14528
14528
Gopalkrishnan R. Iyer1
Professor of Marketing
College of Business
Florida Atlantic University
777 Glades Road
Boca Raton, FL 33431
USA
Phone: 561-297-0917
E-mail: [email protected]
Sarah Xiao
Lecturer in Marketing
Durham University Business School
Durham, DH1 3LB, UK
Tel: +44 (0)191 334 5317
E-Mail: [email protected]
Arun Sharma
Professor of Marketing
Department of Marketing
University of Miami
P.O. Box 248147
Coral Gables, FL 33124
USA
Phone: 305-284-1770
E-Mail: [email protected]
Michael Nicholson
Professorial Teaching Fellow
Durham University Business School
Durham, DH1 3LB, UK
Tel: +44 (0)191 334 5402
E-Mail: [email protected]
Cite as:
Iyer, G.R. et al., Behavioral issues in price setting in business-to-business marketing: A
framework for analysis, Industrial Marketing Management (2015),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2015.02.001
1
Corresponding Author
1
Highlights
Managerial price setting processes are examined through insights obtained from
behavioral decision making.
Issue understanding, cognitive biases and heuristics are offered as major managerial
factors that impact price setting.
An agenda for future research is offered along with managerial suggestions for price
setting.
2
Behavioral Issues in Price Setting in Business-to-Business Marketing:
A Framework for Analysis
Abstract
Business-to-business pricing research has often focused on developing rational and normative
frameworks and models for pricing issues, strategies and tactics. However, there has been less
attention given to behavioral models that help us understand the realities of pricing and how
managers actually set prices. Specifically, there has been less attention given to the various
individual and group influences on the price setting process. We apply insights from a steadily
increasing body of literature on behavioral decision making to identify some relevant behavioral
issues that may affect managerial price setting processes in business-to-business contexts. We
conclude with some implications for theory building and practice and an agenda for future
research.
3
Research on pricing in business-to-business markets is sparse, though some recent
articles have shed light on various aspects of pricing, including supply chain pricing (Voeth and
Herbst 2006), price planning (Lancioni 2005b), pricing in international markets (Forman and
Hunt 2005), and pricing of integrated solutions (Sharma and Iyer 2011). In addition, recent
research has also called attention to the study of value-based pricing (Hinterhuber 2004) as well
as the need to understand the impacts and influences of key managers (Lancioni, Schau and
Smith 2005), including the CEO (Liozu and Hinterhuber 2013), on price setting.
While normative frameworks have been suggested in the past for price setting in
business-to-business contexts, research has also suggested that managers take decisions that
appear to deviate from what could be considered optimal given the application of these
frameworks (Kopalle, Mela and Marsh 1999; Liozu 2013; Urbany 2001). However, what is
“optimal” can only be determined from the idiosyncratic environmental and organizational
context of the firm as well as the firm’s intended pricing objectives. Moreover, while there is
some research in organizational buying behavior that contends that individual managers’
interpretations and cognitive processes affect purchasing decisions (Barclay and Bunn 2006;
Wilson, McMurrian and Woodside 2001), similar research on pricing in industrial markets is
only in its infancy. For example, Lancioni et al. (2005) demonstrate that managers often face
internal “roadblocks” from within their organizations in the price setting process. On the other
hand, Liozu and Hinterhuber (2013) find from their empirical study that CEO championing of
pricing activities actually enhances the firm’s pricing capabilities and contributes to better firm
performance.
decision making, which contends that managerial cognitive biases are key sources for deviations
4
from optimal decisions, we attempt to understand the impacts of managerial factors on the price
setting process. Our primary objective is to build a case for the study of managerial cognitions
that could affect the use and application of normative frameworks of price setting. With this
objective in mind, we attempt to make three distinct contributions to the current sparse research
from behavioral research from various disciplines, including behavioral economics, management
and behavioral finance, to understand how behavioral issues may contribute to the price setting
customer or the purchasing manager (e.g., Anderson et al. 2000), we place our attention on the
manager in the selling or marketing firm. Second, we offer a preliminary framework that
contends that managerial issue identification, cognitive biases and heuristics intervene in the
price setting process, specifically in the observed outcomes of normative decision frameworks.
Prior literature on price setting has shown that managers often use pricing objectives that may
not be appropriate given the environmental and organizational context (Carricano 2014; Griffith
and Rust 1997). Also, managers may rely too much on one method of pricing (e.g., the cost-plus
method), while ignoring other methods (Nagle, Hogan and Zale 2010). Moreover, they may not
view pricing as a dynamic strategy that needs to be altered with response to changing contexts
(Monroe and Cox 2001). Finally, given the paucity of behavioral as well as prescriptive research
as an agenda for future academic research that would enhance our understanding of how
managers set prices. In this context, we also offer suggestions and implications that could result
in enhanced managerial decision competence and thus, improvements in the price setting process
in business-to-business markets.
5
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we take stock of
current research in business-to-business marketing, in general, and pricing in particular, and call
attention to understanding managerial factors that could impact the price setting process. We
then selectively review the literature on behavioral decision making from various disciplines and
identify some factors that may impact price setting in business-to-business markets. We then
offer some implications for theory and practice as well as an agenda for future research.
Scholars have proposed several rational and normative frameworks for decision making
with respect to prices (see, for examples, Morris and Calantone 1990; Noble and Gruca 1999;
Oxenfeldt 1973; Tellis 1986). Such a normative focus is indeed warranted given that pricing is
often viewed by managers in tactical rather strategic terms (Dutta et al. 2002), and most
managers are daunted by the complexities of developing elaborate pricing plans for their
products (Lancioni 2005b). However, at the same time, researchers are aware that most firms do
not always make the correct strategic decisions and in the context of pricing, these could have
severe financial implications for the firm (Cudahy and Coleman 2007; Hinterhuber 2004;
Sharma and Iyer 2011). In fact, a recent survey revealed that 70% of executives do not believe
that their firms have clear pricing strategies (Accenture 2011). Baker, Marn and Zawada (2010a)
suggest that most firms do not invest in pricing infrastructure and for a Global 1200 company, a
one-percent improvement in average prices of services and goods could lead to an 8.7% increase
in operating profits.
