in early 1983: “It is probably correct that
the Japanese are selling RAMs in the United States at higher prices. It
is a classic case of competitors using predatory low pricing to take the
lion’s share of a market, and then increasing prices once they dominate
that market.”86
By mid-1983, however, the market for DRAMs was again picking up,
and the industry faced looming shortages. Prices in Japan rose sharply,
pushed up to U.S. levels.87 After depositions were taken from Silicon
Valley representatives of the Japanese chip makers in the spring of 1983,
the Justice Department’s antitrust investigation simply faded away.88 As
the industry entered one of its cyclical boom periods, trade frictions
receded as an urgent matter requiring attention in Washington.
What was most notable over this period of renewed friction, as the
64K DRAM entered the market, was a subtle shift in the argument about
predatory behavior in semiconductors. By 1980 a large and highly visible
Japanese R&D subsidy in semiconductors, directly focused on DRAMs
and related manufacturing technology, had been ended.89 Formal quotas
had also been ended, and tariffs were low and dropping rapidly.90 Al¬
though complaints about access to the Japanese market persisted, and
even intensified in early 1983, it could no longer be claimed that higher
prices in the home market enabled Japanese producers to persistently
price below average cost in foreign markets. If Japanese producers were
losing money in the United States on sales of dumped memory chips,
they had to be losing money at home as well.
Thus, the U.S. industry analysis of Japanese predation in 1982 nec¬
essarily had to change from one where the Japanese government’s policies
of R&D subsidy and home market protection created conditions encour¬
aging firms to price exports low, without necessarily requiring explicitly
predatory behavior (since home market profits could offset foreign
losses). Instead, the argument now was that, to sustain massive losses
around the world for a prolonged period of time, Japanese firms must
necessarily have adopted an explicitly predatory strategy, with the expec¬
tation that in the long run, with the exit of foreign competitors, rents
could be collected to offset the initial costs of predation. The appearance
of significantly higher U.S. prices for a period beginning in March 1982,
and the charge that the fruits of predation were finally being harvested,
added an additional element to the mix, namely, collusion: American
producers argued that, having achieved a dominant position in the market
for DRAMs, Japanese companies were cooperating, either on their own,
or with administrative support from their government, to cut back supply
on foreign markets in order to collect monopoly rents. Since 1982 this
mix of strategic government industrial and trade policy with strategic—
89. Substantial (but considerably less visible) support from NTT and a privately funded
cooperative follow-up to MITI’s VLSI project, continued, however. See chapter 2 for
details.
90. In February 1985 Japan and the United States agreed to end all tariffs on semicon¬
ductors, effective the following month. “Japan and US Agree to Abolish Semi-Conductor
Tariff Next Month,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, February 9, 1985, p. 3.
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 153
Sectoral Negotiations
As the decibel level mounted in public exchanges between U.S. and
Japanese semiconductor companies, pressure for an increasing level of
government involvement in trade issues also rose. The U.S. government
had already responded to a considerable degree back in the spring of
1981, when several planks of the American chip industry’s public policy
platform—notably, accelerated bilateral tariff cuts and adoption of an
incremental R&D tax credit—had been implemented quite quickly. By
early 1982, however, when Japanese producers had displaced American
suppliers in the 64K DRAM market to a degree visible to even the most
determined optimists, political pressure for further action was building
rapidly. In February 1982 senior Reagan administration officials were
considering a Defense Department proposal to impose restrictions on
imports of 64K DRAMs on national security grounds.91 As previously
discussed, top Commerce Department officials used threats and bluffing
to persuade MITI to intervene with Japanese companies.
Processes set in motion over this period were to result in the first
formal bilateral negotiations over semiconductor trade issues, soon to
become a staple of U.S.-Japan relations. Exchanges between U.S. and
Japanese officials led to the idea of forming an ongoing bilateral “working
group” concerned with trade frictions in high-technology industries, such
as semiconductors, to deal with such issues as market access, export
pricing, national treatment, and elimination of tariffs. The formation of
this forum was also seen by the U.S. government, and presented to U.S.
semiconductor companies, as an alternative to aggressive pursuit of a
dumping case.92 In the spring of 1982 the U.S. and Japanese governments
91. Art Pine, “Computer Chips from Japan May Be Curbed,” Wall Street Journal,
February 5, 1982, p. 6.
92. Author’s discussion with former U.S. government officials, September 1992. High-
technology sectors other than semiconductors in which there had been some history of
trade friction included telecommunications (particularly NTT procurement), the Japanese
satellite market, the Japanese computer market, and cooperation on joint R&D projects.
See John Sullivan Wilson, “The United States Government Trade Policy Response to
Japanese Competition in Semiconductors: 1982-1987,” report to the U.S. Congress (Office
154 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
97. Other steps listed in the confidential “chairman’s note” included an agreement to
expand “supply sources ... for some semiconductor products in order to give more business
opportunities to U.S.-based semiconductor producers,” “opportunities to make direct con¬
tacts with semiconductor user divisions of the companies,” and “such measures as dispatch¬
ing to or stationing in the U.S. of staffs responsible for procurement.” These measures
were described as applicable to “Japanese semiconductor users who are also semiconductor
producers,” but a concluding sentence in the note promises “best efforts ... to increase
the number of companies which will become subject to the above-mentioned measures of
encouragement.”
The confidential chairman’s note is reproduced in Semiconductor Industry Association,
Japanese Market Barriers in Microelectronics: Memorandum in Support of a Petition Pur¬
suant to Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974 as Amended (Washington: Dewey, Ballantine,
Bushby, Palmer and Wood, June 14, 1985), p. 91; and in Wilson, “The United States
Government Trade Policy Response,” pp. 46-47.
Clyde Prestowitz, cochair of the U.S. HTWG representation at the time, argues that
the existence of this “secret side letter,” with its agreement to “encourage” Japan users to
“enlarge opportunities,” was the most significant new aspect of the November 1983 rec¬
ommendations. However, this specific language is also found in the main public text, not
just in the confidential note. See Clyde V. Prestowitz Jr., “The New Chip Agreement: Does
It Go Far Enough?” Electronics, October 1991, p. 25; and Prestowitz, Trading Places,
p. 156.
The reasons for keeping this note confidential were most likely related to another issue.
The note specifically suggests that private business decisions of Japanese firms are to be
“subjected” to “measures of encouragement,” and therefore acknowledges an explicit MITI
role in influencing these decisions. Also, although industry sources say little significance
was read into the language at the time, the note applies to JJ.S.-based semiconductor
156 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
producers (as opposed to all foreign semiconductor producers) and might therefore be
interpreted as violating GATT commitments to equal most-favored-nation treatment for all
trading partners.
98. “Recommendations of the U.S.-Japan Work Group on High Technology Industries,
Semiconductors”; and author’s discussion with former U.S. government officials, Septem¬
ber 1992. NTT announced a process for testing and certifying semiconductors based on the
HTWG recommendation in March 1984. Electronics Industries Association of Japan, IC
Gaido Bukku, p. 62.
99. The chip mask protection measures also followed a much publicized dispute be¬
tween Intel and Japan’s NEL over the latter’s copying of an Intel microprocessor.
100. See Wilson, “The United States Government Trade Policy Response,” pp. 47-50;
and SI A, Japanese Market Barriers, p. 68.
THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY 157
offered only to top and middle management in the six largest companies,
with little or no effort invested in contacting smaller users.101 Moreover,
when overall chip sales veered into sharp decline in late 1984, American
chip sales in Japan declined even more rapidly, and U.S. companies’
market share sagged. Evidence of an active MITI effort to kickstart
foreign company sales, or of success in forging long-term relationships,
was notably lacking in the declining market. Many in both U.S. govern¬
ment and industry argued that, despite an almost three-year investment
in the HTWG effort, little in the way of tangible results had actually
been achieved.
Over the long term, though, the HTWG set several important prece¬
dents. This set of negotiations institutionalized continuing high-level bi¬
lateral negotiations over trade issues in a single high-technology sector.
The initial result of this process, the November 1983 HTWG recommen¬
dations, was the very first “semiconductor agreement.” It marked the
first time MITI explicitly agreed to use its leverage with private Japanese
firms to promote imports of semiconductors—such voluntary import ex¬
pansion (VIE) measures were to occupy an increasingly prominent po¬
sition in the MITI program for dealing with trade frictions as the 1980s
progressed. And it was the first time—but not the last—a “secret side
letter” was used as a device to avoid some of the difficult issues raised
by such commitments. The vagueness of the language in which the
negotiators couched these commitments, and the subsequent debates
over the extent to which they had been honored, foreshadowed even
sharper exchanges over language and meaning in later semiconductor
agreements.
As had been true in the past, and would be again, a decline in the
global semiconductor market and in the fortunes of U.S. producers was
the catalyst for a renewed offensive on trade policy, as the truce forged
by the HTWG fell apart. The last such surge in political activity had
occurred in the spring of 1982, spurred by the Japanese manufacturers’
capture of the lion’s share of the 64K DRAM market, weak chip demand,
and heavy price cutting. A major study documenting the arguments that
the Japanese had subsidized their chip producers, engaged in predatory
pricing, and denied U.S. firms free access to the Japanese market had
been commissioned at this time.102 By the time this study was released,
101. Wilson, “The United States Government Trade Policy Response,” pp. 48-49.
102. Semiconductor Industry Association, The Effect of Government Targeting on World
Semiconductor Competition (Cupertino, Calif., 1983).
158 THE GENESIS OF AN AMERICAN TRADE POLICY
103. See Wilson, “The United States Government Trade Policy Response,” pp. 41-42;
SIA, “The U.S.-Japan Work Group,” pp. 1-2; and Destler and Sato, “U.S.-Japan High
Technology Trade,” pp. 38-44.
CHAPTER FOUR
The Semiconductor
Trade Arrangement and
Its Aftermath
159
160 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Briefly, the historical period from 1985 through 1991 may be broken
into four more or less distinct periods for the purposes of understanding
semiconductor trade policy.
1. See Micron Technology, Inc., “In the Matter of 64K Dynamic Random Access
Memory Components from Japan, Petition for the Imposition of Antidumping Duty,”
presented to the U.S. Department of Commerce, June 21, 1985 (public version), p. 22; and
U S. International Trade Commission, 64K Dynamic Random Access Memory Components
from Japan, USITC Publication 1862 (Washington, June 1986), p. A-67.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 163
In the spring of 1985 the debate over the existence of barriers to U.S.
companies’ access to the Japanese semiconductor market heated up con¬
siderably in the United States. Known only to a small number of insiders
in American industry and government, some dramatic reports of collusive
practices within the Japanese semiconductor industry had surfaced and
after investigation been judged credible by the U.S. side.
The failure of U.S. firms to reclaim a larger share of the semiconductor
market in Japan after formal trade barriers had been lifted in the mid-
1970s had long been shrouded in conflicting explanations, allegations,
and suspicions, but no smoking gun had ever materialized. Indeed, as
noted in the chapter 3, there was, in the commodity memory chip market,
at least, some evidence that Japanese firms had managed by the late
1970s to turn superior levels of quality into a competitive advantage and
a reasonable explanation for the Americans’ failure to make headway.
But what of the rest of the market?
From the perspective of American industry, the stubborn fixity of its
Japanese market share coupled with the history of Japanese trade and
3. See note 237 in chapter 2 for examples of such reports. The Consulting Group, BA
Asia Limited, in The Japanese Semiconductor Industry 1980 (Hong Kong, May 1980),
pp. 178-79, cites a case in which Japanese power supply makers refused to buy imported
capacitors, claiming that NTT required that only domestic components be used in equip¬
ment sold to it. Japanese customs practices—capricious misclassification of items and
“uplifts” routinely and arbitrarily added to invoiced values—were also cited as an informal
barrier to imports during this period. See U.S. Department of Commerce, A Report on
The U.S. Semiconductor Industry (1979), p. 96.
4. See Semiconductor Industry Association, The Effect of Government Targeting on
Worldwide Semiconductor Competition (Washington, 1983), pp. 79-84. The examples given
are 8080-type microprocessors and programmable read-only memory chips (PROMs).
5. SIA, Effect of Government Targeting, p. 79.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 165
6. My account of this episode draws on confidential letters and drafts from U.S. sources
that I was permitted to review and interviews with former U.S. government officials.
Sources of information about the activities of the Council of Nine, and its very existence,
were considered extremely sensitive by both American government and industry.
7. Some within the government apparently argued that such activities were unlikely to
succeed in the long run in benefiting their organizers and thus could safely be ignored.
Interview with government official, February 1996. As noted in chapter 3, from the early
through mid-1980s, semiconductor prices in the Japanese market generally had been near,
and at times below, U.S. prices.
8. The major reason why the existence of the council never surfaced at the time is
probably the sensitivity of sources of information about its activities. Also, because some
Japanese subsidiaries of U. S. companies as well as major Japanese semiconductor producers
were alleged to have been involved in these activities, the implications for trade negotiations
between the United States and Japan would not necessarily have been clean and sharp.
9. Although by all accounts the existence of the council was only one of several issues,
including concerns about national security, that created a consensus to move forward with
the 301 case.
10. Shortly after the 301 case was filed, a senior Japanese trade official reportedly told
a senior U.S. official that “this case has shaken MITI to the core” because of the history
that might be dug up. Interview with former U.S. government official, January 1996.
166 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
by NEC that it “plans to reduce exports to the U.S., while increasing its
production in the U.S.,” and an announcement by Toshiba that it too
planned to cut its U.S. chip exports by 20 percent in fiscal 1985.14 Despite
these measures, LDP Policy Board Chairman Fujio publicly stepped up
the pressure at the end of July, declaring it necessary to consider the
“possibility of restricting exports of automobiles and semiconductors and
imposing an export surcharge.”15
U.S. government investigations of the Micron 64K DRAM dumping
case and the SIA’s Section 301 petition continued to move forward rap¬
idly through August 1985, when Intel, AMD, and National Semiconduc¬
tor launched yet another dumping case against Japanese EPROM pro¬
ducers. In September Micron filed a private antitrust case as well, against
Japanese DRAM producers.16
The chip market meanwhile remained mired in recession: by October,
Intel, Mostek, and National Semiconductor had announced their inten¬
tion to close down facilities and phase out their production of DRAMs.17
Three Japanese companies with U.S. manufacturing facilities—Fujitsu,
Hitachi, and Toshiba—announced postponements in plans to expand
their U.S. manufacturing operations, while NEC announced a complete
halt in its fabrication of new 64K DRAMs.18
14. See “Hitachi to Reduce Semiconductor Exports to U.S. for This Fiscal Year by
30%,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, July 23, 1985, p. 1; “Toshiba to Cut Semiconductor Exports
to U.S.,” Kyodo News Wire story, July 24, 1985; and “Chip Makers to Cut Exports to
U.S.,” Japan Economic Journal, July 30, 1985, pp. 1, 4.
15. See “Also Restriction on Exports of Automobiles and Semiconductors; Policy
Board Chairman Fujio,” Yomiuri Shimbun, July 27, 1985, p. 2.
16. That $300 million suit was dropped in October 1986, a month after the signing of
the STA. See Wall Street Journal, October 2, 1986, p. 4.
17. Most US firms dropped out of DRAMs after the initial cuts in semiconductor
exports by Hitachi, NEC, and Toshiba. This contradicts the assertion by analysts affiliated
with the SIA that “the move toward production regulation by the Japanese producers’
group began . . . [when] Japanese DRAM producers had few competitors left except each
other.” Thomas R. Howell, Brent L. Bartlett, and Warren Davis, Creating Advantage:
Semiconductors and Government Industrial Policy in the 1990s (Washington: Semiconductor
Industry Association and Dewey Ballantine, 1992), p. 117.
Also, Japanese chip exporters had previously cut DRAM exports in response to political
pressure, in 1982, when Japanese world market share was very much smaller than in 1985.
Political pressure, rather than a sudden jump in market power, appears to have stimulated
supply cuts in both cases.
18. “Construction of Very Large-Scale Integrated Circuit Plant in U.S.; Toshiba Post¬
pones Plan; By Half a Year, or One Year, Due to Semiconductor Depression,” Nihon Keizai
Shimbun, October 23, 1985, p. 9; and “NEC to Adjust Production of 64K DRAMs;
Suspends Pre-process Operations; To Digest Semiconductor Products in Stock,” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, October 31, 1985, p. 9.
168 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
19. Of course, the government was considering this action because of industry com¬
plaints. See “U.S. Heading Toward Antidumping Investigation on 256 Kilobit DRAM of
Japanese Make; Conference of Secretaries Advises President; Hard Fight over ‘Strategic
Goods’ Gives Rise to Crisis Feeling,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, November 8, 1985, p. 6.
20. “Semiconductor Maker, Full Power for 256K Price Hike, MPU for Price Cut,”
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 14, 1986, p. 18.
21. See “Semiconductor Industry Showing Signs of Recovery from Depression,” Sankei
Shimbun, December 5, 1985, p. 6; see also “Following ‘Leather,’ Also ‘Semiconductors’
Have Hard Sailing; Japan-US Consultations; MITI Officials in Charge Impatient Without
Good Idea,” Tokyo Shimbun, December 6, 1985, p. 3; “Semiconductor Companies Remain
Calm Toward Preliminary Ruling of ‘Guilty’ on 64K DRAM; Upper-Grade Item Now
Attached with Major Importance; Consultations between Japanese and US Governments
Are Watched,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, December 6, 1985, p. 8.
22. See “Int’l Price Recovery Sparks Semiconductor Industries; Samsung Planning to
Expand 64K D-RAM Plant to Meet Rising Demands,” Korea Herald, December 26, 1985;
and “Chip Manufacturers Slate New Facility Investments,” Korea Herald, February 2,1986.
By December 1985 regional price differentials appear to have been created in the 64K
DRAM market, with Japanese domestic prices falling even as U.S. export prices were
rising. See, for example, “Price Reduction Demand for Semiconductors Intensifies,” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, December 4, 1985, p. 20.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 169
23. This dumping investigation was unusual in two respects. First, it was one of a
handful of antidumping cases ever initiated by the U.S. government itself, rather than an
industry petitioning the government. Second, it covered 256K and higher density DRAMs,
including new products not yet on the market.
24. “Nippon Electric and Hitachi Begin to Curb 256K DRAM Production; Watching
U.S. Dumping Investigations,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, December 18, 1985, p. 9. See also
“NEC, Hitachi Hold Down 256K DRAM Production; To Avoid U.S. Dumping Charge,”
Japan Economic Journal, December 28, 1985, p. 18.
25. See “Super LSI Domestic Shipment Price Hike a Little Over 10%, Consideration
of Friction with U.S.,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 11, 1986, p. 1; “Semiconductor
Maker Full Power,” p. 18; and “Semiconductor Demand to Recover This Year; From
Demand-Price Survey, Price Crash Period Ends; Bottom Spreads Supports Price,” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, January 14, 1986, p. 18.
26. “Negotiation for Determining Price, Next Month to Be the Peak; Makers Forceful
for 256K Price Hike; Users Demand Price Reduction Due to Yen Appreciation,” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, January 29, 1986, p. 20; and “Semiconductor: Due to Japan-U.S. Trade
Friction, Unprecedented Price Rise; U.S.-Made Import Doubtful; Maker Confident in
Profit Maintenance,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 30, 1986, p. 20.
27. “This price increase by Japanese makers, aimed at calming bilateral trade friction,
170 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
has its roots in political judgments beyond simple market principles.” “Semiconductors:
Abnormal Price Increase Caused as a Result of the U.S.-Japan Trade Friction,” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, January 30, 1986, p. 20. The article concludes, “One maker pointed out
that the year 1986 marks the first time all the makers share a sense of cooperation in the
history of the semiconductor industry, unlike in the past when they were competing with
each other for higher production and lower prices. They expect that less price competition
will bring them larger profits in [fiscal] 1986.”
28. The preliminary dumping margins found by the Commerce Department in these
cases were relatively high and undoubtedly created further pressure for a negotiated solu¬
tion to the conflict. For EPROMs, the rates were as follows: Hitachi, 29.9 percent; Toshiba,
21.7 percent; NEC, 188 percent; Fujitsu, 145.9 percent. See “Political Settlement Between
Japan and US Expected by Manufacturers; Tentative Decision of ‘Guilty’ on EPROM,”
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, March 13, 1986, p. 9.
29. “EPROM Prices in Steady Tone—Semiconductors; Japanese Manufacturers Exer¬
cise Self-Restraint on Low-Priced Sales,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, April 2, 1986, p. 18.
30. In that speech Tanahashi reportedly stated that “it is expected that the total share
of U.S.-made semiconductors used by five large Japanese manufacturers will account for
19.5 to 20 percent in 1990.” This was interpreted in the Japanese press as a proposal from
the Japanese side. See “How Should We Settle Japan-US Semiconductor Friction?” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, April 2, 1986, p. 2. It was precisely at this point that reports of a 20
percent market share target by 1990 began to circulate within the Japanese semiconductor
industry. See Mikio Fujiwara, “This Is a Side Letter to the U.S.-Japan Semiconductor
Agreement,” Bungei Shunju, May 1988, pp. 124-37 (the author, an executive in a Japanese
semiconductor firm, wrote the article under a pseudonym).
On the U.S. side, this March industry meeting prompted an investigation by the Federal
Trade Commission. See “Suspicions about Violation of Antimonopoly Law—Guarantee
of Share Rate for Semiconductors Imported from US; Fair Trade Commission’s View,”
Asahi Shimbun, April 24, 1986, p. 2. The commission’s probe was not unusual; it has often
examined the outcomes of antidumping agreements.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 171
31. The legal basis for the proposal being considered was “flexible application of the
Export Trade Control Ordinance or formation of export cartels on the basis of the Export
and Import Transactions Law.” “MITI Heading Toward Introduction of Minimum Price
System for Semiconductor Exports to US; Proposal Will be Made to US Next Month, at
Earliest,” Sankei Shimbun, February 20, 1986, p. 7.
32. See Louise Kehoe, “US and Japan Poised for Agreement on Semiconductors,”
Financial Times, March 20, 1986, p. 6. Even in its preliminary form the global price
monitoring scheme was an immediate target for its critics: a Financial Times editorial of
March 18 blasted the plan as a “blatantly protectionist” international cartel. Clayton K.
Yeutter, then U.S. Trade Representative, responded that “there is no chance whatsoever
of that occurring, and any such suggestion would be vehemently opposed by the U.S.
government!” See “US, Japan, and Semiconductors,” letter to the editor, Financial Times,
April 25, 1986, p. 21.
It is interesting to contrast Yeutter’s comments with the following assessment of objec¬
tives by Clyde V. Prestowitz Jr., who as an adviser to Secretary Malcolm Baldrige helped
shape the Commerce Department’s position in the semiconductor negotiations: “we would
have to persuade the Japanese government to force up prices in its home market as well as
in third-country markets (that is, markets in countries other than the United States and
Japan). This amounted to getting the Japanese government to force its companies to make
a profit and even to impose controls to avoid excess production—in short, a government-
led cartel.
For the free-traders of the United States to be asking Japan to cartelize its industry was
the supreme irony. Yet it was logical.” Clyde V. Prestowitz Jr., Trading Places: How We
Allowed Japan to Take the Lead (Basic Books, 1988), p. 62.
33. See Yoko Shibata and Louise Kehoe, “NEC Bid to Beat US Dumping Rules,”
Financial Times, April 21, 1986, p. 6.
172 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
American Producers,” Wall Street Journal, May 30, 1986, p. 40; and Jim Van Nostrand,
“U.S. Claims Trade Breakthrough in Semi Talks,” Electronic Engineering Times, June 2,
1986, pp. 1, 16.
36. Christian Tyler, “Europeans in Chip Dumping Check,” Financial Times, May 1,
1986, p. 6.
37. See Louise Kehoe, “Japanese Targeting Further Chip Market, US Makers Claim,”
Financial Times, June 20, 1986, p. 7.
38. Tim Dickson, “EEC Chip Makers Accuse Japan,” Financial Times, July 1, 1986,
p. 14.
39. Louise Kehoe, “Compromise Likely in US-Japan Semiconductor Talks,” Financial
Times, June 25, 1986, p. 4.
40. Louise Kehoe, “US, Japan Fail to Meet Chip Row Deadline,” Financial Times,
July 2, 1986, p. 6; and Louise Kehoe and Carla Rapoport, Financial Times, “Not Long
Left to Turn a Chip Truce Into a Treaty,” July 9, 1986, p. 5.
174 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
41. Louise Kehoe and Carla Rapoport, “Tokyo May Agree to Aid US Chip Sales in
Japan,” Financial Times, July 21, 1986; and “US and Japan Near Accord on Semiconduc¬
tors,” Financial Times, July 21, 1986, pp. 1, 18.
42. See Brenton R. Schlender, “Japanese Dumping of Chips in U.S. Said to Continue,”
Wall Street Journal, July 25, 1986, p. 8; and Louise Kehoe and Carla Rapoport, “Japan
Stepping Up Chip Dumping, Says US,” Financial Times, July 26, 1986, p. 20.
43. See Louise Kehoe, “Stalemate in Chips Trade Talks,” Financial Times, July 28
1986, p. 1.
44. Carla Rapoport, “Japan Yields to US Demands on Microchip Price Monitoring,”
Financial Times, August 4, 1986, p. 1.
45. See Kehoe, “Stalemate in Chips Trade Talks,” p. 1; and Rapoport, “Japan Yields
to US Demands,” p. 1.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 175
From the start it was clear that some Japanese chip executives opposed
the concessions made by MITI in the STA.46 Indeed, Japanese company
executives and others immediately raised doubts about the legality of
both the third-country price monitoring system and the apparent com¬
mitment to increase foreign chip sales in the Japanese market.47
But even more stringent and direct controls over the Japanese industry
had been built into the STA. An explicit, though little discussed, provi¬
sion of the agreement required MITI to exert direct control over Japanese
256K DRAM exports, to ensure that shipments to the United States
through mid-September took place at the “normal” rate.48 Although this
transitional provision was designed to thwart a last-minute rush of ship¬
ments by Japanese companies in July and August to circumvent the loom¬
ing specter of price floors, the U.S. government had clearly set a prece¬
dent for tolerating—indeed, requiring—direct intervention by MITI in
setting quantities to be shipped by individual companies. Recall also
46. As early as July 7, the chairman of the Keidanren (a business organization repre¬
senting Japan’s largest corporations) expressed “apprehension about the excessively restric¬
tive nature of the agreement.” “Japanese Makers Dissatisfied with Chip Trade Accord,”
Nikkei News Bulletin, July 7, 1986. In August a MITI official was quoted as saying, “We
still don’t think we have [the Japanese industry’s] agreement.” See Carla Rapoport, “Tokyo
Concerned About Setting a Trade Precedent,” Financial Times, August 4, 1986, p. 4. See
also Tim Dickson and Carla Rapoport, “EEC and Japan Criticise Semiconductor Agree¬
ment,” Financial Times, August 2, 1986, p. 1.
47. Brenton R. Schlender and Stephen Kreider Yoder, “U.S.-Japan Semiconductor
Agreement Is Expected to Prove Difficult to Enforce,” Wall Street Journal, August 4, 1986,
p. 19; Rapaport, “Japan Yields to US Demands,” p. 1; and “Tokyo Concerned about
Setting,” p. 4.
48. This agreement was contained in a supplementary “secret” memorandum dated
August 1, 1986, initialed by Yeutter and Watanabe. The exact text is as follows:
52. This is point 5 of section II, “Third Country Market Measures,” of the letter.
53. During the negotiations, the American side first suggested that the Japanese use
their export control act for enforcement purposes. Author’s interview with a member of
the U.S. negotiation team, 1989.
54. “Certificate of Approval for Exports to US Withheld, Semiconductors; For Part
Covering Last Minute Contracts; Carrying Out of Promise at Time of Reaching Agreement
at Negotiations, MITI; 256 Kilobit DRAMs as Objects,” Asahi Shimbun, August 6, 1986,
pp. 12-13; “MITI ‘Blocked’ Big Chip Exports Before Price Rise,” Japan Times, August 7,
1986, p. 1; and “MITI to Control July Semiconductor Exports,” Nikkei News Bulletin,
August 7, 1986.
55. The range of FMVs set for individual companies apparently became much more
compressed over time. Company-specific 256K DRAM FMVs initially set in July for the
third quarter of 1986 reportedly ranged from $2.50 to $8.00. The second round of FMVs,
for the fourth quarter of 1986, reportedly ranged from $2.50 to $4.00, while the third
round, set for the first quarter of 1987, spanned $2.50 to $3.00. The FMVs for the second
quarter of 1987 were reportedly identical to the first-quarter floor prices, but those in the
third quarter of 1987 dropped to the $1.89-$2.75 range (averaging $2.34). See Nikkei Top
Articles, December 2,1986; “U.S. Announces No Revision—Fair Prices of Japanese-Make
Semiconductors for April-June Period,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, March 24, 1987, p. 3; and
“U.S. Dept, of Commerce Announces Fair Market Prices for ICs,” Nikkei News Bulletin,
September 28, 1987.
178 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
60. See “To Unify Standards for Calculating Original Costs of Semi-conductors; MITI’s
Policy; Aimed at Calming Down Dissatisfaction over Price Differentials in Exports to Third
Nations,” Asahi Shimbun, November 23, 1986, p. 9.
61. ‘“One Product Having Three Prices’ Distorts Markets; Five Months Since Japan-
US Semiconductor Negotiations; Mutilated Restrictions with Loopholes; Third Nations
Single Out Agreement for Criticism,” Asahi Shimbun, December 10, 1986, p. 9; and
“Approval Necessary for Over ¥50,000—Semiconductor Exports; Trade Control Ordi¬
nance to be Revised; to Prevent Evasion of Price Monitoring,” Asahi Shimbun, December
12, 1986, p. 9.
180 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Controlling Production
62. See John Sullivan Wilson, “The United States Government Trade Policy Response
to Japanese Competition in Semiconductors, 1982-1987,” report to the U.S. Congress
(Office of Technology Assessment, September 1987), p. 119.
63. See “Nippon Electric Switches to Policy of Cutting 256K DRAM Production;
Structure for Monthly Production of Nine Million Will Be Established; MITI’s Guidance
Swallowed for Easing of Friction,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, March 6, 1987, p. 9; and “NEC
to Cut 256K DRAM Output by 10%,” Nikkei Top Articles, March 6, 1987. In “NEC Cuts
Domestic Output of 256K 40% in March,” the Japan Economic Journal reported on
April 4, 1987, that “while the Government has asked Japanese microchip makers to curtail
production to help alleviate the chip trade dispute with the U.S., NEC did not comply with
the call until February, saying that the domestic market had no oversupply of memory
chips” (p. 19). By March 1987 TI Japan was apparently the lone holdout against production
cutbacks among Japanese DRAM producers. See Robert Ristelhueber, “TI Speeding Up
U.S. DRAM Output,” Electronic News, April 20, 1987, pp. 1, 6.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 181
78. It was reported in the Japanese press that TI Japan had been asked by MITI on
March 25 to cooperate by reducing 256K DRAM output. See “MITI to Guide Japan TI
Into Production Reduction—256K DRAM,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, March 26, 1987, p. 9;
“Semiconductor Manufacturing Coordination Guidance to Be Applied to Foreign-Capital
Manufacturers, Too; MITI,” Asahi Shimbun, March 24, 1987, p. 9.
79. See “TI Japan to Cut Output of 256K DRAMs by 13%,” Electronic News April
6, 1987, p. 4.
80. Ristelhueber, “TI Speeding Up U.S. DRAM Output,” p. 6.
81. “Semi-conductor Market Wobbling Due to Foreign Pressure (Part 2—Conclusion);
Spot Transactions Continue to Decline,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, April 1, 1987, p. 20.
82. “MITI-ordered Production Cutbacks Raise Local Prices of 256K DRAMs,” Japan
Economic Journal, April 18, 1987.
83. “We Ask EC Representative Denman; Semiconductors,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun,
April 11, 1987, p. 7; and “Japanese Semiconductors, Southeast Asia Crying Out Over
Shortage; Will Not Tolerate Sparks from Japan-US Friction,” Yomiuri Shimbun April 12
1987, p. 7.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 185
Thus by April 1987 both the production and the export of DRAMs by
Japanese companies had been placed under fairly tight MITI controls.
The vice chairman of NEC publicly acknowledged MITTs role but called
upon Japanese companies “to extricate themselves from the inclination
toward excessive competition, as can be seen from the rivalry among ten
84. TI Japan, for example, was reported to be experiencing long delays in receiving
MITI export approvals. A spokesperson was quoted as saying that TI “didn’t know if the
delay was intentional or not.” See Jack Robertson, “Japan Export Delays Draw Fire From
U.S. Makers,” Electronic News, April 6, 1987, p. 4. A frank discussion of the use of export
licensing procedures to control export prices may be found in Fujiwara, “This Is a Side
Letter,” pp. 124-37.
85. See General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), Japan—Trade in Semicon¬
ductors: Report of the Panel (Geneva, March 24, 1988).
86. MITI, “Japanese Position Paper,” Tokyo, April 10, 1987, p. 8.
186 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
87. The NEC’s Atsuyoshi Ouchi stated in an interview: “Under MITI’s administrative
guidance, the 256K DRAM of Japanese make is subjected to thoroughgoing measures for
the reduction of production and the restriction of exports. Also, the ‘gray market’ for
transactions through brokers, which market is said to be the cause for sales at low prices,
has almost disappeared.” “US Semiconductor Retaliation; Industrial Circles Will Review
International Strategy; Inclination toward Excessive Competition Will Be Improved; Ja¬
pan’s Experiential Rule Shaken,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, April 19, 1987, p. 4.
88. “Semi-conductor Retaliation; Manufacturers Showing Signs of Self-Reflection!?!),”
Asahi Shimbun, May 3, 1987, p. 8.
89. “Semi-conductor Retaliation,” p. 8.
90. See the description of this report in “Contents of Facilities Investments Also Will
Be ‘Supervised’; MITI Will Change Survey Method for Prevention of Friction; Reduction
of Excessive Investments Will Be Urged,” Asahi Shimbun, January 12, 1988, p. 11.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 187
91. See “MITI’s Council on Machinery and Information Industries Draws up Report
Calling for Promotion of ‘International Cooperation’ by Semiconductor Manufacturers;
Establishment of ‘Prospects for World Demand’ Urged,” Mainichi Shimbun, June 12, 1987,
p. 9.
92. Council on Future Prospects of the Machinery and Information Industries, Pros¬
pects for International Cooperation in the Machinery and Information Industries (Tokyo:
MITI, August 24, 1987) (in Japanese). Concrete proposals for the semiconductor industry
included these two points (p. 41):
1. Coordinating Information Gathering and Providing Information on Demand and
Supply: . . . Also, in light of past failures, we expect to make an accurate forecast of
international demand and supply of semiconductors. It is desirable to promote the idea of
establishing an international practice among related industries so that they can exchange
ideas and information without breaking any laws.
At present, MITI is making a short-term forecast of demand and supply of semicon¬
ductors through discussions at the investigation committee on semiconductor demand and
supply forecasts. It is necessary to listen to the opinions of makers, users, and experts on
relevant items (of semiconductors), make a short and long term forecast of demand and
supply in major markets, and examine the possibility of providing adequate information
that will benefit companies’ planning for manufacturing and investment.
2. Preventing Dumping: On preventing dumping, we should monitor export prices and
costs according to the US-Japan Semiconductor Agreement. Considering the fact that prices
below production cost are due to production in excess of actual demand, we should seek
cooperation of related companies and maintain a production level that matches with actual
demand based on the demand and supply forecast mentioned above. Moreover, we need
to investigate whether we need to improve the current antidumping system.
93. “Contents of Facilities Investment,” p. 11; and author’s interview with Japanese
semiconductor industry analyst, November 1989.
94. “Share of Imported 256K DRAM Chips May be Rising,” Nikkei News Bulletin,
May 13, 1987.
188 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
European Reaction
Why was Europe not consulted, in order to head off these complaints?
Europeans certainly realized that the game was afoot in the first part of
1986, and they shot off messages to the Americans and Japanese asking
that strictly bilateral talks affecting third-country markets be broken off.98
The European Community and the United States were at the time em¬
broiled in disputes over agricultural trade issues, and that may have made
cooperation on other issues more difficult. And since European produc¬
ers accounted for only 10 to 12 percent of global chip production, they
may indeed have simply been viewed as a marginal player, an unnecessary
complication in what were already difficult bilateral talks.
An irony in all this was that a movement was already under way in
Europe to lobby for an STA-like outcome for the European market. By
May 1986, European chip producers, in envy of the extraordinary polit¬
ical success of the American SI A, had followed its example by forming
the European Electronic Component Manufacturers Association
(EECA) in order to bring dumping cases against Japanese chip imports.99
In December 1986 the EECA filed a dumping complaint with the Euro¬
pean Community, and by April 1987 the Community had widened the
investigation to include both DRAMs and EPROMs.100 The EECA ar¬
gued that supplies diverted from the U.S. market by the STA were being
shifted to the European market, further depressing prices.
After the STA was signed in September 1986, prices continued to drop
in the European market (as in Japan) through the spring of 1987.101 After
sanctions were imposed and more-restrictive production guidelines im¬
posed by MITI in the second quarter of 1987, prices quickly rose. In the
fall of 1987 Japanese vendors were informing their European customers
that an allocation system had been installed, and by late 1987 prices in
the European market had risen substantially above U.S. levels. Through
1988 and into 1989, Japanese vendors continued to tell European cus-
102. One cannot, of course, neglect the possibility that this was merely a convenient
excuse. However, according to a number of knowledgeable Japanese involved in that coun¬
try’s electronics industry (who spoke to me in late 1989), MITI continued administrative
guidance on investment through the spring of 1988, continued to guide the regional allo¬
cation of DRAM shipments until mid-1989, and continued to offer opinions on companies’
investment plans through at least late 1989.
103. Commission of the European Communities, “Japan to Implement GATT Rec¬
ommendations on Trade in Semiconductors,” press release, Brussels, June 22, 1989. Japan
had actually issued a proposed response to the GATT panel report on March 7, but it was
apparently not accepted by the Community until June.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 191
104. The U.S. Commerce Department added an 8 percent profit margin to a con¬
structed cost of production in setting the FMV
105. Lucy Kellaway, “Japan-EC Microchip Agreement Hits Snag,” Financial Times,
October 5, 1989, p. 2.
106. An antidumping duty was also set to apply to gray market imports. See Commis¬
sion Regulation no. 165/90, January 23, 1990, published in Official Journal of the European
Communities, January 25, 1990, pp. L 20/5-30.
192 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
107. See “Japan to Raise Output of 256 Kilobit DRAM by 10%,” Kyodo News wire
dispatch, June 24,1987, which reports that MITI officials “instructed” Japanese chip makers
to increase production of 256K DRAMs, and quotes them as saying that the ministry would
“allow” the growth in response to an increase in overseas demand; see also “MITI to Ease
‘Guidance’ for Reduced Chip Production,” Nikkei News Bulletin, June 10,1987; and “MITI
to Partially Lift Restrictions on Chip Production,” Nikkei News Bulletin, June 11, 1987.
108. “MITI Reports Microchip Output Estimate (1),” Nikkei News Bulletin, June 25,
1987.
109. “IC Manufacturers Prepared to Expand Production in Kyushu; No Moderation,”
Asahi Shimbun, June 16, 1987, p. 11.
110. “1M DRAM Price to be Unchanged in June,” Nikkei News Bulletin, June 10,
1987.
111. Rufus Baker, “Toshiba Cuts 1-Mb Chip Ships,” Electronic Buyers’ News, Septem¬
ber 14, 1987, pp. 1, 80.
112. See “MITI to Keep Closer Watch on ASIC Prices,” Nikkei News Bulletin, June
23, 1987.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 193
arrays, had joined memory chips on the list of products for which MITI
guidance was holding down production.113
As a recovery in the computer industry continued briskly through the
fall of 1987, prices for chips continued to be pushed upward. In the late-
September forecast for the final quarter of 1987, MITI again raised pro¬
duction quotas for DRAMs: by roughly 5 percent for 256K chips and
80 percent for 1M memories.114 By October a serious shortage appeared
to be on the horizon, and manufacturers were reported to be turning
away large orders. Domestic Japanese prices even began to approach the
FMV export price floors.115
Controls on Investment
113. See “Anonymous Round Table Discussion on Silicon,” Kinzoku Jihyo, no. 1319,
November 15, 1987.
114. “MITI Lifts Limit on Chip Production,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, September 25,
1987, p. 3.
115. “Semiconductors; Sudden Increase in Demand Leads to Growth of Strong Con¬
cern Over Shortage of Supply,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, October 2, 1987, p. 20.
116. “Nine Semiconductor Companies Keep Facilities Investments Moderated in Re¬
vised Plans as Well, In Accordance with MITI’s Guidance,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Oc¬
tober 10, 1987, p. 8.
117. “Nine Semiconductor Companies Keep Facilities Investments Moderated,” p. 8.
194 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
licly proclaiming that they were acting to remove limits on chip produc¬
tion, American trade negotiators continued to press MITI to limit in¬
vestments by Japanese firms in new capacity well into 1988.121
What was the real content of the changes in the export control regime
made in November 1987? Organizationally, responsibility for approval of
export license applications was moved from MITI’s semiconductor mon¬
itoring office (charged with surveillance of export prices) to a separate
office, so that “there was no feedback from the Monitoring Office to the
office dealing with COCOM screening.” However, “in cases where export
prices were ‘extremely below cost,’ MITI would express its concern to
the companies concerned. . . . Under the old system . . . some misun¬
derstanding seemed to have been created among exporters that delays
had been caused by inappropriate pricing. The new system would elimi¬
nate such misunderstandings.”122
What of the infamous production “forecasts”? After November 1987
the production forecast system was henceforth to be described by
MITI as
a reference for manufacturers in their production schedules. MITI ex¬
plained its objective to manufacturers and impressed upon them the need
to reflect real demand in their production. Individual companies were
expected voluntarily to bring their production almost in line with the fore¬
casts, taking into account the appropriate total production. The forecasts
were not legally binding and the Government did not allocate production
volume to individual companies. For manufacturers to conspire on pro¬
duction volume was against the anti-trust laws in Japan.123
Certainly the statistical record does not indicate a sea change in the
relative accuracy of the “forecasts” of the most politically sensitive prod¬
ucts—DRAMs and EPROMs—before and after November 1987. During
the final quarter of 1986, before MITI clamped down hard on Japanese
producers, the DRAM production forecasts were wildly inaccurate, with
production of both 64K and 256K parts exceeding one-quarter-ahead
forecasts by margins in the range of 30 to 50 percent of actual production.
126. “At present, manufacturers are hurrying the expansion of [1M DRAM] produc¬
tion. Because of such technical problems as the delay in the improvement of the yield rate,
however, production in the July-September period also is likely to increase by only about
2,700,000.” “Semiconductor Prices Continue Rising; Shortage of Supply Will Reach Peak
in July-September Period,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, July 16, 1988, p. 18.