Researchers have also uncovered that managerial price setting suffers from various issues
6
and how it relates to price (Hinterhuber 2004; Hogan and Lucke 2006; Morris and Calantone
1990). Moreover, significant opportunities are lost given that even marginal increases in prices
could yield significantly more profits as compared to other strategic or tactical actions
(Hinterhuber 2004). Apart from a failure to adjust prices to account for changes in industry
demand when pricing through a product’s lifecycle (Baker, et al. 2010b), significant concerns
arise when companies set prices lower than what the market could pay (Eugster, Kakkar and
Roegner 2000). This is because low prices contribute to lost opportunity and in markets that are
often inelastic, represent errors that do not, even fortuitously, translate into increased sales.
Indeed, there is considerable evidence from practice that errors in pricing may have serious
consequences for the organization (Baker, Marn and Zawada 2010b; Eugster, Kakkar and
Roegner 2000; Johansson, Krishnamurthy and Schlissberg 2003; Krishnamurthy, Johansson and
Schlissberg 2003).
approaches within economics. The primary assumptions are that customers (or, purchasing
firm’s representatives) use a rational calculus in responding to prices and that marketing firms set
their prices rationally with a view to cover costs and achieve broader firm-level objectives. The
rational behavior hypothesis has largely remained unchallenged, even though the discrepancies
between economic theory and pricing practices have been highlighted in the past (e.g., Hall and
Hitch 1939). In fact, most academic approaches to pricing are either descriptive studies of
behaviors. What is lacking is a cumulative understanding of the price setting practices followed
by firms and the factors that contribute to successful practices (Ingenbleek 2007).
7
Since buying decisions in business-to-business markets are taken within an organizational
context, it made sense to assume that firms behaved rationally to maximize their own firms’
objectives and that the individual decision makers’ preferences and tastes mattered very little,
given the pursuit of organizational objectives. Similarly, normative models for developing
pricing in the business-to-business marketing context are motivated by the premise that
marketing firms set their prices rationally with respect to some clear and coherent objectives and
Thus, pricing research in business markets has largely ignored the role of the individual
manager in pricing decisions and the idiosyncratic impacts they may have on the price setting
process. This is in sharp contrast to other areas of business-to-business marketing, most notably
organizational buying decisions, where the roles and impacts of individuals and groups are
organizational buying, such as those offered by Robinson, Faris and Wind (1967), Webster and
Wind (1972) and Sheth (1973) explicitly considered the fact that the purchasing manager as well
as informal groups within the organization, such as the buying center, played a part in
organizational buying decisions. Later research and frameworks have also explicitly recognized
the role of buying center groups in various aspects of organizational buying decisions (e.g.,
Bellizzi 1979; Johnston and Lewin 1996; Kauffman 1996; Kohli 1989). In contrast to strictly
buying. More specifically, they include individual influences on organizational buying calling
specific attention to the organizational buyer’s personal values and needs, as in the Webster and
Wind (1972) model, and to the buyer’s psychological world, as in the Sheth (1973) model.
8
Webster and Wind (1972) acknowledged that organizational buying may be affected by
factors that are not strictly rational and economic. They labeled these influences as “nontask”
factors and considered a variety of individual, social, organizational and environmental forces
that affected otherwise rational economic organizational buying decisions. In Sheth’s (1973)
model, expectations and background, among other factors such as differences in information
sources, search behaviors, perceptual distortion and satisfaction with past purchases were posited
to influence decisions makers in industrial buying. Both these models consider and incorporate
Apart from the vast body of research on buying centers, there is also research within
organizational buying literature on the influence of individual managers on the buying processes
and decisions. While some research focuses on the demographics of managers, including their
education, experience and position within the organization, there is also explicit recognition of
the fact that individual managers may use different decision rules for evaluations, or may frame
the decision context differently (Crow and Lindquist 1982; Qualls and Puto 1989). Moreover,
individual managers may vary in their risk perceptions and how they manage such risks (Hawes
and Barnhouse 1987; Kauffman 1996; Puto, Patton and King 1985). An early review of the
organizational buying research also revealed individual managers’ personality and motivation
have been topics of research on the buying process (Johnston and Lewin 1996).
More recently, organizational buying research has also focused on subjective evaluations
by individual managers and buying centers (Brown et al. 2011; Brown et al. 2012). Specifically,
research on perceptions of the business-to-business brands suggest that brand cues are evaluated
by buyers through use of subjective information as well (Brown et al. 2012). Thus, this research
stream explicitly calls attention to the decision heuristics used by managers and contends that
9
overtly “rational” approaches to organizational buying have not allowed for the examination of
subjective judgments in organizational buying (Barclay and Bunn 2006; Brown et al. 2011;
Such an examination of group and individual factors are largely lacking in research on
pricing in business markets. There may be several reasons for this neglect in pricing research.