‘“It took chip makers longer than they expected to get good yields of one-megabit
chips,’ says Jim Feldhan, vice-president of In-Stat Inc., a Scottsdale Ariz. market research
firm that tracks the semiconductor industry. Mr. Feldhan says as many as 90% of all one-
megabit chips were defective and had to be discarded as recently as early this year, but
that lately yields of good chips have improved to around 50%.” Brenton R. Schlender,
“Chip Prices Fall: Easing of Shortage Seen,” Wall Street Journal, July 18, 1988.
“Currently, major makers are shipping an estimated 12 million units of 1-M DRAM
chips monthly.
The industry had planned to reach that level four to six months earlier. Apart from
Toshiba, however, producers were unexpectedly slow to boost production. Then, compa¬
nies’ average yield rate, a production yardstick that measures the percentage of useable
chips, stood at between 40% and 50%.” Tadashi Tamaki, “Heavy Investment in Chip
Factories Spurs Fear of Glut,” Japan Economic Journal, October 1, 1988, pp. 1, 5.
198 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
A. Quarterly forecasts
Percent
B. Semiannual forecasts
and Hitachi, had had some difficulties raising their manufacturing yields
in their early production of the 1M DRAM.
But if such yield problems, in the aggregate, played a significant role
in creating shortages, of 1M DRAMs in 1988, it is hard to see how they
could have been unexpected, given the accuracy of the MITI forecasts.
Since manufacturing time from starting a silicon wafer on the line to a
finished memory chip is typically 60 to 75 days, to adjust production
scheduling in midquarter to compensate for unexpected yield problems
during that same quarter and still hit the three-month forecast would be
most difficult.127 To accurately hit both three-month and six-month fore¬
cast targets, as happened with both the 256K and the 1M DRAM pro¬
duction forecasts for 1988, would seem to require quite an accurate
estimate of yields over a roughly six-month period. Thus, a continuous
history of coming within 10 percent of three- and six-month production
forecasts, in a product requiring over two months of processing on the
production line, suggests that unanticipated yield problems could not
have been a major issue for the industry as a whole in 1988.
Although yields were undoubtedly low in the initial stages of 1M
DRAM production (as has been true for every generation of chip), it is
hard to reconcile big surprises in yields with the pinpoint accuracy of the
MITI production forecasts. Thus both one- and two-quarter-ahead
DRAM production forecasts exceeded actual output by about 9 percent
in the second quarter of 1988 (figure Ala). At other times during 1988,
forecast output for 1M DRAMS stayed within 2 to 4 percent of actual
production. At their worst, unanticipated yield problems could only have
been a marginal factor.
Japanese chip manufacturers quoted in the Japanese trade press, on
the other hand, gave producers’ restraint in production and investment
the lion’s share of the credit for the 1988 DRAM crisis. Reacting to
reports of a shortage of semiconductors and American user complaints,
127. The “unexpected yield problems” thesis attained its most extreme form in the
assertion that the earthquake that Japan suffered on December 17,1987, by shaking up chip
plants and yields, was a proximate cause of the price surge of early 1988. This story was
given wide circulation by George Gilder in “How the Computer Companies Lost Their
Memories,” Forbes, June 13, 1988, p. 81. MITI’s Forecast Committee actually met on
December 15, two days before the big earthquake, to discuss DRAM production during
the first quarter of 1988. That forecast was extremely accurate: actual production fell short
of the forecast by only -1.6 percent for 64K parts, -7.7 percent for 256K parts, and -1.9
percent for 1M parts.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 201
128. “One Year Since Retaliation on Semiconductors; Interview with Government and
Industry Circles on Prospects,” Mainichi Shimbun, March 26, 1988, p. 9.
129. The MITI forecasts were available for one quarter ahead only from the first
through third quarters of 1987 and were switched to a six-month forecast at the end of
1988.
202 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
By the fall of 1987 a regional allocation system for exports had been
put in place. (See the section on “European Reaction” above.) In 1988
this system was to create large price differentials between DRAMs of¬
fered for sale in domestic Japanese markets and those shipped in foreign
markets. The allocation system was not ended until mid-1989.130
Guidance on Investment
130. Author’s interviews with Japanese semiconductor executives and analysts, Novem¬
ber 1989.
131. See “Contents of Facilities Investments,” p. 11. The Asahi reporter wrote, “The
surveys until now have been conducted by means of questionnaires with major emphasis
on the monetary amounts of investments. In the coming survey, however, MITI will examine
the contents of investments as well, and ask about such details as the kinds of products and
the amount of production of the respective items. It has decided on revision of its survey
method, from the standpoint that the trade friction, which is represented by the Japan-
U.S. semiconductor problem, has often been caused by excessive investments on the part
of Japanese enterprises. Depending on circumstances, MITI will ask enterprises for reduc¬
tion of the investments, which it has judged to be clearly excessive as a result of its
survey. ... In August of last year, the 'Discussion Council on Future Prospects of the
Machinery and Information Industries,’ which is a personal consultative organ of the Di¬
rector General of the MITI Machinery and Information Industries Bureau, drew up a
report which recognized the necessity for the Government to intervene in the decisions to
be made by enterprises on production and investments, for the purpose of preventing the
occurrence of trade friction.”
MITI’s reaction to the possibility that enterprises might object was the following: “The
survey is to be conducted with the cooperation of enterprises in all cases. The main purpose
of the survey is to grasp the reality. Even if MITI judges investments to be excessive, it will
only take such steps as to urge caution.”
Eight months later, an editorial in the Japan Economic Journal explicitly noted the
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 203
existence of the investment control system: “While the Japanese government was busily
setting up an export price monitoring system and instituting a series of production, and
plant and equipment investment controls, the demand from Japanese and American semi¬
conductor users rebounded sharply.” “Editorial: Chip Pact Obsolete,” Japan Economic
Journal, August 13, 1988, p. 22.
132. “Growing Moves to Raise Export Prices, Centered on Exports to US; Semicon¬
ductor Prices Upped by Five to Ten Percent,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, February 1, 1988,
p. 1.
133. One newspaper (“Prices of Japanese-Make Semiconductors Rise Sharply in East
Asia; Almost Twice as Fligh as Level at Start of This Year,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun,
December 23,1987, p. 18) reported that “manufacturers maintain a cautious attitude toward
expansion of production under MITI’s guidance.” The same paper (“Listen to GATT’s
Decision,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, March 7, 1988, p. 2) later noted that “MITI is carrying
out strict administrative guidance, such as to allot production quotas for the respective
items to manufacturing companies, etc., in an effort to make the agreement truly effective.”
See also “Semiconductor Shortage; Prices of Personal Computers and Word Processors
Rising Gradually,” Asahi Shimbun, June 23,1988, p. 3. This article, published seven months
after MITI declared that it would not formally restrict production, explains a current
semiconductor shortage in part by saying, “On the other hand, however, it is also strongly
viewed that MITI’s guidance toward various manufacturers for their reduced production—
as a counter-measure for the Japan-US semiconductor friction—took effect to excess.”
134. Tight restrictions were reportedly maintained through March 1988 (author’s inter¬
view with Japanese industry source, 1989). Another Japanese analyst close to the semicon-
204 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
ductor industry whom I interviewed at this time told me of reports then circulating that
chip makers were submitting investment plans to MITI for informal review.
135. “Big Semiconductor Companies to Increase Facilities Investments for Fiscal 1988
by 38%; Stress to be Laid on 1M DRAM,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, May 27, 1988, p. 8.
136. Commenting on the proposed increases in investment, the Mainichi Shimbun
wrote, “However, whether or not the shortage of stocks will be dissolved by such increased
production is not clear. As for the reason why, semiconductor industry circles carried out
facilities investments to excess and increased their production on a large scale, centering
on fiscal 1983 and 1984, and they suffered from a big depression in 1985. There was such a
bitter experience, and they generally agree on the view that ‘there was a tragedy in the fact
that various companies were mainly producing memory chips in those days’ (NEC Chair¬
man Atsuyoshi Ouchi). In view of facilities investments, too, the amount of NEC’s facilities
investments is one-third of that in those days (¥140 billion in fiscal 1984), and Toshiba—
about one-half (¥148 billion in fiscal 1984). Moreover, it is because all manufacturers
remain cautious about production leaning toward memory chips, as is represented by such
words as ‘We want to maintain 20% for [production of] memory chips.’ Accordingly, the
shortage of memory chips is likely to be carried over to next year.” “Semiconductor Shortage
Serious; Going beyond Production Increase Setup,” Mainichi Shimbun, June 29, 1988,
p. 8.
137. Naoshi Tamaki and Akira Kikuzumi, “Shortage of DRAMs Causing Headaches,”
Japan Economic Journal, July 2, 1988, p. 4.
138. For example, a May 7 analysis in the Japan Economic Journal gave three reasons
for the sluggish investment in chip production. Said the reporter, “one reason is the fact
that manufacturers are loath to repeat the debacle of 1984-85 [when demand shrank
drastically after a buildup in capacity]. Another reason is the fact that Japanese semicon¬
ductor makers are making comfortable profits from the present arrangements based on the
Japan-U.S. semiconductor agreement signed in the autumn of 1986 at the urging of the
Ministry of International Trade and Industry. Production cutbacks enforced by the agree¬
ment have sharply boosted the market prices of semiconductors and Japanese manufacturers
have come to value profits more than market shares [emphasis added], A third reason, on
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 205
The silicon cycle has completely come undone. The reason for this is the
constraint on investment on the part of semiconductor makers, done in the
name of “cooperation.” Koji Kobayashi, chairman of NEC, asserts that
“The semiconductor manufacturers will not let the tragedy of 1984 happen
again. . . . According to one of the top men at a leading chip manufacturer,
‘I would not want this to be construed as a cartel. Manufacturers have
become more open in sharing information, so that there is more coordi¬
nation. In the old days, we used to send industrial spies to gather infor¬
mation about the activities of our rivals, but recently, that practice has
vanished.’ For example, Toshiba announced that ‘Mass production of the
next-generation 4 megabit chips is not planned for this year, and we can
not predict when it will start.’ Such openness should dispel any lack of trust
within the industry, and is related to efforts to keep excessive competition
under control. ... It does not appear that the chip makers’ move away
from memory chips and their cooperative efforts to avoid excessive com¬
petition are temporary phenomena.” The shortage of memory chips is thus
expected to continue for a long time.140
The same themes were echoed in an August 1988 analysis in the Japan
Economic Journal. After noting that capital investment in fiscal 1988 was
expected to reach 430.8 billion yen, compared with 762.8 billion yen
during the boom year of fiscal 1984, the reporter quoted Yukio Honda,
director of MITI’s industrial electronics division, as saying, “This figure
mirrors the manufacturers’ prudent stance toward capacity expansion for
fear of another recession in the future.” The article continued:
the other hand, is Japanese manufacturers’ fear that any large-scale equipment investments
will rekindle trade friction with U.S. industry.” Takahashi, “Producers Slow to React,”
p. 10.
139. The Japan Economic Journal ran an editorial on May 28, for example, that com¬
mented, “It is unnecessary to note that semiconductor manufacturers are aware that the
government’s supply-demand forecasts mean nothing less than quantitative production
controls, though the ministry takes the position that it is simply one of the many forecasts
it routinely employs. Similarly, the legality of the government’s semiconductor export price
monitoring system is also ambiguous. There is no doubt that the monitoring of exports by
the overseas subsidiaries of Japanese semiconductor manufacturers has no legal justifica¬
tion.” “Editorial: Scrap the Chip Pact,” Japan Economic Journal, May 28, 1988, p. 22.
140. “Supply-Demand Structure for Semiconductor Industry Shifts,” Nihon Keizai
Shimbun, June 8, 1988, p. 9.
206 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Chip makers have long been vying for larger market shares, as mass pro¬
duction leads to remarkable cost reductions. Manufacturers embarked on
capacity expansion in peak years which repeatedly caused overproduction
and a resulting recession. Any coordinated action among manufacturers
was unthinkable. But after the 1986 Japan-U.S. chip pact, MITI led the
manufacturers to reduce IC production by about 30% in early 1987. “The
pact helped to virtually create a coordinated production control by chip
makers that we have never seen before,” a broker said. . . . The Japan-
U.S. microchip agreement so far has failed to achieve improved access for
U.S. semiconductor makers to the Japanese market. But it seems certain
that the pact helped Japanese chip makers strengthen their profitability
through production control.141
141. Shigehisa Shibayama, “Chip Shortage Expected to Last Through ’89,” Japan Eco¬
nomic Journal, August 13, 1988, p. 5.
142. Nomura Securities Co., Ltd., “Economic Insight: Heavy Demand for Memory
Chips,” Japan Times, September 17, 1988, p. 9.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 207
ber 1988 Washington meeting between U.S. and Japanese trade negoti¬
ators. The American side’s summary memorandum for that session de¬
scribed the following exchange:
Finally, USG [U.S. government] expressed concern about the role of Fore¬
cast Committee and its impact on market. USG stated many feel Forecast
Committee influences or sets production and investment levels rather than
simply forecasting. USG said language used by GOJ [government of Japan]
to describe Forecast Committee suggests a broader role, and asked how
exactly Forecast Committee can “stabilize” market. USG also asked how
it is that Forecast Committee has been as accurate as it has in projecting
production levels.
GOJ responded that there is no reason for USG concern about Forecast
Committee. GOJ stated forecasts are accurate because they are provided
by companies themselves which are then aggregated by Committee. GOJ
stated Japanese industrial society is very competitive and each member of
Forecast Committee is very interested in how much its competitors pro¬
duce. GOJ said Forecast Committee had “freed the Japanese semiconduc¬
tor companies from unnecessary competition” after period two years ago
during which companies competed in supply and manufacturing.143
146. See Tadashi Tamaki, “Heavy Investment in Chip Factories Spurs Fear of Glut,”
Japan Economic Journal, October 1, 1988, pp. 1, 5; and Tamaki and Kikuzumi, “Shortage
of DRAMs Causing Headaches,” p. 4.
147. See “Concerned About Increase in Japan’s Investments; Interview with US TI
Chairman,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, October 4, 1988, p. 8; and “IC Maker Fears Output
Rise Might Kindle Dumping,” Japan Economic Journal, October 15, 1988, p. 19.
148. With the release of the fourth-quarter 1988 forecast, MITI officials predicted
further shortages of 1M DRAMs through at least March 1989. “1M DRAM Microchips to
be in Short Supply,” Japan Economic Journal, October 15, 1988, p. 17. In a widely cited
interview, Toshiba’s Tsuyoshi Kawanishi told U.S. industry executives in late September
that memory chip shortages could be expected to last another three years. “Prolonged Chip
Shortage Seen,” Financial Times, September 28, 1988, p. 26; “Chips Shortage Will Last 3
Years,” Business Times (Malaysia), September 28, 1988, p. 13.
149. “Chip Makers to Hike Investment,” Japan Economic Journal, November 5, 1988,
p. 12.
150. David E. Sanger, “A New Japanese Push on Chips,” New York Times, November
9, 1988, p. Dl.
151. See “Semiconductor Memory Chips; High Prices Sustained, Due to Tightness of
Demand and Supply,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, November 9, 1988, p. 20; “1M DRAM Chip
Prices to Continue to be High in Dec.,” Nikkei Top Articles, November 23, 1988; and
“Semiconductor Prices on Spot Market; High Prices Continuing for Chips of High-Speed
Processing;” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 24, 1989, p. 20.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 209
The period from late 1987 through early 1989 saw a continued attempt
by Japanese chip producers, with government backing, to dry up un¬
authorized sales in the gray market. MITI export regulations—which
required foreign chip buyers to register with MITI, and obtain a certifi¬
cate from manufacturers attesting to the origin of exported chips, before
the ministry would grant an export license—were potent bureaucratic
barricades blocking off access to the Japanese gray market by foreign
purchasers.
The major manufacturers also moved on their own in 1988 to reduce
supplies filtering into the Japanese gray market. Producers increased their
surveillance of chip sales, to watch for unauthorized resale of their prod¬
ucts by authorized buyers. Retaliation for such gray market transactions
could serve to discourage them. In 1988 and 1989 reports of these efforts
to reduce gray market sales surfaced with increasing frequency in the
Japanese trade press.152
152. “The spot market prices of semi-conductor memory chips have been sharply rising
from the bottom prices in the first half of last year, as various manufacturers have been
tightening their supply to the spot market because the Japan-US semiconductor friction
came to arise. Especially, that the market prices having been rising since the beginning of
this year reflects the fact that the manufacturers’ side has been strengthening their moni¬
toring of memory chip sales in order to prevent the channeling thereof through their
affiliated routes. At one time, memory chips flowing back from users to the market and
memory chips removed from such products as used personal computers were seen on the
market for sale. In this case, too, it is said that ‘there is almost nothing because manufac¬
turers are strengthening their watch’ (spot market dealer).” “Semiconductor Memories—
Spot Market Prices Continuing to Rise; 256K Prices Double from Beginning of This Year,”
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, October 4, 1988, p. 20.
“On the spot market, centering on Akihabara, Tokyo, the shortage of DRAM chips
has become still more serious than ever . . . there is a voice saying as follows: ‘Manufac¬
turers have been tightening their monitoring of sales, and so the influx [of 256K DRAM
chips] into the spot market through their authorized agents has stopped completely. We
cannot answer inquiries.’ (spot market dealer).” “Semiconductor Memory Priced One Stage
Higher; Demand Remains Vigorous,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, December 13, 1988, p. 20.
“There is a voice saying that ‘High-speed processing [DRAM] chips will not appear on
the spot market because domestic manufacturers are strengthening their monitoring of
sales’ (spot market dealer in Akihabara, Tokyo).” “Semiconductor Prices on Spot Market,”
p. 20.
“Industry experts said Japanese manufacturers are restricting the outflow of high-speed
256-kilobit DRAMs into the spot market.” “Spot Prices of Microchips Up Slightly,” Nikkei
Top Articles, February 9, 1989.
210 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Percent
to-year Fisher Ideal price comparisons and presents detailed price anal¬
yses). As American users howled in pain over enormous, unprecedented
price increases, criticism of the STA mounted.
American chip producers responded by arguing that reductions in
supply and increases in price were the consequence of a successful cam¬
paign of predation, rather than an outcome created or facilitated by the
STA. One influential defense articulated this view in a particularly con¬
cise way:
Any economist will tell you that we shouldn’t complain about foreigners
dumping, because consumers benefit. The one exception is if foreign firms
can put domestic firms out of business, and then raise prices. If it is costly
to re-enter the business (like it is to restart DRAM production), foreign
firms can gain monopoly profits at the consumer’s expense.
. . . Rather than signaling a bankrupt trade policy, today’s shortages in
DRAMs should remind us that dumped products in an industry like semi¬
conductors usually lead to higher prices and limited availability if domestic
suppliers are allowed to be destroyed.153
153. David B. Yoffie, “Chip Shortage: Don’t Blame the Pact,” Wall Street Journal, June
21, 1988. Yoffie, a professor at the Harvard Business School, became a member of Intel’s
board of directors in 1989.
154. Wilfred Corrigan, in testimony before the Subcommittee on Oversight and Inves¬
tigations, House Committee on Energy and Commerce, March 1, 1989, as reported in
“Japan Should Be Targeted by Super 301 for Failure to Honor Chips Pact, SIA Says,”
International Trade Reporter, vol. 6 (March 8, 1989), p. 290. The published transcript of
his testimony contains a slightly different, and somewhat garbled, variant of these remarks.
See Unfair Foreign Trade Practices, Hearings before the Subcommittee on Oversight and
Investigations of the House Committee on Energy and Commerce (GPO, 1989), p. 107.
212 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Price Stabilization
155. Use of the expression “high price stability” began appearing in the Japanese press
around early 1989. For example, “it has become definite that the 'high price stability’ will
be sustained for the time being, while being backed by steady-toned demand.” “1M
DRAM; 'High Price Stability’ to be Sustained in April-June Period, Too,” Nihon Keizai
Shimbun, February 1, 1989, p. 9.
156. Monthly statistics on shipments through May 1989 were readily available when I
interviewed a MITI official on this subject in December 1989. These MITI statistics were
even more extensive and detailed than the quarterly numbers assembled for the publicly
released “forecast.”
157. Production of 1M DRAMs during the last quarter of 1988 was roughly 69.6 million
units, compared with an average quarterly output rate of 92 million units during the first
half of 1989. See MITI, Machinery and Information Industries Bureau, “Semiconductor
Supply-Demand Forecast,” September 30, 1988, December 23, 1988, and June 22, 1989.
The largest quarterly increase in producer inventories of 1M DRAMs prior to this, regis¬
tered in the first quarter of 1987 (when MITI had first provided producers with “guidance”
to reduce 1M DRAM shipments), was 0.5 million units.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 213
of 1989, producers began to cut back production in the late spring, sliced
shipments even more, and increased their inventories of parts.
Unofficial production estimates by the semiconductor industry con¬
sulting firm Dataquest provide an even clearer picture of what was going
on. Figure 4-4 shows Dataquest’s quarterly estimates of DRAM produc¬
tion by several groupings of firms.
It is clear that the major Japanese DRAM producers, as a group, cut
back production after the second quarter of 1989. (Because of steadily
increasing productivity on chip manufacturing lines, constant output ac¬
tually means cutbacks in production runs.) The additional 1M DRAM
chip supply, entering a market increasingly depressed by sagging com¬
puter demand, was mostly coming from non-Japanese suppliers, who
were rapidly increasing production.
At the time this was happening, 1M DRAM prices were far above the
price floors then set for exports (roughly triple the average FMV; see
214 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
it does not seem that there will be a collapse of prices at one stroke.
Manufacturers have established a “co-ordination structure” among them¬
selves in the last several years, and they unanimously say that they “will
head toward a soft landing, which will gradually follow a downward curve.”
Concerning this artificial price policy, American users, which depend on
Japanese products for the greater part of their semiconductor procurement,
are now beginning to voice criticism. The focus of the Japan-US friction,
in which the low prices were a problem, is likely to be placed on the high-
price stabilization of Japanese products from now on.
... On the other hand, however, users show their dissatisfaction, as
follows: “That good showing [high profits of Japanese semiconductor mak¬
ers] in their settlements of accounts stands on the sacrifice of users.” Users
demand “a price reduction to the fair market value (FMV).”
... In the US too, users came to show obvious moves for taking the
price determination right away from Japanese manufacturers, as they are
irritated at Japanese manufacturers price determination based on their
dango [collusion] constitution. The rising of arguments in the US for cre¬
ating a semi-conductor futures market, is a sign indicating their intention
to leave the price-determination right to the market. Also, seven US man¬
ufacturing companies’ establishment of “US Memories,” which is a DRAM
joint production company, shows their intention of trying to weaken Japa¬
nese manufacturers’ price control.158
conductor industry worsens, many experts wonder how long this “coordi¬
nation structure” among manufacturers will last.159
159. “Falling Spot Price: Over-Production and Less Demand for Semiconductors in
Japan,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, August 3, 1989, p. 24.
160. NEC withdrew its plan to increase monthly production of 1M DRAMs from
6 million to 8 million chips. Nikkan Kogyo, July 29, 1989, p. 1; Nihon Kogyo, July 29, 1989,
p. 1.
161. “Major Semiconductor Manufacturers to Reduce 1M-DRAM Production by 10%
from September,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, September 14, 1989, p. 10.
162. The announced cuts were from 6 million to 5 million units per month. Dempa
Shimbun, October 31, 1989, p. 1; Nikkan Kogyo, October 31, 1989, p. 1; Nihon Kogyo,
October 31, 1989, p. 5.
163. Author’s interview with a U.S. government official, May 1990.
164. Author’s interview at a Japanese semiconductor company, November 1989. Re¬
ports of MITI guidance on facilities investments in automobiles and electronics, complete
with a threat to invoke the trade control ordinance, were reported in “Temptations of
MITI’s ‘Managed Trade’ (Part 1)—Request for Expansion of Imports; Balancing of Exports
and Imports Pressed for,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, December 14, 1989, p. 7. MITI officials
I interviewed during this same period admitted only to talking to producers about the
political dimensions of their investments, such as investment locations in the European
216 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Community. Even that level of intervention was officially denied: “MITI . . . has vigorously
denied guiding Japanese companies to spread their investments around European Com¬
munity countries rather than concentrating them in the UK. ‘We have never given any
guidance on this issue. It is a matter that is entirely up to companies themselves to decide,’
MITI said here yesterday.” Ian Rodger, “Tokyo Denies Issuing Anti-UK Guidance,”
Financial Times, December 21, 1988, p. 3.
165. Author’s interviews with Japanese semiconductor executives, November and De¬
cember 1989.
166. See “U.S. Request Contains Contradictions; ‘Concerned over Increase in Japan’s
Facilities Investments,’” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, November 5, 1989, p. 3; “Urges Holding
Down of Expansion of Facilities Investments; On Automobiles, Iron-Steel, Electronic
Equipment, and Ship-Building,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, November 7, 1989, p. 1; and
“Temptations of MITI’s ‘Managed Trade’ (Part 2)—‘Guidance’ Also for Facilities Invest¬
ments,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, December 15, 1989, p. 7.
167. See MITI, “Japan’s Coordination Policy in Response to the GATT Panel Report
on Semiconductors,” Tokyo, March 7, 1989.
168. Author’s interviews with a Japanese semiconductor executive and with MITI of¬
ficials, 1991.
169. “MITI Helps Prevent Memory Chip Price Fall,” Nikkei Top Articles, May 25, 1990.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 217
170. “DRAM Co-op: Now’s the Time,” Electronic Buyers’ News, July 10, 1989, p. 17.
171. Brian Robinson, “SIA, AEA Urge DRAM Alliance Formations,” Electronic Buy¬
ers’ News, March 20, 1989.
172. Jack Robertson, “Confirm Major IBM Role in Creation of U.S. Memories,” Elec¬
tronic News, June 26, 1989, pp. 1, 58; and John Thompson and Stacey Peterson, “DRAMs:
Made in the USA,” Computer Systems News, June 26, 1989, pp. 1, 8.
173. Patrick Burnson, “DRAM Joint Venture Draws Praise,” Infoworld, July 3, 1989,
p. 32; and Ann Thryft, “Domestic DRAM Makers Applaud U.S. Memories,” Computer
Design, July 17, 1989, pp. 1, 38.
174. David Roman, “DRAM Co-op Catching On,” Electronic Buyers' News, Septem¬
ber 18, 1989, pp. 20-22.
218 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
175. David Roman and Brian Robinson, “IC Coops: A Cartel Threat?,” Electronic
Buyers’ News, July 31, 1989, pp. 1, 50.
176. Richard March, ‘‘Clock Running on Stalled U.S. Chip Consortium,” PC Week,
October 2, 1989, p. 139; and Eric Nee, “Apple Shuns DRAM Consortium,” Computer
Systems News, October 2, 1989, pp. 3, 8.
177. David Roman, “U.S. Memories Suffers Rejections”; and Hugh G. Willett, “Cy¬
press Would Speed IBM Design,” Electronic Buyers' News, November 20, 1989, pp. 1, 66.
The IBM technology actually was licensed to Micron, but Rodgers and Cypress ultimately
did not take the plunge into DRAMs.
178. Richard March, “U.S. Memory-chip Group Garners Lukewarm Support,” PC
Week, December 11, 1989, p. 137; and David Roman, “Co-Op Gets IBM License,” Elec¬
tronic Buyers' News, December 25, 1989, pp. 1, 4.
179. David Roman, “U.S. Memories Lades Away,” Electronic Buyers’ News January
22, 1990, pp. 1, 56.
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 219
180. “The contrast was striking: On the day last week when American electronics
companies decided to abandon their cooperative venture to make computer chips, their
competitors in Tokyo had already moved in lockstep.
“One by one, within hours, Japan’s biggest chip makers announced plans to cut their
production of one-megabit memory chips. . . . There was far too much supply, each com¬
pany explained in great detail, and unless production was cut, prices would continue to fall
drastically.
'The Japanese companies, despite repeated contentions that they are now each other’s
fiercest competitors, were acting much like a cartel.” David E. Sanger, “Contrasts on
Chips,” New York Times, January 18, 1990, p. Dl.
Sanger’s account is incorrect on one important point—that Japanese producers chose
to reveal their cutback plans just after the proposed U.S. Memories DRAM production
consortium failed. The cutbacks described by Sanger were reported in the Japanese press
on Sunday, January 7, and in the U.S. press on Tuesday, January 9. See “Drastic Drop of
1M DRAM Price: Semiconductor Makers Reinforce Production Cut (10-15%) Starting
This Month,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 1,1990, p. 5; and G. Pascal Zachary, “Japan’s
Biggest Memory-Chip Makers Are Cutting Output in Bid to Ease Glut,” Wall Street Journal,
January 9, 1990, p. B4. The critical meeting at which the U.S. Memories proposal clearly
failed was on Wednesday, January 10, and its failure was publicly announced on Monday,
January 15. See Stephen Kreider Yoder, “U.S. Memories to Abandon Bid for Chip Ven¬
ture,” Wall Street Journal, January 15, 1990, p. B4; “Lessons Linger as U.S. Memories
Fails,” Wall Street Journal, January 16, 1990, p. Bl; and Andrew Pollack, “Memory Chip
Cooperative Is Officially Declared Dead,” New York Times, January 16, 1990, p. Dl.
181. These charges were widely repeated within the U.S. semiconductor industry. They
actually appeared in print in an article by Michael Borrus (“Chips of State,” Issues in
220 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Science and Technology (Fall 1990), pp. 40-48), which claimed that “the Japanese press
reported that Japanese firms were creating a glut in the market to lower prices and thus
discourage the [U.S. Memories] initiative” (p. 44).
Despite considerable effort, I was unable to turn up any such report in the Japanese
press, and in a telephone conversation in November 1990 Borrus, an analyst at the Berkeley
Roundtable on the International Economy, acknowledged to me that he could provide no
specific reference for this claim. The belief that Japanese makers had engineered a shortage
to kill U.S. Memories was, however, fueled by the New York Times, which claimed (incor¬
rectly) that production cuts were announced just after the abandonment of U.S. Memories:
“No one has suggested that Japan’s production cuts and the abandonment of U.S. Memories
are directly related. But both were spurred by a growing glut of chips, after two years of
huge demand.” Sanger, “Contrasts on Chips,” p. D20.
As noted above (and in the Japanese press), Japanese producers were actually cutting
back on shipments of DRAMs in 1989, in order to shore up prices—the precise opposite
of behavior consistent with “creating a glut in the market.”
182. See “Drastic Drop of 1M DRAM Price: Semiconductor Makers Reinforce Pro¬
duction Cut (10-15% Starting This Month),” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 7, 1990, p. 5.
“Another Sharp Price Reduction for Semiconductors,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, January 18,
1990, p. 24, reported an 11 percent cut in 1M DRAM output at Toshiba, 17 percent at
NEC, 22 percent at Mitsubishi, 15 percent at both Fujitsu and Hitachi, and 27.5 percent at
Oki.
183. “Price Reduction in Semiconductors Stopped; Positive Result of Production Cuts,”
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, February 27, 1990, p. 24.
184. G. Pascal Zachary, “Computer Firms Face Shortage in DRAM Chips,” Wall Street
Journal, March 9, 1990, p. A4; Corinne Bernstein-Levy, “Cost Reversal Baffles Buyers,”
Electronic Buyers’ News, March 5, 1990, pp. 1, 50; and Barbara Darrow, “DRAM Dearth
Overblown, Vendors Say,” Infoworld, March 19, 1990, p. 105.
185. See “1M DRAM Wholesale Market Recovered; Major Manufacturers Began
Increasing Production,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, June 21, 1990, p. 3.
186. See “Makers Once Again Boosting 1M DRAM Production,” Nikkei Top Articles,
June 21, 1990; “Wholesale Prices Cut for 1M DRAM; First Reduction in Six Months,”
THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 221
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, September 15, 1990, p. 24; and “Major Chip Manufacturers Hesi¬
tate in Increasing 1M DRAM Production,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, October 4, 1990, p. 3.
187. David Roman, “DRAMs Slide Again,” Electronic Buyers’ News, June 25, 1990,
pp. 1, 58.
188. Dempa Shimbun, May 28, 1990, p. 1; Nikkan Kogyo, May 26, 1990, p. 6; “Future
Direction of Sematech,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, June 5, 1990, p. 11; and Satoshi Isaka,
“Electronics Makers Still Optimistic,” Japan Economic Journal, June 23, 1990, p. 17.
189. “Spot dealing in semiconductor memory chips has decreased rapidly and some of
the buyers are closing their businesses. This is because there is a diminished supply of chips
in the spot market due to the manufacturers’ instructions to their own authorized distrib¬
utors. . . .
“The spot market has been said to reflect the trend of demand and supply of semicon¬
ductors accurately and a leading index for authorized distributors. While this basic belief
has not been destroyed, some point out that ‘free price formation has been threatened as
manufacturers’ influence over distribution has grown, and administrative guidance, backed
by the U.S.-Japan Semiconductor Agreement, has strengthened.” “Rapid Decrease in Spot
Dealing of Semiconductor Memory,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, June 7, 1990, p. 24.
190. “Wholesale Prices Cut for 1M DRAM; First Reduction in Six Months,” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, September 15, 1990, p. 24; and “Sharp Wholesale Price Reduction of
1M,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, October 10, 1990, p. 24.
191. See “Spot Chip Prices Continue to Decrease,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, October
31, 1990, p. 24.
222 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
The reason for the price drop of 1M can be said to be that production
capability is larger than actual demand. Although domestic LSI makers
have been trying to stabilize the price of 1M through large production cuts,
since “the Japanese 1M market share in the U.S. has dropped below 50%”
(according to Mitsubishi) production cuts may not be effective. The lower
market share in the U.S. is due to the fact that several other makers such
as Samsung, Siemens, and Micron Technology have improved their supply
capability. Therefore Japanese makers cannot depend on production cuts
to stabilize price and must “wait for demand to recover.”192
194. “How Far Will 4M DRAM Fall; Demand Slower Than Mass Production,” Nihon
Keizai Shimbun, August 14, 1991, p. 18; and “Further Price Reduction of 4M DRAM,”
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, August 8, 1991, p. 20.
195. Since every generation of DRAMs quadruples the number of bits on a chip, and
higher density chips are more desirable because of their lower power consumption, lower
interconnection costs, and reduced space requirements, “crossover” is generally defined to
occur when newer generation memory chips are five to six times more costly than older
generation chips. Because a new generation of chip is introduced roughly every three years,
crossover between generations would also be expected to take place at three-year intervals.
224 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
198. See David Roman, “Korean DRAM Case Fizzles,” Electronic Buyers’ News,
March 22, 1993, pp. 1, 44; and Bob Davis, “Panel Clears Way for U.S. to Impose Import
Duties on Korean Microchips,” Wall Street Journal, April 23, 1993, p. All. Indeed, some
within the industry charged that the mild penalties on Korean chips were the result of
political pressure from computer makers.
199. “Semiconductors Face Lower Antidumping Duties,” Korea Times, August 26,
1995, p. 8; and “USA: Samsung Electronics Cleared from Anti-dumping Charges,” Korea
Economic Weekly, November 9, 1995.
200. See Linda Bernier, “EC Acts on Dumping,” Electronic Engineering Times, March
8, 1993, p. 97. The Korean price floors were company specific like the U.S. FMVs, rather
than the single common floor applied by the EC to Japanese,chips.
226 THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
201. “EU Suspends Antidumping Rule on Semiconductors,” Korea Times, August 26,
1995, p. 8. The suspension was extended in January 1996. “EU to Suspend Anti-dumping
Regulations on DRAM Chip Imports,” Korea Economic Weekly, January 3, 1996.
202. See Greg Garry and Hugh G. Willett, “Korean Chip Dumping?” Electronic
Buyers' News, February 5, 1990, pp. 1, 58.
203. “Samsung Cuts DRAM Production to 20% of Peak,” Nikkei Top Articles, Feb¬
ruary 27, 1990; and “Japan’s 1-MB DRAMs Yet to Respond to U.S.’s BB Ratio Upswing,”
Nikkei Top Articles, May 9, 1990.
CHAPTER FIVE
It was in September 1986 that the United States and Japan officially
signed the first bilateral Semiconductor Trade Arrangement (STA). Re¬
ports in the Japanese press suggested that the formal arrangement was
preceded by a period of informal pressure on the Japanese semiconductor
industry—what in the United States might be called jawboning—from
political and government circles in Japan, reacting in turn to foreign
complaints. From July 1985 on, for more than year before the formal
signing of the STA, Japanese industry was encouraged to reduce low-
priced DRAM exports to the United States and exercise restraint in
production. This effort was actually successful in raising 64K DRAM
prices, but it came too late to preempt the formal conclusion of the
dumping case involving that product, or to preempt the filing of other
trade cases (in EPROMs and in 256K and higher DRAMs). The STA,
which led to suspension of these later dumping cases, the suspension also
of a Section 301 complaint about market access, and the termination of
a private antitrust suit, intervened in the market at three distinct levels.
First, there was the public document released to the media, which
described a couple of major sets of measures. One section of the agree¬
ment described actions to be undertaken by the Japanese and American
governments to encourage increased sales in the Japanese market of
227
228 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
1. “Arrangement between the Government of Japan and the Government of the United
States of America Concerning Trade in Semiconductor Products,” September 1986, sec. I,
point 2. (Hereafter STA.)
2. STA, sec. I, point 4.
3. The products to be included were MOS (metal oxide semiconductor, a standard
lower cost chip technology) static random access memory chips (SRAMs), ECL (a high-
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 229
speed, higher cost technology) RAM chips, certain microprocessors, microcontrollers, and
ASICs (application-specific integrated circuits). Quotations in text are from STA, sec. II,
point 2, paras. 4, 5.
4. The precise wording for the 20 percent market share target was reported in Louise
Kehoe, “Stalemate in Chips Trade Talks,” Financial Times, July 28, 1986, p. 1, and Carla
Rapaport, “Japan Yields to US Demands on Microchip Price Monitoring,” Financial
Times, August 4, 1986, p. 1, before the STA was actually signed. Crucial paragraphs from
this “secret” side letter were published verbatim in Mikio Fujiwara, “This Is a Side Letter
to the U.S.-Japan Semiconductor Agreement,” Bungei Shunju (May 1988), pp. 124-37, and
in Inside U.S. Trade, November 18, 1988, pp. 15-16.
5. Author’s interviews with U.S. trade negotiators, 1990, 1992.
6. The top Japanese negotiator described the situation as follows: “A rumor circulated
that the semiconductor agreement included, aside from the published part, a secret side
letter in which Japan promised to raise to 20% the share of American products in the
Japanese semiconductor market within five years. I can state categorically that there was
no such secret letter in the semiconductor agreement.” Makoto Kuroda, “Talking Tough
about Trade,” Journal of Japanese Trade and Industry, no. 6 (1988), p. 31.
7. STA, point 5, sec. 1. The relevant passage (sec. II, point 5) read: “the Government
of Japan will take appropriate actions available under laws and regulations in Japan, in¬
cluding ETC [the Export Trade Control ordinance], in order to prevent dumping.”
230 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Although both these public and private actions were taken within the
political context of the STA, it might reasonably be argued that they were
not part of the STA proper. Implementing actions, after all, were not
formally defined by the two sides within the agreement. All actions either
deliberately implemented (if undertaken or actively encouraged by gov¬
ernment) or passively tolerated (if a private response) by either govern¬
ment, in response to the arrangement's often vague language and sur¬
rounding politics, will be considered here as part of a constantly mutating
STA trade “regime.” An ongoing political dialogue between governments
and companies shaped all these measures. Rather than forming a static
set of policies, the STA was more of a legal and political framework for
a complex, dynamic game involving both public and private players. The
moves in this ill-defined game were a collection of formal and informal
actions—some announced publicly, others undertaken relatively pri¬
vately—evolving constantly over time.
8. The most prominent exception to this pattern was the 16K DRAM, where two
different and incompatible designs coexisted—one with a single power supply voltage, the
other with dual voltage requirements. Both configurations were produced by multiple
companies, however.
9. Merely qualifying and testing a second source for a part already in use has been
estimated by one industry source to cost $120,000. Qualification costs were large enough
to prompt at least one group of relatively large computer manufacturers to form a coop¬
erative chip qualification joint venture, in order to pool these costs. And within the elec¬
tronics purchasing community, talk of the economic pressure to reduce the number of
suppliers is a staple of everyday conversation.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 233
10. See, for example, U.S. International Trade Commission, 64K Dynamic Random
Access Memory Components from Japan, USITC publication 1862 (June 1986), p. A-12.
234 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
11. U.S. International Trade Commission, 64K Dynamic Random Access Memory
Components from Japan, USITC publication 1735 (August 1985), pp. A10-A11.
12. The estimate is that of Don Bell, of Bell Microproducts Inc., whom I thank for
spending the morning of February 16, 1989, attempting to educate me in the intricacies of
the DRAM market.
13. A U.S. International Trade Commission investigation of Korean DRAM sales in
the United States, for example, found that all Korean sales were made on a spot basis, and
found no consistent pattern of Korean products being sold above or below spot sales prices
for U.S.-made products. In contrast, an EC investigation of Korean DRAM exports to the
European Community over roughly the same period found Korean producers’ prices un¬
dercutting those of Community producers by 9.3 to 20.7 percent (weighted-average mar¬
gins). However, the EC report makes no mention of distinctions drawn between contract
and spot sales. In principle, and one suspects in practice, the types of transactions used in
these price comparisons can make a significant difference in the conclusion drawn.
See “Commission Regulation (EEC) no. 2686/92,” Official Journal of the European
Communities, September 17, 1992, p. L 272/19; and U.S. International Trade Commission,
DRAMs of One Megabit and Above from the Republic of Korea, USITC publication 2519,
(June 1992), pp. A-45, A-50. In 100 OEM spot market price comparisons, Korean prices
were below those of the U.S. product in 47 cases, above them in 48, and the two types of
product were priced identically in 5 cases. In 67 comparisons of authorized distributor
purchases, the Korean product was priced lower in 23 cases, above U.S. prices in 42, and
priced identically in 2 cases.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 235
Source: U.S. Internationa] Trade Commission, 64K Dynamic Random Access Memory Components from Japan,
USITC publication 1735 (August 1985), pp. A40-A41. Prices shown are for DRAMs with an access time of 150
nanoseconds.
a. 10,000 to 100,000 units.
b. Fewer than 10,000 units.
and slackening (late 1984 on) market conditions.14 In four out of six
quarters of relatively robust demand (through the second quarter of
1984), spot prices exceeded contract sales prices to OEMs. In seven out
of nine months of a period of slackening demand (during and after the
last quarter of 1984), spot prices were at or below contract price levels.
As will be seen, spot prices soared much farther above contract price
levels during the DRAM shortage of 1988 than during the tight market
of 1983-84, depicted in this figure.
Further analysis suggests that the quantity commitments that appear
to be the economic heart of OEM “contract” pricing should perhaps best
14. See U.S. International Trade Commission, 64K Dynamic Random Access Memory
Components From Japan (1985), pp. A40-A41. The prices shown are for DRAMs with an
access time of 150 nanoseconds.