First, even though buying centers are often informal and vary according to the buying decision,
managers responsible for the purchasing function can be recognized from their position titles and
from organizational charts. In contrast, the responsibility for the pricing function is not so
readily discerned; it could reside with divisional managers, product managers, inter-departmental
teams or may even be a C-suite decision. Second, while much of organizational buying research
is conducted using actual organizational participants as respondents and informants and can be
identified from organized sampling frames, large-scale empirical survey research on pricing is
often conducted among experienced MBA and executive education students (see for example,
Forman and Hunt 2013; Hunt and Forman 2006; Morris and Schurink 1993, while some
exceptions are studies in the European context in the decades prior reviewed by Ingenbleek
2007). The lack of availability of ready populations for sampling restricts study of pricing
decisions and behaviors to specific questions and also, more often than not, insights are often
drawn from case studies and small sample qualitative research. What is lacking is a cumulative
understanding of pricing practices from a wider variety of studies (Ingenbleek 2007). Finally, it
is possible that the conceptualization of organizations as rational entities may be pervading most
of pricing research and may also be restricting researchers to include only objective information
10
However, a growing body of literature now suggests that managers may not follow a
rational calculus (Ariely 2009; Urbany 2001) and do make pricing errors, some of them
egregious enough to threaten the firm’s financial stability. Part of the reason could be that pricing
decisions may rely on easily understood or simplistic cost-plus or competitive parity pricing
methods, while cognitive complexity may be devoted to other organizational decisions such as
product design and development, sales, and promotion. Also, a strong cost focus often permeates
the firm (Smith 1995), given that pricing decisions may be embedded across both marketing and
the firm. Managerial discretion, when available, manifests itself only as deviations from the list
price through discounts and rebates. Even here, costs are often the primary consideration. For
example, a salesperson may be authorized to not give more than say, a five-percent discount,
often estimated from the margin loss the firm could bear for business development and/or
additional sales. On the other hand, empirical research indicates that delegation of pricing
authority to the salesforce results in superior firm performance, especially under conditions when
salespeople possess better market and customer information as compared to managers placed
Over the years, research with business-to-business marketing has developed and offered
pragmatic frameworks and tools for managers (see for example, Anderson et al. 2000; Lancioni
2005b; Morris and Calantone 1990). In general, it is offered that systematic pricing plans would
enable managers to avoid errors in their pricing decisions. Marketing, in general, appears to
have discarded profit maximization objectives through pricing and instead, entreats the
consideration of several diverse objectives (Morris and Calantone 1990; Oxenfeldt 1973;
Skouras et al. 2005), such as pricing to achieve target unit sales, revenues and market share.
11
Similarly, when it comes to selecting a pricing method, an array of different techniques and
approaches are offered from which managers could choose, with choice of the “best” method
itself contingent on specific objectives and customer, market and industry factors, among other
We contend that a focus on the various behavioral issues that contribute to deviations
from standard economic theory as well as to irrational pricing behaviors would lead to a more
acknowledgment of irrationality would enable the development of frameworks and schemas that
would help reduce serious errors in pricing that may detract from firm performance or even
threaten its survival. In the next section, we offer a framework that would contribute to
As argued earlier, our understanding of ways prices are actually set by firms would not
only enable the development of better normative frameworks for pricing but also enable
researchers to propose models and frameworks that are more realistic. Rational and normative
pricing models are often structured as conditional if-then logical statements. In such models,
there is little scope for roles played by managerial discretionary decision making. In reality,
however, pricing decisions, even though aided by decision models, are the purview of specific
individuals and groups in the organization. Despite similarities in contexts and availability of
decision making models, pricing decisions may suffer from unwarranted risk avoidance
(Guiltinan 1976; Hunt and Forman 2006), inappropriateness of chosen objectives (Smith 1995),
perceptions of lack of decision making control (Hinterhuber 2004; Lancioni 2005a), inflexibility
12
in decisions (Monroe and Cox 2001), and lack of knowledge of sophisticated methods (Morris
The impetus for the study of managerial impacts on organizational decisions as well as
behavioral dynamics within and across organizations and theories of decision making that
explicitly consider rational limits on human cognitive capabilities (e.g., Cyert and March 1963;
March 1978; Simon 1955, 1957). Simon (1955) was prescient in advancing the notion that
humans are limited by cognitive and calculative abilities to analyze all the information needed to
make accurate rational choices. This form of bounded rationality, while appearing to lead to
rational decision making, may be rational only in intentions and not always in its outcomes.
Instead, individuals in organizations engage in satisficing rather than optimizing (Simon 1957).
The limitations imposed by bounded-ness of rationality are particularly severe when decision
makers face situations that are uncertain, complex and/or ambiguous (Duncan 1972; Spender
Behavioral decision theories have identified several strategies through which managers
reduce the complexity in decision making and/or deal with perceived uncertainty (Cyert and
March 1963; March 1978; Nelson and Winter 1982; Simon 1947; Weick 1979). Complexity and
uncertainty are often dealt with through simplified mental models that attempt to organize
knowledge about the environment (Cyert and March 1963). More importantly, managers attempt
to satisfice rather than optimize (March 1978) and/or follow various rules-of-thumb or routines
or heuristics (Kahneman, Slovic and Tversky 1982; Nelson and Winter 1982). While such
simplifications lead to decisions, the resulting decisions may not be fully optimal.
13
Pricing research in industrial markets does acknowledge the role of managerial discretion
in the price setting process as well as the decision making errors attributed to managers (Liozu
2013; Liozu et al. 2011). However, there is less attention given to putative behavioral issues,
particularly the heuristics that may contribute as aids in reducing decision making complexity
but also biases that could contribute to bad decisions (Hammond et al. 2006; Liozu 2012). In the
context of pricing, Liozu (2013) elaborates managerial attempts to simplify decisions as those of
satisficing, following rules of thumb, defining standard operating procedures and organizational
treat individual and group characteristics as specific exogenous factors that impact the price
setting process. Indeed, as noted earlier, comprehensive models of buyer behavior consider
individual and buying group factors explicitly in models of organizational buyer behaviors. In
terms of pricing research, this would lead to examination of various individual and group factors,
including but not limited to, managerial characteristics (e.g., age, education, experience, position
in the firm), managerial attitudes and dispositions (e.g., risk taking, conservativeness), and group
understand how managerial interpretation of issues as well as their biases and heuristics
influence the price setting process. In such a framework, there is explicit recognition of the fact
that price setting process is influenced not only by contextual factors but also by managerial
judgments, and for better or for worse. For example, the impacts of contextual factors such as
present in the environment as well as within the organization on the price setting process could
14
consideration of individual and group judgments that could contribute to decisions other than
The effects of environmental context on organizational decisions has been studied not
only by researchers within business-to-business marketing but also by those in the broader
disciplines of strategic marketing and general management. Specifically, with respect to pricing,
Morris and Schurink (1993) identify three specific environmental influences – rate of
environmental change, market structure heterogeneity and competitive rivalry – on the pricing
behaviors. The rate of environmental change or environmental dynamism refers to the pace and
extent of changes in the firm’s environment (Morris and Schurink 1993; Miller and Freisen
1983). Higher rates of change may call for aggressive pricing and frequent price changes.
Market structure heterogeneity refers to the extent to which markets are characterized by
and Schurink 1993; Sheth 1985). These would impact whether the firm’s price objectives are
uniform across various markets or customized to specific markets. Competitive rivalry is the
extent to which one or more competitors are in intense competition with the firm for the same
groups of suppliers and/or customers. Here, pricing objectives, method and initial prices may be
pegged to the competition rather than flowing from solely internal considerations.
Apart from the environmental context, several aspects of the organizational context, or
forces within the organization, also have impacts on the price setting process. For example,
Lancioni et al. (2005) demonstrate that different groups and departments within the firm may
create hurdles and obstacles in the development and implementation of pricing strategy. Also,
bureaucratic structures may increase internal administrative and overhead costs (D’Aveni and
15
Ravenscraft 1994), which could be reflected in the higher initial prices and/or lack of price
flexibility. The degree of autonomy and control over pricing would affect not only the selection
of pricing objectives but also the choice of pricing methods and the flexibility in pricing. On one
hand, it appears that CEO influences in price setting actually enhances pricing capabilities, but
on the other hand, it may be argued that top management involvement in price setting reduces
the decision-making autonomy of functional managers (Lancioni et al. 2005; Liozu and
Hinterhuber 2013). Recent research has also shown that a firm’s pricing capability is a distinct
organizational resource and an important source of competitive advantage (Dutta et al. 2002;
The above discussion provides a summary view of how some forces in the environmental
context and organizational context would affect the price setting process. However, the
discussion thus far does not take into account individual managerial issues in decision making.
From the current literature on behavioral decision making approaches, we can identify issue
interpretation, cognitive biases and heuristics as three major managerial factors that would affect
the influence of contextual forces on the prices setting process (see Figure 1). We briefly discuss
Issue Interpretation
sociology, has brought attention to how the context affects individuals and groups (Mowday and
Sutton 1993). Specifically, it has been shown it is important to understand how decision makers
interpret their contexts (Mowday and Sutton 1993; Thomas and McDaniel 1990). The relevant
context can be interpreted as an “opportunity” or a “threat” (Dutton and Jackson 1987; Thomas,
16
Clark and Gioia 1993). As Dutton and Jackson (1987; p. 80) elaborate: “the opportunity
category implies a positive situation in which a gain is likely and over which one has a fair
amount of control; in contrast, the “threat” category implies a negative situation in which a loss
is likely and over which one has relatively little control” (emphasis in the original). Thus, the
elements needed for categorization of the context as an opportunity or threat are the perception
of the situation as positive or negative, the evaluation of the outcome as a gain or loss, and the
perception of control.
In terms of the framework offered in Figure 1, both the environmental and organizational
develop from the literature, the specific interpretation of the context matters since it affects not
only the mobilization of action in a particular direction but also the levels of risk taking,
involvement, and commitment. Thus, interpretation of the environmental context or the framing
of the strategic issue would contribute not only to the depth of decision-making but also the
decision choices made. In the case of price setting, interpretation of the context as an
opportunity may enable the involvement of multiple groups from the organization in the price
setting process (Dutton and Jackson 1987); contribute to the development of risk-taking
objectives and price taking strategies, and; may lead to prices that attempt to skim the market.
On the other hand, interpretation of the context as a threat could lead to more conservative and
isolationist approaches to price setting. Therefore, how managers interpret the context must be
Cognitive Biases
Recent approaches in the field of behavioral economics and behavioral decision making
suggest that far from expecting rational decision-making within organizations, managers are
17
“fundamentally irrational” and their decisions are influenced by cognitive biases (Ariely 2009).
Simply defined, cognitive biases are subjective opinions or predispositions that may be due to
the systematic use of some simple decision rules, heuristics, or “rules of thumb” (Bazerman
1990; Das and Teng 1999; Kahneman, Slovic and Tversky 1982). The resulting decisions often
deviate from outcomes that are suggested by the application of a rational calculus (Ariely 2009;
Lovallo and Sibony 2010). Thus, in the context of pricing, the consequent impact of individual
factors in price setting could lead to deviations from prices suggested by normative frameworks
(Urbany 2001).
While the study of behavioral biases within marketing is more prevalent for
understanding consumer markets, there is scarce research within marketing of the various
psychological and group decision biases that are held by managers, especially pricing decision
makers. We extract, primarily from the fields of behavioral economics and behavioral finance,
some relevant biases that may affect each stage of the pricing plan comprising of setting
Apart from the above studies, the relative neglect of studies of behavioral biases in
business-to-business markets, especially within pricing, may be due to the assumption that
individual factors matter less in a firm’s strategic decisions. However, research within finance
and strategy literatures suggests that managers in organizations that have systematic processes
for collective decision making are also prone to several behavioral biases.
18
Table 1 organizes the pricing issues along the lines of the systematic pricing plan
suggested by Lancioni (2005b). Several putative behavioral biases that may affect managerial
decisions are then identified from literature along with their implications for pricing. A link is
attempted between specific biases that may be present at each stage of the pricing decision-
making along with a descriptive impact of such biases. Two caveats are in order: one, some of
the biases listed at each stage could affect other stages as well and two, the organization of the
biases and impacts are not based on prior empirical research, which is currently lacking anyway.
However, the putative behavioral biases could serve to make a case for understanding whether
such biases are manifest in pricing decisions as well as the consequent impacts of these biases.
In the context of pricing decisions, such biases play an important role in interpreting the
environmental context and also translating the organizational objectives into pricing behaviors.
Managers may underestimate uncertainty and engage in overconfident decisions, or they may be
satisfied with merely good enough performance outcomes. Table 1 provides the various possible
biases that may impede the translation of organizational priorities, given the environmental
Heuristics
Research in behavioral decision theory has shown that individuals, including managers,
use unconscious routines in decision making (Hammond et al. 2006). These heuristics serve to
reduce or at least, help manage, the complexities in understanding the decision context as well as
reacting to it. These rules are also enshrined in organizational routines and organizational
knowledge and process experience enables managers to learn heuristics (Bingham and
Eisenhardt 2011).