236 EFFECTS OF TFIE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
For the period up to the mid-1980s there is essentially only one pub¬
lished source of historical price data on DRAMs: Dataquest, an Amer¬
ican market research firm. Dataquest publishes quarterly estimates of
DRAM production, by bit capacity, and an aggregate worldwide “aver¬
age selling price” (ASP) for every capacity chip in large-scale production
at the time of the estimate. The ASP is a “billing” price; that is, it reflects
bills sent out and (one hopes) receipts collected when product is actually
shipped. Because there is often a lag between negotiation of a contract
and actual shipment, current “billing” price is a weighted average of
“booking” prices in both current and earlier periods, when the contracts
were actually negotiated. The Dataquest ASPs are thus probably best
conceptualized as some weighted average (with unknown, variable
weights) of current spot and distributor prices, and current and lagged
contract prices.
There are numerous methodological difficulties in the procedures used
by Dataquest to produce these and other price estimates.15 Nonetheless,
for all practical purposes, these numbers were until the 1990s the only
consistent, long-term source of detailed information on semiconductor
prices and will be used here to analyze pricing trends.
In looking at long-term trends in memory pricing, one frequent prac¬
tice in the industry is to calculate a cost per bit of memory, for example
by dividing total revenues by the total bits of memory produced in all
generations of memory chip at any moment in time. This essentially
15. The producer price index series produced by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics
are not useful in this context. A detailed critique of available statistics may be found in
Kenneth Flamm, “Measurement of DRAM Prices: Technology and Market Structure,” in
Murray F. Foss, Marilyn E. Manser, and Allan H. Young, eds.. Price Measurements and
Their Uses (University of Chicago Press, 1993), pp. 157-97.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 237
weights the price of every type of chip by that chip’s share of total bits
produced. Changes in this price index, unfortunately, confound period-
to-period shifts in demand from one type of chip to another with changes
in chip prices. Even if all prices remained constant, for example, the
aggregate cost per bit might drop significantly if the composition of
demand were to shift toward a chip with a lower price per bit.
A better practice is to use a constant set of weights for prices being
compared in any two periods. One particularly attractive weighting
scheme is the so-called Fisher Ideal price index, which has desirable
properties as an approximation to a theoretically ideal price index.16
Figures 5-2 and 5-3 show annual percentage rates of change for Fisher
Ideal price indices for DRAMs and EPROMs (the products subject to
dumping investigations), constructed using Dataquest worldwide ASP
estimates, along with the widely used (if conceptually less attractive)
calculations of aggregate cost per bit. Although there are some differ¬
ences between the two series, the overall trends are very similar. The
same figures also show annual rates of change in two aggregate measures
of the quantity of chips produced: aggregate bits of memory and an
(again conceptually more attractive) index formed by dividing aggregate
expenditure by a Fisher Ideal price index. Again there are some differ¬
ences, but the overall trends are very similar.
In both DRAMs and EPROMs, annual rates of change in price hit
all-time historical highs in 1987 and 1988, after the STA went into effect.
Indeed, for the first time in the history of memory chip production,
positive annual changes in price were registered in 1988 for both types
16. The Fisher Ideal index I am constructing is the geometric mean of two price indexes
calculated using a single weight on the price of every type of chip in two adjacent time
periods (the weights are constant in the two time periods); this approach does not confuse
the effect of price changes with the shift in usage from one generation of chip to another.
The weights used for the first index are the expenditure shares of chips in the starting
period, while the second index uses expenditure shares for each type of chip in the ending
period: the Fisher Ideal price index giving the price in period 1 relative to period 0 is
Diewert has shown that this weighting scheme produces a “superlative index”—a second-
order approximation to a true, exact price comparison between two periods derived
from microeconomic theory. See W. E. Dewert, “Superlative Index Numbers and Con¬
sistency in Aggregation,” Econometrica, vol. 46 (July 1978), pp. 883-900. Indices for
adjacent pairs of time periods have been chained together to produce a single, contin¬
uous price index.
238 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
A. Price changes
Percent
B. Quantity changes
Percent
A. Price changes
Percent
B. Quantity changes
Percent
of chips. The contrast with the historical record was particularly striking
in DRAMs, where previously recorded annual rates of change had stayed
within roughly the —20 to —60 percent range. Prices fell by only 10
percent in 1987, then suddenly jumped up by well over 20 percent in 1988.
The deviation from historical trend was so egregious, in fact, that
some argued that a secular upward shift in the price of DRAMs was
occurring. Within the industry this came to be known as the proposition
that future memory pricing would follow the “bi rule” rather than the
“tt rule.”17 The tt rule refers to the fact that, in the past, DRAM prices
for each generation of chip had tended to decline asymptotically toward
the $3 level (tt = 3.14159 . . .) as mass production of that generation
peaked, then to half that level at the end of its life. Since a new generation
of chip was introduced on average about every three years, and since
each new generation of chip quadrupled the number of bits on a chip,
this amounted to a 75 percent reduction in the cost of a bit of memory
every three years, or an annual rate of decline of about 36 percent per
year. (Remarkably, this is roughly the annual decline in memory bit cost
produced by analyses of actual historical data. See figure 5-4 for data on
DRAM prices through 1985.) The bi rule (“bi” is also, coincidentally,
the pronunciation of the Japanese kanji character meaning “doubling”)
suggests that in the future every new-generation chip will approximately
double in price as mass production peaks. (See figure 5-5 for DRAM
pricing after 1985.) Following the previous logic, this means a 50 percent
decline in bit cost every three years, for an annual rate of decline of
about 20 percent, or about a 50 percent smaller long-run cost decline
than under the tt rule.
The cyclical sensitivity of semiconductor demand is also apparent in
the large swings in price change depicted in figures 5-2 and 5-3.18 Al¬
though 1985—the year when trade friction kicked the political process
leading to the STA into motion—had set a historical record for plunges
17. See M. P. Lepselter and S. M. Sze, “DRAM Pricing Trends—The tt Rule,” IEEE
Circuits and Devices Magazine, vol. 1 (January 1985), pp. 53—54; Yasuo Tarui, “From the
it Rule to the Bi Rule,” Nikkei Microdevices, no. 27 (July 1987), pp. 165-67; and Yasuo
Tarui and Tadaaki Tarui, “New DRAM Pricing Trends: The Bi Rule,” IEEE Circuits and
Devices Magazine, vol. 7 (March 1991), pp. 44-45.
18. Cyclical impacts on semiconductor industry employment are discussed in detail in
Kenneth Flamm, “Internationalization in the Semiconductor Industry,” in Joseph Grunwald
and Kenneth Flamm, The Global Factory: Foreign Assembly in International Trade (Brook¬
ings, 1985), pp. 101-03.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 241
in DRAM prices, the plunge was only marginally steeper than that seen
in 1981. In EPROMs, on the other hand, the price decline of 1985 actually
fell short of the drop registered in 1981 and was about the same as that
seen in 1978. Rates of increase in chip output also fell close to historical
lows in the years after 1986, in both DRAMs and EPROMs.19
19. At least one study, commissioned by the Semiconductor Industry Association, the
U.S. industry group, argues that the movement of prices in DRAMs after the STA went
into effect had returned price levels to their long-term trend by 1989, and therefore that
the STA had no apparent deleterious effects in raising prices above long-term trends. See
Technecon Analytic Research, Inc., “Impact of the Semiconductor Agreement on DRAM
Prices,” Washington, December 1990. The logic of this argument, however, suffers from
three significant flaws.
First, all forecasts of trend price levels are very sensitive to the choice of base period
used to estimate the trend. By choosing a particular base period, one can raise or lower
trend growth rates arbitrarily. By excluding the period of sharp recession in 1985 from
242 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from Dataquest, “DO First Monday Report”; Electronic Business
Buyer; and Nikkei Telecomm (on-line data service), “Large User Contract Price.”
a. Electronic Business Buyer.
b. Dataquest, “DQ First Monday Report.”
the period used to estimate the trend, the rate of decline was reduced in this study.
Second, the “correct” trend in this study is estimated by taking price as a function of
cumulative bits of memory produced. Even if this relationship held exactly true to historical
trend after the STA went into effect, and price was exactly as predicted by some historical
function of the cumulative bits of memory produced, producer behavior in response to the
STA would still have raised prices in an “ahistorical” fashion by cutting back on the number
of bits produced. That is, looking at a graph of price versus cumulative bits would lead one
to conclude that nothing representing a break from historical, structural relationships had
occurred—but if producers had indeed cut back substantially on production (and cumula¬
tive bits produced) relative to past trends, prices would indeed have risen extraordinarily.
In other words, even if some structural relation between price and cumulative bits were
unaffected by the events set in motion by the STA, the growth of bits produced over time
certainly was, and this latter channel would have been expected to be the primary effect of
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 243
ernment began to set floor prices for export sales of DRAMs by Japanese
companies. Initially, different standards were set for sales to the U.S.
market and other (third-country) export markets; after U.S. protests,
however, the systems were later unified. (In response to European pro¬
tests, the pricing guidelines were separated again in 1989.)
Regulation of Japanese export sales ultimately involved four elements.
First, an export licensing system was adopted. This system required de
facto government approval of the export price, which was to be set above
minimum norms established by Japan’s Ministry of International Trade
and Industry (MITI). Second, foreign purchasers of Japanese chips were
required to register with MITI. Third, all export transactions required a
certificate from the original chip manufacturer attesting to the fact that
the chips in question were actually manufactured by that producer.
Fourth, MITI established informal regional allocation guidelines, to en¬
sure that supplies were not diverted from one export market to favor
another.
By most accounts, MITI’s guidance was quite effective in setting min¬
imum pricing standards for Japanese DRAM manufacturers’ direct ex¬
port sales. (Because Japanese manufacturers were at this time responsi¬
ble for between 80 and 90 percent of world DRAM sales, this effectively
worked as a floor on price in the global market.) The intent of the second
and third elements was clearly to reduce access by foreign purchasers to
Japanese gray market channels not under the direct supervision and con¬
trol of Japanese chip manufacturers. Predictably, prices in the unregu¬
lated domestic Japanese market soon dropped below foreign export
prices.
The rising differential between U.S. and Japanese DRAM prices was
exacerbated by producer actions that, from the standpoint of U.S. con¬
sumers, made the true price of their DRAMs even greater than the hefty
contract prices reported to market researchers. The practice of tying sales
of DRAMs to consumer purchases of other chips that would not other¬
wise have been bought from Japanese DRAM vendors (particularly ap-
restrictions on supply associated with the STA. The Technecon Analytic Research study
actually notes that the growth in bits produced (and consumed) in the late 1980s was well
below historical trends.
Third, the assumption that some fixed structural relationship exists between price and
cumulative bit production is dubious. As will be seen in chapter 6, although yields, and
therefore marginal costs, may have a relatively simple relationship to cumulative output,
there is no reason to expect prices to follow marginal costs very closely, particularly over
periods when production is constrained by available capacity.
244 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Figure 5-7 gives the equivalent time series for 1M DRAMs.24 All
available data seem to show unprecedented, sustained increases in
DRAM prices from 1987 on. (Compare this with 64K DRAM pricing
during the shortage of 1983-84, for example, in figure 5-1.)
Weekly data on large-user wholesale prices in the Japanese market are
also regularly published in Nihon Keizai Shimbun (commonly called Nik¬
kei, a Japanese business daily roughly equivalent in terms of reputation
and stature to the American Wall Street Journal or the London Financial
Times).25 Various contract (or large-user) pricing data for both U.S. and
24. The “DQ First Monday Report” contract prices refer to 120-nanosecond, 1M parts,
in plastic cases, which were the cheapest available 1M part. It is surprising, then, that the
Dataquest ASPs—which presumably average these with more expensive parts and with
higher priced parts sold through distributors and in the spot market—for at least three
quarters, during a period of relatively stable prices, are at or below an average of volume
contract prices. This casts some doubt on the reliability of one or the other of these data
sources.
25. These data are reprinted on a weekly basis in the Japan Economic Journal, the
English-language weekly based on Nikkei. When possible the former is used here, supple¬
mented by online data available from Nikkei’s computerized data base, and selected issues
of Nikkei itself. Data sampled on a weekly basis were averaged to calculate a monthly time
series; monthly series were averaged to create a quarterly series. Monthly (quarterly)
246 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Japanese sales are shown in figures 5-8 and 5-9. Figure 5-8 contrasts the
Nikkei large-user Japanese wholesale price for 256K DRAMs with “DQ
First Monday Report” 256K DRAM contract prices. It is clear that Da-
taquest’s Japanese volume contract price basically follows the Nikkei
wholesale price reasonably closely (albeit with occasional bursts of
noise), and the two are probably different estimates of the same under¬
lying concept. The Dataquest estimates for Japan should probably be
regarded as less reliable than the Nikkei numbers, because they appear
to be subject to frequent retroactive revisions.26
estimated yen per chip was converted to dollars using market average monthly (quarterly)
exchange rates reported by the International Monetary Fund.
26. Indeed, no two sources for the Dataquest price series appear to give exactly the
same numbers, particularly for prices of product sold outside the United States. For this
reason, one may speculate that revisions to the exchange rates used to convert prices to
dollars (the currency in which Dataquest reports all contract prices) may play an important
role in these retrospective changes.
The most dramatic example of retrospective revision of the Dataquest regional contract
price estimates involved the U.S. government’s use of these data in its submission to the
GATT panel investigation of the STA, in order to challenge price data furnished by Euro¬
pean companies. The European data, however, were apparently also supplied by Dataquest!
The data submitted by the U.S. government, in turn, differed from data furnished to me
by Dataquest in February 1989.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 247
Figure 5-8. Monthly Contract Prices for 256K DRAMs in the United
States and Japan, 1985-92
Dollars per chip
Sources: Dataquest “DO First Monday Report”; Nihon Keizei Shimbun (various issues); and Nikkei Telecomm
(on-line service).
Figure 5-8 seems to show quite clearly that a large and significant differ¬
ential between the U.S. and Japanese markets existed in 1988 and most of
1989 in large-volume, direct “contract” sales between Japanese manufac¬
turers and their customers in the two regions. Figure 5-9 compares the
Nikkei time series on wholesale 1M DRAM prices with Dataquest contract
pricing data in the United States and Japan. Figure 5-10 compares a Nikkei
time series on wholesale 64K DRAM prices with Dataquest quarterly world¬
wide average sales prices. (U.S. contract price estimates were unavailable
for 64K parts.) Both seem to tell basically the same story of significant
regional differentials from late 1987 through late 1989. Contemporary ac¬
counts in the Japanese business press also report large price differentials
between Japanese and foreign markets over this period.27
27. For example, on April 9, 1988, the Japan Economic Journal reported that Korean
chip exports to Japan had dropped steeply, because Korean producers had found prices
higher and profitability greater in the U.S. market. Noted the Journal in “Korean Chip
248 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
The data displayed thus far have largely ignored DRAMs sold by
distributors and in the spot market. This misses an important dimension
of the change in market conditions after the signing of the STA. To
Producers Shun Japan to Harvest Higher Profit in U.S.” (April 9,1988), p. 4, “The reasons
for the shift are obvious. With Japanese semiconductor exports to the U.S. down sharply
as a result of increased trade friction between the two nations, prices on the underfed U.S.
market have begun to skyrocket. ... At the same time, though supplies in Japan were also
dwindling, Japanese companies were reluctant to accept price hikes beyond the typical
¥340 cost for large users. Not surprisingly, Korean makers moved quickly to enter the
more lucrative U.S. markets.”
On July 18, 1988, Nihon Keizai Shimbun's morning edition carried a front-page story
reporting that the price differential between the Japanese and foreign market for a 256K
DRAM had widened from 100 yen, as trade friction heated up, to 200 to 300 yen. (An
English-language summary of the story was carried in “Foreign Semiconductor Prices Even
Higher,” Japan Economic Journal, July 30, 1988, p. 10. Depreciation of the dollar in the
intervening period makes the dollar value of that change in the differential substantially
greater.) On August 9, 1988, Nihon Keizai's morning edition carried a story on page 18
reporting that Japanese semiconductor producers had begun stepping up exports, with
much higher price tags than these products carried in the domestic market. (An English-
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 249
Figure 5-10. Quarterly Japanese and World Contract Prices for 64K
DRAMs, 1985-89
Dollars per chip
Sources: Author's calculations from unpublished Dataquest data; Dataquest, "DQ First Monday Report”; and
Nihon Keizai Shimbun (various issues).
remedy this situation I have constructed time series showing retail spot
prices for memory chips, beginning in the spring of 1985. To do so, I
collected weekly data on sales prices from one of the larger retail vendors
of memory chips in the United States during this period.28 The advertised
prices are dated (an important point, since there is typically a substantial
language summary appears in “Japan Chip Makers Step Up Exports Amid Shortages,”
Japan Economic Journal, August 20, 1988, p. 15. The story also notes that observers feared
this might exacerbate shortages in the domestic market.)
28. The vendor was Microprocessors Unlimited, of Beggs, Oklahoma; the weekly ad¬
vertisements were found in the pages of PC Week and Infoworld magazines. The prices
shown refer to the following parts: the 64K DRAM is a 64K x 1, 150-nanosecond, DIP-
packaged chip; the 256K DRAM is a 256K x 1, 120-nanosecond DIP package; the 1M
DRAM is a 1M x 1, 100-nanosecond DIP package through October 1989, and an 80-
nanosecond chip after that month. For comparison purposes, a 100-nanosecond 1M DRAM
sold for $10.99 in the first week of November 1989, whereas an 80-nanosecond part sold for
$10.99 the following week.
250 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Figure 5-11. Monthly Spot Prices for 256K DRAMs in the United States
and Japan, 1985-91
Sources: Author’s calculations based on published advertisements of Microprocessors Unlimited; Nihon Keizai
Shimbun (various issues); and Nikkei Telecomm (on-line service).
lag between the submission of advertising copy and its publication); con¬
tacts with this vendor have also made it clear to me that these were real
prices, that is, product was actually available in stock at these prices.
Figure 5-11 shows spot retail prices for 120-nanosecond, 256K DRAMs.
The contrast with figure 5-8 is striking: spot retail prices quadrupled
between early 1987 and early 1988!
Some data may also be gathered on spot pricing in Japan. Beginning
in October 1988, spot price data for 256K DRAMs, of unspecified speed,
have been published regularly in Nihon Keizai Shimbun. Weekly prices
have been averaged over the month;29 some occasional reports on spot
prices have also been collected from news articles in Nikkei and are also
29. Prices from the Tuesday or Wednesday morning editions of Nikkei were used,
beginning in October 1988. Data from before that date are taken from an assortment of
occasional Nikkei news reports on DRAM market conditions. Monthly exchange rate data
published by the International Monetary Fund were used to convert yen prices to U.S.
dollars.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 251
Figure 5-12. Monthly Spot Prices for 1M DRAMs in the United States
and Japan, 1986-92
shown in figure 5-11. The fragmentary data shown here suggest that
Japanese spot prices generally followed the upward trajectory of Amer¬
ican spot prices, but with a lag, so that some differential persisted through
mid-1988. In the fall of 1988 Japanese spot prices seem to have briefly
passed American spot prices, only to fall to approximate parity with U.S.
prices in 1989. These data suggest that MITI’s attempts to wall off the
Japanese gray market from the foreign gray market only slowed conver¬
gence and did not prevent arbitrage from linking prices in the two mar¬
kets. This is not completely surprising, since the gray market is virtually
by definition a bastion of untamed entrepreneurialism.
Figure 5-12 shows an equivalent retail, spot price series I have con¬
structed for 1M DRAMs (with 100-nanosecond access times), along with
data on Japanese 1M DRAM spot prices collected from Nikkei. The
pattern of regional differentials shown by these more fragmentary data
is similar to that for 256K DRAMs. U.S. buyers paid some premium
relative to Japanese buyers through mid-1988; Japanese spot prices may
252 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
have briefly shot past U.S. levels at the end of the year, and 1989 brought
with it rough parity. The increase in price from mid-1987 to late 1988 is
notable, but far less striking than that for 256K DRAMs.
In DRAMs, then, the overall pattern was one of a significant regional
price differential in contract pricing between the domestic Japanese and
overseas markets from 1987 through 1988. The differential disappeared
in 1989, as semiconductor demand slackened and prices began to fall
sharply. In the spot market, in contrast, there was some transitory dif¬
ferential in pricing between the Japanese and American markets, but
after some short lag prices essentially tended to converge in the two
regions. What this suggests is that government price and export controls
were relatively effective in controlling direct transactions between the
major Japanese producers and their large customers, but considerably
less effective in regulating transactions in the secondary spot market,
where arbitrage between the American and Japanese markets approxi¬
mately equalized prices in the two regions.30
Overall regional contract price indexes for DRAMs may be con¬
structed using estimates of contract prices in the United States and Japan
for individual products. A Fisher Ideal price index for the United States
was constructed by taking quarterly Dataquest contract price estimates
in the United States for 256K and 1M DRAMs, and Dataquest ASP
estimates for 64K DRAMs, and using expenditure shares constructed
using relative volumes of worldwide production of these products at U.S.
prices to construct weights for period-to-period comparisons. A chained
index built up from quarter-to-quarter Fisher Ideal comparisons was then
calculated for the United States.31 A similar index was constructed for
Japan but used Nikkei estimates of large-user wholesale prices, and rel¬
ative global volumes, to produce quarterly Japanese expenditure share
weights.32 Since comparisons of contract prices show U.S. and Japanese
30. Export controls were notoriously porous to small-scale evasions. Chips are compact
and light, and a million-yen shipment could fit into a small box or large attache case.
Anecdotes of such irregular traffic abounded in 1987 and 1988.
31. For 256K DRAMs quarterly averages of Dataquest “DQ First Monday Report”
price estimates for volume contracts were used throughout this period. For 1M DRAMs
Dataquest worldwide ASP estimates were used until the first quarter of 1987, when the
Monday contract price series starts; thereafter the latter series was used. For 64K DRAMs
Dataquest worldwide ASP estimates were used throughout, since Monday contract price
data were unavailable for this product.
32. Quarterly averages of Nikkei weekly price quotes for 256K DRAMs were used
throughout. For 64K DRAMs average Nikkei large-user price quotes were used through
the second quarter of 1989, after which Dataquest worldwide ASPs were used. For 1M
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 253
Figure 5-13. Quarterly Fisher Ideal Price Indexes for Large-User
Purchases of DRAMs in the United States and Japan, 1986-89
1986:4 = 100
Sources: Author’s calculations based on unpublished Dataquest data; Nihon Keizai Shimbun (various issues); and
Nikkei Telecomm (on-line service).
prices for all sizes of DRAMs at rough parity in the fourth quarter of
1986, the DRAM price indexes for the United States and Japan were
calculated taking that quarter equal to 100.
Figure 5-13 shows the relative movement in the two regions of an
aggregate price index for large-user purchases of DRAMs from 1986
through 1989. The aggregate differential between the United States and
Japan looks very much like the pattern of differentials observed in each
of the individual varieties of DRAM, with U.S. prices rising well above
Japanese levels in 1987 and 1988, peaking at a level almost 50 percent
higher than in Japan in the second quarter of 1988, then falling to rough
parity by the end of 1989.
DRAMs Dataquest worldwide ASPs were used through the first quarter of 1987, then
replaced with Nikkei average large-user wholesale prices beyond that date.
254 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Fewer data are available on the market for EPROMs (in particular,
data on Japanese spot pricing are infrequently reported in the business
press). Nonetheless, it is clear that a considerably different situation
prevailed. Whereas the overall trend toward rising prices in 1987 and
1988 is similar to that in DRAMs, significant regional differentials in
contract pricing did not appear.
Figure 5-14 compares quarterly averages of Nikkei large-user whole¬
sale prices with Dataquest volume contract prices, where comparative
data are available, for 128K and 256K EPROMs. (As in DRAMs, the
Nikkei numbers probably should be viewed as more reliable than the
Dataquest estimates for the Japanese market.) No persistent price dif¬
ferential appears to have emerged; Japanese EPROM prices generally
tracked American EPROM prices, though often with a lag of roughly a
quarter. The data clearly suggest that Japanese EPROM prices basically
followed American prices downward after late 1988. Contemporary Jap¬
anese press accounts report that prices for imported foreign EPROMs
were pulling domestic price levels down over this period.33
33. “The drop [in EPROM prices] was attributed mainly to price competition among
foreign-affiliated makers hoping to expand their market share in Japan.” “Prices of EPROM
Chips Decline,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, April 19, 1989.
“The price of EPROMs was pushed down by competition from foreign manufacturers.”
“Semiconductor Prices on the Decline,” Nikkei Top Articles, April 24, 1989.
“In September . . . 1M chips dipped to 1,050-1,100 [yen], . . . Some U.S.-produced
EPROMs are now selling for around 1,000 yen, according to an official at a semiconductor
trading house.” “EPROM Prices Drop for the First Time in Six Months,” Nikkei Top
Articles, October 2, 1990.
“Imported EPROMs are also having an impact on prices . . . excess American output
is entering the Japanese market, said a sales agent.” “1M EPROM Prices Plummet below
900 Yen,” Nikkei Top Articles, November 2, 1990.
34. Because Dataquest identifies chip suppliers by the label on the chip, the reported
U.S. share of the DRAM market and the calculated HHI credit chips manufactured by
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 255
Figure 5-14. Quarterly Wholesale Prices for 128K and 256K EPROMs
in the United States and Japan, Selected Years, 1985-92
A. 128K EPROMs
Dollars per chip
B. 256K EPROMs
Dollars per chip
Sources: Dataquest, “DQ First Monday Report”; Nihon Keizei Shimbun (various issues); and Nikkei Telecomm
(on-line service).
256 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
64K DRAMs
1979 0.525 67 0 33 0 0
1980 0.264 59 0 41 0 0
1981 0.178 67 6 28 0 0
1982 0.129 60 6 33 0 0
1983 0.108 53 7 38 2 0
1984 0.092 48 10 38 4 0
1985 0.091 54 7 31 4 4
1986 0.099 56 11 19 5 10
1987 0.106 44 13 20 6 17
1988 0.170 19 22 21 1 37
1989 0.273 4 17 34 0 45
256K DRAMs
1982 1.000 100 0 0 0 0
1983 0.265 92 1 7 0 0
1984 0.213 89 3 9 0 0
1985 0.165 82 3 15 0 0
1986 0.135 77 5 15 1 2
1987 0.102 55 11 24 2 9
1988 0.091 46 18 28 2 7
1989 0.078 43 19 25 3 10
1M DRAMs
1985 0.964 99 0 1 0 0
1986 0.369 87 0 13 0 0
1987 0.347 93 6 1 0 0
1988 0.173 78 10 6 3 2
1989 0.135 54 16 14 5 11
1990 0.110 45 15 21 5 15
Source: Author's calculations based on unpublished Dataquest data.
a. Fujitsu, Hitachi, Mitsubishi Electric, NEC, and Toshiba.
Korea’s Samsung but marketed by Intel under its label to Intel, and Toshiba-made DRAMS
sold by Motorola to Motorola.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 257
64K EPROMs
1980 0.625 0 0 100 0 0
1981 0.389 11 0 89 0 0
1982 0.273 50 0 50 0 0
1983 0.157 60 1 40 0 0
1984 0.143 65 2 31 1 0
1985 0.136 65 2 30 4 0
1986 0.138 64 0 29 6 0
1987 0.089 44 4 38 13 0
1988 0.114 14 3 54 26 3
1989 0.131 7 3 59 29 2
128K EPROMs
1982 0.916 0 0 100 0 0
1983 0.405 22 0 78 0 0
1984 0.165 61 0 39 0 0
1985 0.154 77 0 23 0 0
1986 0.155 65 0 34 0 0
1987 0.112 50 1 43 6 0
1988 0.119 29 2 52 17 0
1989 0.153 17 1 58 24 0
256K EPROMs
1983 0.536 13 0 88 0 0
1984 0.394 18 0 82 0 0
1985 0.202 46 0 54 0 0
1986 0.155 59 0 41 0 0
1987 0.107 47 3 44 5 0
1988 0.097 36 2 50 12 0
1989 0.093 27 1 55 18 0
512K EPROMs
1984 0.500 0 0 100 0 0
1985 0.479 6 0 94 0 0
1986 0.257 32 0 68 0 0
1987 0.138 57 6 36 1 0
1988 0.105 46 3 42 8 0
1989 0.111 26 2 57 14 0
1M EPROMs
1987 0.253 80 0 20 0 0
1988 0.161 82 0 18 0 0
1989 0.133 63 0 34 3 0
2M EPROMs
1988 1.000 100 0 0 0 0
1989 0.882 96 0 4 0 0
4M EPROMs
1989 0.290 80 0 20 0 0
Index
down from .0597 in 1982.35 What this probably indicates is that semicon¬
ductor firms tend to specialize in particular types of products. It is also
evident that HHIs typically vary enormously over the product life cycle,
with values of one when the very first firm introduces a new-generation
chip, dropping over time as others enter the business, then rising again
at the end of the life cycle as firms phase out their production of the older
product and shift to newer items.
Thus, consideration of whether or not excessive monopoly power ex¬
ists, or whether the industry is more concentrated than the historical
norm, cannot be independent of the stage in the product life cycle. One
convenient measure of how advanced in the product cycle a generation
of product might be is cumulative output over time. Figures 5-15 and
5-16 show the evolution of HHIs over time for various generations of
35. See U.S. Bureau df the Census, 1987 Census of Manufactures: Concentration Ratios
in Manufacturing (U.S. Commerce Department, 1987), pp. 6-38.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 259
Index
36. These calculations use Dataquest estimates of annual production by all merchant
companies. Production by exclusively captive producers (with no sales on the open mer¬
chant market) such as IBM is excluded.
260 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
ise. For the three most recent generations of DRAM, Japanese market
shares were 67 percent (in 64K parts), 82 percent (256K), and 99 percent
(1M) in 1986, when the STA was signed. In EPROMs, overall, Japanese
company shares were considerably lower: 65 percent (128K), 59 percent
(256K), and 32 percent (512K). Thus, proportionate reductions in pro¬
duction or exports by Japanese producers would have potentially greater
relative impacts on aggregate supply in DRAMs than in EPROMs.
Furthermore, very different adjustments to Japanese production of
DRAMs and EPROMs are revealed in estimates of Japanese chip output
after the STA was implemented. Some of the best and most detailed
semiconductor statistics available cover DRAM and EPROM production
in Japan. As a consequence of the STA and the operation of the MITI
supply-demand forecast committee, Japanese companies reported a large
amount of data to MITI, from which quarterly estimates of Japanese
production, consumption, and net exports were compiled through late
1988. After the dissolution of this committee in 1989, MITI continued to
compile these estimates on a semester basis.37
As in DRAMs, MITI was reportedly issuing guidance to Japanese
producers to reduce EPROM production in 19 87.38 As will be seen
shortly, moreover, foreign producers rapidly expanded EPROM sales in
the Japanese market, and by 1989 Japan’s share of world output for many
types of EPROMs had fallen sharply and Japan had become a significant
net importer of EPROMs. This contrasted with the situation in DRAMs,
where Japan remained a large net exporter and continued to dominate
world supply.
In looking at production statistics, one should note that output in a
fully utilized chip fabrication facility is not fixed over time, but instead
rises on an S-shaped profile (figure 5-17). This occurs for two basic
reasons. First, as fabrication technology gradually improves, smaller fea¬
ture sizes become feasible. As the chip size is shrunk, more chips can be
fit onto the surface of the large silicon wafers on which the processing
actually takes place. Three or more such “die shrinks” may typically
Yield
Manufacturing line
improvement
final test yield
due
including half-good
to the
product and redundancy
redundant
Equivalent yield circuits
improvement due to
half-good chips
(without redundancy)
Planned yields
Years
Source: C. H. Stapper and others, “Evolution and Accomplishments of VLSI Yield Management at IBM,” IBM
Journal of Research and Development, vol. 26 (September 1982), pp. 532-45.
occur over the life cycle of the product within a single company.39 Second,
for a given die size, better control over the manufacturing process asso¬
ciated with experience and learning-by-doing creates improved yields—
the number of good chips that can be extracted from each batch of
processed silicon. Learning economies—predictable declines in unit cost
39. A desirable effect of incrementally smaller chips is gradually improved speed. Thus
the access time of the standard 256K DRAM produced by most manufacturers went from
150 to 120 nanoseconds over the 1987-88 period, as the result of die shrinks.
262 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
40. In a 1986 submission to the Commerce Department, Texas Instruments gave the
following estimates of time elapsed from the beginning of chip fabrication to sale to the
final consumer, for a 64K DRAM: wafer fabrication, 20-28 days; die inventory, 7-14 days;
assembly and testing, 10-14 days; and finished goods inventory, 20-30 days. See Texas
Instruments (1986), pp. 18-19.
41. The share of older vintage 256K DRAM chips exported dropped sharply in 1990
and 1991, however.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 263
256K EPROMs
Advanced Micro Devices11 n.a. n.a. n.a. 10 10
Intel 7 13 20 7 8
Hitachi 20 20 12 3 3
Mitsubishi Electric 21 15 16 4 4
Fujitsu 22 23 18 5 5
Toshiba 19 20 16 2 2
NEC 10 2 2 0 0
Others 2 7 16 69 68
512K EPROMs
Advanced Micro Devices11 n.a. n.a. n.a. 21 22
Intel 7 11 17 18 17
Fujitsu 18 15 27 9 7
Toshiba 16 12 13 4 4
Hitachi 17 11 15 5 5
Mitsubishi Electric 18 13 10 4 4
NEC 24 34 11 2 2
Others 0 3 7 37 39
Source: Unpublished data from Nikkei Telecomm (on-line service). First quarter of 1992 is estimated,
n.a. Not available.
a. Advanced Micro Devices is not broken out separately in 1988-90; in those years it is included in "Others.”
42. See Semiconductor Industry Association, Antidumping Law Reform and the Sem¬
iconductor Industry: A Discussion of the Issues (Cupertino, Calif., February 1990), for what
appears to be the only published description of this methodology.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 267
Let us consider the “average FMV” for some type of chip, defined as
the unweighted average across companies and minor product variants of
the true FMVs set for Japanese imports. If we treat the “error” added
on to the confidential, true-cost estimates to produce public, ranged cost
estimates as a random error with zero mean, averaging public ranged
cost estimates across minor variants on a specific type of product within
a company, and across companies, will produce an unbiased estimate of
this average FMV. Similarly, adding 25 percent to the maximum public
ranged estimate among the population of ranged average costs for all
companies will produce a number that must always be greater than or
equal to the greatest true FMV among all Japanese companies, and
therefore bounds the true FMV from above. Using these calculations,
then, we can construct an upper bound on the maximum company-
specific FMV and an estimate of the average FMV across all companies.
The picture is slightly complicated by the fact that—particularly in the
initial quarters of the operation of the FMV system—the Commerce
Department reviewed and made changes to the cost estimates submitted
by the companies in their quarterly reports prior to issuing FMVs. After
the system had operated for a while, however, and both the Commerce
Department and the companies had iterated onto a set of procedures
that produced estimates acceptable to the Commerce Department, FMVs
generally were set quite close to the constructed cost projections sub¬
mitted by Japanese companies.43
There is some evidence that actual FMVs had settled down around
companies’ projected cost submissions by mid- to late 1987. Figure 5-20
shows estimates I have constructed of average FMVs across companies
for 256K DRAMs (as well as a bound on maximum company-specific
FMV) based on public cost submissions to the Commerce Department
(of projected cost in period t — l).44 These are shown along with ranges
for actual FMVs for this product reported in the Japanese trade press in
1986-87. As can be seen, after initial large discrepancies between com¬
pany and Commerce Department calculations of cost, the midpoint of
the range for actual FMV—as reported by the press—settles around the
43. Interview with law firm staff responsible for Japanese company submission to the
U.S. Commerce Department, January 1990.
44. Because the type and extent of data reported for every company were different,
and often varied over time, the details of how these estimates were constructed are not
always obvious. These details are discussed fully in appendix 5-B.
268 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Sources: Author’s calculations based on data in table 5B-1; Dataquest, DQ First Monday Report; Dataquest
average sales price; and Semiconductor Industry Association, Antidumping Law Reform and the Semiconductor
Industry: A Discussion of the Issues (San Jose, Calif., February 1990), p. 8.
45. The SI A is not always consistent in how it associates these estimates of actual cost
with a time period. In Semiconductor Industry Association, Anitdumping Law Reform,
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 269
actual cost estimates are given for the quarter in which the report was submitted (although
the actual cost pertained to the previous quarter), whereas in SIA, Four Years of Experience
under the U.S.-Japan Semiconductor Agreement: “A Deal Is a Deal” (San Jose, Calif.,
November 1990), the actual cost estimates are assigned to the quarter in which the cost
occurred (that is, the quarter prior to the submission quarter).
46. See SIA, Four Years of Experience, p. 65.
270 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Sources: See figure 5-20; and Semiconductor Industry Association, Four Years of Experience under the U.S.-Japan
Semiconductor Agreement: “A Deal Is a Deal” (San Jose, Calif., November 1990).
Figure 5-22. Prices and Estimated Foreign Market Value (FMV) for
512K and 1M EPROMs, 1987-90
A. 512K EPROMs
B. 1M EPROMs
Dollars per chip
47. For 64K DRAMs data excluding foreign affiliates producing in Japan were unavail¬
able. In this case I use published MITI data on shipments and exports, which include the
output of U.S. affiliates in Japan, but for this product Japanese production by IBM and TI
is believed to have been insignificant. The unpublished MITI data were provided to U.S.
government officials and obtained by me. In producing the estimate it is assumed that
Japanese producers supply 100 percent of Japanese chip consumption.
48. The methods used to construct table 5-4 are briefly summarized as follows: start
with constructed time series on DRAM prices in Japan and the rest of the world (ROW),
P/ and Pro„ (the price indexes shown in figure 5-13, with the ROW price the same the as
U.S. price), total DRAM production by Japanese producers, St, and DRAM sales revenues
in Japan (Japanese companies’ DRAM production less exports times Japanese DRAM
price, summed over all chip types) and ROW (ROW companies’ DRAM production plus
Japanese companies’ exports times ROW DRAM price, summed over all chip types).
Dividing regional sales by the regional price indexes produces quantity indexes <2, and Qrow.
r~». as q <N r- CO q r- o q q q co —;
V sd
X Tj- CO in oo 00 Os
oo On o
co (N in r- sd o in i1 (N
op co co
On | 1
1 1
.
O q q in q q q q co q in q
C^O
in o cd sd sd cd sd GO
oo Os 00
CO
sd
(N m cd
O' co T—• m ii CO 00
Oo CO co
On | 1 T—1
t 1 1
oo t> o CN q q q q o q in q q
00 q r-H
00 csi in cd o
oo Os CO
in CO so so
Os (N (N in | m in o T—i
Oo T"H r-H
CO CO 1 r-H
On I
’"h 1 1
£
’"'■i q rsj o 00 q q q On q 00 q oo q
IT) tj- sd r-H sd in O in o cd oi sd
Co Os (N T-“H (N in <N m CO (N so
00 t-H r-H (N (N 1
Os 1 1
§
1
c
o
oo q q SO in oo q t—H q
5.6
17.4
6.3
o q
K '
IN so CO in o SO in cd cd o (N
-Uri OO t-H o (N r- in CN |1 in CO
°0 r-H i | | 1
c
o ,'H 1
u
"a CO q © in q sO q q q CO q q q q
o t\ CO On q o sd o ud in cd cd o
Oo 00 o H OS i> co i-H i r-H co (N
cq Os t-H
1
i
1
i
|
i
|
so ’-H
>5
C
S3 <N q in 00 00 q (N CO q q q 00 q q
t\ Os 00 oi © (N t—1 t—5 O rt- os cd tj-
t Oo r- OS Os r- SO CN i i (N H
Os | | |
i i
»-H
f
o
r-H q On CO q q (N q CO q CO q q q
^u t\ Os cd cd cd O in cd r-H (N in cd r-H
a; Oo r- 00 00 »n in i
i
i
i
| l
1
Os
1
~o
<j <u
£> S
<u<U
C/5
JU G
13
C/5
o
sg. * X
<U X J£ OJ <U
S I
^ -*—>
c
3
G £ c
03
_
s ^ .2
q$ ° o
cu c > s '5b 2
~
> 1
<U $ o
o
0) CS
Ur C/5 P 2 <U£
-2
13
n
Ur U—1 CAI
S e ^
C X
o
S
Uft
O CU
>N
c
(U
O 0
5 3 CS C/5 T3 03 E kr
O. 0) 0
C/5
<u
0X) O
Ur p
<—
0
C/5
0) 4—*
OX) G
E § c E G 03
tij ^ O
u>
o
u
0
0
2
c
X
0
C
O
O
o i- II S-H
II O
G -O
U) O ts Ur
-o O CD
>-• G G G 03
<L>
0 -r
<U
<u
•2 <u
0 O
«4-( i— q q Ur
x ^
c c
•S
S5
CL Ur T3
l o <2 sd
to N4—1 H-i Ur
<U sd V <D CJ cc 0
<u E <u Ur
in in ■» 00 c O 'HH 00 0Q 00
<D
0JD
s CL
<u
OX) OX) •-
CL O
97.9
-o-
130.7
sC On
ON mi
nC
(N O n (N
97.0
138.4 oo
ON (N IT) C m nd m
rf ON OO
I
oo
97.7
153.0
cn NO NO o ON NO NO NO 1—H mi
oo 00 ON mi NO NO 00 On
m O ON m i ON
m i T““t
i 1
I I
m r-
95.7
124.2
h Tl CO O fO On r- OO OO
no
^ cn
Ti mi
m rf
1/3 no
n I
On ^ NO
ON ON
I I
I
86.8
113.4
ON oo ON NO NO On
no
o
ON
ON
^
Is
(N on
tT H
rf- nO OO rj
1—( Tf" CO
I
V i i
t"- vq
104.0
83.2
On CO OO
mi jh in On n ON ON O
On r- on ^ h m on
I
n On GO -h cn cn
79.4
98.5
ON ON ©
CO ON © © 0\ O' oi N"
ON r- no on | I ON ^
I I
on oo no
79.5
84.9
NO ON NO ON
ON ON C in d os >n on
GO m> m | |
JD
"c0
/3 13
/3 C
Price before removal of controls
C/3
C
<D <D
u*
— C/3 $ d) *3 <2
3 ,03 2 o c § o
C
o £ C <4_|
o £
d>
c > ^ d>
*5b £ > 1 S *5b
o d> 03
/3 d> * d>£
i-i c
i-H 2 8 t— 8 8
o S d> >s 0)
cCO s 1/5
Price elasticity = — 2
£ <o 5 S O
cm
d> "O
u. g I "O
d> u,
03 Q- d) 3 CL ^
(1986:4=100)
O _ ox) o G 00 OX) O
O © E I a. c 03 X) E 3 03 X
Rest of world
x o o o
1 ii
8 TO d> d> y « s d) d) y § a
.E .£ .S .E 5 Q. y
u o r- -§ c C S. a £
d> d> d> d> £ JJ ■= d) d) cut < «
s £ OX) OX) OX) Of) •= ^'5 OX) OX)
c c ■— c/5 ?