19
Prior literature has shown that managers rely on simple rules and methods of pricing so
much that they appear to lack knowledge and understanding (Morris and Morris 1990). Also,
simple pricing methods, such as cost-plus pricing, are relied upon more than other more
theory, the application of the cost-plus heuristic is a managerial mechanism of coping with the
complexity involved in pricing (Liozu 2012). In a vast majority of cases, it is possible that such
a heuristic enables effective price setting; however, in other cases, the application of
inappropriate heuristic could result in damaging consequences for the firm’s revenues and
overall performance. Thus, knowing which heuristic is appropriate given the environmental and
organizational context may serve to reduce some of the pricing errors. More importantly,
periodic evaluation of the heuristics used and the contexts in which they are used could
Two brief case examples on pricing of solutions and relationship selling illustrate the
possible operations of managerial factors noted above in current pricing practices. The primary
purpose of these vignettes is to highlight our contention that managerial issues in the price
Pricing of Solutions
Over the last several years, major firms such as IBM, HP and others have focused on
marketing integrated customer solutions rather than merely products. Essentially, solutions
involve an almost seamless integration of products and services that are customized to specific
customer needs (Davies, Brady, and Hobday 2006; Sawhney 2006). The high levels of technical
and commercial integration of solutions make these more than merely product or price bundles
(Krishnamurthy et al. 2003; Sawhney 2006). Customized and well-integrated solutions promise
20
to offer great value to customers and greater margins for the firm; however, it has been suggested
that only few firms have been successful in their solutions marketing strategies (Johansson et al.
2003; Krishnamurthy et al. 2003). In fact, one study noted that as many as three-fourths of the
firms that had tried offering solutions failed to achieve their objectives (Krishnamurthy et al.
2003). It was observed that only 20 to 25% of the firms realized price premiums from their
solution offerings (Roegner and Gobbi 2001). Apart from issues in the design, development and
marketing of solutions, one major reason why many solutions marketers failed to recover the
high costs of investments is because customers often did not perceive the premium prices
charged for solutions as justified compared to their own valuation of the offerings (Johansson et
al. 2003; Krishnamurthy et al. 2003; Sharma and Iyer 2011). This was because firms priced their
solutions only after they were developed rather than much before and many simply extended
their existing pricing methods to solutions (Johansson et al. 2003; Roegner and Gobbi 2001).
Thus, rather than focusing on customer value, target prices and appropriate pricing
strategies, firms treated a radically different offering quite the same as far as pricing was
concerned. Given the very different context (solutions as compared to individual products or
even product bundles), managers may have been quite optimistic in viewing solutions as an
opportunity to extract premium prices without considering whether such solutions enhanced
customer value. Thus, the interpretation of the context as an opportunity could have led to
greater risk taking and possibly less in-depth analysis of the situation and the pricing decision.
It could also be possible that managers may be operating under a status quo bias and did
not perceive that integrated solutions were novel offerings that required changes to existing
pricing outlooks and price setting processes and/or the use of new methods to price integrated
solutions (see for example, Samuelson and Zeckhauser 1988). Or, managers may be subject to a
21
familiarity bias and prefer existing heuristics, such as cost-plus pricing, that they are more
familiar with (see for example, Huberman 2001), rather than use new methods to understand and
extract customer perceived value of integrated solutions. Thus, behavioral approaches enable us
to go beyond simply the decision and its consequences and help identify possible causes for
Relationship Pricing
While relationship marketing approaches have been in vogue in various industries since
the 1980s and in academic literature on business-to-business marketing soon after, few firms
have been successful in developing and implementing profitable customer relationship marketing
strategies (Richards and Jones 2008). The profitability of a relationship marketing approach
hinges on the assumption that loyal customers would pay premium prices. However, this is not
always true and firms often do not take into account the different costs of serving different types
of customers when determining the price (Reinartz and Kumar 2000). While techniques are
available that would help firms better segment their customer base and price accordingly (Rust et
al. 2001), there is scant evidence to suggest that pricing in relationship settings is taken as
seriously as it should be. In fact, evidence from commercial banking suggests that many
commercial banks do not invest in creating relationships with their customers and their pricing
remains “poorly informed and inconsistent” (Helps and Saari 2005). Thus, rather than focusing
on the long-term relationship, firms often take a much narrow view of the market and engage in
pricing over the transaction rather than through the relationship (Nunes and Hanson 2012).
From the behavioral perspective, such a short-term focus on relationships may be the
result of a loss aversion bias (see for example, Tversky and Kahneman 1991). Managers may be
22
operating under the assumption that costly investments upfront in building relationships may
often lead to losses over the long-term, especially when the firm and customers engage in easily
perspective may help us understand the reasons why managers view short-term profits (including
Descriptive realities of the individual influences on price setting within organizations can
be explained by two alternative perspectives. One, the popular research stream pioneered by
Tversky, Kahneman and others maintains that individuals are subject to biases and these biases
contribute to deviations from behaviors and outcomes that are suggested by normative models of
economic decision making (Tversky and Kahneman 1974; Kahneman, Slovic and Tversky
1982). Thus, this perspective holds that while models of economic rationality may suggest
specific optimal decisions and outcomes, actual decisions are often suboptimal and error-prone
The second perspective that has often developed under the shadow of the biases program
noted above maintains that economic rationality is a myth and optimality is a chimerical
objective. This perspective is more directly influenced by Herbert Simon’s (1955) views of
bounded rationality and maintains that the goals of individuals and systems are those of
satisficing rather than optimizing (Gigerenzer and Goldstein 1996). Thus, the appropriate goal is
to seek out the option, alternative or object that meets the organism’s aspirational level rather
than engage in a complex and unachievable search for optimality that is doomed at the outset,
23
given limits on human cognition and computational abilities (Gigerenzer and Goldstein 1996;
Simon 1955).
While we are not in a position to engage in or even add to the debate between the two
perspectives (see, for example, Kahneman and Tversky 1996; Gigerenzer 1996), suffice it to say
that both perspectives point to limits in individual decision-making that may lead to suboptimal
decisions. In the case of prices, whether approached from the perspectives of biases or from the
objectives of satisficing, suboptimal prices are a reality and could detract from supra-
Behavioral research on pricing is now the dominant framework for analyzing pricing
within consumer marketing. For over the last four decades, consumer perceptions of price and
their reactions to prices and price changes have been the subject of much academic research on
pricing. However, similar behavioral theories and frameworks are largely absent within
business pricing as a rational organizational decision that is impervious to individual tastes and
pricing decisions as rational, with any pricing errors attributed not to psychological factors but to
lapses in strategy.
The application of behavioral thinking to price setting by firms has the potential to
enhance our understanding in several different ways. First, by challenging the assumption that
prices are rationally set, it opens the door to pricing that works rather than prices that are
optimal. This may bring theory and practice closer to appropriate pricing in different contexts
rather than relying on general assumptions of rationality and optimality. Second, opening the
24
examination of putative causes rather than offering normative frameworks that may be
theory rather than merely critiquing practice for failure to follow theory. Third, the study of
behavioral biases helps understand reality as it is rather than whether a theory applies to reality.
This key focus on ontology enables descriptive theories that would complement deductive logic
approach to strategy brings the field of strategy closer to reality by taking into explicit account
“realistic assumptions about human cognition, emotion, and social interaction” (Powell et al.
2011; p. 1369). Behavioral approaches do not reject rationality; instead, they reject the
achievable objective. Cognizant of the bounded-ness of human rationality as well as the variety
something that is given or as an outcome (Simon 1955; Levinthal 2011; March 1994). In the
behavioral world, only presumed rational choices are made, satisficing is more relevant than
optimizing, and analysis and actions reveal the boundary conditions of decision making and
sophistication tends to move us away from a more accurate picture of the real world. While
deductive logic may be a useful starting place, descriptive and empirical realities tell us how it is
really out there. Such revisions to our conceptions of reality would help us develop theories not
only for a better understanding of the business-to-business world, but also for providing practical
25
guidelines for managerial action. We offer some approaches to research and theory in the
section below.
While behavioral issues and biases have been a focus of inquiry within marketing for
some time now, there has been less emphasis on the exploration of these themes within the area
We have made only a preliminary and exploratory contribution to the study of behavioral biases
in price setting, including the types of biases that may detract from optimum prices in business-
to-business marketing. As noted by Powell et al. (2011), the key concern in behavioral strategy
is not good research but “a lack of conceptual unity” (p. 1371). While some prior research has
pointed to suboptimal pricing behaviors (notably, Kopalle, Mela and Marsh 1999; Little and
Shapiro 1980, and; Urbany 2001), we have explored the idea that behavioral biases could result
in suboptimal managerial price setting behaviors. In other words, we have introduced the
possibility that suboptimal price setting by managers may be due to various inherent biases and
explicitly considering the possibility that managerial decisions may be biased, the door is opened
for an examination of what was wrong with decisions and how decision making may be
as suggested by Ariely (2009), firms can begin to understand irrationality and engage in
decisions that could confront biases and reduce their impacts (Lovallo and Sibony 2010).
26
The framework we have offered sheds some light on the various sources of behavioral
biases that could impact price setting. However, as all frameworks go, there is a need to ground
conceptual insights into empirical realities. This is especially true in the context of behavioral
issues and cognitive psychology, wherein Gigerenzer (1991) notes that scientific tools could
The recognition that human cognition and processing capabilities are limited and that
human decision-making is subject to various biases is the first step in a behavioral approach to
appropriate tools and techniques, the key issue may not be whether they work, but why they are
not used more often. Moreover, the decision-making context may be more complex as compared
to the simplistic assumptions in extant models of pricing. More importantly, the study of
deviations from rationality offer a better perspective on the world we live in rather than the
optimal worlds we should strive to live in. Therefore, understanding behavioral biases and
confronting them head-on may be the best way to minimize the incidence of suboptimal pricing.
However, since this research stream is still in its infancy, future research focus could be on
identifying the various behavioral biases and unravelling their impacts, as noted below.
Some research on organizational buying, however, has been quite prescient in its
acknowledgment of various behavioral and individual factors that affect otherwise “rational”
buying decisions (Montgomery1975; Wilson 1984; Woodside and Wilson 2000). For example,
Montgomery (1975) found that a vast majority of new items accepted by supermarket buyers
were dropped within 12 months, suggesting a rather high frequency of mistakes in buying
27
decisions. An analysis of buying decisions in the utility industry by Wilson (1984) revealed that
prices were revised only annually unless adjustments were requested by vendors. Woodside and
parties framed “problems and people using a limited number of issues and categories” (p.365).
This suggests that instead of exploring all possible alternatives, contingencies and outcomes as
suggested by rational economic models, managers relied more on implicit and limited decision
framing processes.
alone the research on biases in such pricing, much work needs to be done to obtain a state-of-the-
art knowledge of extant realities. Within the area of pricing research, Urbany (2001) was
prescient in his call for research that would enable greater understanding of errors in pricing,
their contributory causes, and consequent impacts. In an attempt to understand how cognitive
biases may affect price setting, we have only made a beginning in identifying possible biases that
could impact price setting processes in the business-to-business marketing contexts. We hope
that this beginning may be an appropriate start for attempts to answer other relevant questions
empirically to further our knowledge on the specific types of cognitive biases and how they
impact the pricing decision in organizations. Some these directions for future research are
1. What manifest forms of behavioral biases impact pricing decisions? Currently, except for
a few frameworks, we do not have adequate knowledge of what types of biases may be
contribute to suboptimal pricing and other systematic errors. We need more cross-industry
research to identify the phenomena and understand the potential manifestations of various
28
behavioral biases. Moreover, it may be possible that different forms of behavioral biases
may be manifest in different industries or in the same industry across different country
contexts. An important research question may be: What are the most relevant biases
contexts?