Japan
^
3 ON
T—t
c c c c -p C/5 ^
J= sz 2 <
_ CO CO 03 CO 2 < cd 03
0) w
o
S i £
'G g.u u u u fS u u eS
CO
0-
276 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Assume demand for DRAMs in Japan and ROW is given by a constant price elasticity
demand function with elasticity -1.5, Q: = Z; P~' 5, where Zy is a Japan-specific constant
that varies over time, reflecting shifts in aggregate demand within Japan. A similar equation
describes demand in the rest of the world. Zy is calculated in every quarter by dividing
quantity 2, by Pf15 (and Zrow analogously). Given the two Q’s and the two P’s (corre¬
sponding to border controls and different prices inside and outside Japan), the effect of the
removal of border controls given the same total production is to produce a single new world
price P' and new quantities Q’ and Q’ro„ consumed in Japan and the rest of the world,
which must solve the system of three equations in three unknowns:
p, _
\Zj + ZrJ
With the constant elasticity demand function, the effect on consumer welfare of a change
in price from Pa to P’ equals
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 277
49. The figure for Japanese companies is calculated by converting a fiscal 1988 operating
profit of 150 billion yen to dollars at 130 yen to the dollar. See Barclays de Zoete Wedd
Research, Japan-Electronics, Semiconductors (Tokyo, December 1988), p. 17. The figure
for all suppliers is according to the consulting firm In-Stat. See Richard McCausland,
“Semiconductor Makers Concerned Price Cuts Could Hamper Growth,” Electronic News,
January 2, 1989, p. 22.
50. This value is roughly consistent with a report circulating in Japanese industry circles
278 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
in the spring of 1989, according to which MITI had calculated that “bubble money” was
running around 45 billion yen per month at that time.
51. Tyson argues that “In EPROMs, a product in which American companies still
retained a significant share of the world market at the time the [STA] was signed, the
outcome was very different. . . . American and other buyers did not report shortages in
EPROM supplies, and American EPROM suppliers such as Intel asserted that EPROM
prices never significantly rose above their marginal costs because of competitive mar¬
ket conditions.” Laura D’Andrea Tyson, Who’s Bashing Whom? Trade Conflict in High-
Technology Industries (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1992), p. 121.
52. Indeed, cost disadvantages faced by U.S. semiconductor manufacturers were one
of the reasons why the Sematech manufacturing consortium was formed to improve the
productivity and competitiveness of American chip producers.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 279
sold in the Japanese market under the Intel brand name.53 Mitsubishi, at
least, could apparently manufacture and sell EPROMs at prevailing
prices at a profit, and found it more attractive to do so than to increase
production of DRAMs, which it also manufactured.
A third possible explanation is that the levels set for FMVs prevented
Japanese producers from selling their output in foreign markets. But, as
we have seen, these price floors were not binding in the U.S. market
through 1988 and were never an obstacle to selling product in the Japa¬
nese market. Nevertheless, Japanese producers steadily cut back their
output of EPROMs, and Japanese consumers increased their use of im¬
ported product in their stead.
This observation and the details of the Intel-Mitsubishi accord suggest
an alternative explanation. Japanese producers as a group may have cut
back production as a deliberate policy aimed at increasing imports and
foreign market share, and assuaging friction with foreign chip makers,
who had continued to market and sell EPROMs even after they dropped
out of DRAMs. Although it is impossible to determine just how impor¬
tant political factors were in explaining all the unusual market develop¬
ments observed after 1985, the review in chapter 4 of the details of the
STA makes it clear that they were present and played some role. While
EPROMs’ role in the memory market declined precipitously in the 1990s
(replaced by so-called flash memory chips, a superior electronically re¬
programmable form of nonvolatile memory), EPROMs provided incum¬
bent producers with a strong technology base for the new products.54
53. Andrew Pollack, “Intel to Resell Japanese Chips,” New York Times, July 30, 1987,
p. D4.
54. MITI dropped EPROMs from its semiannual forecast in 1994.
280 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
55. See Electronics Industry Almanac, 1992 (Tokyo: Dempa Publications, 1992),
p. 909 (in Japanese). However, the WSTS statistics also exclude shipments by some small
foreign producers that do not belong to the WSTS, as well as IBM, so that in theory
(although almost certainly not in practice) it would be possible for the MITI number to
exceed the WSTS-based measure of market share.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 281
56. “Arrangement between the Government of Japan and the Government of the
United States of America Concerning Trade in Semiconductor Products,” June 11, 1991,
sec. 2, para. 10.
57. "Arrangement,” annex A., pp. 9-10. For production arrangements involving joint
participation by both Japanese and U.S. firms (joint ventures, production under license,
foundry arrangements), these definitions ultimately also involved considerable ambiguity,
and the U.S. Department of Commerce ultimately created a detailed handbook defining
on a case-by-case basis whether the output of a particular factory with such transnational
links was to be considered “foreign.”
58. U.S. Trade Representative, “Questions and Answers on the U.S.-Japan Semicon¬
ductor Arrangement,” June 4, 1991.
282 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Percent
Sources: SIA, Four Years of Experience, app. 4; Electronics Industry Almanac, 1992 (Tokyo: Dempa Publications,
1992), p. 910; "Trend in Foreign Market Share in Japan under the 1991 Semiconductor Arrangement,” graph attached
to Electronics Industry Association of Japan, “UCOM Chairman Comments on Foreign Semiconductor Market Share
in Third Quarter of 1995," press release, December 14, 1995; and "Foreign Share of Japanese Chip Market Soars,"
Computing Japan (on line), March 21, 1996.
59. David Roman, “IBM Launches OEM Chip Push in Japan,” Electronic Buyers’
News, August 3, 1992, p. 3; Junko Yoshida, “IBM Japan’s Efforts to Sell Chips Stalled:
Distribs Will Sell Its ‘High-Function’ ICs,” Electronic Engineering Times, August 10, 1992,
p. 94.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 283
60. The U.S. Trade Representative’s June 1993 projections had suggested that FI would
drop to about 19.6 for the first quarter of 1993. David Lammers, “U.S. Uneasy about Japan
Chip-Share Dip,” Electronic Engineering Times, June 21, 1993, p. 4.
61. Bob Davis, “U.S. Chip Firms Seem to Lead Japanese Ones in Sales This Year, but
Experts Aren’t Sure Why,” Wall Street Journal, December 24, 1992, p. 30; T. R. Reid,
“U.S. Again Leads in Computer Chips,” Washington Post, November 20, 1992, pp. Al,
A42; and Ken Yamada, “Intel Is Ranked No. 1 Chip Maker for 1992 by Study,” Wall Street
Journal, January 5, 1993, p. B6.
62. William R. Cline, “Yen Appreciation Does Reduce Japan’s Surplus,” Wall Street
Journal, May 20, 1993, p. A16.
284 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
where sitl is the foreign share of product i at time 11, and min is the share
of product i in aggregate Japanese semiconductor sales at time tl. Then
the change in foreign share from time tl to time t2, Sl2 - Sn, can be
decomposed into a portion due to increased foreign penetration of par¬
ticular market segments, and a portion due to shifts in the composition
of market demand. That is,
Sl2 — = 2
i
Sit2mit2 ~ Sil\rnit\
63. Nihon LSI Logic’s manufacturing facilities were a 50 percent joint venture with
Kawasaki Steel. The market shares are calculated from data available on the Nikkei Telecom
online computer database.
64. Author’s interview with K. K. Yawata, Nihon LSI Logic, Tokyo, March 1991.
65. See Jacob M. Schlesinger, “U.S. Chip Makers Find ‘Quotas’ Help Them Crack
Japan’s Market,’’ Wall Street Journal, December 20, 1990, pp. Al, A6.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 285
The first terms summed after the second equality are the changes in
market share due to increased foreign penetration, while the second set
of terms are changes in market share due to changes in the overall com¬
position of demand. So, if there are no changes in market composition
(mIf2 — m,„ = 0 for all i), all change in foreign market share is attributed
to increased foreign penetration; conversely, if foreign penetration is
unchanged in all market segments (s„2 - sin = 0 for all i), all change in
foreign market share is attributed to changes in the aggregate composi¬
tion of demand.
This is not the only possible decomposition of share change into a
penetration component and a market composition component. The de¬
composition just described can be referred to as the “initial market
composition” variant, since changes in foreign penetration within seg¬
ments were weighted by the initial share of that segment in the aggregate
market, while changes in market composition were weighted by final
foreign market share in each segment. An alternative decomposition, to
be referred to as the “initial foreign share” variant, can be given as
where the initial foreign share of each segment has been used to weight
changes in market composition, and final market segment shares in total
sales are the weights on changes in foreign share by segment. Still a third
decomposition may be constructed that takes the mean of the previous
two sets of weights on changes in market composition and foreign pene¬
tration, that is,
66. None of these decompositions is invariant to the level of disaggregation used. More
or less disaggregated product categories will give somewhat different decompositions of the
contribution of foreign penetration by segment, and market composition, to aggregate
foreign market share change.
<o> oior--ococcoro
Os
r- —■ sc r- — ro sc —•
Os
<3
-s:
Os NCO'fsi'C^nM Os ri in C O to - ro h
r-i — m rq r-i —
<0
O 00 • O <N O O so Os — O CO (N O'
00 OS O O
Foreign Share of the Japanese Semiconductor Market Due to Changes in Foreign Penetration and
o
3 »n <N • • m no oo "3- inH\o^THOt
C rr a. ® o in O;oorjfsjion^q
*3 J o c e o o o o 00000000
o
I I I I III
£
c -3 in vo • J h ON O0 Nf
N (N ® ™ -si- t~~ rr ’-H3-Ht^'r<TTOS’-H00
O C e <%i o o ^ O^HT_HOCNOO^t
6 ^ I
eg F
cx.
O O E E o O O O
o OOOOOOOO
53 I I I I I I
£ s: s
e
.0
c
o c .2 —* NO J, O CN ON O NO 't N ON H so o T OS
<3. .£P 3 (N~) O ra n (v| m n o 1 o so m o 1 so
S 2 ^ E E pi 6 6 Nf o ^r
o o ^
o Cl C
^ su
ex.
Initial foreign penetration
o • 00 no r- cn (NhOfN^fsOOsCC
3 <n w a. -rt O ON OssO(N(N^t(NO^
“3 O E c o d o o
O OOOOOO
%
1 3
3 -2 O in 00 h sOM^hsOOONsO
• SP 3 (N Tf 03 r- so i-H ornoor^iooor-ios
^ 2
Composition, Selected Periods, 1986-94“
O ^
O C <n O^H^-HOCNOO^t-
LT 3 I
T3
3 5s.
3
3 rv1 ^
so 05
- -3 IT) Os
0O «o
O Ol (N
Os ^5
c>inr^ococoom
•2 ^ "3 Os
^
. tT
cs
6 (sj 06 Os (NOOs(Nsd^t-C^(N
(N T-H 1-H y—I r-H t-H
^ CO
«sj £>
SO
o cj
’5b
TO
c _o
03
+
03 c^3 o
e- V-H
0
3 ’5b 0
u, 0
CJ
tS0 O
u O •-
o
Table 5-5.
E
O 3 ’*3 CL) O ’5b E o .2 '5b E
3 2, u c o —
“3 _o SO .2
03 E E 13 o t— 2 >
C3 C — 03
Percent
O O CO CO CO .0 CJ ro Os *0 CO 00 00 n
aOOO
03
C C/3
as u
^ -2 H 1 aOOOi2 c .22
g; £ ^ ^ PQ < Q s s 2 s < Q
lTt
^ >3 S ps Os
•**«<
.&0
S
0 (N r- <n Os —; Os in so —T os sO 0 cn cn —* r- mososinso —
-s, « rsi 0 0 *—H d ^ Os (N in -h 00 d 06 sd in sd d o r! ri O' ro ri
00 (N m (N in (N in <n m ^h Os m m in —< r- <n
Os
Os
r-
(N
Os Os
J Os
sO
sO
cn
»n
00
rn
CN
m
so
(N
(N
(N
T-H
<N
r-
H
cn (N
T-H T-H
r-
0
soin(nr^ososinso
ooooo(Ninm
1—H 1—H d d d d d d d d d d d d d d 00000 o o
I I I I
O SO SO 00
n GO --h
os o r- 00 so r- in
o in (N m ^ m
HO^in^ONOr^mH^ooin
(Ncnooooomoocomsoso
OOOO 0000000 dddddddddddddd
I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
h m n io cn os os os os m o o hhinhooin»nM(NnnH
Os ro © ^ m os o o so o i—i O <N ■— 1 r t-1 o o m o o gn cn t—* t'" o> O
I I
< -Si
I I I I I I I I I I I I 1?
os r-
‘5 A
r- r- 00 so o 00 so in 00 t-h o^cocohhoo(Nsonsor>h
00 CN) Os CO in t-h o o 00 o t-h o
OOOO d d d © d d d 00000000000000
u uo
0 —1 in 00 m 00 in 0 SO r- CN (N in (N 0 t-H m (N SO r- <N in 0> CN
(N 00 0 0 (N in (N (N T-H cn (N O O 0 O 0 O (N O O (N SO Os
UJ
d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d D.
CL
H
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
. , O'
C
o :
c
bo
§ S; CN in O r- 00 t-H 0 Os cs os (N sO ^H so m in in <N o 00 o o o
£ «
_? -K
00 CN d r 4 SO OS csi
t-H t-H (N
OS r-H t-H
t-H <n
(N
t-H
rsi
Os
(N
T-H
06 d d os d in n
m t-H so t-H
r- (N (N
o
‘5b
E ^
2D
m-Japanese companies
B o X) <D
O
o
o x .am
£3 ’>
C/3 ‘o < A 2 V
3
o
<D
Cl
C/5 D-a
-o
C/5 cd cd C/5 Lh •o
o
C/5
Lh
O X
-•SS
- u cd <u
h a JO o <D
C/5 M in d
cd O
^
4- cn op
o ^ H U ^
cn o
Ui la Cl
3
«s
o O O
^ ^
Q,
Ih
s A 53 o
‘5b
cd 0
c/5
\/
v C
O JJ O
O
0 2
- O Cd
Q.OC ’So
_ 2
^
<L> —
o S 'oi) JO H S
O
o .a E
3 t»
O H-
.S2 rO
H-*
s <->
O v> C/5 O C/5 PC o <L> *rs &O
ft ^ d . o
Os o "O el Cu <1 "3 OX)
o CL
c
cd
2 g C S3 P !Z
I
I
o
.a
2
y cd
1
s
-g ^
is
W
LU CO <
5 CL oc U c/5 o
^ a
P o u £
o 2 X Oh
U UJ O P
O Os
288 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
when sales by Intel, the U.S. microprocessor leader, soared and for¬
eign market share shot up, increases in U.S. market share in Japan
due to memory chip sales almost exactly equaled those due to micro¬
components.
The second part of table 5-5 breaks out the sources of increased
foreign market share in Japan during 1990-94 in much greater detail.
This much more disaggregated set of data comes from a survey admin¬
istered by the Nomura Research Institute (NRI) in collaboration with
the Users’ Committee of Foreign Semiconductors (UCOM), an organi¬
zation of the sixty-two major Japanese semiconductor users set up in 1988
to encourage increased access by foreign semiconductor suppliers to the
Japanese market.67 The respondents to the NRI survey account for about
two-thirds of Japanese semiconductor consumption.68 The NRI survey
uses a definition of “foreign” that appears to correspond to the F2 variant
favored by the Japanese government (that is, a definition based on the
label appearing on the finished chip).
The specific product areas accounting for the bulk of the foreign mar¬
ket share gain (each contributing half a percent or more and in the
aggregate approaching 7 percent of a 7.4 percent increase in foreign
market share) are ASICs (including gate array, full custom, and standard
cell logic chip types), microprocessors, Mask ROMs and other memory
(nonprogrammable and specialized memory chips), industrial ICs, stan¬
dard logic and application-specific standard products, and microper¬
ipherals. The story told by these data is also one in which increased
foreign penetration in specific product areas, rather than compositional
shifts in the market, is the force driving increased foreign market share—
6.7 percentage points out of a total increase in foreign market share of
7.4 percent. The greater disaggregation adds more complexity to the
picture, however. In both microprocessors and DRAMs, for example,
67. UCOM, affilated with the Electronics Industry Association of Japan, has sent trade
missions overseas to stimulate chip purchases, held seminars on applications and design
opportunities, and established a California liaison office to interface with smaller U.S.
suppliers unable to set up Japan-based organizations.
68. Surveyed companies purchased $13.4 billion in semiconductors in 1990 (based on
the NRI survey), compared with a total Japanese market of about $19.5 billion (based on
WSTS statistics)—or 69 percent of the market. For the second and third quarters of 1994
(the period covered by the NRI survey in 1994), surveyed companies purchased $9.77
billion compared with a total Japanese semiconductor market (WSTS data) of $14.96 bil¬
lion—or 65 percent of the market.
290 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
shifts in overall market demand toward these products were more im¬
portant than increases in foreign market share in accounting for the net
contribution of these products to the overall foreign share.
In fact, the detailed data shown here on the contribution of foreign
memory chip sales in Japan reveal a bit of a puzzle and allow an important
insight into the operation of the system for tracking foreign market share.
Adding up market share changes of the various memory chips on the list
of products in the NRI survey gives a net contribution of roughly
2 percent to foreign market share, about the same as the contribution
that U.S. firms alone made to foreign market share in this segment, as
shown in the analysis of WSTS data in the top part of table 5-5. At first
glance, this is perplexing because it was widely reported that there were
large increases in Korean DRAM shipments to Japan during this period,
so one would have expected the increase in foreign share in memory
chips to have been much larger than that corresponding to U.S. compa¬
nies alone.69
A good part of the answer may lie in the NRI survey definitions,
which, like the Japanese government’s preferred F2 measure, apparently
classified as foreign those products with non-Japanese labels. Newspaper
reports suggest that with increasing frequency Korean DRAMs were
being procured by Japanese companies for sale in Japan.70 If shipped in
assembled form to Japanese companies, then finished, stamped with a
Japanese brand name, and sold in Japan, these products would be class¬
ified as Japanese, using F2 (and in the NRI survey would not be counted
as foreign in table 5-5). They would, however, be counted as foreign by
the U.S.-favored FI formula.
Indeed, there is some good recent evidence that Japanese and Korean
vendors were deliberately structuring deals designed to take advantage
of the definitional complexities hovering over what was defined to be
“foreign” and what “domestic.” In March of 1995, NEC and Samsung
announced a curious deal in which Samsung would ship Korean-made
DRAMs to NEC in Japan, to be sold under NEC’s brand name, while
NEC’s Scottish factory would ship an equal volume of DRAMs to Sam¬
sung’s European assembly facility, where they would then be stamped
69. By 1994 imports from South Korea and Taiwan had risen to 15 percent of the
Japanese memory market. “Memory Chip Imports from ROK, Taiwan Rise,” Nihon Keizai
Shimbun, March 11, 1995, p. 1.
70. See for example Tetsuya Iguchi, “Japanese, Korean Rivals Forging DRAM Alli¬
ances,” Nikkei Weekly, October 18, 1993.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 291
71. Jim Handy, “NEC to Get 4MB DRAMs from Samsung Electronics,” Dataquest,
“DQ Monday Report” (on-line data service), March 13, 1995. See also, “Samsung, NEC
in Euro DRAM Deal,” Electronic Engineering Times, February 13, 1995, p. 16.
72. For example, Korea’s Hyundai and Japan’s Fujitsu announced a 1993 deal under
which the Korean company would license its 4M DRAM chip to Fujitsu in exchange for
the right to acquire DRAM chips made at a U.S. Fujitsu plant and sell them under its own
brand name. Hyundai was thus able to avoid an 11 percent dumping tariff imposed by the
United States on its Korean-made DRAMs. See Don Clark, “Fujitsu and Hyundai Elec¬
tronics Form Unusual Joint Venture in Memory Chips,” Wall Street Journal, October 7,
1993; and Jim DeTar, “Fujitsu, Hyundai In DRAM Talks,” Electronic News, October 11,
1993, pp. 1-2. Korea’s Goldstar also signed a 1993 pact with Hitachi to build chips under
license from Hitachi’s design that it would then supply to Hitachi in Japan. See David
Lammers and Junko Yoshida, “Fujitsu and Hyundai in DRAM Pact,” Electronic Engi¬
neering Times, October 11, 1993, p. 1.
73. As the result of this deal with NEC and of other export arrangements, Samsung
was projecting a 50 percent increase in its exports to Japan in 1995, to reach a total of
130 billion yen. “Memory Chip Imports from ROK, Taiwan Rise,” p. 1.
292 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Conclusions
Degrees of freedom 5 13 6 9
Source: Author’s calculations based on unpublished data provided by confidential industry sources.
and small outline cases (SO, in the case of 1M DRAMs);75 and chips
with relatively uncommon organizations,76 a sample of 83 agreements for
64K DRAMs, 174 for 256K DRAMs, and 128 for 1M DRAMs remained.
The distribution of these contracts by lead time (months from nego¬
tiation date to start date) and duration (months from start date to end
date) is shown in table 5-A1. For 64K and 256K DRAMs the contract
75. These involved a small number of observations divided among a relatively large
group of other packages. Only 256K DRAMs with access times of 120 nanoseconds or
faster were packaged in PLCC cases in the contracts in this sample.
76. Chip organizations other than 64K x 1, 256K x 1, 1M x 1, or 256K x 4 (the
latter two are 1M DRAM types) appeared only in a relatively small number of contracts
in my sample.
298 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
distributions are shown for periods before and after September 1986,
when the STA went into force. (Only two of the contracts for 1M chips
in this sample were negotiated before September 1986, and no such
disaggregation is shown.) For 64K chips, all contracts in the sample were
for parts with a 64K x 1 organization and plastic DIP packaging.77 For
256K DRAMs, contracts covered both DIP and PLCC packages.78 The
1M contracts include parts with both 256K x 4 and 1M x 1 organiza¬
tions, and both DIP and SO cases, which were all found in abundant
numbers. This proliferation of chip types demonstrates a trend toward
increasing product variety in the DRAM market.
It is readily apparent that delivery on the vast bulk of these contracts
begins within a very short period after their negotiation. The contract
lengths cluster around three, six, and twelve months’ duration. More
than 40 percent of the contracts for 64K and 256K DRAMs could be
considered “spot,” in that shipments were scheduled to begin in the
month they were negotiated; a smaller but still substantial fraction
(28 percent of the 256K shipments; 14 percent of the 64Ks) were to begin
in the month following the contract’s negotiation. The great bulk of the
remaining contracts for 64K and 256K parts began within two to four
months, except for a small number of outliers clustered at five to seven
months.
Contracts for 64K and 256K DRAMs negotiated after September 1986
tended to have longer lead times and to last longer than contracts before
that date. A formal chi-square test comparing pre- and post-STA distri¬
butions generally confirms these casual impressions.79 The period prior
to the signing of the STA was one in which markets saw abundant supplies
and generally declining prices, while 1987 and 1988 were generally
marked by firm or rising prices and tightening supplies. Not surprisingly,
77. Four contracts for parts in ceramic cases were discarded from the sample; the rest
of the discards were also in plastic DIP packaging.
78. A small but nontrivial number of contracts for parts with 64K x 4 organizations
or for ZIP, ceramic, or SIMM packaging were dropped from the sample as well.
79. Both the lead times and lengths of contracts signed for the newer 256K DRAMs
seem to have changed after the STA was signed, whereas lead times shortened but contract
lengths did not seem to change in transactions involving the more mature 64K products.
For 256K DRAMs we reject the hypothesis that these contracts were drawn from identical
populations of lead times at the 5 percent significance level, and we reject a similar hy¬
pothesis on contract lengths at the 1 percent level. For 64K DRAMs we reject the hypothesis
of a single distribution of lead times at the 5 percent level, but we are unable to reject the
hypothesis of a common distribution of contract lengths at even the 10 percent significance
level.
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 299
had been indicated elsewhere, and I could not reject the null hypothesis
of no regional differences between the United States and Europe.
Fifth, estimated quantity discounts were very small and statistically
insignificant. Other available data on contract pricing, disaggregated by
size of transaction, also seem to show little systematic relationship be¬
tween price and contract size.81 Since interviews with purchasing man¬
agers at computer companies in 1989 frequently suggested that the largest
companies often did pay lower contract prices, I interpret this to im¬
ply that the overall size of the account, rather than the size of one
sales transaction for a single type of chip, determined any applicable
discounts.82
Sixth, a general pattern of Korean vendors selling their product at
somewhat higher prices emerged, consistent with anecdotal observations
by market participants.83 In effect, transactions with Korean producers
probably more resembled a short-term, spot market-like exchange than
the less volatile, long-term agreements generally characterizing contracts
between large purchasers and producers. During a period of scarcity, the
Korean producers appear to have charged a higher price, above the long¬
term contract price and approaching the spot gray market price. During
a period of relative glut, on the other hand, we would expect this spot
price to lie below the long-term contract price. This analysis is consistent
with the reports in the trade press on Korean producer Samsung’s deal¬
ings with its American distributors.84 It is confirmed by a U.S. ITC
81. See U.S. International Trade Commission, 64K Dynamic Random Access Memory
Components, 1985, pp. A40-A45.
82. A 1992 U.S. International Trade Commission report suggests that contract sales
may reasonably be divided into large, “Tier 1“ premium OEM accounts, and a second tier
of smaller accounts, including franchise distributors and value-added resellers. The report
actually suggests that premium customers may pay higher prices, because of their more
demanding and lengthy qualification requirements. See U.S. International Trade Commis¬
sion, DRAMs of One Megabit and Above, p. A-43. Since this report covered a period of
slack demand in which prices were generally declining quite sharply, one might interpret
this to mean that second-tier contracts were shorter term, more like spot transactions.
83. In all likelihood a single Korean firm—Samsung—was responsible for all of the
Korean product shipped in this sample of contracts.
84. At the peak of the DRAM shortage, in the summer of 1988, Samsung attempted
to hike its prices to levels that its American distributors protested left them uncompetitive,
and ended its ship-from-stock-and-debit policy, which effectively let distributors hold price-
protected inventory. The distributors had thus been able to capture the benefit from rising
prices by maintaining large inventories of product, without the downside risk that falling
prices would pose with a large inventory. The practice was reinstated when the market
slowed down in early 1989. See Electronic News, August 15,1988, p. 47; February 27,1989,
EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT 301
p. 27; April 3, 1989, p. 35. When prices turned down sharply in early 1990, Samsung
shocked its American distributors by doing away with the customary “price protection”
altogether, so that the effective prices paid by authorized distributors would more closely
follow the ups and downs of the spot market (and more of the price risk would be transferred
to the distributors). American distributors complained bitterly about Samsung’s “broker
mentality” (that it was behaving like a broker, passing on the full volatility of gray market
spot pricing into its contracts with distributors, rather than moderating price swings with
its contract pricing practices). See Bob Ferguson, “Samsung Notifies Distributors: Ship and
Debit Will End Feb. 1,” Electronic News, January 22, 1990, p. 34; Ferguson, “Samsung
Terminates Six Distributors,” Electronic News, February 5, 1990, p. 38; and Ferguson,
“Brajdas Files Suit vs. Samsung over Inventory Returns, Credits,” Electronic News, July
2, 1990, p. 32.
85. See U.S. International Trade Commission, DRAMs of One Megabit and Above,
p. A-45.
86. This appendix is based on SIA, Antidumping Law Reform-, and the author’s inter¬
views with Commerce Department officials and industry sources in 1990. The text describes
the state of practice about 1990; in the first few quarters after the STA went into effect
there was some variation as these procedures were developed.
87. Production overhead expense included depreciation of capital equipment, allocated
across product lines according to generally accepted accounting practices.
302 EFFECTS OF THE SEMICONDUCTOR TRADE ARRANGEMENT
Table 5-B1. Foreign Market Value (FMV) Projected Cost Estimates for
Japanese DRAM Manufacturers, by Company, Selected Quarters,
1986-89°
Dollars per chip
256K DRAMs
1987:1 1.86 2.33 1.86
1987:2 1.87 2.48 2.08 3.10 2.14
1987:3 2.65 1.76 2.57 2.45 3.31 2.36
1987:4 2.68 2.69 2.19 2.10 3.37 2.42
1988:1 2.25 1.49 1.89 1.36 2.81 1.75
1988:2 1.69 2.31 1.98 1.84 2.89 1.96
1988:3 1.72 2.50 1.89 2.19 3.12 2.07
1988:4 2.07 2.40 2.15 2.23 2.99 2.21
1989:1 2.47 2.10 1.95 2.15 3.09 2.17
1989:2 2.39 2.49 2.11 2.20 3.11 2.30
1989:3 2.34 2.31 2.30 2.02 2.92 2.24
1989:4 2.03 2.07 2.19 1.88 2.74 2.04
1.97 1.58 2.06 2.02 2.74 3.43 2.07
1.93 1.78 1.87 2.80 3.50 2.10
2.90 2.14 1.75 2.16 2.03 3.62 2.20
1990:4 2.15 2.16 1.59 1.71 2.71 1.90
2.51 1.78 2.34 1.89 3.14 2.13
2.02 2.98 1.99 3.73 2.33
1991:3 2.13 1.92 4.39 1.80 5.49 2.56
Company
Year and Maximum Unweighted
quarter Mitsubishi NEC Fujitsu Hitachi Toshiba + 25b% average
1M DRAMs
1987:1 23.75 29.69 23.75
1987:2 22.14 13.31 27.67 17.72
1987:3 15.67 15.96 11.34 9.47 19.95 13.11
1987:4 13.32 9.78 11.85 8.41 16.65 10.84
1988:1 10.21 5.92 13.98 6.81 17.48 9.23
1988:2 8.10 6.90 8.48 6.44 10.59 7.48
1988:3 9.22 7.51 8.20 11.52 8.31
1988:4 8.76 6.20 8.76 10.95 7.90
1989:1 9.45 5.44 6.33 7.10 11.82 7.08
1989:2 9.10 6.09 7.84 6.98 11.37 7.51
1989:3 4.54 6.61 5.06 8.27 5.40
1989:4 3.65 4.68 4.71 5.88 4.35
6.33 3.71 5.62 5.62 7.91 5.32
5.48 5.72 4.87 4.89 7.15 5.24
4.70 5.22 4.89 4.14 2.93 6.52 4.38
1990:4 5.26 4.35 3.90 3.22 6.58 4.18
3.31 3.97 3.79 4.06 5.08 3.78
4.98 3.89 4.44 3.83 3.33 6.23 4.09
1991:3 4.87 4.35 3.95 4.86 6.09 4.51
Source: Based on data taken from unpublished company submissions to the U.S. Department of Commerce.
“FMV” date is the quarter after the quarter to which the projected cost applies and two quarters after the quarter
in which the projection was submitted.
n.a. Not available.
a. Cost concepts used are, by company:
256K DRAMs: Mitsubishi, export sales price (ESP) for M5M4256AP type chip; NEC, average of constructed
value (CV) for 41256P, 41256CF, and 41256L type chips; Fujitsu, CV for MB81256/7P type chip; Hitachi, average of
CV for 50256P NMOS and CV for 51258P CMOS type chips in dual in-line package; Toshiba, average of ESP for
41256AP and 41256P type chips for 1987:2 to 1989:1 and 41256AP only for 1989:2 to 1989:4 and ESP for 256K x 1
NMOS in dual in-line package for 1990:1 to 1991:3.
1M DRAMs: Mitsubishi, ESP for M5M41000P for 1987:1 and ESP for M5M41000AP for 1987:3 to 1991:3; NEC,
average of CV for 421000C/421001C/421002C, 421000LA/421001LA/421002LA and 421000V/421001V/421002V for
1990:2 to 1991:3; Fujitsu, CV for MB81C1000/1P chip type; Hitachi, CV for lMxl CMOS chip type in dual in-line
package; Toshiba, ESP for TC511000P for 1987:2; average for TC511000P and TC511000AP for 1987:3 to 1988:3 and
ESP for 1M CMOS DRAM in dual in-line package for 1989:1 to 1991:2.
b. If reported value is 20 percent less than true value, true value is 25 percent greater than reported value.
Because the adjustments were generally small, ESP and PP were essen¬
tially the same value as CV.
Foreign Market Value (FMV). The floor price for a company’s DRAM
exports was related to these cost concepts in the following manner. Thirty
days after the beginning of a quarter, companies were required to submit
data showing actual costs in the previous quarter and projected costs for
the current quarter. The de facto practice in the Commerce Department
was to require the use of the previous quarter’s actual costs as projected
costs for the current quarter, because those were the only numbers that
could be based on objective calculations using actual data and did
not rely on hypothetical assumptions about cost declines and yield
improvements.
Projected ESP and PP for the current quarter were used to set FMVs
for sales delivered to a customer inside or outside the United States for
the next quarter. Thus FMV in quarter t was approximately equal to
projected cost in quarter t — 1. This in turn was approximately equal to
actual reported cost in quarter t — 2.
Estimates of Company FMVs. Public submissions contained at least
some ranged data on the above cost concepts for Mitsubishi, NEC,
Fujitsu, Hitachi, and NEC. FMVs for Matsushita, Oki, and Texas In¬
struments Japan were calculated as a single weighted average of the FMVs
for the five larger producers. Product types and reported data changed
over time for many companies. Although some data were reported in
each quarter for every company, reporting was not consistent. Table
5-B1 reports estimates of FMV based on projected costs for each of these
companies where such a number could be constructed. In all cases the
estimated FMVs are based on prior-quarter projections of CV or ESP.
Where multiple versions of these chips were accounted for on separate
cost tables, the numbers reported are an unweighted average of available
data on unit costs for these different chip types.
CHAPTER SIX
Dumping in DRAMs
1. A brief history of the origins of this new standard may be found in Pietro Nivola,
“Trade Policy: Refereeing the Playing Field,” in Thomas E. Mann, ed., A Question of
Balance: The President, the Congress, and Foreign Policy (Brookings, 1990), pp. 229-30;
and Gary N. Horlick, “The United States Antidumping System,” in John H. Jackson and
Edwin A. Vermlost, eds., Antidumping Law and Practice: A Comparative Study (University
of Michigan Press, 1989), pp. 133-34.
2. Horlick, “United States Antidumping System,” p. 136.
3. See Micron Technology’s petition to the U.S. Commerce Department, International
Trade Administration, and the U.S. International Trade Commission, Petition for the Im¬
position of Antidumping Duty (June 1985), pp. 11-14.
305
306 DUMPING IN DRAMS
4. According to U.S. law, dumping is defined as sales of imports at “less than fair
value” that cause “material injury to a U.S. domestic industry.” To determine the fair value
to which U.S. import prices are to be compared, the Department of Commerce is instructed
by law to determine foreign market value (FMV) using sales prices in the exporter’s home
market. If the data are insufficient, Commerce must then use prices for sales to third
countries. If these data too are inadequate, Commerce must calculate a “constructed value”
to estimate the FMV. The statute says that actual foreign sales data may be disregarded
when, first, they fall below total costs of production over an extended period of time and
in substantial quantities, and second, they do not permit full recovery of all costs within a
reasonable time and in the normal course of trade. The department is reported to take the
“extended period” as its investigation period, “substantial quantities” as 10 percent of sales
by volume, and generally to ignore the second requirement. See N. David Palmeter, “The
Antidumping Law: A Legal and Administrative Nontariff Barrier,” in Richard Boltuck and
Robert E. Litan, eds., Down in the Dumps: Administration of the Unfair Trade Laws
(Brookings, 1991), pp. 71-75. Also see Tracy Murray, “The Administration of the Anti¬
dumping Duty Law by the Department of Commerce,” pp. 23-27 and 38-40, in this same
volume.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 307
behavior might be going on occurs when a firm’s price falls short of its
short-run marginal cost or, even more obviously, average variable cost
(which bounds short-run marginal cost from below over the relevant
range).8
In considering why a firm might rationally choose to produce and sell
at a price that fails to cover the current marginal cost of production, it is
helpful to distinguish between “strategic” and “nonstrategic” behavior.
I shall label a firm’s behavior “strategic” when it explicitly takes account
of the impacts of its decisions on the behavior of other economic agents,
and “nonstrategic” when decisions consider the actions or choices of
other agents as fixed, unaffected by one’s own actions. Predatory pricing,
as alleged by the U.S. semiconductor industry of its Japanese rivals
(described in chapter 3), can be classified as a form of strategic behavior.
One possible explanation, consistent with nonstrategic behavior, for
pricing below marginal cost is that increased production may lower a
firm’s future production costs, through learning effects (discussed be¬
low). In this case, measured current marginal cost overstates “true”
marginal cost, which should take into account the cost-reducing effects
of current production on future output.9
But another possible explanation for behavior of this sort is a strategic
motive on the part of the dumper: either predation, defined here as
actions intended to encourage other firms to exit the industry; limit pric¬
ing, intended to discourage entry by other firms; or a defensive response
against predatory behavior by others.10 In this case the rents from the
8. See Janusz A. Ordover and Garth Saloner, “Predation, Monopolization, and Anti¬
trust,” in Richard Schmalensee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Or¬
ganization, vol. 1 (North-Holland, 1989), pp. 579-90, for a detailed survey of the literature
on tests for predatory behavior.
9. Such learning economies can also be used as a strategic instrument, with a firm’s
production decisions taking into account the impact of its learning on the actions of its
rivals. See Drew Fudenberg and Jean Tirole, “Learning by Doing and Market Perfor¬
mance,” Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 14 (Autumn 1983), pp. 522-30, for such a model.
Deardorff, “Economic Perspectives on Antidumping Law,” pp. 37-38, points out that
low-priced sales designed to build brand loyalty or otherwise alter consumer preferences
might also rationally lead a producer to sacrifice current profitability for future rents, and
to price below marginal cost. In effect, greater current output shifts future demand sched¬
ules, and current marginal revenue then understates “true” marginal revenue. Such
“demand-side learning effects,” however, may be considered a form of strategic behavior,
since they are designed to alter the behavioral response to price of other economic agents,
in this case consumers rather than rival firms.
10. The modern rehabilitation of the theory of predation focuses on its impact on rival
firms’ expectations about future profitability: as an exit-inducing investment in “disinfor-
310 DUMPING IN DRAMS
mation” about the predator’s cost structure, for example, or as the consequence of asym¬
metric financial constraints among competing firms created by imperfections in capital
markets. The basic references are Paul Milgrom and John Roberts, “Limit Pricing and
Entry under Incomplete Information: An Equilibrium Analysis,” Econometrica, vol. 2
(March 1982), pp. 443-60; and David M. Kreps and Robert Wilson, “Reputation and
Imperfect Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 27 (August 1982), pp. 253-79.
Useful interpretations are found in Paul Milgrom, “Predation,” in John Eatwell, Murray
Milgate, and Peter Newman, eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London:
MacMillan, 1987), pp. 937-38; and Jean Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization
(MIT Press, 1988), pp. 367-80.
11. Criticism of a short-run marginal cost test for predation generally argues that the
rule is not stringent enough; prices above short-run marginal cost may still be associated
with socially costly predatory activity. See Tirole, Theory of Industrial Organization,
pp. 372-73; and Ordover and Saloner, “Predation, Monopolization, and Antitrust,” pp.
579-80.
12. As, for example, Deardorff, “Economic Perspectives on Antidumping Law,” pp.
35-36.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 311
spective also leads one to focus on the close relationship between “fair
trade” laws and competition and antitrust policy. It might be argued that
some binding international standards for competitive business behavior
(and their enforcement) might be offered as a constructive alternative to
national “fair value” dumping tests based on constructed costs, as rem¬
edies for predation.
I will not attempt in this chapter to evaluate whether predation is a
plausible description of what was going on in the DRAM marketplace in
the 1980s; that question is explored—but not resolved—in the next chap¬
ter. I merely note that predatory behavior was one of the allegations
made by the U.S. industry in pressing its case for protection. However,
the modern theory of predation has been interpreted to suggest that high-
technology industries are particularly important places to look for such
behavior.13
13. Paul Milgrom argues that “policymakers should be especially sensitive to predatory
pricing in growing, technologically advanced industries, where the temptation to discourage
entry is large and the costs of curtailed entry even larger.” (Milgrom, “Predation,” p. 938.)
See Kenneth Flamm, “Semiconductor Dependency and Strategic Trade Policy,” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics (1993), pp. 249-344, for further considera¬
tion of the plausibility of strategic behavior in semiconductor competition.
312 DUMPING IN DRAMS
14. “The Learning Curve and Competition,” Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 12 (Spring
1981), pp. 49-70.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 313
15. For example, a new state-of-the-art fabrication facility in Taiwan reported in 1992
that it took four months to qualify production processes, followed by five months of further
work to raise production from 1,000 to 10,000 wafers a month, at a facility with a current
production rate of 15,000 wafers per month. See Klaus C. Wiemer and James R. Burnett,
“The Fab of the Future: Concept and Reality,” Semiconductor International (July 1992),
pp. 96-98.
314 DUMPING IN DRAMS
has been increasing rapidly. For the upcoming 256M DRAM, for exam¬
ple, industry sources have estimated both the R&D and plant investment
required to be about $1 billion each.16
In my somewhat stylized depiction of the industry, a DRAM producer
will be assumed to produce a homogeneous commodity, perfectly substi¬
tutable for that of other producers.17 Difficult issues concerning the tim¬
ing of the switchover from one generation of DRAM to another, and
intergenerational externalities, are ignored by assuming that a DRAM
producer faces a fixed period over which the product is sold, and that
costs to develop and produce the product are relevant to that genera¬
tion of DRAM alone. The product life cycle begins at time 0 and ends at
time 1 (hence, the unit of time is the “product life cycle”). Every pro¬
ducer faces revenue function R, giving total revenues at any moment t as
a function of its own production y(t) and the aggregate output of all other
producers x(t). (All revenues and costs are measured in constant-dollar
terms.)
Semiconductor production is believed to be characterized by strong
learning economies. As was explained in chapter 5, output from a fully
utilized chip fabrication facility is not fixed over time, but instead rises
on an S-shaped profile (see figure 5-17 and the accompanying discussion).
Although the Spence model of learning economies is rather unsuitable
for analyzing production decisions in an industry where capacity con¬
straints may be important, as is the case in the semiconductor industry,
it shows, as we have seen, that even with nonstrategic behavior econom¬
ically rational firms will engage in forward pricing. For simplicity in mod¬
eling producer behavior, I will, following Spence, ignore discounting over
time on the grounds that product life cycles are short (typically, a new
generation of DRAM is introduced every three years) and the additional
complexity is substantial.18
p = dE = y_
dt K' ’
effects of inflation, so that any applicable discount rate would be smaller than if measured
in nominal terms. This, coupled with the shortness of the product life cycle for DRAMs,
should make my undiscounted life cycle profit calculation a reasonably tolerable approxi¬
mation to the more complex discounted flow.
316 DUMPING IN DRAMS
Spence’s Model
If wafer processing capacity K is not fixed over the life cycle but is
continuously variable, as is implicit in Spence’s formulation, then we have
a special case of the above model in which r is zero (capital costs are
included in wafer processing cost c and some arbitrary initial scale for
capacity K is set), capital is a completely variable input, and a producer
is free to choose any nonnegative u (that is, u is unbounded above, not
bounded by one) and to produce any yielded chip output desired. Under
these circumstances, as is easily shown in appendix 6-A, formal maxim-
19. The world record for bringing a new fabrication facility on line is said to be nine
months. See Larry Waller, “DRAM Users and Makers: Shotgun Marriages Kick In,”
Electronics, November 1988, pp. 29-30.
20. An alternative, to be presented in the next chapter, is to set up a two-stage com¬
petition among rival firms, with capacity investment as the initial phase, followed by a
second stage in which firms choose output paths subject to capacity constraints. The
solution of the static game presented here corresponds to the open-loop (nonstrategic)
equilibrium of this two-stage game, in which a firm’s first-period choice of capacity takes
its rivals’ choices in both periods as given. The alternative equilibrium concept will assume
second-period subgame perfectness, that is, that firms take into account the effect of their
first-period capacity choices on their rivals’ second-period output paths. This creates stra¬
tegic interactions among firms. See Avinash Dixit, “Comparative Statics for Oligopoly,”
International Economic Review, vol. 27 (February 1986), p. 114; and Carl Shapiro, “The¬
ories af Oligopoly Behavior,” in Schmalensee and Willig, Handbook of Industrial Organi¬
zation, vol. 1, pp. 383-86.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 317
(6-2)
(6-3) 8 (1) = 0
(6-4) 8 = — — u K wF .
w
21. Andrew R. Dick, “Learning by Doing and Dumping in the Semiconductor Indus¬
try,” Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 34 (April 1991), pp. 133-59, for example, invokes
the Spence model to motivate his assumptions about the time path of semiconductor prices
over the product life cycle, but ignores the constant pricing prediction of the Spence model.
318 DUMPING IN DRAMS
22. Richard E. Baldwin and Paul R. Krugman, “Market Access and International
Competition: A Simulation Study of 16K Random Access Memories,” in Robert C. Feen-
stra, ed., Empirical Methods for International Trade (MIT Press, 1988), pp. 171-97. A
somewhat different exposition of this model is given in Elhanan Helpman and Paul R.
Krugman, Trade Policy and Market Structure (MIT Press, 1989), chap. 8. The later inter¬
pretation (henceforth referred to as H-K) differs in some significant respects from B-K.
For example, the learning curve in B-K has yields improving with cumulative wafers pro¬
cessed (that is, faulty chips have the same yield-enhancing effects as good ones), whereas
H-K presents a more conventional view of the learning curve, with yield rates rising with
cumulative output of yielded (good) chips. The B-K assumption on yields, although not
the accepted approach to modeling yield improvement within the industry, simplifies the
mathematical structure of the model.
23. There is a great deal of confusion in the industry about what exactly forward pricing
means. Does it mean that learning economies are to be taken into account when forecasting
marginal costs, and prices, for future deliveries in forward contracts with large customers,
or does it mean—as in the Spence model—going even further and producing quantities
such that marginal revenue falls below current marginal cost? Note that even when output
is capacity constrained one can have aggressive “forward pricing” in the sense of price
DUMPING IN DRAMS 319
(and, necessarily, marginal revenue) falling below current marginal cost: if one examines
the simulations in this chapter, price is below both current marginal and average cost in
the earliest portion of the product cycle (see table 6-4). Thus capacity-constrained output
and aggressive forward pricing are not mutually inconsistent—the firm is producing as
much as it can and reducing the price to whatever level is needed to sell it all.
24. See Baldwin and Krugman, “Market Access and International Competition,”
p. 185.
25. Baldwin and Krugman, “Market Acccess and International Competition,” p. 195;
and Helpman and Krugman, Trade Policy and Market Structure, p. 173. The conjectural
variations approach has each firm assuming that if it increases its output by one unit, each
of its competitors will change its output by v units, where v can take on a range of values.
The case of v = 0 is the Cournot assumption.
26. “Comment on ‘Market Access and International Competition,’ ” in Robert C. Feen-
stra, ed.. Empirical Methods for International Trade (MIT Press, 1988), pp. 198-202.
320 DUMPING IN DRAMS
where the B-K specification fixes u equal to one and y equal to zero.
Even with its relatively general structure, the above analysis provides
several insights into questions concerning pricing and dumping over the
product life cycle. First, pricing below current marginal cost will never
be observed near the end of the product cycle among competitive, non-
strategic, profit-maximizing firms. This follows immediately from the fact
that, if any output is being produced, marginal revenue will never be less
than the right-hand side of equation 6-2 (see appendix 6-A), which at
time 1—the end of the product cycle—equals current marginal cost
(d + ciw). Since price exceeds marginal revenue, price also must exceed
current marginal cost in some neighborhood of time 1, the end of the
product cycle.
Second, it is common practice in the semiconductor industry to note
that chip prices seem to fall with cumulative experience, just as consid¬
eration of learning economies suggests that unit costs should. Indeed,
analysts often identify average unit cost with price, then estimate an
empirical “learning curve” by regressing the logarithm of market price
against the logarithm of cumulative output for the industry. Slopes of this
line typically are found to be around -0.3.28
The analysis just laid out, however, suggests that this implicit interpre¬
tation of prices as proportional to some variant of current unit costs is
generally hard to justify. We have seen that firms may be forward pricing,
with prices set below current marginal costs of production. In this case,
to break even (or make a profit) over the product cycle, prices must, over
at least some other period, be set above current marginal costs. Thus
28. See, for example, Integrated Circuit Economics, Mid-Term 1989 (Scottsdale, Ariz.,
1989); Boston Consulting Group, Perspectives on Experience (Boston, 1972); and Douglas
Irwin and Peter J. Klenow, “Learning-by-Doing Spillovers in the Semiconductor Industry,”
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 102, no. 6 (1994), pp. 1200-27.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 323
prices may in general be below current marginal costs over some period,
and above current marginal costs at other times, and the practice of
treating price as proportional to some definition of unit cost becomes
questionable.29
However, in one important special case, namely, when production
proceeds at full blast over the entire product life cycle, an explicit rela¬
tionship between price and cumulative volume does emerge. In that case,
output is fixed by initial capacity investments and the effects of learning
economies on yields, while price is determined by the parameters of the
demand curve, given whatever output is produced at full capacity. It can
be shown that in this case
dlogP _ dP E _ e
3log£ dE P p’
29. Needless to say, since average unit cost (in which fixed costs such as R&D and
capacity investments are allocated to different time periods over the product cycle, and the
average of this fixed cost per unit produced is added onto marginal cost) must lie above
current marginal cost, the same criticism applies to identifying price with any definition of
average unit cost.
30. To get this result, assume the industry is made up of N identical firms, each pro¬
ducing output y. Let industry demand be given by inverse demand function g, so that P =
g(Ny). With full-blast, capacity-constrained production, y at any moment in time is given
by w{e)K, with K representing capacity (in wafer starts) per firm and w yielded (good)
chips per wafer, a function of firm cumulative experience e. E (= Ne) is industry cumulative
experience. Substituting for y in the expression for P, and differentiating with respect to
E, we end up with
dgy dw e
dy g de w
Can we say anything about the relationship between price and long-
run average cost? The model sketched out thus far takes the number of
firms in the industry—which will affect profitability and pricing—as
given. One “natural” way to close the model is to specify that firms enter
the industry until rents earned by producers—that is, the integrand in
equation 6-1—just equal zero. The zero profit condition then determines
N, the number of firms entering the industry (we will ignore the difficul¬
ties created if one insists that N be an integer). Zero profits mean that
total life cycle revenues just equal total life cycle costs. Therefore (after
dividing both concepts by total output over the product life cycle) average
life cycle price must equal average life cycle cost per unit.
But is there any clear relationship between current price and current
“fully allocated” average cost at any given moment? Current short-run
marginal cost is a relatively clear concept: it is the additional current cost
not be identical. Indeed e with a 70 percent learning curve is actually equal to 0.5, not 0.3.
Irwin and Klenow's 1994 study, “Learning-by-Doing Spillovers,” which like all other
studies regressing price on cumulative output finds an elasticity of price with respect to
cumulative output of about - .3, interprets this to imply an 80 percent learning curve. For
the reasons just given, this parameter can actually be interpreted as supporting a much
larger, 70 percent learning curve in a capacity-constrained operating environment.
Irwin and Klenow recognize that if firms are capacity constrained, their methodology
is suspect. They argue that an aggregate semiconductor industry capacity utilization mea¬
sure produced by the SIA varied between 43 and 78 percent over 1978-92: “if these capacity
figures apply to DRAM production, then the assumption that capacity constraints do not
bind seems appropriate” (p. 1214). This assumption is unwarranted, however, since the
SIA survey also includes older, economically marginal facilities that produce specialized,
older-vintage, and custom chips on fully depreciated, obsolete lines as demand warrants.
Current-generation DRAMs are generally produced in leading-edge facilities with new
equipment that are basically run at full capacity around the clock for at least the first years
of their lives. Stories in the business press (see chapters 3 and 4) suggest that, at the very
minimum, during periods of cyclical boom in chip demand aggregate DRAM output has
been constrained by available capacity.
The only available data on plant-level capacity utilization for current-generation semi¬
conductor fabrication lines appear to support the notion of a capacity-constrained operating
environment. In their detailed, international study of sixteen semiconductor lines (twelve
of which used current generation 6-inch wafers and equipment, four of which used slightly
older 5-inch wafers and equipment, and one of which used older 4-inch wafers), the Com¬
petitive Semiconductor Manufacturing survey of the University of California, Berkeley,
found that “most but not all of the fabs in our sample were fully loaded [relative to their
capacity] throughout their four-year period of observation.” See Robert C. Leachman,
“Introduction,” in Robert C. Leachman, ed., The Competitive Semiconductor Manufactur¬
ing Survey: Second Report on Results of the Main Phase, report CSM-08 (Engineering
Systems Research Center, University of California, Berkeley, 1994), pp. 17-18.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 325
saved by producing one less unit at any given moment. This is the incre¬
mental cost saved when output is reduced by one unit.32 In my model,
current short-run marginal cost—d + clw—is constant at any moment
and equal to current average variable cost.
To define a fully allocated current average cost, however, it is necessary
first to define an intertemporal cost allocation rule to spread fixed entry
costs F and capital costs rK over the product life cycle. Dividing the
capital and entry cost allocated to some instant in time by output pro¬
duced at that moment yields a current average fixed cost per unit pro¬
duced. If this current average fixed cost is added to current average
variable cost (identical to short-run marginal cost in my model), we have
a long-run average cost (LRAC) concept that satisfies the basic require¬
ments of a long-run average cost: when multiplied by output at that
moment, and when all such products are summed over all moments, total
costs of production over the entire product life cycle are given.
In one special case—when d, the yielded chip output-sensitive part
of variable cost, is “small” (in a sense to be defined in a moment), and
it is assumed that free entry by other competing firms into the industry
forces life cycle profits to zero—a clear pattern in the relationship be¬
tween price and both marginal and average cost over the product life
cycle exists. Differentiating our industry demand function with respect
to time (and assuming determinants of demand other than price remain
constant), we must have
P _ l z
P ~ p z’
linking rates of change in price over time with growth rates in industry
output, where (3 is the price elasticity of demand and z is industry output.
Now, recall that we have defined LRAC as
cuK + rK + F
LRAC = + d,
y
32. When a firm operates at less than full capacity, this is identical to the increased cost
incurred in producing one more unit. When operating at full capacity, the incremental cost
of an additional unit is effectively infinite; the marginal cost curve is L-shaped, with a kink
at full-capacity output.
326 DUMPING IN DRAMS
cuK
MC = - + d,
y
and average cost always exceeds marginal cost by the average fixed cost.
Differentiating with respect to time, then, gives33
rK + F
■I- d
LRAC d y
1 - y- + - < 0
LRAC LRAC LRAC u
MC d ly u
1 - < 0
MC MC \y u
and both marginal and average cost must be falling over the entire prod¬
uct life cycle.34 More interestingly, because demand is elastic (p < -1 )
and the industry is populated by identical firms (so z/z = y/y), we must
then have
+ d\
P LR AC (1 d \ y y u
1 - >0,
P ~ LRAC ~ \(3 + LRAC) y " LRAC 1 u
\
if output-sensitive variable cost d is “smaf in the sense of other costs’
share in average cost (AC), 1 — d/LRAC, exceeding 1/p in absolute value.
Because our assumption about entry means that total life cycle costs
are exactly equal to total life cycle revenues, price less the fully allocated
long-run average cost as defined above (that is, profit per unit), multi¬
plied by output and summed over every moment of the product cycle,
must be exactly equal to zero. Thus, if price exceeds the fully allocated
average cost concept at any instant, it must fall below fully allocated
average cost at some other instant over the product cycle, and vice versa.
Under the assumption of “small” output-sensitive variable costs, price
must fall more slowly than average cost, and average cost falls over the
entire product life cycle. Therefore, for there to be zero profit over the
rK+F
Dollars
product life cycle, price must originally lie below average cost in the early
part of the product cycle, then rise above it at the end. In this case the
relationship among various cost concepts will appear as in figure 6-1, and
we would expect to observe below-average-cost “dumping” in the early
part of the product life cycle as the consequence of normal competitive
behavior.35
The scenario sketched out in figure 6-1, however, depends critically on
the assumption that costs incurred after wafer processing are a “small”
component of cost throughout the product cycle.36 As we shall see in a
35. This argument is made by example, in the special case of all firms engaging in full-
blast production over the entire product life cycle, in Richard E. Baldwin, “The US-Japan
Semiconductor Arrangement,” discussion paper 387, Centre for Economic Policy Research,
London, March 1990, pp. 17-19; and Baldwin, “The Impact of the 1986 US-Japan Semi¬
conductor Agreement,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 6 (June 1994), pp. 129-52.
Baldwin implicitly assumes that all variable costs are yield-sensitive (that is, that d = 0).
36. The behavior shown in figure 6-1 is also assumed, without explanation, in Dick,
“Learning by Doing,” pp. 133-59.
328 DUMPING IN DRAMS
37. Define a cost allocation rule g(z,t), where z is a vector of arguments and t is time,
such that
FAAC = - + d + -.
w y
that is, current average variable cost plus average fixed cost. We know that the optimal
path must contain a capacity-constrained segment, and that along this portion of the optimal
path
P = P'Ny = P'NKweE.
in symmetric industry equilibrium. If price P is to always equal FAAC along this segment,
however, differentiating the expression for FAAC with respect to t, and setting this equal
DUMPING IN DRAMS 329
If not these, then what paths over time for prices and costs would one
expect to see in the simple model outlined here? Our next step is to take
this simple control model and solve it to explicitly derive an individual
firm’s behavior over time. To sharpen our characterization of a profit-
maximizing firm’s optimal policy, we must address some additional issues.
Since in equilibrium N, P, and other variables will generally be functions of all the param¬
eters of the optimal control problem, a function g that satisfies this last equation must
generally include all parameters of the control problem as arguments, unless wE = 0, in
which case g is constant. (In this case, I note in appendix 6-A that all capacity is utilized
and output is constant over the entire product life cycle.) Thus, as long as there are learning
economies (wE does not equal zero), a cost allocation rule g varying only with F, r, K, and
t cannot satisfy the requirement that P = FA AC, for arbitrary values of the parameters of
the control problem, over this capacity-constrained interval.
Also, we have already noted that it is possible for P less than current marginal cost to
be optimal in the presence of learning economies. (Indeed, the simulations reported below
contain examples of such behavior.) Reexamining the definition of FA AC, it is clear that g
must be negative for P = FA AC to hold true over such an interval.
38. See also Integrated Circuit Engineering, Mid-Term 1988 (Scottsdale, Ariz., 1988),
p. 6-35.
330 DUMPING IN DRAMS
39. B-K use the same functional form but do not face the stuck yield problem, because
the argument in their learning curve is experience in processing gross wafers, not yielded
good chips. The latter specification is generally industry practice in estimating learning
curves.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 331
that improved manufacturing yields come from two main sources: refine¬
ments of the operation of the production line (with each new refinement
building on previous experience), and die shrinks (reductions in the fea¬
ture size for chip designs, made possible by improved use of existing
process equipment). These are iterative and sequential in nature. That
is, lessons learned from running a line over some period of time are then
applied to refine the operation of that line over a subsequent period.
However, by this logic, if numerous identical production lines are run
in an identical fashion over the same period of time, then the same lessons
are being learned, in parallel, on each line, and yields at the end of the
period should be no higher than if only a single line were being run. Of
course, if a new line—with no experience and lower yields—is put into
operation after an older line has been running for some time, and it is
possible to completely transfer the fruits of experience across facilities,
then the maximum experience on any one line would be the experience
variable determining production yields. Because all investment occurs at
a single initial moment in my simple model, all lines will have identical
amounts of production experience at any subsequent moment in time,
and cumulative output per facility is the desired measure of experience.
It is possible that the lessons learned on different lines are not the
same, if completely different “experiments” in production refinement are
being conducted at every production facility. If, once again, experience
can be completely transferred across facilities, and there is no duplication
in lessons learned in different facilities, then it might be argued that
company-wide, absolute cumulative output, rather than cumulative out¬
put per unit capacity, is the relevant experience variable.40 Empirical
discussion suggests, however, that the transfer of experience across facil¬
ities is quite costly.41
only partially transferable across plants and across firms as the yields often depend on
specific conditions of fabrication processes of a particular plant.”
42. The relationship between this specification and the “per fab” and “per company”
specifications of learning effects may be sketched out as follows. Let Y be total company
output, q output per fab, K company capacity, / capacity per fab (plant size), and m the
number of fabs per company. The basic hypothesis is that E = q m'\ with p an “appropri¬
ability” parameter taking on a value of zero if only the plant’s own experience is relevant
to yields, and one if all company-owned plants’ experience is relevant. Any intermediate
degree of appropriability can be assumed by choosing the appropriate value for p. Since
K , Y ■ Y
m = and q = —, then E = E ' —r, *y = 1 — p. If capacity is measured in units
K Ky
such that / approximately equals one, then my assumed relationship holds as it stands.
If not, rescale experience variable E as £' = E f'~y, and substitute for E in equation 6-6.
43. An alternative specification might make cumulative output, or cumulative output
per unit capacity, the state variable, subject to some initial value; this alternative state
variable times K to some power would then be the argument of w, the function giving yield
per wafer. Such a specification, however, makes initial yield (with no experience) a function
of the scale of capacity investment, which is undesirable. (In that case, increasing or
decreasing capacity simply to raise initial yield on every line will play an entirely artificial
role in determining optimal capacity.)
DUMPING IN DRAMS 333
solves the B-K conundrum.44 An exact solution for E(t), assuming ca¬
pacity-constrained output (see appendix 6-B), is given by
44. The existing empirical literature on learning curves gives us little help in deciding
the correct specification. If data on cumulative output from a given facility, or aggregate
data from a group of facilities with fixed capacities, are used to estimate the relationship
y = wK using equation 6-6, we get an equation like
Ln[y(t)] = a + e Ln[Q(t)],
that is, giving the natural logarithm of total output as a linear function of the natural
logarithm of cumulative output Q, even if cumulative output per unit capacity is the relevant
experience variable. The effects of capacity size K have been absorbed into constant a.
Data from different facilities of varying size within a single company, or from different
companies, along with an additional variable controlling for capacity size, are required to
identify and estimate y.
45. The critical assumption is that all good chips coming off the wafer fab line incur all
the costs of assembly and final test before being culled.
If we denote DRAM consumers’ inverse demand function for finished chips by P(&,£y),
then the producer’s maximization problem, taking into account assembly and final test yield
losses, is to
max„(,)X f P&(t,
0
n
£y(0] 4y(0 - 7 £y
^
(0
334 DUMPING IN DRAMS
the results, we must only remember to divide all gross per unit cost and
revenue measures (price, marginal revenue, marginal cost, etc.) emerg¬
ing from the optimization analysis by in order to get the net cost and
revenue measures per good unit observed in the chip marketplace.
(6-9) z = a Pp,
(6-10)
Model Solution
Next, I briefly summarize the method used to solve numerically for an
optimal policy. Full details may be found in appendixes 6-A and 6-B. It
is useful to categorize optimal policies in terms of two possibilities. One
possibility is that full-blast production is followed by an “interior seg¬
ment” where a firm is producing at less than full capacity. In this case an
E = uwK1^.
Now, if we define an inverse demand function for “gross” chips (including product ruined
in assembly and final test) by
and substitute, we get exactly the maximization problem given earlier in equation 6-1,
where
P[x(t),y(t)} = P[x(t),y(t)]y(t).
DUMPING IN DRAMS 335
When the firm produces at less than full capacity, an optimal, profit-
maximizing policy must set the difference between marginal cost and
marginal revenue equal to 8IKy, the value of an additional unit of current
production in reducing future production costs over the remainder of the
product cycle. As in the Spence model, marginal revenue along this
interior segment will be constant, equal to terminal marginal cost. We
may solve a differential equation giving experience at time ts, E(ts,K)
after a period of full-blast production through optimal switchpoint ts to
an interior segment, and using this result, derive an equation giving ts as
a function of K, N, and other parameters of the control problem:
(6-11)
This is just the condition that marginal revenue at time ts (on the left-
hand side) equals current marginal cost at terminal time 1 (on the right-
hand side).46
A second equation giving optimal capacity may be derived from equa¬
tion 6-5. After solving for 8 over both interior and boundary segments,
and substituting into equation 6-5, we have an expression implicitly giving
as a function of optimal ts, and N. Together with equation 6-11, for
given N and various other parameters, we have two equations in two
unknowns. An optimal ts and K pair must solve these two equations.
46. The expression within the outermost parentheses in the denominator on the right-
hand side of this equation is experience at terminal time 1, after producing from ts to time
1 at a constant output level; the entire denominator is yield at time 1.
336 DUMPING IN DRAMS
In many important cases the optimal path may not contain an interior
segment, so we never switch from full-blast production, and u{t) will
always equal one. The transversality condition (equation 6-3) will still
hold, however, and using this boundary value we can solve an equation
of motion for 8, and derive a different version of equation 6-5, which
implicitly determines A” as a function of N and other parameters.
Since, however, this expression gives us a necessary condition for op¬
timal K conditional on full capacity utilization over the entire product
cycle, we must be careful to ensure that such a path is in fact a Cournot
equilibrium. In searching for Cournot equilibria, then, attempts were
made to solve both the two-equation system characterizing an optimal
policy with interior segments, for a ts and K pair, and the single equation
giving optimal K assuming full capacity utilization throughout the prod¬
uct cycle. Solutions found were then checked as possible Cournot equi¬
libria, by perturbing both firm capacity K and switching time ts by 0.01
in all feasible directions, while maintaining the hypothesized equilibrium
output path for all other firms, and calculating the impact on firm prof¬
itability (which should necessarily be negative if the perturbations are
from a Cournot equilibrium). The procedure assures us that we have
found a local maximum satisfying the first-order necessary conditions.
47. With a constant wafer processing cost as the only cost element (the model that
underlies these studies), we have
A learning elasticity e equal to 0.47 is solved from the 72 percent learning curve, since 2~e
= .72. See Robert N. Noyce, “Microelectronics,” Scientific American, September 1977,
pp. 62-69; and Office of Technology Assessment, International Competitiveness in Elec¬
tronics, OTA-ISC-200 (1983), p. 76. Engineers at IBM, on the basis of studies of production
costs for IBM bipolar integrated circuits in the 1960s and 1970s, derived a virtually identical
71 percent learning curve. See William E. Harding, “Semiconductor Manufacturing in
IBM, 1957 to the Present: A Perspective,” IBM Journal of Research and Development, vol.
25 (September 1981), p. 652. Douglas W. Webbink’s 1977 survey of the integrated circuit
industry notes that interviewed companies believed e to generally lie in the 0.32 to 0.52
range, depending on the type of device. Staff Report on the Semiconductor Industry (Federal
Trade Commission, 1977), p. 52.
Note that B-K appear to have erred in interpreting the number reported in the 1983
Office of Technology Assessment study’s report of a 72 percent learning curve—their basis
for assuming that e = 0.28, when it actually corresponds to e = 0.47!
Irwin and Klenow, “Learning-by-Doing Spillovers,” interprets their results as reflecting
an 80 percent learning curve, but this depends critically on the assumption that producers
are not capacity constrained over their product life cycle. In a capacity-constrained envi¬
ronment, their results are consistent with a 70 percent learning curve (see note 34).
48. Since the unit of time is the (assumed five-year) product cycle, yields after two
years correspond to time .4, after three years to .6, and so on. The data are given in VLSI
Research, Depreciation Schedules: Their Impact on the Competitiveness of Semiconductor
Manufacturers, San Jose, Calif., 1990, addendum 2. The data in this addendum correspond
to a “typical” wafer fab running 2,500 wafer starts per week, at full capacity over the
product life of the 1M DRAM. Conversation with Dan Hutcheson, VLSI Research, August
19, 1991.
49. If instead y were set equal to zero, the estimate of <(> would have risen from 31 to
36, but the estimated e would not have changed.
338 DUMPING IN DRAMS
E(t) = E0 +
m
Ky ’
50. This makes use of the fact that, approximately, ln(l + x) = x, for small values
of x.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 339
51. The data are Dataquest estimates of quarterly output. Reported shipments by
Motorola have been added to Toshiba’s output, and reported shipments by Intel to Sam¬
sung’s output (since it is believed that most Motorola chips were fabricated by Toshiba,
and Intel chips were “private labeled” Samsung output during this period).
52. Irwin and Klenow, “Learning-by-Doing Spillovers,” find some evidence of weak
interfirm spillovers (an additional unit of a firm’s own output contributes three times as
much relevant experience as an additional unit produced by a competitor). Their study is
critically dependent on the assumption of no capacity constraints (see note 34) and the
assumption that a firm’s marginal revenue—proportional to industry price, with a constraint
of proportionality dependent only on firm market share—is set equal to marginal cost. In
their study, however, price is measured using Dataquest’s estimates of average selling price,
which average together long-term contract prices with spot market prices actually observed
in the market during any quarter. Since marginal revenue is defined as the revenue from
an incremental unit produced and sold into the market under prevailing conditions, the
relevant price for marginal revenue calculations is arguably the spot market price. Thus,
their marginal revenue measure almost certainly underestimates true marginal revenue
(and marginal cost, assumed to be set equal by profit-maximizing producer behavior absent
capacity constraints) in tight markets, and overestimates marginal revenue and cost in slack
markets.
ITi V“i \C «/~, l/“i sC <N
I
00 00
O' ro —
nO
On
o o o o o o
• g^
m -^j- m Tt O
ts I
UJ
•a ©
o o o o o
I
rt n a in 't (N
o oo m oo oo no
ON rn
ON 00
1 s o o o o o © °
2 *> o
</j
I
t.
3
O
On^-ONN^
nO (N| Tt Tf © O'
§ 'S no
•S
i«5
© n n ri oi n n o o o o o o
c
3
m m >n -
n n cn n \o
m
o o o o o o o
I I I I I
£
'o'
*—i m m in in r-oo-^t
rn t)- q rf in in on o
>5 On i-* »T) (N O O ^
-h h
^ h \d ri
MO X O
°)
O
©
3
C
Li_ lO
T 7 ^
tr> On
3
'O ~ a.
6) *■- 00 M r-H Tt r-t c*~)
■*S 3 OnOOOOOOM E
in rf ti- Tt tj- \o o Tf- m cj o o
O
in 6 cn ri Nt h
!j| in o o in o
i I 7 I I <u ~
<38 c £
3
D-
Source: Author’s calculations.
C 3
O
•2£5 3
a. c
3 .o
O '33 (-
c/5 £
?° £ o
oc OX)^
<n
"O <D
c 5 3 <*; 4=
OX) £ OX) O- TO O <4-.
vO 3
0
>) x>as E
5
u, O
_o n- c
•2 •§
r w
S
:- U C •? 03 •~
3 -C
/5 - U V) - Oi -C
u(5 •2- U
n Ifl3 c33 fc2<U *<u«
X5
° * _GJ w •©
C *- •—> frl w
C O '© _ W •*
E °
5
C/i .tJ ‘ZT UJ • - 3
g>0 PC E (2 I t£ z ii J p I u, z S <0
00 < to t2 x £ z 2 $ • OX)
TO qj
£ -J
</) Q
DUMPING IN DRAMS 341
firm effects were statistically significant, and a joint hypothesis that they
were all zero could not be rejected at any reasonable significance level.53
The point estimate of e in the full model and in the model with a
common coefficient on inverse cumulative output was barely over 0.5
(corresponding to a 30 percent learning curve), and 0.67 with no interfirm
effects (corresponding to a 37 percent learning curve). This confirms
other evidence suggesting substantial learning economies. A formal sta¬
tistical test for a common coefficient on inverse cumulative output (cor¬
responding to the hypothesis that y = 0) was not entirely conclusive.54
In summary, all available data seem to point to a large yield elasticity
with respect to production experience, close to 0.5, and at least some
evidence may suggest that absolute cumulative output is not an appro¬
priate choice as the “experience” variable.551 shall use .49 as my estimate
of e, and 31 as my estimate of cj> (the constant that determines chips
initially yielded per wafer).
53. The F-statistic for this hypothesis was 1.12 with 7, 4 degrees of freedom; the Wald
chi-square statistic was 7.84 with 7 degrees of freedom.
54. The F-statistic leads us not to reject the hypothesis at either the 5 or the 10 percent
significance level, while the Wald chi-square statistic leads us to reject the hypothesis at
the 10 percent, but not at the 5 percent significance level.
55. Estimation of a learning elasticity requires data on either current and cumulative
output, or current average variable cost and cumulative output. The dubious practice
of using price as a proxy for current unit cost will almost certainly lead to incorrect
results, since the simple models of pricing behavior reviewed above suggest that market
prices will diverge from either current average or marginal cost.
56. Robert W Wilson, Peter K. Ashton, and Thomas P. Egan, Innovation, Competition,
and Government Policy in the Semiconductor Industry (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books,
1980), pp. 126-27; William F. Finan and Chris B. Amundsen, “An Analysis of the Effects
of Targeting on the Competitiveness of the U.S. Semiconductor Industry,” study prepared
for the Office of the U.S. Trade Representative, the Department of Commerce, and the
Department of Labor, Quick, Finan and Associates (Washington, 1986), p. C-18; and Finan
and Amundsen, “Modeling US-Japan Competition in Semiconductors,” Journal of Policy
Modeling, vol. 8 (Fall 1986), p. 321.
342 DUMPING IN DRAMS
estimates makes any attempt to control for the effect of variation in the
overall level of economic activity on chip demand. In previous work I
estimated an overall price elasticity of demand for semiconductors used
in the computer industry of -1.6, assuming a quality adjustment equiv¬
alent to the improvement in bit density observed in DRAMs, and chip
use in computers fixed in proportion to computer output.57
To get as reliable an estimate as possible for 1M DRAM demand, I
estimated a demand function giving the logarithm of quantity shipped of
1M DRAMs as a linear function of the logarithm of real 1M DRAM
price, logarithms of real prices for 64K and 256K DRAMs (as possible
substitutes), the logarithm of real U.S. GNP, and a linear trend.58 The
last two variables were included to capture the effect of fluctuations in
overall economic activity and intergenerational “transition” effects.59 The
implicit GNP price deflator, rebased so that the fourth quarter of 1989
was equal to one, was used to deflate all monetary values to “real” fourth-
quarter 1989 levels. Deflated GNP and substitute DRAM prices were
converted to indexes with a value of one in the fourth quarter of 1989; as
a result, the constant in a regression equation may be interpreted as the
level of DRAM demand corresponding to fourth-quarter 1989 values for
these variables.
In principle, because of the long time lag in the DRAM production
process (almost a full quarter), we would not expect disturbances in the
demand for DRAMs to have a significant effect on production within
57. See Joseph Grunwald and Kenneth Flamm, The Global Factory: Foreign Assembly
in International Trade (Brookings, 1985), pp. 130-32.
58. This demand equation should be interpreted as a “final” demand for DRAMs. That
is, demand for semiconductor inputs can be derived from a cost function C for semicon¬
ductor-using products of the form C(p,Z), where p is a vector of input prices (including
semiconductors) and Z is some given level of electronic system output making use of
semiconductor inputs. Demand for DRAMs is simply the partial derivative of C with respect
to the price of DRAMs, CPdram(p,Z). The demand for Z is a function of electronic system
prices (Pz), the prices of other finished goods (P0), and the level of aggregate economic
activity (AT, that is, Z = f(Pz,P0,X). Electronics systems prices in turn are related to
their unit cost of production C(p,Z)/Z in competitive markets, so Pz = g[C(p,Z)/Z]. We
then have Z = f{g[C{p,Z)IZ},P0X} implicitly giving Z as a function of p, P0, and X.
Substituting this implicit function for Z in derived demand for DRAMs CPdram(p,Z), we
then have a “final” demand for DRAMs as a function of input prices, prices of other
finished goods, and the overall level of economic activity.
59. The data on quantity are Dataquest estimates and cover quarterly worldwide ship¬
ments from the second quarter of 1985 to the fourth quarter of 1989 by merchant producers.
Data for DRAM prices are also quarterly Dataquest estimates of average sales price over
this same period. Real (deflated) GNP and the implicit GNP price deflator are taken from
Economic Report of the President, various years.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 343
that same quarter, and therefore we would not expect simultaneity be¬
tween price and quantity within any given quarter to be an important
complication in estimating this demand function. Nonetheless, in addition
to ordinary least squares, I used an instrumental variables estimator to
estimate the coefficients of this equation.60 The estimated regression
equations, using both methods, are shown in table 6-2.
All fully specified regressions produced an estimated price elasticity
near —1.5. Dropping either the linear time trend variable or the loga¬
rithm of real GNP as a measure of aggregate economic trends affecting
demand had little effect on the estimated own-price elasticity. Interest¬
ingly, dropping both GNP and the time trend substantially raised the
estimated price elasticity, to - 2.1, near the range where other estimates
of DRAM price elasticities—which, as already noted, ignore variation in
aggregate economic activity—have clustered.
On the basis of these results, —1.5 was used as an estimate of 1M
DRAM own-price elasticity (3, and the value 190,000 as an estimate of
product life cycle demand “level” a.61 To transform this demand function
into a demand for “gross” fabricated dice (prior to test and assembly
losses), it was assumed that net output of tested and finished chips equals
0.9 times the number of good dice produced in wafer fab.62 With the
functional form assumed, a simple transformation of a is merely substi¬
tuted for its original value in order to derive the appropriate inverse
demand function.63
60. The logarithms of cumulative output through the previous quarter of 1M, 256K,
and 64K DRAMs were used—in addition to the other exogenous variables included in
demand—to instrument DRAM price variables. Cumulative output would be expected to
affect supply of DRAMs, via learning economies, but have no direct effect on demand.
Values lagged one quarter were used as additional instruments.
61. Exp(22.97) multiplied by 20 (= 190,000 million) gives the demand that would be
observed at a 1M DRAM price of $1 over a twenty-quarter (five-year) product cycle, given
real output and substitute price levels prevailing in the fourth quarter of 1989.
62. For estimated test and assembly yields in this general neighborhood, see VLSI
Research, Depreciation Schedules, addendum A; and ICE, Mid-Term 1988, pp. 7-16
to 7-17.
63. That is, P(^z)^ = (£Ny/a)1/p^ = (Nyla')1'13, where a' - aU(1 + fi)-
344 DUMPING IN DRAMS
Log of price
64 K 1.23 2.43 0.51 0.78 2.67 0.29
256K 0.63 1.68 0.37 -0.01 1.86 -0.01
1M -1.47 0.49 -2.99 -1.54 0.51 -3.01
Trend 0.29 0.27 1.06 0.20 0.29 0.67
Log real GNP -1.76 36.26 -0.05 10.77 39.67 0.27
Constant 22.97 1.02 22.54 23.24 1.09 21.40
R2 0.95 0.949
Std. error of regression 0.726 0.736
Degrees of freedom 12 12
Log of price
64 K 1.17 2.02 0.58 1.17 2.14 0.55
256K 0.59 1.45 0.41 0.23 1.54 0.15
1M -1.47 0.47 -3.11 -1.53 0.49 -3.14
Trend 0.28 0.10 2.81 0.27 0.10 2.70
Constant 22.97 0.98 23.51 23.22 1.04 22.43
R2 0.9503 0.95
Std. error of regression 0.698 0.702
Degrees of freedom 13 13
Log of price
64K 0.66 2.38 0.28 0.27 2.57 0.10
256K -0.07 1.56 -0.04 -0.58 1.66 -0.35
1M -1.55 0.49 -3.19 -1.61 0.50 -3.21
Log real GNP 33.99 13.77 2.47 35.70 14.32 2.49
Constant 23.01 1.02 22.47 23.33 1.08 21.56
R2 0.946 0.944
Std. error of regression 0.929 0.739
Degrees of freedom 13 13
Log of price
64K 5.40 1.65 3.27 5.46 1.74 3.14
256K 0.87 1.77 0.49 0.36 1.88 0.19
1M -2.17 0.49 -4.44 -2.19 0.52 -4.23
Constant 23.67 1.15 20.51 23.87 1.23 19.42
R2 0.92 0.919
Std. error of regression 0.852 0.857
Degrees of freedom 14 14
Source: Author’s calculations.
a. Prices instrumented with constant, trend, cumulative output of 64K, 256K, and 1M DRAMs, and LRGNP;
LRGNP and cumulative outputs lagged one year.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 345
Baseline Simulations
Table 6-4 gives the optimal values of ts and K derived from numerical
solution of the optimal control problem described above. The roots of a
system of two nonlinear equations in two unknowns (equations B-l and
B-2 in appendix 6-B), or one equation in one unknown (in the case
where full-blast production over the entire product life cycle is the opti¬
mal policy, equation B-2' in appendix 6-B) were sought. Table 6-4 also
shows a “gross rent,” defined as profits net of all costs other than fixed
entry cost F, received by each producer. The columns of table 6-4 cor¬
respond to different assumed numbers of firms in the industry, and the
rows to differing assumptions about parameter y, which defines the ex¬
perience variable relevant to learning economies.
Since identical firms are assumed to make up the industry in equilib¬
rium, one may “close” the model by assuming free entry, that is, that
firms enter the industry up to the point where gross rent per firm just
covers the fixed cost of entry F. Because we are restricted to an integer
number of firms, we define the equilibrium number of firms as that where
one more entrant reduces rent per firm below the entry cost F. As a
64. VLSI Research, Depreciation Schedules, addendum 2, puts material and labor cost
at $381 per wafer processed in 1989; a $10 wafer probe test cost is added based on ICE,
Mid-Term 1988, p. 7-9.
65. The package cost comes from conversations with Dan Hutcheson of VLSI Re¬
search, and the assembly cost is estimated to range from 7 to 20 cents offshore, or from
10 to 50 cents per device onshore (in the United States, Europe, and Japan) according to
ICE, Mid-Term 1988, pp. 7-16 to 7-18. I have used a “typical” value of 32 cents. Final
testing cost is estimated in ICE, p. 7-18 to be 20 cents per unit, for a grand total of 75 cents
for package, assembly, and final testing.
66. The data on which this calculation is based are found in ICE, Mid-Term 1988,
p. 7-20. I have excluded R&D and interest expense as demerits of overhead.
346 DUMPING IN DRAMS
HHI = 2 sf,
1= 1
where s, is the market share of company i. The index ranges in value from one, with
monopoly, to zero, with a competitive industry composed of an infinite number of equally
sized firms. In the special case of N identical firms, this index is just equal to 1 IN.
in
sO —1 On
3*
r- -H
in co 04
04
3-
sO ^h ro
3 sO in
1—4
04
3"
00 T-H CO
co Os OS
04
3-
,
sO 1—< ro On r-H O 3 o
CO 3 O O^ o
04
r-H »n
co
sd 1 sd
in
00 r-
0
so r-H SO
CO
CO r—H SO
Os
r-H in 3 sd
1
0-' 3-
(N r-H r-H 04 r-H m so Os
CO On On r-
O
Table 6-4. Solution of the Optimal Control Problem, Nonstrategic Baseline Simulation
Tf c--
sd 3-
r-*
I
3 ' 3 r-H O 3 r-H 04
Os O On On o~ 3"
On SO
sd 06
3"
Number of firms
OO
SO SO
r*^
r- O
04
so r-
co
On
04
o
Os
0"* 06 Os
04
SO
00
00
3
00
r-H 04
00
so
00
r-H o
3 04
On
r- 00
OS
0^
CO
©
CM 3"
r™1
On 04 Os T-l SO 04 r-H
0^
Os
CO
co
r-H r-
so
CO o
VO
sO 04
r-H
r-H
CO
3-
Os
in
Os Os
CO
04
3-
Os in
00 r-H r-H
in r-H 04 3“
rH r—l r-H I
3" 04 co O so r-H 00 r-H SO
CO O r- 00 in 3 ■3-
Os r-H
sd 00
04^ r-H
CO
o
lO 3; O 04 04 3 r-H SO
00
Os oo SO
CO
r-H in
0^
00 Os
04
O 0
3 04 co" 04 co"
oo
o
o 04 0 r-H r~H O Os r-H O
00 Os O' Os r-H in
co CO
in 3^
CO so
3"
0 04 O' 04 0"
r-H
r-H
O'v o SO
3- r-
co
3- O
SO
CO
SO
Os
rH O
O'
CO
00
r-H O
3"
in so °o
sd
Os 04" r-H in 0^ 00"
04 CO CO co
3
a.
3a. 3 3
4—• CL
■*—* a.
OX) 3 OX) 3 3
C : O
2. s C : O
OX)
c o
, 1/5
’55
w -2 CTn |gj 00 ^
f*" so wST iH
i
4—> c ° o >>-9 © X)
O 8 >>-9 c
u “3 <D
U. II Q-O-3 U -3 D
U, H feL-Q 3 <D
3 " -n
0 > C/D « s o-T 3 CL „ . _ V5 re a.'~
° C
; o
u. c3E ^
^ 3 T3
0 c ; o u
E o ^ - ; o
3 -n > C/5
v_
P tT3 -g
; oUt
W o rwt 1 E | £ u C
3 a 3 W a re > w a
o a O
r- CN ON CO r- SO SO in r-~ CO CO
o o <N r- (N o 00 in os 00 CO
r- o CD in
CO co CO © <N d * d
r-H I r-H r-H r-H r-H r-H r-H r-H
1 1 1 1
CO 00 r- r- SO 00 On (N CO r-H t so (N
in OS in 00 CN CO r- On in «n oo C"; CO 00
r- r—H c^.
O d d SO o d
r-H r-H r-H r-H
CO 00 o r- O’ o r- (N o On rH O 00 r-H o
l> On 00 oo m in <N SO in so 00 CO 00
Os 00^
a. Millions of product-cycle wafer starts.
00
© © r-* d sd d "S Tt- d
r-H Os' r-H r-H r-H Tf r-H On r-H t3"
CO in
Source: Author's calculations.