2. How and to what extent do behavioral biases impact pricing decisions? While some forms
of biases may not be much cause for concern, severe deviations from rationality and
various behavioral biases may contribute to suboptimal decisions. Here as well, the impacts
of biases in some industries may be more severe than others. For example, given the high
costs of drug development, the impacts of biases may be more severe in the pharmaceutical
research question may be: What are the consequent impacts of various biases, given the
premise that irrationality is simply human nature and that some forms of biases may have a
3. How do managers rationalize their pricing decisions? Given the possibility of behavioral
biases, do managers recognize their own failures? If not, how do managers rationalize their
pricing decisions, especially given the fact that pricing decisions in business-to-business
contexts may need organizational approval and review? Research is needed not only on
managerial cognitive frameworks but also on their explanations for the various pricing
decisions taken. Such research may also uncover broader group and organizational
influences on suboptimal pricing, beyond the control of individual managers. Thus, while
29
biases may be hidden from view, the decision and its consequent impacts can be observed.
For example, Lovallo and Sibony (2010) suggest that confident managers are more likely to
have their plans approved as compared to those who identify all the various risks and
eventualities inherent in the decision. When confidently proposed plans fail, managerial
contributing to specific decisions, an important research question may be: How are bad
decisions rationalized?
4. How do behavioral biases in pricing play out in different cultures? While research on
international pricing has focused on offering normative models for use by export and other
international managers, we know less about the price setting process in different cultural
contexts. For example, is price setting in traditional cultures the sole prerogative of the
senior executive? An important research question may be: Does price setting in different
cultures impacted by various other behavioral biases? We need research on identifying the
cultural incidence of various biases and their impacts to fully understand the cultural context
of pricing.
5. What strategies should be adopted to minimize biases and their impacts? While much of
the research on behavioral strategy has been descriptive while business-to-business pricing
minimize the various potential behavioral biases and their impacts. An important research
question may be: What is the effectiveness of various techniques for reducing biases
30
6. What is the nature of exchange when both managers and their customers are subject to
behavioral biases? While extant research on behavioral biases is one-sided, that is, focused
marketing is dyadic. If current research on behavioral issues and biases in pricing from
consumer markets could be extended to business customers, then such customers would be
prone to biases in their purchasing decisions. However, if managers are also subject to
biases, the very nature of the exchange relationship may be drastically different. An
important research question may be: How do two biased parties to an exchange view, set
and accept prices? Such a research stream could also gain from the vast amount of research
There are several inductive approaches already known to marketing and industrial
marketing scholars that have the potential to bridge the gap between the behavioral biases we
have explored and empirical realities in price setting. In a seminal contribution, Howard and
Morgenroth (1968) use a novel approach to study executive decision making, especially with
respect to price setting. Given the problems in studying executive decision rules either before or
after the fact, they used multiple approaches to gain an in-depth and more accurate understanding
of how executives actually take decisions and if such decisions deviated from the optimum. A
complex multi-source multi-method research design was used, including interviews, observation
of the processes, records of past decisions and various supporting data along with further reviews
with responding executives (Howard and Morgenroth 1968). Thus, better insights into actual
31
Similarly, research in the field of organizational buying has used methods such as the
analysis of verbal protocols in understanding the processes and realities of decision making
(Crow, Olshavsky and Summers 1980; Woodside and Wilson 2000). Woodside and Wilson
(2000) find it most appropriate to use verbal protocols or the “think aloud method” (van
Someren, Barnard and Sandberg 1994) to understand contingency models relied upon by
executives in decision making. Using a novel research method that combines the use of thick
with creative uses of think aloud method and interviews, Woodside and Wilson (2000)
demonstrate that even complex aspects of decision making can be mapped by tapping into the
suggested by Ariely (2009) and leadership commitment and cultural change, as suggested by
Lovallo and Sibony (2010). Ariely (2009) contends that firms and managers must question their
assumptions and engage qualified experts who would help the firm in behavioral
experimentation and small trials. Similarly, Lovallo and Sibony (2010) suggest that biases
should be recognized and discussed within the organization and confronted directly with
What we have offered here are the first steps – the contention that suboptimal pricing
may be the result of various behavioral biases and an identification of the relevant biases
affecting price setting. However, understanding decision making in its actual context offers the
best potential for uncovering the implicit decision rules and the biases in decision making.
32
Challenges of Behavioral Research
Answers to the above research questions would greatly enhance our understanding of the
complexities involved when behavioral biases affect pricing decisions. However, such research
may not be easy to undertake. For one, the types of controlled experiments that are in use in the
areas of behavioral economics and marketing may not be possible among busy executives in
may be less forthcoming about their choices, especially through methods such as personal
interviews. Third, empirical research on uncovering group level biases may be hard to
undertake.
However, given the increase in executive education programs in business schools, several
practicing managers are now enrolled as students in such programs. These manager-students not
only provide a somewhat homogeneous sample but may also be more willing to participate in
academic research. With suitable sample selection criteria, methods that are used in other
disciplines to study behavioral biases can also be applied to understand biases in business-to-
business pricing. Thus, despite challenges, the field is rife with opportunities for future research.
The idea that managerial decisions may be subject to various biases that yield suboptimal
outcomes may be quite distressing for managers keen on taking the best decisions and obtaining
the best results. Also, given bounded rationality and satisficing, optimality may be an illusory
objective. However, despite such pessimism, recent research actually suggests that a variety of
approaches and heuristics actually followed by decision makers results in decisions that either
overcome some of the limitations of the various biases or contribute to decisions that are
33
sometimes even better than those suggested by models of optimality. For example, we can use
research by the medical profession that seeks to reduce biases in decision-making by doctors as a
starting point.