3 3 3 3 3
a CL CL
s* Q-
3 3 3 3 bJO 3
bD b£) bJD bo
O O
b. Millions of dollars.
a © 3 ^ ° C ° c £ ~
'<r> ’35 to *co £ C^T
00
so
C/3
O 3 3 sO
C/3
<U
C/3
in a> w 03
C/3
CO O < ,3 3 C/3
<U W
O o o O
d
o c
d o G
d o
C
d
o 3 o ^
Uh <u u. (U Ui o u. <L) 2 .—
■§
II CL u. II CL u II CL '5 3 u II D- CL o
S *3
3 <4—H i y <4-1
3 3 i 3 <4—1 1 I 03
3 Ui C/3 03 Ui CL , C/3 u, CL „ C/3 03 i-i CL „ . 03
,0) C/3 a> 3 C/3 -3 C/3 ,4) S g-
£ H-i
45 s ■§
O
V-(
£ <4=2
3 S 1
O
i-H
£ <4-1
.3 S -g
O
t-T
£ ^3 s -g • £ <4-1
.03
3
O
e a
w o
c
w o
3
o £03 o
CS PJ o c3 03 03
o o a o a
(N O' so © r-
q
rsi o
o in
co
VO
cO q
© © o d —< d o d d
I I I I I I
o
I I I O Tj-
o o o o co o r- o O 00
Os co -^t CM
6? .«o o O
£ § u co
o
co
o
<N
q I
•2 5-S5 d © d o o o o o
•£* n C£ I I l l I I
a: 2 ^ o o o o o o
£
•2 =x Si i-H q q ^t q 00 q q q
-c> | 2^ d in oi d CO NO CO 00 On
~ r- CO oo 00 o NO CO rH
I- 3 - rq in q On q o ©^
s £ co" NO r-" oo" r-" oo"
| a- ^ ri
O' § 3 rH rH rH (N (N CO <N
©
>> Si
& ~
Q
c
Q
«
^ q q q q ON q q CO ON
q
NO NO NO NO oi
•Hi ill © 3
•*- oi
C (N CO in in in NO NO NO
c ©
o
o
in
&
"^3
C ~x q q in 00 q oo oo q q
a 1^5 <N CO in CO NO On rH
Co "sf in m NO ON On
O
~ IS ^ in r-
©
©_ ©_ CO q
00
q
(N
q
rH rH rH H cn"
£
ju
h>
o
a
5*.
a
5 <3c 3
1§ rH r-
NO
o
o
o
o
o
o
CO
CO
CO
CO
CO
CO
o
S | S H o
b
■*^i -s e -S T—H
i“<
NO
rH
in
q
in
q
in
q
CO
q
CO
q
CO
CO
in
q
K}
a S*_ ©^ d d d d d d d d d
■o 1 I
£
U
s
■£ X.
£ -C>
5
CO
int
vo
_cu i
3 s oo oo
q os q NO q in CO
e2 o ^ d d d d d d
in On in in <N © m rN On 00
m (N rg © *-h © © in
f d o d d d *7 ©i ©i ©l ©1 ©
I ii ii ii i ii i i 1 1 1
0.91-
0.71-
© o o o r- o © © © On © <n
°s. "3" fN
d © ©
CO co CN o o o
o © O o o I I I
© © o © o © o o o
I I I I I I
o o o o o o
in © SO SO
SO © © CO co 00 Os
sO i-H VO 00 00 in SO CO
©^ in (N (N ©^ ©_
ri in © oo" ©" ,—T oo"
T-H r-H r-H (N (N CO <N
£ <u
— CJ
so VO so r- so CN r-
in in m sO SO
250 million
i-H 00 (N 00 rn cn
a. — o
i-H
<N o
m
in
CO
in
©
co
sO
CO
r—1
vO
On
On
00 <N o 'is
m © ©_ rn r*^ cn oo c .2
t-H T-H r-T (N rf
I «I
'5b e
D O
£> _
c« 3
u J3 o
M -O >*
£ o SJ
I <u *-
u Cl cj
O <*_ 3
S • O -O
On © o o o co co o
(N O o o o co CO o 5.2 £ c <*- >
o m in in co CO in c o JJ
o <N (N (N (N co CO <N 'ob~o ~
W c • 3
•O « O.
w - u t:
»sEg
(D V
•- ^
« ° ea 3 q O
£ "2
3=0 =
.9 -2 Z%
o tJ £ c
3 3 •“
£ — a «? lift
Cl Cl 2 ,E
^ c/5
w F" O C 3 ~
a 55 w> " Q. 2. « 2
iiEo. L C P U W
l ir v
>* O o o -o c
is) O
c c 2 2
s 5 a.>~
o o c c <u o_
kT 2 « «.S 3
© 2 S C.2
5 > ►5 — uj u.
oo
so so m CO
Os 00 c/3 c/3 s o.y T3 a> ••
© © © O © ©
352 DUMPING IN DRAMS
the cycle. Indeed, for all values of y, given my assumptions about other
parameter values, price falls short of marginal cost only at the very
beginning of the product cycle. Further perusal of this table makes clear,
however, that the timing of periods of sales at less than average cost is
quite sensitive to the specification of the experience variable—depending
on y, such episodes can occur at the beginning of the product cycle, the
middle, or the end, or in some combination.
Table 6-5 also shows that the value of y makes a big difference in the
structure of a symmetric-industry equilibrium. With cumulative output
per facility (y = 1) the relevant experience variable, a relatively large
number of firms (nine to fourteen) populate the industry. With y much
below .9, no more than three or four firms make up the industry.
Figure 6-3 shows the path of price, marginal revenue, marginal cost,
and average cost over time in the case where entry costs are $250 million
and y equals one. Figure 6-4 shows the time path for these variables over
the product cycle when y is instead equal to zero.
Ironically, the specification of firm behavior in the B-K model—full-
blast production over the entire product cycle—turns out to be optimal
if parameter y is close to one (see table 6-4). The irony arises because
the B-K model also specifies absolute cumulative output (y = 0) as the
experience variable, and given realistic choices for other parameters,
optimal behavior would then require cutting back production to levels
below capacity after about the first third of the product cycle.
68. These indexes are calculated from unpublished Dataquest estimates of DRAMs
shipped from 1974 through the end of 1989. Note that there were two distinct varieties of
16K DRAM, one with a single voltage power source, the other requiring dual voltages;
each is treated as a separate product in this figure. In calculating concentration indexes for
1M DRAMs, I have allocated Motorola-labeled product to Toshiba (since virtually all of
Motorola’s product over this period is believed to have been assembled from Toshiba-
fabricated dice, or produced by a Toshiba-Motorola joint venture); 1M DRAMs bearing
the Intel label have been assigned to Samsung, since it is believed that virtually all of Intel’s
sales over this period were “private labeled” Samsung product. Neither of these adjust¬
ments has a particularly significant effect on the pattern of concentration.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 353
Figure 6-3. Time Profile of 1M DRAM Costs and Prices in Simulated
Nonstrategic Equilibrium with Gamma = la
Dollars per chip
the concentration index declines sharply from an very high initial level,
as one producer after another comes on line with volume production.
The index then levels off near .1, rising sharply at the end of the product
cycle as producers drop the product line one after another. Although the
early phases of the 256K and 1M DRAM may have been somewhat more
concentrated than in earlier generations’ life cycles, they too seem des¬
tined to eventually follow this pattern.
If one compares the Hirschman-Herfindahl indexes associated with
my simulations with the pattern depicted in figure 5-15, only the re¬
sults associated with the specification of cumulative output per facility
354 DUMPING IN DRAMS
tity production did not really ramp up until 1988). Figure 6-5 charts the
actual behavior of one set of estimates of large-volume contract prices
for 1M DRAMs in the U.S. and Japanese markets through autumn 1993,
along with simulated 1M DRAM price levels associated with assumed 7
equal to one and zero, respectively.69 The period from the first quarter
of 1988 through the first quarter of 1989 was a period of extreme shortage
in DRAM markets, whereas the period after late 1989 was marked by
lackluster demand. Given that the early portion of my empirical approx¬
imation to the learning curve is probably poorer than in later periods
(see the discussion above), and that my assumption of symmetric firms
is probably least appropriate in the early stages of the product cycle, I
am not surprised to find that the very earliest part of the predicted time
69. These data are monthly averages of Nikkei and Dataquest estimates of average
contract prices in these markets. The data are reported in Computer Reseller News and
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, various issues. For more on the strengths and weaknesses of these
data, and a thorough discussion of the segmented spot and contract markets in which
DRAMs are sold, see Flamm, “Measurement of DRAM Prices,” pp. 157-97.
356 DUMPING IN DRAMS
path for prices seems the least accurate. All things considered, the sim¬
ulation with 7=1 seems to do a reasonable job of tracking real 1M
DRAM prices. The simulation with 7 = 0 clearly does not.
Thus, two pieces of evidence—observed and predicted concentration
indexes, and the time path of DRAM prices—seem to suggest that a
value of 7 close to one provides significantly more realistic predictions
than a value close to zero.
A final point to consider is that, according to industry folklore, DRAM
producers have traditionally run their plants at full blast when they were
in operation at all, a behavior that is consistent with the simulations
presented here. However, beginning in mid-1989 Japanese DRAM pro¬
ducers announced production cutbacks. This raises three issues that I do
not explore further here. First, DRAM capacity may be shifted, at some
cost, to production of other types of integrated circuits, a possibility not
explicitly incorporated into my model. Second, DRAM demand is noto¬
riously cyclical, and the consequences of shifts in demand for optimal
producer behavior are, again, not explicitly explored here. Third, pro¬
duction of DRAMs after the conclusion of the 1986 Semiconductor Trade
Arrangement was clearly affected by political constraints, may have led
to a degree of collusive behavior among producers, and otherwise in¬
volved political economic factors not incorporated into my model.
Indeed, while the simulations depicted in tables 6-4 and 6-5 all show
an episode of below-average-cost pricing at the beginning of the product
cycle, possibly followed by a later episode, it would be incorrect to assert
that below-average-cost pricing will always necessarily be observed at the
beginning of the product life cycle.70 Figure 6-6 shows that by artfully
changing a single parameter (in this case, by greatly raising initial yields,
making E0 = 500), assuming y = 1 and F = $250 million, one arrives
at a symmetric-industry equilibrium where price never falls below mar-
ginal cost, and price falls below average cost only during the latter half
of the product cycle.71
Conclusions
In recent years, pricing below a constructed long-run average cost has
become the principal grounds for applying the U.S. dumping laws to
U.S. imports of some foreign products. Although this practice has little
obvious economic defense, it is possible to argue that a test based on
marginal cost might serve as a useful screen for potentially predatory
behavior by foreign exporters. However, in the presence of learning econ¬
omies, such as are thought to be present in many high-tech industries,
including semiconductors, below-marginal-cost pricing can be rational
even in the absence of strategic behavior such as predation.
In this chapter I have developed a more realistic model of pricing over
the life cycle of a product in which both fixed costs and learning econ¬
omies are significant. Using empirically plausible parameters for produc¬
tion of 1M DRAMs, and assuming nonstrategic producer behavior, I
have found that below-marginal-cost pricing is likely to be observed only
in the very earliest stages of the product cycle.
The analysis has also shed considerable light on other facets of pricing
and production over the product life cycle. A specification of learning
economies based on cumulative output per facility as the “experience”
variable was found to yield results that were considerably more realistic
than other possible—and widely used—specifications. Contrary to pop¬
ular belief, below-average-cost pricing does not necessarily have to occur
near the beginning of the product cycle.
The model presented here appears to produce fairly realistic predic¬
tions of industry structure and pricing behavior when used with empiri¬
cally plausible parameters. Extensions of this work to consider the pos¬
sibility of strategic, noncooperative behavior on the part of producers,
as well as cooperative or collusive behavior, are explored in the next
chapter. Policy issues to be explored within this framework will focus on
the impact of government policies on industry structure and aggregate
national welfare.
71. The symmetric equilibrium depicted in this figure corresponds to an industry with
eighteen producers, each with a product life cycle capacity of 3.88 million wafer starts,
producing full blast over the entire cycle.
DUMPING IN DRAMS 359
y(0
s.t. E = — = u(t) w(E) K' y w£ > 0,
... <5. dH dH dy
d + uweK,
W1,h8= -^= IC*
dR
where Rv denotes —, marginal revenue.
y dy
360 DUMPING IN DRAMS
Ry-d-- + ^r = 0.
y w Ky
d2H
Ryy (Kwf < 0.
du2
c 8
u ~ 1 R — d-h — >0
(A-l.b) * w Ky
c 8
(A-l.c) w = 0; R - d-f —-- < 0 8 = 0.
y w Ky
_8_
Rv — d + — —
y w Ky
c — uwK l--,
w ~cu~— =0-
where u*(t) is the optimal utilization rate and E* the trajectory of ex¬
perience variable E corresponding to u*(t).72 Then
1 r
S {R>-d +
oL
f _ , 8 j dy ^ dx
+ R- jr ~ Kl
cu dt = 0.
1r
In , 8 8
I /vv — a + —- ww - y — uw - cu - r dt = 0.
i \ y Ky K'1
o L
Thus,
1 r
. C 8 8
IKy - d-+ — ~ 7 — uw - r dt — 0.
i \ y w KV a7
oL
= 0 if u is interior;
> 0 if u = 1;
< 0 if u = 0;
IP'
(A-2.a) P" <-for z > 0.
z
In these two cases, firm revenue R is strictly concave in y, with Ryy <
0 everywhere. Now, since functions R and w are assumed twice continu¬
ously differentiable in their arguments, so too will be the Hamiltonian
H, with Huu = Ryy (Kw)2 < 0. H is strictly concave in u. For given K,
then, the necessary conditions for optimal u are also sufficient to guar¬
antee maximization of H. More important, the strict concavity of H in
u, and the constant bounds constraining feasible u, mean that we may
invoke an appropriate theorem to conclude that optimal u is continuous
in other arguments of H,73 Since the other arguments of H are continuous
functions of time, u must be as well.
Note also that u(t) is a continuously differentiable function of time
within an interior segment. This is a consequence of the linearity of E
in u, and the strict concavity of the Hamiltonian.74
73. For example, a result proven by Debreu, found in Kevin Lancaster, Mathematical
Economics (Dover, 1987), pp. 349-50, or a theorem due to Fiacco cited in Garth P.
McCormick, Nonlinear Programming: Theory, Algorithms, and Applications (Wiley, 1983),
pp. 245-46.
More directly, we may note that the strict concavity of H in u means that, at every
moment, the u(t) that maximizes H is unique. Since the set of feasible values from which
u(t) is chosen is compact, we may invoke theorem 6.1 from Wendell H. Fleming and
Raymond W. Rishel, Deterministic and Stochastic Optimal Control (Springer-Verlag, 1975),
p. 75, to conclude that u(t) is a continuous function of time.
74. Consider optimal control u*(t) over some interior segment tt < t < t2. Because of
the strict concavity of the Hamiltonian, a local interior maximum of H must also be a
global maximum of H with no constraints on control u{t). Optimal control u*{t) over this
interval must also be the optimal control for the problem
subject to the initial and terminal conditions that E(t) take on the values at times t, and t2
associated with optimal control u*(t) in the original problem, but with no bounds on control
u(t). As Fleming and Rishel, Deterministic and Stochastic Optimal Control (corollary 6.1,
364 DUMPING IN DRAMS
(Ry) = 0
= |[/”(1 + % + P]
But this contradicts (A.2.a) and our assumption that Rzz < 0. So we
must have y = 0.
Now y = uKw
y
y = uKw + uKwe — = 0, which can only be true if
Ky
/. u < 0.
p. 77), note, the linearity of the equations of motion in the control variable, and the
concavity of the Hamiltonian, are sufficient to guarantee that the optimal control is
a continuously differentiable function of time for this subproblem, with no constraints
on u{t).
DUMPING IN DRAMS 365
A-l.c cannot hold, it can never be optimal for u = 0 and nothing ever
produced.
Note the role of learning economies in this model. If wE = 0 every¬
where (there is no learning), 8 must be constant and equal to zero, and
optimal u must be constant over the product cycle. Optimal capacity
choice implies Ry — d — c/w must be greater than zero, and therefore
u = 1. The first-order conditions then require that K be chosen so
that variable profit generated by a marginal unit of capital
(Ry — d — c/w)w just covers the cost of capital (r) and all available
capacity is fully utilized over the entire product life cycle.
industry output.
Consider industry sales, given by
*■ 4+§+p P ^ii+D
Pz
+ 1
P - - (1 + X) + 1
1 + X
Let ct =
N
So Ry
1, cartel;
where a =
7-, Cournot.
\N
In y\ l(T ^
5 ~ + 1
\ a ) IP /
Let w = <j)£e, with E = y/Ky, E{0) = E0, 0 < e < 1, 0 < y < 1.
Initial yield (<j>£o) is independent of capacity choice. We are mainly
interested in two specific cases: y = 0 (learning depends on absolute
production experience), and y = 1 (learning depends on experience per
unit capacity, or facility).
Then y = fyE^uK.
Over the interval from zero to ts, where u — 1,
E = = c}) £* K'~y.
Ky
DUMPING IN DRAMS 367
We also know
dH
8 = weK
dE
8 + 8 = f2(t,K), with
Solving for 8, for some t in the interval (0, ts), given boundary value
8(4) = we have
8„ +
8(() =
,//i(t) di
p + g /4>a:Mp E(t,K)
8b(44,K,8J + E(ts,K)f 1 -
(3 + 1 \ a / E(ts,K)
- d {l- E(t,K)
vi / E(t,K)'
1 [E(t„K) \ I J / [E(I„K)\
Over the interval from ts to one, optimal u is set such that y{t,k) =
y(ts,k)—in other words, constant output. E(ts,k), y(ts,k) are given by
expressions in the last section. Over the interval from ts to one, then,
z, _ yb’K)
368 DUMPING IN DRAMS
c u wEK
8 = -
w w2
<\>2E(ts,Ky KeE(t,KY
-c = ; >„K);
VE(t,Kf
where
-czE(ts,Ky K
hit ; ts,K)
E(t,Ky + '
or, making use of the fact that 8(1) = 0 (the transversality condition),
define function hE as
cK1
<y[E{ts,K) + <yK'-\t-ts) E(ts,Kyy
cKy
4>[E(ts,K) + ^-^(1-0 £(f, ,*)«]«
cKr> f 1 1
mts,Ky |[i + e(t,ts,K)Y “ [i + 0(1 ,ts,K)Y
In particular, we can solve for 8E(ts ; ts,k), that is, the value of 8 at ts
which, given some assumed ts, solves the equation of motion over an
DUMPING IN DRAMS 369
Our specification has ruled out the possibility that optimal u = 0. The
optimal path for u will consist of a capacity-constrained (u = 1) segment
through time ts, possibly followed by an interior segment. For the mo¬
ment, assume that ts < 1 .
Case 1. ts < 1. At ts, we also know that u(t) will be entering an interior
segment, so
or, substituting,
—c
<\>[E(ts,K) + ^~^l-ts)E(ts,KYY
(B-l)
This is just the condition that marginal revenue equal current marginal
cost at terminal time 1. If K is chosen nonstrategically to maximize
profits, optimal K must satisfy
370 DUMPING IN DRAMS
Since the expression in brackets is zero after ts, and u is one before ts,
this can be written as
I ts ,
y)J
ts 0 l
+ Yy <\)E(t,KY(l - dt - cts - r = 0.
We may substitute for 8 with the functions 8B and 8£, described earlier.
Noting that
over the interval from ts to one, we can solve analytically for the first
integral above, so, substituting,
1
+ e
C7(l~4) e(u,/Q 1
+ j [«„(»,jo - d\
(i-0 [i + e(u,*)]' Q(us,k)
An optimal choice of ts and K, then, must solve equations B-l and B-2.
Industry Profits
Total rents per firm, gross of fixed entry cost F, earned in an industry
made up of N identical firms can be calculated as (for given optimal ts
and K):
i
(moo'
1 a
- d y{t,K) — cu{t)K - rK\ dt, or
11 Ny(t,KY
a
- d y(t,K) | dt +
Ny(t„K)Y
a
- d y(ts,K)(l-ts)
1
+ i
cKl -
cK(l-ts) e(U,£) - rK.
(1-0 [1 + 0(1,4, X)]' 6(1 ,t„K)
CHAPTER SEVEN
Strategic Issues
Conceptions of “Strategic”
What precisely is meant by this use of the word “strategic”? There
are at least three senses in which the word might apply to the semicon¬
ductor industry.
National Security
372
STRATEGIC ISSUES 373
Total manufacturing
\ $5.4 trillion $20 trillion $40 trillion /
and service economy
Electronics products
\ $384 billion $751 billion $2 trillion /
and services
Semiconductor
manufacturing \ $21 billion $63 billion $200 billion /
Semiconductor \ .....
. • , . , \ $9 billion $20 billion $60 billion /
materials and equipment \
Fundamental sciences
and processes Software
Strategic Sectors
5. Semiconductor Industry Association (SIA), Key Facts and Issues (1989), p. 24. The
376 STRATEGIC ISSUES
The difficulty with this argument in its simplest form may be discerned
by glancing at the input-output table for any major economy. Virtually
all goods (other than final consumer goods) produced by any industrial
sector also serve as inputs into most other sectors. Thus any policy of
labeling as “strategic” industries those that supply significant inputs to
other industries ends up declaring virtually all industries strategic. A
policy arguing for support of “strategic” domestic industries then be¬
comes a recipe for intervening to support virtually anything.
Clearly, if competitive products are available from foreign suppliers at
a competitive price, no harm is necessarily done to other industries up
and down the food chain. Indeed, a favorite response of skeptical econ¬
omists to claims that the U.S. semiconductor industry is in some sense
“strategic” has been to pose the question, “How are computer chips
different from potato chips?”6
One might point out three important differences. First, a potato chip
is a final consumption good, so that poor-quality, high-priced potato
chips, although onerous to the consumer, have no direct impact on other
industries. Semiconductors, on the other hand, are an input to a large
and important array of user industries, for which access to the latest
technology at a competitive price is critical. Second, entry into potato
“food chain” metaphor was widely applied in Washington during the policy debates over
high-definition television of 1988-89: “Loss of consumer electronics has affected today’s
U.S. competitiveness. . . . The U.S. electronics infrastructure is like a biological food chain
with many interdependent segments-when one link is weakened or destroyed, other links
feel injury. Many believe competitive problems experienced today by the U.S. semiconduc¬
tor industry can be traced to this lost segment.” American Electronics Association, ATV
Task Force Economic Impact Team, High Definition Television (HDTV): Economic Anal¬
ysis of Impact (Washington, November 1988), p. i.
“When a personal computer adopts the kind of flat display screen associated with
HDTV technology, it will not only create additional demand for the products associated
with this new industry, but it will also require a large number of semiconductors to support
the new projector and display technology that will be incorporated in the screen itself. The
use of these inputs will give a boost to demand for products from these related industries,
contributing to increases in their output and improving the chances that they will be
profitable and have the funds to support further innovation.
These linkages create a kind of feed-back mechanism that provides its greatest advan¬
tages to our industrial base when the entire ‘food chain’ of the electronics industry is
improved.” Testimony submitted by Robert Cohen in High Definition Television, Hearings
before the Subcommittee on Telecommunications and Finance of the House Committee on
Energy and Commerce, 101 Cong. 1 sess. (Government Printing Office, 1989), p. 226.
6. The comment has been attributed to Michael Boskin, who was chairman of the
Council of Economic Advisers in the Bush administration, but firm evidence that he actually
said it appears to be lacking.
STRATEGIC ISSUES 377
chip making is relatively easy, whereas entry into computer chip manu¬
facture may involve large sunk investments and technology that is difficult
to obtain. Third, computer chips are high-tech goods, requiring large,
continuing investments in R&D; potato chips do not. An empirical lit¬
erature tells us that much R&D is likely to have significant economic
impacts that are not fully captured by the high-tech firm making the
R&D investment.
These circumstances make it credible that one or both of two things
might occur in the computer chip industry that would be unlikely to
happen in the potato chip industry. Barriers to entry may make the
exercise of monopoly power possible, allowing computer chip companies
to earn monopoly rents. Spillovers of knowledge from chip R&D, as well
as production, to other firms and industries may create externalities that
result in economic benefits to firms other than the firm making the in¬
vestment in R&D.
Many economists would agree that these two possibilities create condi¬
tions under which intervention to sustain a “strategic” industry might be
economically justifiable.7 First, if there are significant technological exter¬
nalities in semiconductor production, so that social returns exceed private
returns, policies to correct for presumed underinvestment in these activities
may be appropriate. There is some empirical tradition of economists arguing
that particular capital goods industries have been strategic because of in¬
formational spillovers between producers and users of these goods.8
In semiconductors it is in design, not manufacturing, that it seems
most plausible to argue for technological externalities—that is, that semi¬
conductor users are using the same technologies as semiconductor pro¬
ducers. One is hard pressed to think of examples of other industries that
use the same manufacturing technologies as the semiconductor industry.9
Cross-industry spillovers are more obvious in design. As the density of
7. Paul R. Krugman, for example, identifies these two criteria for “strategic” sectors
as academically respectable economic arguments for selectively promoting specific indus¬
tries. See his “Introduction: New Thinking about Trade Policy,” in Krugman, ed., Strategic
Trade Policy and the New International Economics (MIT Press, 1986), pp. 12-15.
8. See, for example, Nathan Rosenberg, “Technological Change in the Machine Tool
Industry, 1840-1910,” Journal of Economic History, vol. 23, no. 4 (1963), pp. 414-43; and
Bo Carlsson and Staffan Jacobsson, “What Makes the Automation Industry Strategic?”
Economics of Innovation and New Technology, vol. 1, no. 4 (1991), pp. 257-69.
9. Prominent exceptions include flat panel displays (used for the screens of laptop
computers and similar products), which use a similar manufacturing technology, and the
read-write heads used in computer disk drives.
378 STRATEGIC ISSUES
10. Eric von Hippel, The Sources of Innovation (Oxford University Press, 1988), pp.
19-26.
STRATEGIC ISSUES 379
11. See for example, National Advisory Committee on Semiconductors, Preserving the
Vital Base: America’s Semiconductor Materials and Equipment Industry (GPO, 1990).
12. Otherwise the downstream user would normally substitute other inputs for the
monopolized input as price is raised and dissipate some of the monopolist’s potential rent
in inefficient production. John M. Vernon and Daniel A. Graham, “Profitability of Mon¬
opolization by Vertical Integration,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 79 (July-August
1971), pp. 924-25.
13. The argument is presented in a simple, diagrammatic form in Kenneth Flamm,
“Semiconductors,” in Gary Clyde Hufbauer, ed., Europe 1992: An American Perspective
(Brookings, 1990), pp. 260-63.
380 STRATEGIC ISSUES
Another use of the word “strategic” comes from game theory, where
strategic actions are defined as those intended to influence the moves of
other players.16 Firms act strategically when they take actions intended
to alter the behavior of their rivals. Governments, too, can make strate¬
gic moves, when they implement policies intended to alter the behav¬
ior of the foreign rivals of their domestic firms, or even other foreign
governments.
For example, suppose a government grants a subsidy, linked to value
or volume of production, to a domestic firm selling against a single foreign
rival in a foreign market. That subsidy will have the direct effect of
encouraging the domestic firm to increase output and increase its profit.
By itself (taking the output of the foreign firm as given), this does not
mean that domestic society as a whole benefits from the subsidy, since
the increased profits for the domestic producer will generally be more
than offset by the cost of the subsidy to national taxpayers. But it may
also encourage the foreign rival to cut back its output, as news of the
subsidy makes the rival realize that the domestic firm will definitely
increase its output. Given this reality, the foreign rival may find that
producing less output maximizes its own profits, allowing the domestic
producer to expand its output even further and realize some additional
profit. This indirect effect (working through the foreign producer’s out¬
put decision) of the subsidy is the so-called strategic effect of the govern¬
ment policy, and is what makes it possible that such a strategic trade
policy can work to benefit the interests of the subsidizing nation as a
whole.17
Of course, the domestic welfare gains come at the expense of the
foreign country, since the additional profit earned domestically is accom¬
panied by a decline in the foreign company’s profit. The foreign govern¬
ment may then be tempted to intervene to convince the domestic govern¬
ment to abandon its intervention, or to create an outcome more amenable
to its own company’s interest. The result is a strategic interaction between
the two governments’ policies.
The logical link with the concept of a strategic sector, discussed earlier,
is that the literature on strategic trade policy (defined as policy that works
by altering the behavior of foreign companies or governments) has fo¬
cused on cases where benefits to a nation as a whole exist as a conse¬
quence of monopoly profits captured from foreign interests. The exis¬
tence of significant monopoly power was one of the two economically
defensible reasons why a sector might merit labeling as strategic.
But the other rationale, the presence of externalities, might also cred¬
ibly inspire a strategic government policy. Policies used to force domestic
investments by foreign companies, for example, in order to foster tech¬
nological spillovers to domestic companies, might arguably be labeled a
strategic trade policy.
17. This example is the classic model developed in James A. Brander and Barbara J.
Spencer, “Export Subsidies and International Market Share Rivalry,” Journal of Interna¬
tional Economics, vol. 18 (February 1985), pp. 83-100. See also James A. Brander, “Ra¬
tionales for Strategic Trade and Industrial Policy,” in Krugman, ed., Strategic Trade Policy,
pp. 23-46.
382 STRATEGIC ISSUES
Nonstrategic policies (that is, policies that work only through their
effects on domestic economic actors) might also be attractive in strategic
sectors. Even if an economy or sector were entirely cut off from inter¬
national trade, the government might wish to subsidize investments
thought to be characterized by significant externalities. Or, in a strategic
sector in which domestic firms with a unique competitive advantage face
no foreign rivals, official encouragement of the formation of an export
cartel may further national welfare at the expense of foreign consumers.
In a real world linked by pervasive trade, however, virtually any policy
affecting a strategic industry is also likely to have some effect on actual
or potential foreign competitors’ behavior, and hence also qualify as a
strategic policy.
In principle, however, “strategic trade policy” is not conceptually
equivalent to “government policy in strategic sectors.” Strategic trade
policy requires the existence of actual or potential foreign competitors,
operating in a strategic sector, whereas economic justification for policies
to promote strategic sectors, when motivated by externalities, does not
necessarily require foreign competition. As a practical matter, though,
the two ideas are closely identified with one another.
Discussion of government policies toward the semiconductor industry
typically captures basic elements of all three distinct uses of the word
“strategic.” Semiconductors will be a strategic sector, meriting policy
intervention, if the exploitation of monopoly power in a key semiconduc¬
tor input is a credible likelihood, with potentially significant effects on
downstream user industries, or if externalities are important. Strategic
behavior by semiconductor producers (such as preemptive capacity in¬
vestments or predatory pricing) may justify intervention by government.
Strategic policies undertaken by governments (for example, protection,
subsidy, or the toleration or facilitation of cartels) might also inspire a
response by others.
18. By focusing on monopoly power as the motive for strategic behavior, I ignore the
other possible reason for thinking semiconductors might be a strategic sector, namely,
technological externalities. There is little compelling empirical evidence on this issue, par¬
ticularly on aspects critical to the design of policy: whether spillovers cross industry bound¬
aries as well as firm boundaries, whether they are inherently confined to a local geographic
region, and whether alternative means (such as revised norms for intellectual property
rights, or design and technical standards) can serve to internalize what might otherwise be
externalities for an individual firm.
384 STRATEGIC ISSUES
created a cost advantage for Japanese chip producers, so that their con¬
stant cost of production is J dollars (and their marginal and average cost
schedule is represented by line JJ'). Domestic companies have higher
unit costs of U dollars (and their cost schedule is given by line UU').
Foreign demand is given by demand curve DD', and marginal revenue
by line MR-MR'. If Japanese producers are then able to act as a profit-
maximizing cartel, without fear of foreign entry, they will produce output
Q0, charge price P0, and collect monopoly profit PQAEJ. If entry and
exit in the industry are costless, however, foreign producers can effec¬
tively contest the market, and this threat of entry places a cap on price
at U. One may argue, however, that sunk costs—in the form of special¬
ized and short-lived capital investments—are substantial in this industry.
No individual domestic firm, then, will be willing to invest in a high-cost
production facility, because in the event of a price war the cartel can
STRATEGIC ISSUES 385
lower its price below U and still fully cover costs, while the high-cost
foreign producer will be forced to produce at a loss or to shut down and
lose an amount equal to its sunk costs.
If the alternative is to face a cartel charging price P0, however, it is
clearly advantageous from the viewpoint of the foreign country to
subsidize high-cost domestic production of output Qx at cost level UU'.
Monopoly profits equal to P0ABP, that would otherwise have been
paid to the cartel are saved, and, in addition, consumer surplus equal
to triangle ABC is gained. Subsidy of high-cost domestic production
is superior to passive acceptance of uncontested, cartelized imports.
One should note that fear of dependency on foreign suppliers is not
an exclusively American preoccupation. Chapter 2 of this book described
an episode in which a similar fear appears to have motivated the Japanese
government to invest in augmenting the domestic capability to supply the
materials used by its semiconductor industry.
The U.S. semiconductor industry’s analysis of its Japanese rivals’ be¬
havior, documented in chapters 3 and 4, has evolved historically. Through
1980 the story told was what might now be described as the “conven¬
tional” account of strategic trade policy: formal and informal barriers
protecting Japan’s domestic semiconductor market against American im¬
ports worked to promote the development of the Japanese industry and
its global market share, to the detriment of the sales (and profits) of U.S.
producers.19 After 1980, however, as it became clear that prices in the
American and Japanese markets were essentially identical, allegations of
dumping—that Japanese producers were pricing exports below cost—
necessarily and explicitly began to include an element of predatory be¬
havior on the part of these companies, and an element of collusion. A
more unconventional story of strategic behavior surfaced: below-cost
pricing, it was asserted, was calculated to induce exit by American pro¬
ducers, after which Japanese producers would jointly raise prices and
extract monopoly rents, which would provide a return on their investment
in predation.
The history of this discussion and the American trade policy response
it provoked could be interpreted skeptically as a self-fulfilling prophecy.
19. This is the “import protection as export promotion” policy described by Paul R.
Krugman, “Import Protection as Export Promotion: International Competition in the
Presence of Oligopoly and Economics of Scale,” in Henryk Kierzkowski, ed., Monopolistic
Competition and International Trade (Clarendon Press, 1984), pp. 180-93.
386 STRATEGIC ISSUES
To begin, the most interesting data suggesting the proposition that the
behavior of Japanese DRAM producers has not always reflected normal
competitive market forces are drawn from observation of the market for
DRAMs in 1987 through 1990. The relationships between prices and the
foreign market values (FMVs) constructed by the U.S. Commerce De¬
partment raise interesting questions.
Figure 5-8 showed that, by late 1987 and continuing through late 1989,
U.S. contract prices for 256K DRAMs had risen substantially above
FMVs, and therefore that the FMVs were not constraining U.S. DRAM
import prices over this period. From 1990 on, however, at least some
Japanese DRAM imports appear to have been priced out of the U.S.
market, as 256K DRAM prices fell below average FMVs. Indeed, Japa¬
nese 256K DRAM production fell quite sharply from 1990 on. Despite
rapid and deep cuts in Japanese production, U.S. prices dropped below
the FMV levels.
Figure 5-9 showed a similar pattern in 1M DRAMs. From late 1987
through early 1990, U.S. contract prices stayed above average (and over
most of this period, above even the highest-cost Japanese company’s
individual) FMV. Unlike in 256K DRAMs, however, U.S. prices roughly
tracked average FMV over the remainder of the STA’s lifetime, and
Japanese companies cut neither production nor exports of 1M DRAMs
to the degree visible in 256K parts. Moderate cuts in Japanese output
were apparently successful in boosting prices to levels at or above the
Commerce Department FMVs.
By early 1989 semiconductor demand had begun to weaken. In re¬
sponse to a downward drift in DRAM prices, Japanese manufacturers
began to cut back output in order to maintain high prices. Japanese
newspapers talked of “coordination structures” among Japanese com¬
panies being used to achieve “high price stability.” This was a distinctly
different situation from that in 1988, when prices greatly exceeded price
floors as the industry was at full capacity utilization. With all producers
operating close to capacity, it was more difficult to argue that the indus¬
try’s own restraint, rather than an earlier history of politically mandated
388 STRATEGIC ISSUES
20. See Semiconductor Industry Association, Four Years of Experience under the U.S.-
Japan Semiconductor Trade Agreement: “A Deal is a Deal” (San Jose, Calif., November
1990), p. 65.
STRATEGIC ISSUES 389
for the SI A and given wide circulation by others citing it.21 The argument
starts from the circumstances of the “production coordination” by Jap¬
anese suppliers in late 1985 and early 1986 (described above), which
attracted little contemporary public comment outside Japan (unlike in
1982, when the U.S. Justice Department became involved). Arguing that
moves to reduce DRAM exports and production predated the STA and
therefore must have been independent of government policy, proponents
of this view instead attribute “production coordination” to Japanese chip
makers passing over some threshold of monopoly power as American
producers withdrew:
the move toward production regulation by the Japanese producers’ group
began in 1985, well before the Semiconductor Arrangement had even been
conceptualized, much less actually put in place. . . . Thus, by the third
and fourth quarters of 1985, Japanese DRAM producers had few compet¬
itors left except each other. It was at this precise moment—in late 1985—
that reports began to appear of joint actions by the Japanese DRAM
producers to stabilize price competition by coordinated curtailments in
output.22
23. Tilton studied cartels in the aluminum, cement, petrochemical, and steel industries.
See Restrained Trade: Cartels in Japan's Basic Materials Industries (Cornell University
Press, 1996). As Tilton notes, the Fair Trade Commission is far from independent of other
Japanese government bureaucracies. By informal custom the head commissioner is a former
Ministry of Finance official, while the other four commissioner slots are reserved for a
retiree from the Finance Ministry, MITI, the Justice Ministry, and for a former official
inside the FTC itself (pp. 48-49). On restraints in the Japanese steel industry, see also
Thomas R. Howell and others, Steel and the State: Government Intervention and Steel’s
Structural Crisis (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1988), pp. 202-07.
24. See In the United States District Court for the District of New Jersey, Honeywell,
Inc., a Delaware corporation, Plaintiff, v. Minolta Camera Co. Ltd., a Japanese Corpora¬
tion, and Minolta Corporation, a New York Corporation, Defendants, Civil Action 87-4847,
Transcript of Trial Proceedings, vol. 16 (Newark, N.J., October 11, 1991), pp. 2274-2295;
vol. 33 (Newark, N.J., November 6, 1991), pp. 4960-4966; and vol. 63 (Newark, N.J.,
January 2, 1992), pp. 9727-9734. See also Barnaby J. Feder, “Honeywell-Minolta Dispute
Teaches Conflicting Lessons,” New York Times, February 12, 1992, p. Dl.
STRATEGIC ISSUES 391
25. Yui Kimura, The Japanese Semiconductor Industry (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press,
1988), p. 66.
26. Indeed, Tilton notes that even in highly concentrated basic materials industries,
active MITI involvement was needed in order for cartels to succeed. “In aluminum, cement,
392 STRATEGIC ISSUES
and petrochemicals the policymaking process followed this pattern: MITI pushed industry
to go along with cartels that individual firms privately believed were necessary but that they
could not coordinate on their own.” Tilton, Restrained Trade, p. 207.
27. As anonymous industry executive “B” noted, at a time when the industry was in a
period of peak demand, “Japanese corporations usually don’t buy imported and marketed
wafers even if they are of the same quality and a little cheaper. They may have tried to
obtain ones in the latest shortage, but corporations overseas, then, might well have had no
surplus of supply. Even if Japanese corporations want to buy overseas products on the basis
of quality, ignoring the somewhat different yield involved, the commercial deal may not be
worked out unless the prices are lower than those produced in Japan by 10 to 15 percent;
and even if the prices so favor them, they will never buy very complex super LSIs. Although
the wafers are flown in in only one day, a communications gap still remains a solid barrier
between nations. Overseas corporations, after all, have to build their own plants in Japan
if they are to succeed in selling wafers in Japan, I presume, as the Monsanto Corporation
is going to.” Monsanto, after building such a plant in the late 1980s, was still unable to
significantly increase its share of the Japanese silicon wafer market, and ultimately exited
from the silicon wafer business. “Silicon Semiconductors: Point in Question and Prospects;
A Roundtable Talk With the Names of Speakers Withheld,” Kinzoku Jihyo, no. 1125,
April 5, 1985, p. 171.
STRATEGIC ISSUES 393
28. “Toshiba Trying to Reach 30% Materials Import Target This Year,” Rare Metal
News, no. 1396, April 1, 1987.
29. “According to users, there are even some American [epitaxial] wafers whose prices
are half of Japanese products, including exchange rate differentials and with American
standards. Based on this fact, it is very likely in the future that epi wafers from Japanese
U.S.-based silicon producers, such as Shinetsu Semiconductor, Mitsubishi Metal, and
Osaka Titanium, will be reimported.
Silicon producers point out that ‘the cost of domestic silicon wafers increases in order
to meet the strict Japanese standard, so it is irrational to compare price per surface area
without taking quality into account.’ In addition, Japanese silicon producers operating in
the U.S. also mention that ‘we are currently operating near full capacity in the U.S., and
we cannot sacrifice U.S. users by reexporting the products to Japan.’ ” “Toshiba Trying to
Reach 30% Materials Import Target,” p. 1.
30. At a 1987 anonymous roundtable discussion, when the new fiscal year price nego¬
tiations came up for discussion, executive “E” complained:
The persons in charge of ordering materials for the device manufacturers are trying
to use the high yen value as a weapon. The industries budgeted at 1 dollar equal to
150 yen, but the yen has appreciated to 130 yen per dollar, and they are looking at
the fact that the costs do not match up.
In the past, domestically produced materials and parts have been of high quality.
There had been a long history of transactions, so they were willing to purchase at
somewhat high prices. Recently, however, the struggle to survive is forcing a change
in thinking to move toward the less expensive imported products. There was one
company that was rejoicing at having saved 100 million yen due to such a switchover.
There is less of a consciousness in the industry of taking care of the parts and raw
materials manufacturers.
Up until about the summer of last year [1986], there was quite a bit of difference
in purchase price among different customers for material of the same specifications.
If price cuts were undertaken, they were done while considering the health of the
overall industry; they had a price-leader-type effect.
However, beginning around the fall of last year, the orderliness of the situation
disappeared. The main suppliers were not necessarily the price leaders. Other com¬
panies would cut prices on their own initiative, and a great deal of confusion was
created in the market. It was difficult to make a distinction between the price of
394 STRATEGIC ISSUES
prices from the standard “large user” price levels on that portion of their
demand that they could buy from overseas sources.33
In short, evidence of a residual “buy Japanese” preference can still be
discerned within some corners of the Japanese electronics industry. In
many cases—particularly in semiconductors—quality levels for products
produced by major global suppliers, whether Japanese or foreign, no
longer seem to vary significantly aross companies and therefore do not
provide much of an explanation for such a preference.34
There is another set of economic reasons why companies might prefer
to buy from domestic sources at higher prices linked to “relational con¬
tracting.” A long-term relationship with a preferred supplier may be
fostered to obtain superior service and delivery, or partnerships created
with suppliers to develop technologically superior new inputs, at the price
of commitments to maintain procurement even when input prices are
somewhat above market levels. There is also some evidence of a long¬
standing concern in Japan over the vulnerability to external disruption of
supplies procured from overseas, although the overtones of economic
warfare wrapped into this worry make it more a national security issue
than an industrial concern (and it is hard to see how Japan’s vulnerability
in its dependence on foreign industrial inputs—other than natural re¬
sources—is any more severe than that faced by most other industrial
nations). Finally—and often explicitly linked to government concerns
about the security of supplies for key inputs—there is a long history of
government policy formally and informally encouraging “buy Japanese”
attitudes within the industrial sector, although most of the means of
formal encouragement have now been dismantled.35 Separating out what
portion of the explanation for a domestic preference is economic rather
than the result of politics, history, informal government policy, and the
prevailing business culture is likely to remain an impossible task.
Somewhat less hopeless is the analysis of less subtle forms of industrial
collusion. One of the most provocative issues raised by the operation of
the STA is the extent to which cartel-like private behavior was observed
after the arrangement went into operation and what the potential con¬
sequences of such behavior are. I turn next to these issues.
spring, sliced shipments even more, and increased their stocks of parts
held in inventories.37 In the early fall of 1989, most major Japanese chip
producers announced large production cuts. At the end of July NEC
announced that it had scaled back its plans to increase production of 1M
DRAMs.38 In September, Toshiba, Hitachi, and Mitsubishi each reported
that they were cutting back their production levels by about 10 percent.39
In late October, NEC announced that it too would actually cut current
production levels in the first quarter of 1990.40
Contemporary Japanese press accounts asserted that Japanese chip
makers were collectively cutting back production to slow the decline in
prices, to achieve “high price stabilization.” Talk of a “coordination
structure” also reappeared in the trade press (see chapter 4).
In interviews in November and December of 1989, semiconductor
executives at several Japanese companies were quite frank with me about
their intention to continue to cut back DRAM production in order to
stabilize prices. Asked why, given current prices that were certainly far
above his company’s production costs, he did not cut prices in order to
stimulate sales, one top executive motioned toward a skyscraper visible
through the window, the headquarters of a rival electronics giant, and
remarked that if he cut prices, his neighbor would as well, setting off a
round of continual price cutting. Asked how he could know how much
to cut production in order to stabilize prices, without knowing the plans
of other companies, his colleague responded that the matter was compli¬
cated, with “many aspects,” and declined to elaborate further.41
The subject of coordination among companies is obviously a delicate
one, and while rumors of golf course meetings are a staple of conversation
37. See chapter 4. The basic chronology of events in 1989 was set out as follows in a
presentation by Hitachi’s H. Nakagawa: supply exceeded demand in the second quarter of
1989; booking adjustment by users in the second to fourth quarters of 1989; and production
adjustment by manufacturers after the third quarter of 1989. H. Nakagawa, “Semiconductor
and EDP Market,” slides from a presentation given circa late 1989 (given to the author in
December 1989).
38. NEC withdrew its plan to increase monthly production of 1M DRAMs from
6 million to 8 million chips. Nikkan Kogyo, July 29, 1989, p. 1; Nihon Kogyo, July 29,
1989, p. 1.
39. “Major Semi-Conductor Manufacturers to Reduce 1M-DRAM Production by 10%
from September,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, September 14, 1989, p. 10.
40. The cut was from 6 million units per month to 5 million units. Dempa Shimbun,
October 31, 1989, p. 1; Nikkan Kogyo, October 31, 1989, p. 1; Nihon Kogyo, October 31,
1989, p. 5.
41. Author’s interview in Tokyo, December 1989.
398 STRATEGIC ISSUES
42. The last meeting attended by my source, as of the date of my interview, was in
1990.
43. Personal communication with the author.
STRATEGIC ISSUES 399
44. Fourth-quarter 1989 FMVs for 1M DRAMs were reported by one Japanese industry
source to have been set as follows: Toshiba, $4.50; Hitachi, $5.20; Fujitsu, $5.50; Mitsub¬
ishi, $7.00; NEC, $7.50. Author’s interview in Tokyo, December 1989.
45. See Stefan Wagstyl, “Winning When the Chips Were Down,” Financial Times, May
10, 1988, p. 33; Stefan Wagstyl, “Turning Hard Times Into Good Times,” Financial Times,
June 14, 1988, p. 22; and Terry Dodsworth, Louise Kehoe, and Stefan Wagstyl, “The Chase
to Catch the Japanese,” Financial Times, July 25, 1988, p. 18. At the time, 1M DRAMs
were selling for about four times Toshiba’s estimated cost of production, or 2,000 yen.
Toshiba claimed to be achieving 65 percent yields over this period, at a time when the
industry as a whole averaged under 40 percent.
46. Dataquest estimates show Toshiba with under 20 percent of world 1M DRAM
production in the last quarter of 1989, and under 30 percent even if Motorola’s sales are
counted in the Toshiba market share (Motorola sold Toshiba-fabricated chips under its own
name and operated a DRAM manufacturing joint venture with Toshiba at the time).
400 STRATEGIC ISSUES
Learning Economies
so that Cournot marginal revenue less “true” marginal cost will be pos¬
itive (although MRCournot - MC may be negative if upper-bound MC
exceeds MC by enough). Our basic procedure for testing for competitive
behavior, then, will be to construct an upper bound on marginal cost,
then deduct it from estimated marginal revenue maintaining competitive
Cournot assumptions. Under competition, the result should necessarily
be less than or equal to zero. Under the alternative hypothesis of collu¬
sion (A., > 0), marginal revenue less an upper bound on current marginal
cost may be positive (although it need not be).
The most difficult issue in an exercise like this is always to find data
that allow one to say something reasonable about marginal cost. For two
47. It does, however, permit discounting of future revenues and costs by the firm when
it makes its output choices. An equation such as this (with current MR set equal to current
MC less a positive term) can easily be shown to hold in asymmetric industries (with firms
of different sizes), as firms continuously make production choices over time in the case of
nonstrategic behavior (in which rivals are assumed to have precommitted output paths). A
similar result has also been shown to hold in a symmetric-industry equilibrium (identical
firms) when firms behave strategically in their choice of current output levels (that is, where
firms manipulate rivals’ output levels in future periods, by signaling lower future costs
through increases in their own current output, via learning effects). See Drew Fudenberg
and Jean Tirole, “Learning-by-Doing and Market Performance,” Bell Journal of Econom¬
ics, vol. 14 (Autumn 1983), p. 527.
402 STRATEGIC ISSUES
48. See for example, W. C. Holton and others, JTECH Panel Report on Computer
Integrated Manufacturing (CIM) and Computer Assisted Design (CAD) for the Semicon¬
ductor Industry in Japan (McLean, Va.: Science Applications International Corporation,
1988). “The large semiconductor wafer fabrication plants visited by the JTECH panelists
are engaged in high-volume production of VLSI standard products such as dynamic and
static memories and microprocessors. A single wafer fabrication line is typically used to
produce perhaps five to fifteen different products (for example, static and dynamic random
access memory (RAM) devices of different bit capacity, several different microprocessors)
using one or two standard processes” (pp. 14-15).
STRATEGIC ISSUES 403
COM MC +
m [1 + p(r)],
Y
49. A rule of thumb in the semiconductor business is that there is a 1:1 overall ratio
between the capital cost of new capacity and the volume of annual sales generated by that
capacity. With a five-year life for a new production line and straight-line depreciation, this
suggests that depreciation amounts to roughly 20 percent of sales. For a product such as
DRAMs, whose manufacturing costs account for relatively more of the value of sales than
the overall semiconductor industry average, one would expect this ratio to be even greater.
50. For fifteen data points describing Mitsubishi’s 256K and 1M DRAM costs at various
times from 1987 through 1991, the average estimate of p—estimated as COM divided by
the total cost of wafer fabrication, assembly, and testing—was .36. This corresponds to a
cost structure with R&D amounting to 21 percent of constructed value: p/
[(1 -I- p)(1.08)(l +s)] = .21, with s an estimate of sales, general, and administrative expenses
as a share of COM. A single company wide estimate of p was applied by the Department
of Commerce to all Mitsubishi semiconductor products. See appendix 5-B.
51. It was also possible to estimate ratio s—sales, general, and administrative expenses
(SG&A)—as a share of COM using various data from Mitsubishi and NEC. Using ninety-
two observations for various models of DRAMs over the 1987-91 period, and either the
relationship COP = (1 +s) COM or Constructed Value = (1.08) (1 +s) COM, 5 for NEC
averaged 0.39. This corresponds to a cost structure with SG&A amounting to 26 percent
404 STRATEGIC ISSUES
Source: Author’s calculations and Dataquest and Nikkei data. Calculations explained in the text. Marginal revenue
based on use of alternative price series is graphed.
during the early years of 256K and 1M DRAM production the industry
was somewhat more concentrated than the historical norm, but by 1989
concentration in both these products looked similar to earlier historical
levels. Levels of geographic concentration offered greater promise as a
reason for concern. At the time the STA was signed, reductions in pro¬
duction or exports by Japanese producers could have had potentially great
impacts on aggregate worldwide supply of DRAMs.
Strategic Behavior
(7-3)
1
must hold (see appendix 7-A). Note that this partial derivative is with
respect to K alone, evaluated with u(t) set equal to optimal control u*{t).
This differs from the expression developed from equation 6-5 because,
in the nonstrategic case, initial capacity investments were not viewed by
the firm as affecting rivals’ second-period utilization decisions; that is,
dx/dK = 0 was assumed. With more than two firms in the industry (N >
2), and with symmetric equilibrium, concavity of the industry revenue
function is sufficient to guarantee that rivals will reduce their output
along an interior segment. Since Rx is negative, the additional effect
added on to equation 6-5 must be positive, which means that the marginal
return on additional capacity will be positive at the level of investment
corresponding to the nonstrategic equilibrium. With strategic competi¬
tion, additional capacity will seem attractive.
Along a “boundary” segment (when available capacity actually con¬
strains production), however, the response by competitors to a marginal
increase in one’s own capacity will be zero. Intuitively, when a firm’s
marginal revenue already exceeds its true (corrected for learning econ¬
omies) marginal cost, so that it chooses to operate at maximum capacity,
a small increase in a competitor’s output—which reduces the firm’s mar¬
ginal revenue (with a concave industry revenue function)—will still leave
the firm wishing to produce at maximum output. Thus, if the symmetric
industry equilibrium is one in which firms are everywhere capacity con¬
strained, producing at full blast throughout the product cycle, the stra¬
tegic equilibrium will coincide with a nonstrategic equilibrium. Strategic
behavior will have no effect on the industry equilibrium.
Note that I am allowing only partially strategic behavior with this
modeling strategy. There are two possible instruments of strategic be¬
havior: capacity choice and output (capacity utilization) choice. Output
choice has potential strategic effects via learning economies, insofar as
output at any moment in time affects future cost structure. (Without
learning economies, current output choice has no effect on future cost
structure, and therefore no strategic value.) A firm might choose current
output taking into account the impact of its own current output choice
STRATEGIC ISSUES 409
on rivals’ future output choices, rather than taking the rivals’ future
output path as given. To reduce complexity, I do not allow strategic output
choice, and output paths are chosen as open loop, in which firms precommit
to an output path at the beginning of the second stage of the game.56
However, I do permit strategic competition in capacity. Firms do use
capacity choice strategically, in order to affect rivals’ choice of (open-
loop) output path in the second stage of the game. Thus strategic com¬
petition is permitted in capacity choice, but not in output choice (via
learning effects).
Table 7-1 reworks table 6-4 to reflect strategic behavior, with equation
7-3 used instead of equation 6-5. If no solution for a system based on
equations 6-9 and 7-3 was found, the alternative, corresponding to full-
blast production throughout the product cycle, is identical to (unmodi¬
fied) equation 6-5, since dx/dK = 0 holds along a capacity-constrained
segment. In what I earlier tentatively concluded was the most realistic
set of assumptions about how learning economies work (learning occurs
at the plant level, with parameter y = 1), strategic behavior appears to
have no impact on the symmetric-industry equilibrium, and full-blast
production throughout the product cycle still prevails. In the case where
learning occurs at the company level (y = 0, which had a substantial
interior segment with nonstrategic behavior), capacity per firm increases
by about 50 percent relative to the nonstrategic case, and the equilibrium
number of firms drops from four to three, for the range of fixed R&D
costs considered plausible. The resulting path of DRAM price is shown
in figure 7-5. Strategic behavior thus has no impact with the “per fab
line” specification of learning, but a large impact in the case of compa¬
nywide learning.
For the reasons outlined earlier, the y = 1 case continues to appear
most plausible. Thus I conclude that—within the framework developed
here—my best efforts at discovering realistic values for empirical param¬
eters relevant to 1M DRAM production suggest that strategic competi¬
tion in capacity investments had little potential for shaping market out¬
comes in the industry.
56. One possible (but only partial) empirical justification for this specification is that
there are very long lags between capacity utilization decisions and the resulting output.
The production process for a chip takes almost a full quarter year, so any change in output
rates is observable by one’s rivals only after a substantial lag.
in
ON
r- r-1 .—1
cn CN
CN
sO rH cn
NO in
CN
00 -h cn
Os Os
CN
NO rH cn Os rH O N’ rH O
cn o r- O
cn in
in NO 1 sd
1
00 rH r- NO rH so cn rH SO
o cn ON
in tj- NO
i Tfr
1
CN rH rH CN rH in NO rH OS
cn Os rH ON
NO
1
Tf rH T^- rH rH O rH CN
ON o ON ON r- N-
Os NO
NO oo
1
oo
ON rH i—H rH Tj" 00 rH rH r-
s NO NO
i>
o NO r- OS
rH rH
o
oo r- (N cn CN ON
00 ON
SS 1 o’
rH
1
•2 j*.
CN rH 00 N- rH CN O
-O SO rH CN rH rH
NO 00
-2 s 00
Os
00
ON
00
cn
00 n*
CN
Os rH
OO
d
rH 1 rH 1
5 I rH
ON rH CN Os rH SO CN rH in cn rH rH
r- cn rH r- cn o
u Os
cn rH
NO
CN NO
rH rH rH 1
<L>
-*h
<3
L. rH rH in rH CN cn rH N- rH rH
■*h cn Os Os ON
Co rH
00
CN
CN
N"
tH ON in
rH
rH rH rH rH rH 1
-2 CN
-o N"
cn
rH
o
cn
r-
rH O
00
SO
r-
rH in
in
00 rH NO
N"
o ON rH 00
cn in NO r-'
rH CN rH CN rH rH rH
O
k. cn rH in rH O CN rH CN NO on r-
o oo rH
C fn sd
ON 00
rH
NO
cn
d
in 00 on r-
d d ™
o H Tt CN cn CN cn
O
00 rH o CN rH o rH rH o in oo o
© oo ON r- Os rH NO ON ON
<N ON
cn
rH cn
cn d ^
rH o' CN o' CN o' CN o
rH rH rH
ON o NO rH O NO rH o cn rH O
<§■ cn
r-
cn
NO
cn
ON r-
in
00
NO
in NO OOr
rH ON rH CN rH in oo"
•s CN cn cn rH cn
3
CL
3 3 3
CL CL CL
0X) 3 0X) 3 3 3
0X)
c o c , o a O OX)
C O
© wo 'Tn ’wo C s -h
tn C/3 C/3 wo O cr>
<u
o "h
Os <L> S s
o
00 <D
CJ
O' **
O •H c
d
C
Hi C
d
O
u.
5^3 d
<D <D
Cl CJ "h U. II CL ■Q 3 Hi II CL
r- i 3 d i 5 H i
uo3l 3
c/3
ju C/3
o
3
£
r- r-H r- vO 00 Tf 00 rj (N oo r- o r- to NO
© o rf 00 On • r~ o © rf O 00 04
o- CO
CO CO d ^ rH d O d cd d O
i“H 1 rH 04 04
1 1 1 1
lO r- 00 to CO OV ov cn CO rj- Qn rt 04 to
’”H Ov VO 00 VO oo 04 tJ- OV © 04 tJ-
Ov 04 v® S
to © T to o ^ vd d ^ vd d ^
O 1 rH i rH rH 04 04
,""1
1 1 1
rH OO VO Ov 04 CO OV to oo to CO CO ov 00
vO On 0- rH 00 rH VO VO to rH -j ov © rH O
O
d 00 d 7 00 d °° Ov On d ^
1 1 rH rH rH rH
1 1
o- tO VO CO On OV On 04 00 VO 00 to VO On
© O' to ts r- oo 04 VO H rsl
vN
CO O vq H VO
rH d °r rH d 04 d ^ 04 d n 04 d ^
04 CO 04 04 04 H rH 04 rH
VO Tt O Ov O On o r- o 04 O
t-; On 00 On r- co • VO 00 © • Tt rH • to
O V.0
d ^ 'd- d *> 04 d °°r rt- 0 °° 04
04 o 04 o o 04 rH 04 co"
rH rH rH
co 00 o r- vO O o- 04 o Ov rH O 00 t-4 O
ov 00 r- 00 to to r- 04 VO to VO 00 CO 00
a. Millions of product-cycle wafer starts.
d ^ d d °°r vd d Tf d
r-H ov rH rH rH Tj- rH Ov rH Tj-
co TT Tf to
Source: Author’s calculations.
3 3 3 3
a.
4—'
a. CL
4—*
CL
4-J
oc 3 oc 3 oc 3 3 3
C * O
b. Millions of dollars.
C r O c O O g», O
oc C/5
vO IS sjd <u cd u-, £ * J co 4> 4) • iS
o O
o ^ c o c o 8 >.f c 2 5*5 3 o
3
a
o
u> a. 'o 4)
II a'5 3 4)
CL O 3
4)
Q
cd S• 9-
cd
</5 cd
• 3 cd
i cd «4-i
cd
I Cd <4-
cd
cd
CL
E h- cd
> C/5 4) 9" 4) B* **
« S ■§ o TJC w
>■»
4) 9" —“ cd
E .cd ■o ; o - S ^ ; o E
E c t-
E
<J
i| ls 'W
u
E
cd W a cd O cd ^ PJ O cd ^ o cd W o
o o o a
412 STRATEGIC ISSUES
Source: Author’s calculation and Dataquest and Nikkei data. Calculations explained in the text.
Competitive
output Second-period.
Simulation choice cartel Change
Gamma = lb
fs, end full-blast output 1 0.237
P(l), final price (dollars) 3.77 9.37
Consumer surplus (billions of dollars) 148.9 117.4 -31.5
Industry net profits (billions of dollars) 0.045 4.564 4.5
Gamma = 0C
ts, end full-blast output 0.16047 0.037
P(l), final price (dollars) 1.61 4.08
Consumer surplus (billions of dollars) 287.9 186.4 -101.5
Industry net profits (billions of dollars) 3.957 34.57 30.61
Source: Author’s calculations,
a. Symmetric industry equilibrium assumed.
b. F equals $250 million; N equals fourteen firms; and K equals 4.655 million product-cycle wafer starts.
c. /-'equals $250 million; N equals three firms; and K equals 22.648 million product-cycle wafer starts.
play the two-stage game described above and select sunk capacity in¬
vestments corresponding to the strategic (or the nonstrategic) case.
Now suppose that, after the first (capacity selection) stage but before
the second (production) stage, an external force intervenes and changes
the rules. The country J firms are to be permitted—perhaps even en¬
couraged—to form a cartel structure, to reduce output and raise prices.
How much will consumers of DRAMs lose? How much will producers of
DRAMs gain?
Carry the argument a step further. Suppose country J firms, if left to
their own devices, are perfectly prepared to form a cartel on their own,
but that to do so requires that some “critical mass” of existing DRAM
producers be country J firms. Then country U can prevent cartel forma¬
tion by subsidizing entry by its own firms (which are assumed to be
behaviorally, or for legal reasons, indisposed toward collusion). What
level of subsidies should country U be willing to pay to ensure against
cartel formation?
Table 7-2 shows the loss to consumers and increased producer profits
associated with a second-stage switch from a noncooperative Cournot-
Nash equilibrium to cartel formation. Initial capacities are assumed to
414 STRATEGIC ISSUES
have been chosen as the first stage of the competitive game described
above, with an anticipated competitive second stage. Now, however, the
conjectural variation parameter a has been reset from a competitive,
Cournot value of 1/N to the collusive, cartel value of one, in calculating
the second-stage output path.
It is striking that the lost consumer welfare is so very much larger than
the profits gained by producers.57 There are two reasons for this. First,
fixed cost per unit produced rises considerably when output is cut back
sharply in the second stage relative to the competitive output levels for
which capacity was initially chosen. Second, the existence of learning
economies means that, when producers cut back output, they also raise
their variable costs per unit over the remainder of the product cycle.
Thus, much of what might have been additional monopoly profit, without
scale and learning economies, is chewed up by higher unit costs incurred
when output is reduced.
Thus, for example, in what I have argued is the more realistic case of
y = 1, a switch from competition to collusion in 1M DRAMs costs over
$30 billion in forgone consumer welfare, over a five-year product cycle,
while producing monopoly profits of only about $4.5 billion over the
same period. (Note that at the height of the real-world 1M DRAM
shortage of 1988-89 some analysts’ estimates put “excess” industry prof¬
its at levels of $1 billion to $2 billion per year.)58 Clearly, if these calcu¬
lations are correct, even if country U accounts for only 40 percent of final
DRAM consumption, its consumers should be willing to pay $2.4 billion
or so annually to prevent the formation of a cartel (40 percent of $30
billion is $12 billion, or $2.4 billion annually). Of course, there may be
other, less costly ways to inhibit cartel formation by foreign producers: if
governments can agree to enforce some common international antitrust
standards, for example, and foreign governments apply such norms to
their producers, the benefits of competition might be available to U.S.
consumers at no cost.
57. In the case of a constant-elasticity demand curve, it can be shown that the total
consumer surplus CS is given by:
levels, such as to imply rents in the second stage, further entry by other
firms would presumably be stimulated). Then we have a terrible dilemma
for the potential country U entrant: if it does not enter, the country J
firms may form a cartel in the second stage, in which case it must sit and
watch as others earn rents. If it does enter, however, it disrupts the cartel,
guarantees competition in the second stage, and thus guarantees itself a
loss in a zero-profit equilibrium (since it produces at a cost disadvantage
relative to the rest of the population of firms).
Third, my consumer welfare calculation assumes that monopoly rents
are extracted by a cartel at arm’s length from a competitive user industry,
which then passes on cost increases directly to final consumers. It is well
known that if an input is not fixed in proportion to output, a monopolist
controlling the pricing of an input maximizes profit by integrating forward
into the user industry that purchases that input, in order to avoid substi¬
tution away from the input.59 Since chip-producing firms in country J
may also be systems producers, there would appear to be few barriers to
this occurring in the long run. The welfare cost to final consumers may
increase if this were to occur.
Fourth, what if a domestic chip-consuming industry is imperfectly
competitive and extracts rents from sales to foreign consumers? Can this
not increase the welfare loss from a domestic standpoint, particularly if
forward integration by foreign chip producers and the exit of domestic
equipment producers accompany monopoly rent extraction?
Fifth, the logic of anticartel insurance suggests that chip consumers as
a group ought to be willing to subsidize entry by cartel-busting entrants.
(The ill-fated U.S. Memories consortium, in which chip users proposed
to fund entry into the DRAM business, comes to mind.) However, there
will be a free rider problem. All consumers gain from the entry of a
cartel buster, whether or not they have actually helped pay for it. A
government role would therefore seem to be needed to handle this “pub¬
lic good” aspect of entry.
Sixth, little attention has been paid to intergenerational externalities.
The fact that several firms—particularly Korean companies and Japan’s
NMB Semiconductor—were able to enter the DRAM business in the
mid-1980s with virtually no prior experience suggests that such external¬
ities, if they exist, are not so significant as to be an insuperable barrier
to entry.
Finally, the degree of collusion and, indeed, all the details in the
policy-related story I am telling are extreme. The costs calculated here
probably should best be regarded as an upper bound on the costs cor¬
responding to a more realistic scenario. Is there a convenient way to
parameterize less stark forms of behavior? In particular, one might want
to imagine a scenario in which most producers participate in a cartel, but
one or two “outsiders” form a competitive fringe and do not cooperate
with the cartel (but do not break it either). With asymmetric firms,
however, characterization of equilibrium paths becomes much more
difficult.
Conclusion
So-called strategic arguments for an activist U.S. policy in semicon¬
ductors have focused on two issues: the possible existence of technolog¬
ical externalities—spillovers—between semiconductor production and
other types of industrial activity that are not captured by producers, and
the extent to which monopoly profits can be extracted from downstream
chip users by an upstream cartel. This latter issue has been particularly
important in shaping the debate over trade policy in semiconductors.
There is plenty of general anecdotal evidence of Japanese industry
activities that probably would have violated antitrust laws had they
ocurred in the United States (and at least some of which were arguably
also illegal in Japan) in past decades, and continuing up to the present
day. There are even some specific episodes that suggest similar behavior
in the Japanese semiconductor industry. However, in all cases where it
appears that such activities were successful in creating cartel-like indus¬
trial structures, some degree of active or tacit government support for
such organization can also be discerned.
The latter point clearly holds true in semiconductors. Before 1986,
episodes in which Japanese semiconductor producers successfully man¬
aged a reduction in their collective output or exports were in all cases
undertaken with the support of MITI and generally were undertaken as
a response to acute, external trade friction. From 1986 through 1989 the
organization by MITI of formal structures designed to control output
and prices was overt and explicit. Restraint in production and exports
was clearly linked to a deliberate government policy. It is in some sense
418 STRATEGIC ISSUES
circular to argue that the policy was justified by the predatory intent of
restraints that were implemented as part of the policy.
After 1989, however, the visible hand of MITI as organizer of restraints
had disappeared, and it is at least possible to argue that evidence of
collusive behavior reflected wholly private behavior. Available data—
anecdotal and statistical—in fact, seem to show Japanese DRAM pro¬
ducers behaving in a way that does not appear very competitive in 1990.
One is left to wonder, however, whether behind the scenes there was tacit
government support for a policy of private market sharing, to replace the
cutthroat competition sometimes practiced by the Japanese industry, and
minimize the potential for renewed trade friction.
My simulation results, however, made it clear that a foreign chip cartel,
at least in principle, can create a substantial net welfare loss for an
economy making significant use of the cartelized input. Under the right
empirical circumstances, a serious argument can be made for subsidizing
domestic capabilities as a form of anticartel insurance. Whether those
circumstances existed—or continue to exist—in semiconductors is likely
to remain the subject of continued debate.
Note that this partial derivative is, with respect to K alone, evaluated
with u{t) set equal to optimal control u*(t). This differs from the expres¬
sion developed in appendix 6-B (equation B-2) because of an additional
term,
(7A-1)
added onto the left-hand side. In the nonstrategic case, initial capacity
investments were not viewed by the firm as affecting rivals’ second-period
output decisions, i.e., dx/dK = 0 was assumed. The remainder of this
appendix develops term C-l explicitly.
First I adopt some additional notational conventions: variables sub¬
scripted with y refer to the firm making a strategic calculation, and
variables subscripted with i to its N — 1 rivals.
A firm sees each rival as maximizing its own Hamiltonian, Hh exactly
analogous to the Hamiltonian shown in appendix 6-A, subject to the
constraint that firm fs utilization rate «, be less than or equal to one. (I
rule out the possibility of a symmetric equilibrium with no output pro¬
duced [«, = 0] for reasons described in appendix 6-A.) The firm takes
its rivals’ capacities as given and is interested in how its rivals’ capacity
utilization rates vary with its own capacity choice.
420 STRATEGIC ISSUES
5, = - d + Y7julwE,Kr
dL, _ d/f, _ 0
da, da, 1X1
Since
d//. 5..
~ = (P'x, + P - d + ^) *(£,)*, - cK,
K7
for each rival i, a firm knows that the first-order conditions determining
a, and |x, are
fL/(l ~ U,) = 0,
with |ji, > 0.
w(E,)K,
dlljdK dUjdKv
—
dK I
lx, + r^
dU/dK
da. dUj
w(£,) = w(£,), Kt = Kj,
d Ky d k;
and we need solve only for and instead of 2(TV - 1) such terms.
dKy dKy
dy
Let ——- be uyw(Ey), where subscript y denotes the values of these vari-
dKy
ables for the firm varying Ky.
dXj
Since — = w{E)Kt, the comparative statics are thus given by
OU:
STRATEGIC ISSUES 421
dll,
~ M-i (1 _dKy_
-[w{E)K]uyW{Ey)(F'x, + F)
Let M be the square matrix on the left-hand side of this equation, and
\M\ its determinant.
Then,
dUj (1 - Uj) F,
dKy
1
dfi,- “ \M\
-w(£,.)^w(^)(T% + F)
60. By the strict concavity of the revenue function, zP' < -2P'.
du, .
The general expression for —— is
dKy
Since P' < 0, the right-hand side of this inequality will be negative as long as
—( — 2) + 1 > 0
z
5
z
X. 1
In a symmetric equilibrium, —' = — .
N
Therefore, F’x, + P' < 0 as long as 1 < — • N > 2 is sufficient for the bracketed term
to be negative.
61. Actually there is a third possibility: that p., = 0 and u, = 1, in which case M is
singular and duJdKy undefined. This can only occur at the transition from a boundary to
an interior segment and can never last more than an instant. (With u = 1, industry output
must be rising and marginal revenue Ry falling. But with p = 0 over some interval with u
= 1,
.• . c y 8 c wK
weK'-<
w2^
(Ry) = :~2We7Z + -7Z = —
W TO /G
= -weK1-* - -Iwp/C1-1'
w
= 0,
which cannot be true in a symmetric-industry equilibrium with all firms at full capacity
over some interval. Therefore, we cannot have u = 1 and p = 0 for more than an instant.)
STRATEGIC ISSUES 423
0, w, = 1
dUj
(7A-4) = u
dK„ -, < 0, ut < 1.
K P" 1 '
1+ ~ »[r*N + \
A key point emerging from this analysis is that—in a symmetric equi¬
librium—over periods when output is capacity-constrained, a marginal
increase in capacity will have no impact on rivals’ output. Intuitively,
when a firm’s marginal revenue exceeds its marginal cost, a small increase
in a competitor’s output—which reduces marginal revenue—will still
leave the firm wishing to produce at maximum output.
Returning to the task of simplifying expression C-l, we then have:
du
since = 0 when w, = 1.
dKy
With a constant-elasticity demand, and p the price elasticity, this
becomes:
(7A-6)
1 -P(A - l)y
pAA
1 + K ■1 * >dt =
\ll
l\
1 + (A - 1) 1 +— 1 -
v [ \p / AJ
424 STRATEGIC ISSUES
1 +
yg. K)P(y{t„ K))
$NK { 1) (1 0-
1 + (N- 1)
N y
This term was added to the right-hand side of equation B-2 in solving
for possible equilibria. Again, it is important to note that strategic in¬
vestment behavior has no effect if the symmetric-industry equilibrium
associated with the empirical parameters of the problem is capacity-
constrained throughout the product life cycle.
CHAPTER EIGHT
Conclusion:
Mismanaged Trade?
Since 1959 the United States and Japan have been arguing over the rules
for international industrial competition in semiconductors. In some re¬
spects, little has changed.
In 1959 massive Japanese exports of low-priced germanium transistors
ignited concerns of American semiconductor manufacturers. The tran¬
sistor’s importance for computers, communications, and other electronic
systems in an epoch when markets for advanced electronics were domi¬
nated by military applications led to appeals for protection from imports
on grounds that national security was at stake. Japan’s government and
its transistor industry responded by constructing an export cartel de¬
signed to stabilize prices. Transistor consumers around the globe com¬
plained. The U.S. electronics industry was divided: semiconductor pro¬
ducers demanded protection, while systems producers fought policies that
might raise the price of an important component and create a competitive
disadvantage for them in commercial markets. The problem ultimately
was to disappear because of the phenomenal rate of technological ad¬
vance in microelectronics. As individual transistors were replaced by
much more sophisticated integrated circuits, the American semiconduc¬
tor companies pioneering these innovations created entirely new families
of products and rendered the Japanese cost advantage in the older dis¬
crete semiconductors irrelevant.
Two and a half decades later a wave of low-priced Japanese memory
chip exports again threatened a foundering U.S. semiconductor industry.
425
426 CONCLUSION
Why Semiconductors?
The economics of the semiconductor industry has caused it to be at
the forefront of high-technology trade frictions. For one thing, the rela¬
tion between product prices and costs of production is enormously com-
428 CONCLUSION
dations for this supremacy, but it had never explicitly grappled with the
economic implications of this advanced infrastructure, nor was economic
benefit ever the purpose of its construction. U.S. investment in devel¬
oping semiconductor technology was strategic only in the very narrow
sense of the pursuit of qualitative military advantage.
The development of the Japanese semiconductor industry, however,
was shaped by very different policies. Initially, semiconductors were
merely an incidental appendage on a different beast. Through the 1960s
the primary focus for Japanese industrial policy in electronics was the
domestic computer industry. To sell in the Japanese market, American
computer companies were forced into joint ventures with Japanese coun¬
terparts, endured sales ceilings, or accepted other restrictions. By the
early 1970s, however, several U.S. partners of Japanese electronics com¬
panies had dropped out of the computer business. It had become clear
that a frontal assault on the established mainframe computer market
dominated by IBM was not going to work unless Japanese companies
could offer lower prices to offset the American advantages in virtually
all other aspects of the computer business.
By then the general design principles for a commercial business com¬
puter were well understood. The extraordinary decrease in the cost of
computing power continued, primarily due to ever cheaper and more
powerful components rather than design innovation.1 So Japanese pro¬
ducers realized that by manufacturing state-of-the-art chips at lower cost
and incorporating them into their machines, they might be able to com¬
pete in established markets for computer systems.
Meanwhile, the semiconductor manufacturing divisions of these same
Japanese companies faced equally rocky prospects. In the mid-1960s,
when American companies first began to ship computers based on ad¬
vanced chips, the Ministry of International Trade and Industry undertook
a small program to improve Japanese semiconductor technology. Japan’s
first semiconductor memory chips were built as part of a related MITI
project, the development of a high-speed mainframe computer.
But these efforts had not closed the gap with American companies.
Cheap American chips flooded world markets, including Japan, and Jap¬
anese producers complained loudly about American dumping. Despite
1. See Kenneth Flamm, “Technological Advance and Costs: Computers versus Com¬
munications,” in Robert W. Crandall and Kenneth Flamm, eds., Changing the Rules: Tech¬
nological Change, International Competition, and Regulation in Communications (Brook¬
ings, 1989), pp. 16-19.
CONCLUSION 431
stiff trade and investment barriers, including the refusal to allow foreign
producers to establish Japanese subsidiaries, the share of U.S. imports
in Japanese integrated circuit consumption steadily rose, peaking at
35 percent of the market in 1971.
As a further attempt to combat this trend, MITI introduced more
informal means to discourage the use of foreign chips. Imports of ad¬
vanced American calculator and memory chips—to be incorporated into,
and often reexported as, Japanese calculators—were increasing quickly.
Calculator manufacturer Sharp had started the rush to American chips,
and MITI responded by making an example of the company, denying
necessary licenses to allow it to use imported chips. American companies
attempting to recruit Japanese semiconductor executives to help build
their Japanese sales even found MITI lobbying the executives to dissuade
them from breaking ranks.
MITI’s tactics proved successful. Although Japan abolished trade and
investment restrictions in the mid-1970s, the import share of Japanese
chip consumption continued to shrink. Meanwhile, government agencies
funded much larger programs than they had previously to improve Jap¬
anese semiconductor technology. From 1975 to 1980 the government-
owned telephone company sponsored two consecutive development pro¬
grams for advanced semiconductor equipment and devices, the so-called
Very Large Scale Integration (VLSI) projects. In 1976 MITI began its
own four-year VLSI project. After organizing Japanese companies into
research consortia, these projects pumped large amounts of money into
semiconductor R&D. Japanese and American semiconductor companies
spent comparable shares of their sales revenues on R&D between 1976
and 1985, but from 1976 to 1979 the VLSI subsidies added resources half
again the size of the Japanese industry’s own funding of integrated circuit
R&D.
The VLSI projects helped Japanese companies develop expertise in a
new generation of semiconductor production technologies. The key to
American success in semiconductors had been Silicon Valley and its
American counterparts, dense clusters of technical expertise where chip
manufacturers could buy the latest capital goods developed for use in
production systems. Japanese manufacturers hoping to produce better
and cheaper chips than their American competition would need produc¬
tion machinery superior to that used by American producers. When
products developed by the VLSI projects came to market in the 1980s,
Japanese companies began shipping the most advanced and reliable sys-
432 CONCLUSION
terns in key areas of the chip manufacturing process. With first access to
this equipment, they would henceforth have a head start toward produc¬
ing the best chips at the lowest cost.
The next logical step was to invest aggressively in production facilities
that could use the new systems. Through the 1980s, Japanese semicon¬
ductor companies’ ratio of capital spending to revenues far outpaced that
of American companies. Together, the investment in new manufacturing
technology and the capital spending blitz that followed made Japan the
world leader in semiconductor manufacturing. U.S. companies’ share of
world sales peaked in 1975 then plunged while the Japanese share soared.
And Japanese imports, which constituted one-third of Japan’s apparent
integrated circuit consumption in 1974, fell to 12 percent in 1986.
Alarmed at the earliest of these developments, U.S. chip producers
formed an industry association in 1977 and began to complain to their
government about their inability to secure access to Japanese markets
and about Japanese government industrial policies. A few years later they
began making frequent allegations of Japanese dumping in the U.S.
market.
In response to American complaints, MITI reacted in two ways. It
adopted a decidedly lower public profile. For example, the VLSI program
was abruptly shut down in 1980 (although a private sector version contin¬
ued through 1986). This lower profile was aided by the success of the
Japanese effort: producers could stand on their own and government
funds for R&D became relatively less important as Japanese chip pro¬
duction soared on a self-sustaining trajectory. At the same time, however,
the U.S. complaints gave the ministry ample justification for continuing
to provide “guidance” to Japanese chip makers as it attempted to manage
semiconductor trade frictions with America in the 1980s.
In late 1985, as the semiconductor industry sank into a frighteningly
deep downturn, American chip producers urged their government to
respond to the perceived threat from Japan. The government reacted in
two ways. With financial support from the Department of Defense,
Sematech was formed to improve U.S. chip manufacturing. Unlike pre¬
vious Pentagon investments in semiconductor production, Sematech fo¬
cused on the technological and economic health of the infrastructure of
the entire industry, not just on specialized producers and products cater¬
ing to unique needs of the military. Meanwhile, the U.S. government
pressed suits to stop dumping and other trade violations. The result was
ultimately the Semiconductor Trade Arrangement of 1986.
CONCLUSION 433
The trade arrangement had three major features. First, Japan agreed
to a set of pricing floors administered by the U.S. Department of Com¬
merce on exports of DRAMs and EPROMs, and set up strict border
controls to ensure that exports were not being priced under the floors.
Second, Japan agreed to “monitor” an even broader variety of chips,
based on company-specific cost and price data, and “take appropriate
actions” to prevent dumping in export markets. Because of the inherent
difficulty of controlling flows of such an easily transportable commodity
as semiconductors, the appropriate actions evolved into administrative
guidance to companies on production and investment levels. Third, MITI
(in a “secret” side letter) agreed to a numerical benchmark for foreign
market share, and took actions to encourage Japanese electronics man¬
ufacturers to buy more foreign semiconductors.
The price floors, called foreign market values (FMVs), set by the
Commerce Department and the border controls constructed by MITI to
make them stick hit hard. Significant memory chip price differentials
existed between the Japanese and American markets from 1987 through
1989. These differentials put U.S. computer and electronic equipment
producers at a disadvantage because they had to compete against Japa¬
nese companies purchasing identical memory chips at considerably lower
prices. From the standpoint of the aggregate welfare of the world outside
Japan’s borders, the impact of the regional price differentials was notice¬
able but not staggeringly large. In DRAMs, for example, I estimate that
the net welfare impact of the FMVs and border controls was 5 to 8 percent
of what would have been the value of rest-of-world DRAM consumption
in the absence of border controls (see chapter 5).
Moreover, there were clear limits to how tightly markets could be
controlled. Large regional price differentials existed during these years
in the large user “contract” market, which amounted to 70 to 80 percent
of consumption. In the much more freewheeling and entrepeneurial grey
or spot market, however, regional price differentials were transitory (see
chapter 5). The conclusion, perhaps, is that the more diffused, decen¬
tralized, and competitive the market, the tougher it is to swim upstream
434 CONCLUSION
2. Driven by annual growth rates in PC shipments that averaged more than 23 percent
from 1993 to 1995 and rapidly rising semiconductor content in electronic equipment, PC
circuit boards alone accounted for one-third of world consumption in 1994. Lee Gomes,
“Growth in Computer Shipments Slowing,” San Jose Mercury, January 30, 1996; and Ron¬
ald A. Bohn and Mary A. Olsson, “Semiconductors: An Industry in Transition,” Red
Herring, no. 23 (September 1995).
CONCLUSION 435
actions and attitudes that hindered foreign sales. The sanction or toleration
of dubious (from an antitrust perspective) private activities also made it
more difficult for most foreign firms to break into Japanese markets.
With the implementation of the STA, the Japanese official attitude
toward semiconductor imports publicly reversed course. Instead of re¬
moving obvious obstacles only after foreign pressure had been brought
to bear, MITI became a promoter of foreign imports. And the change
extended far beyond the “import now” placards (in English) attached to
luggage carts at Tokyo’s international airport. MITI officials visited users
of chips to spread the new gospel. It supported industry overseas trade
missions, and set up organizations and infrastructure to make it easier
for foreign producers to reach Japanese chip consumers. Many large
companies set, under government pressure, “voluntary” targets for in¬
creasing their use of imported chips. As industrial giant Matsushita’s
executives noted in interviews with the New York Times, “the 1986 trade
agreement between the United States and Japan was instrumental in
prompting the company to consider American chips.”5
Other factors, of course, also explain the increase in the foreign share
of the Japanese chip market from 9 percent in 1986 to almost 30 percent
in 1991. An appreciating yen made foreign chips considerably cheaper.
The quality of American chips improved: by the late 1980s defect and
failure rates for both American and Japanese chips met the standards set
by demanding multinational customers. And (as noted in chapter 5)
Japanese companies seemed to learn how to cut deals with foreign com¬
panies that helped meet their “import share” targets without significantly
changing their production and sourcing patterns.
But some attributions of the causes of the increasing foreign share of
the Japanese market are wrong. It is not true that Japanese companies’
increasing tendancy to use chips that U.S. manufacturers tended to spe¬
cialize in was responsible for the bulk of the increase. An analysis (see
chapter 5) of two different sets of data concluded that increases in the
rate of foreign penetration in different market segments, as opposed to
5. Andrew Pollack, “The Surplus That Wouldn’t Die,” New York Times, February 27,
1996, p. D8. ‘“In 1988 we imported virtually nothing except some semiconductors,’ said
Toshihiko Murota, managing director of Matsushita Communication Industrial Company.
. . . ‘Even the semiconductors,’ he conceded, ‘were imported only because of the 1986
semiconductor trade agreement. Purchasing managers were comfortable buying from Jap¬
anese companies. So Matsushita went over their heads, requiring its division chiefs to come
up with annual import targets.’ ”
CONCLUSION 437
Where Do We Stand?
The concerns that drove U.S. policy when the STA was negotiated in
1986 confront very different realities a decade later, in 1996.
Technological Competition
6. Douglas Dunn, the president and CEO of Philips Electronics N.V. of the Nether¬
lands, was reported to have told a conference in Tokyo that although the agreement was
“aimed at boosting the share of foreign products in general, Japanese customers are pres¬
sured to buy U.S.-made products. Dunn said the share of European semiconductors in
Japan remains at a mere 1 percent [which] shows that the pact has functioned to shut out
third-country suppliers.” AP wire report, February 2, 1996. See also “SIA to Japan: Let’s
Renew Pact,” Electronic Buyers’ News (February 12, 1996), p. 70.
7. These statements are based on unpublished Dataquest estimates of foreign compa¬
nies’ sales in the Japanese market. From 1986 to 1994 U.S. companies’ share rose from
7.9 percent to 15.7 percent, European companies’ from 0.5 percent to 1.1 percent, and
Korean and Taiwanese companies’ from 0.1 percent to 3.4 percent. Dataquest assigns sales
to companies based on the brand name stamped on the chip.
8. For example, when Miin Wu, President of Macronix International, Taiwan’s largest
supplier of nonvolatile memory chips, was asked in late 1995 if the STA should be allowed
to lapse, he replied: “If every country opens up its market for people to freely compete,
there’s no need for any agreements. Right now, the Japanese believe they are buying enough
from overseas, so there’s no need for an agreement. We should look at the facts, and
whether or not Japan is really doing that. If things go the wrong way and Japan closes its
door, then I’m sure the U.S. government will come back again.” “Plain Talk On What’s
Ahead for Taiwan’s Chip Business,” Electronic Buyers’ News (January 2, 1996), p. T2.
438 CONCLUSION
12. Taro Okabe, “Semiconductor Industry Research Institute Resolves Policy Frame¬
work,” Nikkei Microdevices (December 1994), pp. 120-21.
13. “Ten Japanese Companies Together Try to Develop Semiconductor Production
Equipment ” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, July 8, 1995, pp. 1, 9.
14. Emi Yokota, “Chip Makers Preparing to Form United Front,’” Ekonomisuto, Oc¬
tober 31, 1995, p. 42.
15. “Ministry of Education Seeks Practical Education in Semiconductors,” Nihon Kei¬
zai Shimbun, September 4, 1995, p. 17.
16. “Research On State-of-the-Art Technology with the Cooperation of Businesses and
Universities,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, October 2, 1995, p. 17.
440 CONCLUSION
17. Okabe, “Semiconductor Industry Research Institute.” The ten companies are
NEC, Toshiba, Hitachi, Fujitsu, Mitsubishi, Matsushita, Oki, Sanyo, Sharp, and Sony.
See also “Semiconductor Makers to Jointly Develop Advanced Equipment,” August 23,
1995, in Foreign Broadcast Information Service, Pacific Rim Economic Review: Japan,
August 24, 1995.
18. Okabe, “Semiconductor Industry Research Institute”; Asahi Shimbun, October
22, 1995, p. 3; and unpublished Semi photographic slides, April 1996.
19. David Lammers, “Japanese May Form Equipment Consortium,” Electronic Engi¬
neering Times, July 17, 1995, p. 132; and “Ten Japanese Companies.”
20. “Electronic Firms Form Alliance,” AP wire story, February 13, 1996; Peter N.
Dunn, “Japanese R&D Co-ops Proliferate; Some Confusion over Who Does What,” Solid
State Technology, April 1996, pp. 58, 61; and Hara, “Japanese Set 12-inch.”
21. One Japanese executive has said that SELETE is “for tomorrow’s real business
while ASET is for the primary technology development needed in the next century.” Hara,
“Japanese Set 12-inch.”
CONCLUSION 441
zation may be reconsidering affiliations with foreign-based companies. The U.S. semicon¬
ductor industry, including Sematech, and the U.S. government supported a proposal for a
joint venture between Japan’s Canon and the U.S.-owned Silicon Valley Group to develop
and produce semiconductor lithography equipment, but negotiations were not successful.
26. References to the occasional public discussion of this issue may be found in General
Accounting Office, International Trade: U.S. Business Access to Certain Foreign State-of-
the-Art Technology, GAO/NSIAD 91-278 (September 1991), p. 21.
27. A concise summary of U.S. computer industry thinking at the time may be found
in National Research Council, Computer Science and Technology Board, Keeping the U.S.
Computer Industry Competitive: Defining the Agenda (Washington: National Academy
Press, 1990), chap. 2.
CONCLUSION 443
30. See Mark LaPedus, “5-Year DRAM Deals,” Electronic Buyers’ News, December
18, 1995, p. 1.
31. See for example, Don Clark, “In the Hot World of Chips, Tradition Melts,” Wall
Street Journal, October 30, 1995, p. B4; and Mark LaPedus, “HP May Join Taiwan Ven¬
ture,” Electronic Buyers’ News, January 8, 1996, p. 12. One pronounced trend in the
semiconductor world has been for so-called fabless semiconductor companies—design
houses that contract with outside foundries to manufacture their designs—to invest in the
foundries to ensure the availability of capacity to manufacture their products. Examples in
1994-95 include disk controller producers Adaptec and Opti; graphics controller companies
S3, Cirrus Logic, Trident, and Oak; specialized memory producers Alliance and Lanstar;
and programmable logic makers Actel, Altera, Lattice, and Xilinx. See Mark LaPedus,
“Alliance, S3 Sign Fab Deal—To Build Foundry in Taiwan with UMC,” Electronic Buyers’
News, July 17, 1995, p. 1; Ismini Scouras, “Lanstar Lines Up DRAM Fab,” Electronic
Buyers’ News, February 12, 1996, p. 1; “Fabless Deals,” Fabless Semiconductor Associa¬
tion, downloaded April 1996; and Dataquest, “The Fab Four,” on-line abstract, Data-
qauest, October 1995.
32. Recent announcements include joint ventures to build DRAM production facilities
in the United States by partnerships between Siemens and Motorola, Toshiba and IBM,
and Texas Instruments and Hitachi. Motorola is also considering joining an existing three-way
IBM-Siemens-Toshiba R&D effort to work on technology for 1 gigabit DRAMs. See Clark,
“In the Hot World of Chips”; Darrell Dunn and Mark Hachman, “Motorola Jumps into
DRAM Fray,” Electronic Buyers’ News, October 30, 1995, p. 3; and Loring Wirbel, “TI,
Hitachi Tip Twinstar Setup,” Electronic Engineering Times, January 23, 1995, p. 92.
CONCLUSION 445
cut production and seal its borders. When protests erupted and the gov¬
ernments were forced to abandon production controls, sticking to the
objectives of the arrangement meant driving the controls underground,
in essence by tolerating private cartel-like behavior.
The contradictions built into these policies were ultimately resolved
when buoyant demand and high chip prices between 1992 and 1995 made
price floors irrelevant. Demand was so strong, in fact, that for the second
time in the history of the industry the average cost of a bit of memory
increased slightly in 1993. Memory costs on average seemed to be drop¬
ping at half the historical rate.
This is unlikely to continue. According to the U.S. semiconductor
industry’s projections for the next fifteen years, the cost of producing a
bit of memory will decrease about 26 percent a year, about halfway
between the earlier trend and the record of the early 1990s.33 Further¬
more, long-standing historical patterns are unlikely to have abruptly
ended for the semiconductor industry. The sustained expansion of the
early 1990s could not continue forever, and a cyclical plunge into weak
demand, excess supply, and sharply dropping prices was virtually inevi¬
table. Indeed, in early 1996 the industry seemed poised for just such a
decline.
When downturns come, the rules for semiconductor pricing will again
become an issue. American producers will likely urge limits on how low
import prices can plunge and will launch antidumping cases to accomplish
this end. Chip users will protest, with considerable justification, that the
antidumping laws establish price floors that lack a sound economic basis
and are biased against foreign producers (see chapter 6). Unless (as in
1986) some arrangement is negotiated that effectively sets a global floor
on chip prices (rather than a U.S. floor), U.S. chip users will be tempted
to move their manufacturing operations to take advantage of lower prices
outside the United States. And if a worldwide undertaking to raise global
chip prices uniformly is sanctioned by government actions, the paradox
of U.S. trade policy facilitating the creation of the very cartel-like struc¬
ture that has been the principal threat driving other trade, competition,
and technology policies will unfold.
33. This is the implicit annual rate of decline calculated from Semiconductor Industry
Association, The National Technology Roadmap for Semiconductors (San Jose, Calif.:
1994), p. 11.
446 CONCLUSION
Market Access
From the vantage point of early 1996, the pressure exerted to gain
greater access to the Japanese market has paid off. The target of
20 percent market share written into the trade arrangements of 1986 and
1991 today seems of historical interest only as the foreign share of the
Japanese market approaches 30 percent.
But there was a real history of Japanese discrimination against foreign
products. When, despite considerable obstacles, foreigners established
initial relationships with Japanese customers in the late 1960s and early
1970s, the Japanese government actively worked to disrupt them. The all-
important long-term relationships were broken up. Thus, calls in recent
years for “affirmative action” to assist foreign companies in gaining easier
access to the Japanese market resonated in American ears: the barriers
in Japan appear higher than elsewhere, and the ladders thrown up to
scale them were deliberately smashed by the state.
Given the current situation, however, is it now time to declare what
seems mainly historical to have been resolved? One is tempted to say
yes. Today, all seems well. Under continuing political urging, a strong
web of relationships between foreign and Japanese companies has been
spun. It is hard to see how this network can be dissolved when, by most
accounts, it seems to benefit both sides.
Still, some reservations must be expressed. First, much of the discus¬
sion of the continuing growth in strategic alliances between Japanese and
foreign semiconductor firms seems to overstate the case. Precise and
consistent definitions of what a strategic alliance is are critical in deter¬
mining trends, and little such consistency exists. Collaborations between
a foreign supplier and a Japanese customer resulting in the incoporation
of a foreign chip into the design of a Japanese product certainly seem to
have increased greatly in the past decade.34 But because these collabo¬
rations may not extend beyond production of a very specific product, it
is not clear whether they should be counted as strategic alliances.
Some data portray a volatile process of alliance formation. One source
shows that strategic partnerships between U.S. firms and Japanese chip
makers doubled in the years just before 1987 then decreased sharply in
34. See Electronics Industry Association of Japan, Semiconductor Facts 1995 (Wash¬
ington, 1995), p. 4-1.
CONCLUSION 447
1989 and 1990.35 Other data show that after rising sharply (from 3 in 1980
to a peak of 120 in 1987) new Japanese semiconductor alliances have
fluctuated considerably from year to year. From 1985 through 1994, ac¬
cording to industry consulting firm Dataquest, Japanese companies
formed new semiconductor alliances with other companies an average of
86 times a year. In 1993 the number sank to 71, in 1994 it was 99, and in
1995 it dropped to 83.36
A second cause for concern is the potential impact of a sharp cyclical
decline in the semiconductor market. The major Japanese producers
would be faced with the choice of letting machines and men stand idle
(or with even greater difficulty, reducing their workforce) or cutting back
on purchases of semiconductors from outside vendors and using excess
internal capacity to substitute for purchased parts. When demand is high
and capacity fully utilized, as it has been for the past four years, this has
not been an issue. In slack times there will be a strong economic incentive
to switch to producing products internally. Although proprietary micro¬
processors and custom logic designs may not be easily switched to internal
production lines, there are other chips procured from foreign compa¬
nies—flash memories, static memories, DRAMs, and ASICs, for exam¬
ple—that are not going to be difficult to switch.
Thus it seems safe to predict that in a serious industry downturn, many
alliances with outside vendors—strategic and nonstrategic—that are as¬
sociated with purchases of foreign chips will be put under stress, perhaps
to the breaking point. Although the economic logic driving such a con¬
traction in foreign sales is readily apparent, foreign complaints and re¬
newed trade friction are a very predictable consequence.
Third, the current absence of severe complaints over Japanese prac¬
tices that impede foreign access to the Japanese market does not reflect
a more general consensus that access as a whole is no longer an issue.
Significant disputes exist in other parts of the Japanese economy. The
key point for the semiconductor industry is that rather than pointing to
formal trade barriers, most of the complaints by foreign businesses relate
35. See National Research Council, U. S.-Japan Strategic Alliances in the Semiconductor
Industry (Washington: National Academy Press, 1992) p. 14.
36. Sheridan Tatsuno, “Beyond the Chip Wars: The Boom in Japanese Semiconductor
Alliances,” Venture Japan, vol. 1, no. 2 (1988), pp. 24-25; Dataquest, “1995 Japanese
Semiconductor Alliances: A Slowdown,” on-line abstract, Dataquest, January 1996; and
“Japanese Semiconductor Alliances Taper Off in 1995,” on-line research highlight, March
1996. Dataquest has revised the 1987 peak downward to 117.
448 CONCLUSION
37. See chapter 7. In recent years, MITI has responded to foreign grievances about
anticompetitive practices by referring the complainant to the Japan Fair Trade Commission,
historically an ineffectual arm of the government. MITI recently displayed its power even
within the JFTC’s nominal sphere of antitrust enforcement by issuing an unprecedented
notice to auto dealerships requesting “information about possible violations of the Anti-
monopoly Law.” “Please Tell Us about Violation of an Antimonopoly Law,” Nikkei Sangyo
Shimbun, November 7, 1995, p. 14.
CONCLUSION 449
38. “Collision Foreseen over Semiconductor Accord,” Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Novem¬
ber 3, 1995, p. 3.
39. In early 1996 chief U.S. trade negotiator Ira Shapiro declared to a San Francisco
business conference that the United States would no longer seek numerical targets
in semiconductors from Japan. Newsbyte News Network, “Japan Technology Newsbriefs
3/1/96” (on-line news feed), March 1, 1996.
CONCLUSION 451
40. In some respects the industry has become less globalized. In 1970 U.S. and Japanese
firms produced less than 75 percent of world output and European companies the balance.
The sharp decline in the European industry is as notable as the rise of East Asia. For an
analysis of European decline, see Kenneth Flamm, “Semiconductors,” in Gary Clyde
Hufbauer, ed., Europe 1992: An American Perspective (Brookings, 1990), pp. 225-92.
452 CONCLUSION
41. For a useful analysis, see F. M. Scherer, Competition Policies for an Integrated
World Economy (Brookings, 1994). As Keio University professor Jiro Tamura comments
in this book (after noting that Japanese antitrust law is modeled on U.S. law), Japan’s
“discrepancy in antimonopoly activity [with the United States and Europe] is based less on
the law itself than on the weakness of the enforcement of the law” (pp. 112-13).
42. MITI, “Comment on the Announcement of the Market Share of Foreign-based
Semiconductors,” press release, Tokyo, March 19, 1996.
CONCLUSION 453
sures to keep the new factories running, prices are likely to come down
steeply in a recession. There will almost certainly be accusations of unfair
competition, acute trade frictions, and dumping cases. What are still
largely nationally defined standards (subject to some loose guidance from
the GATT) governing fair values for imports will be used to punish
offending exporters. Within Japan at least some of the foreign semicon¬
ductors so “firmly incorporated as indispensable products” are likely to
prove dispensable as electronics producers consider using idle factories
to make products previously purchased from outside. If, along with the
STA, reliable data on foreign chip purchases disappear, bitter disputes
over what precisely is going on in the Japanese market are likely to erupt.
In the absence of some stipulated facts, disputes over what is happening
will add additional fuel to a furor over why it might be happening.
This brings up some of the potentially positive elements the STA has
contributed to the dialogue on semiconductor trade issues. Gathering
some agreed upon data on what has been a contentious issue for thirty
years serves one very useful purpose. Facts prevent some unhappy com¬
panies from complaining to their government that their experiences are
typical of a broader trend when they are not. Certainly, well understood
data have permitted Japan to argue without dispute that what was once
a problem is one no longer. Without such facts, additional disagreement
is likely whenever trade issues periodically erupt—as they surely will in
this boom and bust industry.
A second positive contribution of the STA is the establishment of a
forum to facilitate speedy resolution of disputes. In the next downturn,
both market access and dumping will certainly be issues. An agreed upon
format for quickly talking about them can avoid time-consuming, acri¬
monious, and possibly inconclusive debates over how to structure talks
and who is to sit at the table.
Third, from the U.S. perspective the STA has illuminated shadowy
corners of the Japanese electronics industry. In an environment of mis¬
trust built by decades of behind-the-scenes exclusionary maneuvering,
the regular dialogue created by the STA has built confidence in the
United States that attitudes have indeed changed. Questions can easily
be asked and answers given. The private industrial relationships that have
now been constructed may be able to sustain the atmosphere of openness
and cooperation. But given the signs of continued official tolerance of
legally dubious insider relationships in at least a few Japanese industries,
there is some justification for U.S. chip companies’ worries that if the
454 CONCLUSION
lights go out, they will again be in the dark, on the outside. A continuing,
regular channel for discussion and consultation could dispel much of the
suspicion that might otherwise poison relations.
How, then, can we take the best features of a decade’s experience with
semiconductor trade policy, eliminate the negative elements, and build a
world trading system in microelectronics that contributes to a prosperous,
competitive, and technologically innovative global industry? One ap¬
proach would be to extract bits and pieces of ideas already under discus¬
sion by government and industry and combine them in what might be
called the Global Semiconductor Conference (GSC).
to entry into national markets when they are identified in an agreed upon
fashion.
The work of the GSC would be to add the detail needed to make these
general rules into practical ones for competitive international semicon¬
ductor markets. In the future the agenda for the GSC might include other
difficult issues. Given that national tests for dumping and other pros¬
cribed trade practices in the semiconductor industry vary considerably,
as do remedies, and can still be manipulated to create disadvantages for
foreign competitors selling in national markets, international harmoni¬
zation of procedures is needed to define the rules of the road for com¬
petition. Current antidumping laws may be adequate for cement or pasta,
but they do not address important features of the semiconductor industry
and other high-technology industries. Procedures that take into account
sunk R&D costs, economies of scale, and learning curves in an econom¬
ically defensible way are needed.
Similarly, an R&D and technology group within the GSC could en¬
courage greater cooperation on government-funded R&D programs to
increase the productivity of global investments in basic microelectronics
research and technology. A standards group of the GSC could define a
framework to facilitate harmonization of international standards for de¬
sign, manufacturing, equipment, and materials in the semiconductor in¬
dustry, when there was broad agreement that uniform standards might
be useful.
Finally, the difficult question of harmonization of antitrust rules and
their enforcement is probably best addressed in small pieces. By working
on this question within the restricted venue of the semiconductor indus¬
try, some experience useful to broader rules would likely be accumulated.
In a sense, the semiconductor industry is already serving as such a labora¬
tory, since the ongoing discussion of dumping and of antidumping remedies
is inextricably linked to theories of predation and antitrust. A sensible way
to deal with accusations of dumping in semiconductors will necessarily be
part of a sensible approach to dealing with questions about anticompetitive
practices and the role governments play in these practices.
tent and reliable data that would permit analytical discussion of market
access issues and some continuing framework that would permit resolu¬
tion of trade and access issues as they arise. Both could contribute to the
quest for an open, competitive world market in semiconductors.
Japan also seemed to have two primary demands in early f996. It
wished to replace a bilateral agreement with a multilateral process and
wanted no numerical targets or benchmarks. These demands also seemed
consistent with construction of an open, competitive trading system.
If Japan and the United States were to simply announce the formation
of a multilateral Global Semiconductor Conference to begin operation
just as the 1991 STA expired, all four objectives could be accomodated.
The GSC would initially include a commitment to collect national data
needed to evaluate market transparency and a framework for timely
consultations on trade, investment, technology, or market access issues
that are raised by GSC members. (As founding members and equal
partners in this enterprise, Japan and the United States would be agreeing
to provide data to each other and react to requests for consultation with
equal alacrity.) The GSC would be open to membership by all nations
that pledged to respect the ground rules established at its foundation.
To tackle an ambitious agenda that might include analyses of pricing
practices, market access, technology programs, and technical standards
clearly will require significant participation and support from industry.
Just as clearly, it will require governments to participate. It is unthinkable
that American semiconductor producers could sit down with foreign
semiconductor producers and discuss pricing, markets, standards, and
cooperative R&D efforts without the U.S. government present. From
the perspective of a user industry, the meeting might seem to be the
perfect cover for the creation of a supplier cartel. At a minimum some
U.S. government oversight would be absolutely necessary to guarantee
that user industry interests are respected (and antitrust suits against
producers avoided).
In addition, most of the issues on the agenda would involve govern¬
ment responsibilities, and companies have no power to cut deals over
these matters. Antitrust rules, dumping, and access to publicly funded
technology programs are areas where governments make policy, not com¬
panies. A framework with industry-government meetings on technical
matters that paralleled government-to-government negotiations over pol¬
icy would need to be constructed.
CONCLUSION 457
Mismanaged Trade?
If one looks only at the Semiconductor Trade Arrangements of 1986
and 1991, simple but contradictory answers to the question posed in
the title to this book spring to mind. Overall, the system of pricing
floors established under the STA probably worked to the net disadvan¬
tage of U.S. interests, and the cartel-like structures fostered by MITI
in implementing what Japan perceived to be its objectives only made
the situation more difficult. There was—and is—no way to set effective
price floors for semiconductors that ultimately would not penalize U.S.
user industries.
The market access the STA opened up has been a different story.
There was a long history of formal and informal barriers that the STA
helped tear down.
At a deeper level, two lessons emerge from trade frictions with Japan
in semiconductors. One is that contradictions between tactical compro¬
mises and strategic, long-run principles in U.S. trade policy ultimately
come home to roost. Having failed to achieve functional access to the
Japanese market in the mid-1970s after formal trade barriers were re¬
moved, the United States essentially decided to use the informal system
of MITI guidance and government collaboration with an industrial inner
circle to achieve an outcome that at least resembled what it thought real
systemic reform might have accomplished. Paradoxically, this decision
probably strengthened what had been waning MITI influence in the Jap¬
anese semiconductor industry. It also enabled Japan to position itself as
458 CONCLUSION
461
462 INDEX
Dynamic random access memory (DRAM) value of the dollar, 247nil; value of the
products: 64K: 64K DRAM wars (1981- yen, 203, 393, 436; venture capital, 24-
83), 148-58; controls and guidance, 160; 25; welfare issues, 381, 382, 412-14, 416,
development, 93-94, 99; dumping, 166, 418, 433, 458-49. See also Learning
167, 168-69, 172, 227; pricing and economies; Trade
production, 160, 162, 168-69, 227, 235/, EECA. See European Electronic
247, 249/, 391; production, 196, 262, Component Manufacturers Association
391; Semiconductor Trade Arrangement EEPROMs. See Electronically erasable
and, 297-301; yield, 261/ programmable read-only memory chips
Dynamic random access memory (DRAM) El A. See Electronics Industries
products: 256K: controls and guidance, Association
175, 177, 187, 192, 198, 229-30; Electrical Communications Laboratory
development, 99, 116; dumping, 160, (ECL), 40
168, 169-70, 173, 176; prices, 169-70, Electronically erasable programmable
187, 203, 223, 244, 245-46, 247/, 250-51, read-only memory chips (EEPROMs),
269, 387; production, 183-84, 192, 196, 176
198, 209/7152, 262, 269, 352, 353; Electronic Arrays, 144
Semiconductor Trade Arrangement and, Electronic components: boom of 1988,
160, 177, 269, 297-301; shortages, 203- 201; in Europe, 25; Japanese regulation,
04 53; ranking of industry, 13, 375-76;
Dynamic random access memory (DRAM) sales, 18n20; in the United States, 24,
products: 1M: controls and guidance, 129, 425
182, 192, 193, 198, 215-16; costs, 401- Electronics, consumer: development, 18;
OS; demand, 341-43, 344; development, integrated chips in, 139; in Japan, 47,
96, 99, 116, 192; dumping, 356-58; 49, 52-53, 54, 60, 68, 125, 133, 431; in
learning curves and economies, 337-38, the United States, 53, 129. See also
400-401; prices, 212-16, 221-23, 245, Calculators; Television and radio
246/, 248/, 249/128, 251, 269, 270/, 354- Electronics Industries Association (EIA:
56, 386-87, 398-99; production, 182, U.S.), 128, 129
192, 193, 198, 200, 212-13, 215, 220, Electronics Industries Association of
262, 269, 386-87, 396-97, 398-99; Japan, 87, 135/725 , 390
shortages, 200, 203-04, 208«148, 213; Electronics Industry Council, 53
Strategic Trade Arrangement and, 298- Electronics Industry Promotion Law
301 (Denshinho). See Law on Temporary
Dynamic random access memory (DRAM) Measures for Promoting the Electronics
products: miscellaneous products; 1 Industry
gigabit, 438; IK, 99/7190; 4K, 99/7190; Electrotechnical Laboratory (ETL). See
16K, 98-99, 139-40, 141, 142, 144, Ministry of International Trade and
232/78 , 352/768 ; 4M, 98/7189, 217, 222- Industry
23; 16M, 98/7189; 256M, 314 Emerson, 129
Emitter coupled logic (ECL), 176
ECL. See Electrical Communications Erasable programmable read only memory
Laboratory; Emitter coupled logic (EPROM): 128K, 254, 255/; 256K, 166,
Economic issues: cartels, 382, 384-24, 254, 255/; 512K, 269, 271/; 1M, 269,
405-17, 418, 443; contract pricing, 294- 271/; dumping cases, 160, 162, 170, 173,
301; cost of manufacture, 402; dumping, 174, 176, 189; prices, 166, 174, 210-11,
305-71; economies of scale, 7, 313; 239, 241, 253-55, 265-66, 269, 271,
effects on demand, 342; employment, 278n51; production and production
23/, 24, 47-48; externalities, 380, controls, 182, 198, 201, 239/, 262, 263/,
383/718; forward pricing, 309-10, 314, 264/, 265-66; role in semiconductor
316-17, 318, 320, 321, 322, 327-28; industry, 383; supply and demand, 231,
government policies and support, 3, 256-66, 278-79, 283, 293
380-81; quality control, 145//59; high- Esaki, Leo, 45/724
technology industries, 458; recessions, ETL. See Electrotechnical Laboratory
162, 167, 205; semiconductor and chip Europe: acquisition of solid-state
industry, 7, 17, 38; subsidies, 383-424; electronics, 18; computer industry, 25-
464 INDEX
OCDM. See Office of Civil and Defense 325«32, 334-36, 337n48, 346-47, 356,
Mobilization 359-65, 407-09; pricing and
OECD. See Organization for Economic profitability, 314-17, 318, 320-21, 322-
Cooperation and Development 28, 335, 345, 347, 352, 371; processes
Office of Civil and Defense Mobilization and timing, 13, 213, 231-32, 261-62,
(OCDM), 128 316« 19, 342-43, 409//56; production
Oki Electric, 144, 172, 183, 277, 391 alliances, 446-47; product life cycle,
computer manufacturing, 96; supplier to 313-58; quantities produced, 238/, 239/,
NTT, 91; Ultra Advanced Computer 260-66, 272-73; research and
Technology Research Association, 81, development in, 13, 147, 31-32, 91-92,
86, 94; Very High Speed Computer 200; silicon and memory chips, 62/x75,
Systems, 61-62 200; technological advances and
Okinawa, 88, 131«10 transfers, 9, 91-92, 94, 331-32, 377,
Okura Group, 135 431-32; testing, 232, 236, 295, 333-34,
Organization for Economic Cooperation 345, 402; transistors, 45; very large scale
and Development (OECD), 80 integration equipment manufacturers,
Osaka Titanium Company (OTC), 110, 96, 98/r 189, 431; yields, 198, 200, 258-
120-21, 122, 123 61, 295, 314, 320, 322, 323, 329, 330-31,
OTC. See Osaka Titanium Company 333-34, 339, 341, 343«60, 402. See also
Manufacturing processes
Pacific Semiconductor, 31, 57-58 Purchasing and sales: authorized
Parkinson, Joseph, 181 distributors, 233, 234; contract, spot,
Patents and licensing: licensing and gray market sales, 141-42, 143, 161,
agreements, 129; “patent war” in Japan, 180, 184, 209-10, 221, 230, 233-36, 243,
68-70; royalties, 71; semiconductor 244, 248-52, 269, 292-301, 443-44;
manufacture, 378; technology transfers, demand, 236, 240, 288, 289, 291-92,
42-44, 56-57, 92, 107, 109, 378; LVSI 293, 312, 334, 341-44, 365-71, 387, 388,
projects, 107, 109, 116, 117t. See also 391, 426; domestic versus foreign
Semiconductor Trade Arrangement products, 394—95; original equipment
Pattern Information Processing System manufacturers (OEMs), 232-33, 235-
(PIPS), 82 36, 295-301; pricing, 233, 234, 236-54;
Philco, 33 “pulls,” 233; quantity commitments,
Philips NV, 57, 129 235-36; regional and country
“Pi" rule. See Dynamic random access differentials, 242-54, 259-60, 272, 293;
memory semiconductor chips, 2, 8; supplies,
Political issues: Japanese semiconductor 247n27, 254, 256-66, 272, 295; term of
and computer industry, 27, 79-80, 84- contracts, 294-301; tying arrangements,
85, 94, 167/717, 283, 284; Japanese trade 243-44; volume prices, 244/722;
policies, 130, 144, 166, 172«34, 373n3; warranting, 233. See also Dumping;
Semiconductor Trade Arrangement, Dynamic random access memory
230-31, 283, 284, 356; U.S. (DRAM) prices
semiconductor and computer industry, Purdue University, 30«32
27-30, 283, 284
Polypropylene, 394 R&D. See Research and development
Prices. See Dynamic random access Radar, 29-30
memory; Erasable programmable read Radio. See Television and radio
only memories; Semiconductor Trade Rapoport, Carla, 176
Arrangement; Semiconductor industry; Rashomon (film), 79
Trade Raytheon, 33, 57
Production processes: capacity constraints, RCA: development of solid-state
313, 318, 320, 321, 322, 323, 339; control electronics, 18, 31, 33, 36; technology
of, 195-201, 203, 213, 434-35; cost, 9, transfer, 42-43; trade policies, 129
305, 308-09, 310, 312, 315, 319, 320-21, RCA Victor, 129
322-28, 335, 344-49, 352, 402-05, 427- Reagan (Ronald) administration, 153, 187,
28, 445; labor in, 13; packaging, 296- 188
301; plant capacity, 315, 317, 323/731, Regency Corporation, 45
INDEX 469
Remington Rand, 129 158, 185-87, 223, 232, 254«33, 283, 316,
Research and development (R&D): cost 373-74, 380, 398-405, 441; cyclical
accounting, 311-12; economies of scale, nature, 16-17, 151-52, 157-58, 240-41,
14-17; General Agreement on Tariffs 312, 356, 382-83, 428, 429, 447;
and Trade and, 3n4; government- economic issues and, 427-29, 447-48,
industry collaborations, 59, 80-85, 428- 452-53; foreign sales, 15; High
29, 458; investment and costs, 7, 11-13, Technology Working Group (HTWG),
14/, 25, 313-14, 315, 428-29, 458; 153-58; history, 8, 18, 49, 429;
semiconductor industry, 312 investment in, 7, 376-77, 384-85; market
Research and development, Japan: 3.5 shares, 20-21, 449; memory chips, 8;
generation program, 80-81, 83, 93, 111; models, 307-71, 372-424; production, 7,
Dendenkosha Information-Processing 313; as a strategic industry, 372-82;
System (DIPS), 93; electron-beam (E- technology and industrial structure, 7-
beam) writing systems, 110, 111; 17, 377; subsidies, 413-14, 428-29;
femtosecond technology, 439; funding, supply and demand, 231-36; end users,
92-93, 102, 103/, 111—19; joint research 2. See also Dumping; Dynamic random
labs, 113; as percent of sales, 12-13; access memory; Integrated circuits;
Pattern Information Processing System Manufacturing processes; Research and
project, 82-83; role of government, 45, Development; Semiconductor Trade
112«225; subsidies, funding, and Arrangement; Silicon chips; Trade;
incentives, 54, 60, 61-65, 66-68, 81, 96- Transistors
98, 111-13, 116-17, 125-26, 152, 441; Semiconductor Industry Association
transfer of technology, 102, 103, 109-10, (SIA): formation, 138, 432;
116, 119; VLSI programs, 94-113, 116, investigations and, 139, 140-41;
125, 431 responses to competition, 147, 164, 216-
Research and development, U.S.: funding, 17, 432; section 301 complaint, 158, 165.
27-30, 117//234, 147-48, 429; joint See also Trade, U.S.
ventures, 147-48; tax credits for, 147; Semiconductor industry, Europe. See
technology transfers, 18, 31-32, 41-44, Europe
57. See also Semiconductor Semiconductor industry, Japan: 1950s, 40-
Manufacturing Technology consortium 49, 128; 1960s, 39, 49-72, 124, 125,
Ricoh, 72 382-83, 426, 430; 1970s, 39-40, 72-116,
Rigaku Electronics, 110 124-25, 137-40, 141, 143, 144, 145, 390,
Rogers, T. J., 217-188 435; 1980s, 116-24, 125, 146, 147-58,
162-226, 288, 382-83, 385, 387-98,
Sadao Inoue, 186 426-27, 435, 444; 1990s, 283, 286-87,
Samsung: DRAM production and sales, 288-92, 438-54; competition and, 124-
168, 212, 221, 226, 443n28; dumping 26, 153, 128-58, 383, 431; cooperation
and, 225, 226; growth, 222; Intel and, and collusion within the industry, 6,
352«68; NEC and, 290-91; U.S. 107-13, 142, 163-65, 168, 186-87, 195,
distributors, 300-01 204-08, 214-15, 219-20, 230, 279, 383,
Sanyo, 129 385-86, 387-98, 417, 448-49; “Den-
SBFC. See Small Business Finance Den” suppliers, 91, 92; government
Corporation policies and strategies, 5-6, 27, 39-40,
SEH. See Shin Etsu Handotai 48, 52, 80-81, 113-19, 124, 125, 160-61,
Selete. See Semiconductor Leading Edge 385-86, 418, 430, 448; growth, 39-52,
Technologies Inc. 99, 100, 113, 120-21; investment in, 15-
Sematech. See Semiconductor 16, 39, 57, 65, 80-81, 87, 122-23, 124,
Manufacturing Technology consortium 128, 138, 163, 166, 193-95, 202-08, 215,
Semiconductor industry: 1950s, 128-32; 434-35; joint ventures, 56-57, 60-61,
1960s, 132-36, 382-83, 425; 1970s, 73, 68-70, 122; liberalization of, 73-90, 93,
77, 136-42; 1980s, 142-58, 157-61, 162- 94, 119, 124, 125, 130, 137, 390; market
63, 192-201, 203, 207, 212, 222, 234-35, share, 20/, 21-24, 77-79, 148-49, 280,
234-54, 272, 292, 382-83, 425-26, 432; 451; production in U.S., 22, 144;
1990s, 223, 289«68, 292, 427, 434, 435, products, 23, 45«24, 71, 99, 392; quality
445; competition in, 124, 147, 148, 153, issues, 145; regulations, 53, 125;
470 INDEX
technology transfer, 41-44, 124; 188-91, 224; foreign market values, 177,
transistors, 49-52. See also Dumping; 180, 191, 211, 213-14, 223-24, 228, 306,
Ministry of International Trade and 307-08, 433-34, 450-51; general
Industry; Research and development, description, 1; Japanese views of, 175,
Japan; Semiconductor Trade 436; market shares, 170, 171, 172, 173—
Arrangement; Trade, Japan 74, 175, 188, 206, 229, 279-92, 293,
Semiconductor Industry Research Institute 435-37, 446-49, 450, 452, 457;
of Japan (SIRIJ), 439-41 monitoring and forecasting, 175-201,
Semiconductor industry, U.S.: 1960s, 132, 203, 223-24, 228, 229-30, 243, 252,
136-37, 382-83, 425, 426-27; 1970s, 272, 281-82, 283-84, 292, 306, 356, 388,
136-37, 141-46, 430; 1980s, 146, 147-58, 434, 444-45, 453, 457-58; patents, 228;
162-226, 382-83, 425-26, 442; 1990s, prices, 171-72, 174, 175-80, 189-90,
283, 372, 437-54, 455-59; captive and 241nl9, 242-43, 297-304, 396;
merchant producers, 20-21, 24; profitability, 204-08, 302, 307-08; public
competition, 6, 15, 88-90, 111, 128-58, policy and, 1-6, 38; regional welfare,
373-74, 383, 405-17, 429, 437, 442, 443, 272-78, 293; renewal and renegotiation,
451-52; fabless companies, 23, 444n31; 223-26, 280-81, 306, 434, 449-50; side
foreign sales, 15; foreign subsidiaries letters, 170, 173-74, 176, 178, 229, 279-
and contractors, 136-37; government 92, 433; third-country markets, 160, 174,
policies and strategies, 27-38, 153, 163, 176, 178-79, 180, 183, 185, 188, 190,
373-74, 382-424, 429-30; investment in, 224, 229, 243, 292. See also Dumping
15-16, 144«51; joint ventures, 430, 444; Sharp: calculators, 68rc86, 72, 75, 431;
market share, 20f, 21-24, 279-92, 437- DRAM production and sales, 142«45;
38, 446-49, 451; products, 23, 71, 72- joint ventures, 86, 95nl80; North
73, 278n51, 375«5, 389; quality issues, American Rockwell and, 72; Texas
145-46; research and development, 12- Instruments and, 69
13; sales and trade issues, 2, 18n20, 73- Shiba Electric, 66
74, 132, 145, 216; as strategic industry, Shin Etsu, 110
372-80, 405, 429-30; subsidies for, 380, Shin Etsu Handotai (SEH), 120, 123
405-17, 429; transistors, 49-52; Very Shockley, William, 30
High Speed Integrated Circuit program, SI A. See Semiconductor Industry
37-38. See also Semiconductor Trade Assoication
Arrangement Side letters. See Letters, side
Semiconductor Leading Edge Technologies Siemens, 222
Inc. (Selete), 440 Signetics, 36, 89
Semiconductor Manufacturing Technology Silicon and memory chips: “bi” rule, 240;
consortium (Sematech), 38, 278«52, costs, 9, 16, 50-51, 240, 337n47, 343,
379, 426, 432, 438-39, 440-41 345, 393n29, 402; crossover point, 223;
Semiconductor Research Consortium die shrinks, 260n39, 331; economies of
(SRC), 440 scale, 14-17; flash memory chips, 279;
Semiconductor Research Cooperative, 147 integrated circuits, 8; lifespan, 11;
Semiconductors. See Dynamic random microprocessor performance, 8«7; prices
access memory; Integrated circuits; of, 7, 317; production, 62«75, 200, 241,
Transistors 260-61, 377-78, 402; product lives, 7;
Semiconductor Technology Academia purchase and sales, 392; reduced
Research Center, 440 instruction set computer chips, 36;
Semiconductor Trade Arrangement (STA; research and development, 30, 49-52,
1986, 1991): background, 127, 158-76, 102, 105-06, 260n39, 438-39, 440-41;
227-29, 306, 426, 432; consequences of, role in high-technology industries, 7;
26, 160-61, 185-87, 210-11, 227-304, wafer starts, 315. See also Dynamic
386, 388, 395-98, 405, 433-37, 453-54, random access memory; Erasable
457; cooperation and collusion within programmable read only memory;
the industry, 163-65, 168, 186-87, 195, Manufacturing processes; Production
204-08, 214-15, 219-20, 230, 279, 283, processes
388, 395-405, 453-54; criticisms of, Siltec, 123
450-54, 457; European markets, 173, Singapore, 451
INDEX 471
customs issues, 164h3; domestic, 135; United States: cooperation with Japan,
DRAM wars, 148-58; five-company 130, 429-59; semiconductor industry
rule, 133-34; foreign sales, 2, 15-16, output, 1; Soviet Union and, 130; trade
75-76, 133, 262; imports and exports, policies, 4. See also Military, U.S.;
47, 49-52, 54-59, 60, 61, 62/, 70-88, Multinational companies, U.S.;
120-22, 123, 130, 160, 195, 209, 243, Research and development, U.S.;
262, 264, 389, 432; integrated circuits, Semiconductor industry, U.S.;
60, 73, 74-88; price- and quantity-fixing Semiconductor Trade Arrangement;
agreements, 133-46, 149, 150-51, 162, Trade, U.S.
163-64; sales agents, 142«45, 143; Users’ Committee of Foreign
strategic and predadory sales policies, Semiconductors (UCOM), 289
152-53, 165; tariffs and quotas, 87, 131, Ushio Denki, 105
133, 147, 149-50, 152, 156; third-country U.S. Memories, 214, 216-19, 244, 396, 416,
exports, 131, 179; two-tier pricing, 138, 443
140-41, 142, 143, 152; U.S. U.S. Semiconductor, 123
interpretation of policies, 152-53, 216,
385-87, 392; voluntary impact expansion Very High Speed Computer Systems
(VIE) measures, 157. See also Dumping; (VHSCS). See Computers
Semiconductor Trade Arrangement Very High Speed Integrated Circuit
Trade, U.S.: 1950s, 128; 1960s, 130-36; (VHSIC). See Integrated circuits;
1970s, 136-46, 430-31; 1980s, 148-58, Semiconductor industry, U.S.
159-224; 1990s, 455-59; contract, spot, Very Large Scale Integration (VLSI). See
gray market sales, 141; DRAM wars, Integrated circuits
148-58; effects of, 127; foreign market VHSCS (Very High Speed Computer
values (FMV), 177, 180, 191, 211, 213-14, Systems). See Computers
223-24, 266-72, 301-304, 387, 399; VHSIC (Very High Speed Integrated
government involvement in, 149-50, 153, Circuit). See Integrated circuits;
163; imports and exports, 128-29, 130— Semiconductor industry, U.S.
32, 137, 141, 144, 156, 157, 163-64, 266- VLSI (Very Large Scale Integration). See
72; national security and, 130, 132, 150; Integrated circuits
section 301 issues, 158, 160, 164-66, 167, VLSI Technology Research Association,
171, 172, 176, 227, 391, 449; tariffs, 156. 100, 102, 107, 111-13
See also Dumping; Semiconductor Trade von Hippel, Eric, 378
Arrangement
Transistors: consumer versus industrial, Wafers. See Silicon and memory chips
50-51; development, 8, 30-33, 48, 49, Western Electric: research and
52; differences, 128; germanium, 49, 92, development, 31, 33, 736; technology
425; Japanese, 40-42, 45-48, 128; transfers, 41n7, 44
obsolesence, 11; technology transfers, Westinghouse, 129
44; U.S., 48, 128. See also Silicon and World Semiconductor Trade Statistics
memory chips; Semiconductor industry (WSTS), 280
TRW Incorporated, 57-58 World Trade Organization (WTO), 449,
451-52
Using a wealth of new data, the author argues that significant changes to the
trade regime for high-technology industries are needed to escape from the
present impasse. Fie lays out the alternatives, from laissez-faire to managed
trade, and argues strongly for a new set of international ground rules to regu¬
late acceptable behavior by government and high-technology industries.