Examining a variety of research conducted in the context of business, health care and
legal organizations and institutions, Gigerenzer and Gaissmaier (2011) conclude that heuristic
decisions, rather than always contributing to errors, are sometimes quite valuable and more
accurate in decision making. Heuristics are prompted by effort reduction considerations and
enable making decisions rapidly with minimal information, and sometimes more accurately, as
compared to complex models (Gigerenzer and Gaissmaier 2011). Thus, simple and/or intuitive
In the last column of Table 1, we offer various insights from prior research on how the
biases noted at each stage of price setting may be reduced. An important insight is the role of
adaptive learning – that is feedback that is obtained from prior decisions – in reducing biases and
errors in the future (Al-Najjar, Baliga and Besanko 2008; Senge 1994). Thus, it is possible that
experts are those individuals in organizations who learn through experience and thus, refine their
decision making abilities to the extent that the outcomes of their decision making rivals complex
models. Given limits on attention and memory, experts reason analytically and intuitively and
Conclusion
one, pricing involves inputs from multiple divisions within the firm, such as finance and
accounting, among others, and stakeholders within and outside the firm, including
34
intermediaries. Moreover, pricing involves considerations of a variety of complex factors within
the firm, including appropriate costing and cost allocations, marginal profits, etc., as well as
outside the firm, including customer demand and competition. The complexity of the pricing
Second, accuracy in pricing may call for information beyond what is available or can be
obtained by the decision-maker. Normative models of pricing may require detailed information
of demand and supply as well as future projections of costs and demand. The absence of
complete and accurate information may also contribute to prices that are recognized as
adjusted. This calls for detailed information on the environment as well as information on the
impacts of prices on the firm’s marginal profits. The inability to respond to such internal and
external considerations fairly quickly may also contribute to pricing errors that affect the
While impacts of various pricing errors emerging due to organizational factors could be
information use, we have focused on the behavioral issues that may be more difficult to address.
The study of business-to-business pricing is ready for a change from its extant focus on
normative models and frameworks to descriptive research on how managers actually set prices.
In this context, the various behavioral biases identified in other disciplines could provide
explanations for suboptimal pricing as well as deviations from rational price-setting. In this
paper, we have merely scratched the surface of a rich, growing and rewarding field of inquiry
and are hopeful that future research would greatly enhance our understanding of pricing practices
35
in business-to-business marketing. Such an understanding would serve to greatly reduce the
36
References
Al-Najjar, N., Baliga, S., & Besank, D. (2008). Market forces meet behavioral biases: cost
misallocation and irrational pricing. RAND Journal of Economics, 39(1), 214-237.
Anderson, J.C., Thomson, J.B.L. & Wynstra, F. (2000). Combining value and price to make
purchase decisions in business markets. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 17,
307-329.
Andersson, Ola and Holm, Håkan J. and Tyran, Jean-Robert and Wengström, Erik (2013).
Deciding for Others Reduces Loss Aversion (September 17, 2013). Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2328642
Ariely, D. (2009). The end of rational economics. Harvard Business Review, July-August, 78-
84.
Arkes, H. & Blumer, C. (1985). The psychology of sunk cost. Organizational Behavior and
Human Decision Process, 35, 124–140.
Baker, W.L., Marn, M.V. & Zawada, C.C. (2010a). Building a better pricing infrastructure.
McKinsey Quarterly, August, 1-6.
Baker, W.L., Marn, M.V. & Zawada, C.C. (2010b). Do you have a long-term pricing strategy?
McKinsey Quarterly, October, 1-7.
Barber, B. & Odean, T. (1999). The courage of misguided convictions. Financial Analysts
Journal, 55, 41-55.
Barclay, D.W., & Bunn, M.D. (2006). Process heuristics in organizational buying: starting to fill
a gap. Journal of Business Research, 59, 186-194.
Bazerman, M.H. (1990). Judgment in managerial decision-making, 2nd ed. New York: John
Wiley and Sons.
Beggan, J.K. (1992). On the social nature of nonsocial perception: the mere ownership effect.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 62, 229–237.
Bellizzi, J.A. (1979). Product type and the relative influence of buyers in commercial
construction. Industrial Marketing Management, 8, 213-220.
Bingham, C.B., & Eisenhardt, K.M. (2011). Rational heuristics: the ‘simple rules’ that strategists
learn from process experience. Strategic Management Journal, 32, 1437-1464.
37
Brown, B.P., Zablah, A.R., Bellenger, D.N., & Johnston, W.J. (2011). When do b2b brands
influence the decision making of organizational buyers? an examination of the relationship
between purchase risk and brand sensitivity. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 28,
194-204.
Brown, B.P., Zablah, A.R., Bellenger, D.N. & Donthu, N. (2012). What factors influence buying
center brand sensitivity? Industrial Marketing Management, 41, 508-520.
Carricano, M. (2014). Pricing myopia: do leading companies capture the full value of their
pricing strategies? Management Decision, 52, 159-178.
Coval, J. D., & Shumway, T. (2005). Do behavioral biases affect prices? Journal of Finance, 60,
1-34.
Crow, L.E. & Lindquist, J.D. (1982). Buyers differ in evaluating suppliers. Industrial Marketing
Management, 11, 205-214.
Crow, L. E., Olshavsky, R. W., & Summers, J. O. (1980). Industrial buyers' choice strategies: a
protocol analysis. Journal of Marketing Research, 17, 34-44.
Cudahy, G., & Coleman, G.L. (2007). The price is right . . . isn’t it? Outlook, 1, 1-8.
Cyert, R.M. & March, J.G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Prentice Hall.
Daniel, K., & Titman, S. (1999). Market efficiency in an irrational world. Financial Analysts'
Journal, 55, 28-40.
Das, T.K., & Teng, B-S. (1999). Cognitive biases and strategic decision processes. Journal of
Management Studies, 36, 757-778.
D’Aveni, R.A., & Ravenscraft, D.J. (1994). Economics of integration versus bureaucracy costs:
does vertical integration improve performance? Academy of Management Journal, 37, 1167-
1206.
Davies, A., Brady, T., & Hobday, M. (2006). Charting a path toward integrated solutions. MIT
Sloan Management Review, 47, 39-48.
De Bondt, W. F. M., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Financial decision-making in markets and firms: a
behavioral perspective. In R. A. Jarrow, V. Maksimovic & W. T. Ziemba (Eds.), Handbooks in
Operations Research and Management Science, (Vol. 9, pp. 385-410). Amsterdam: North
Holland.
Duncan, R. (1972). Characteristics of organizational environments and perceived environmental
uncertainty. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17, 313-327.
38
Dutta, S., Bergen, M. Levy, D., Ritson, M., & Zbaracki, M. (2002). Pricing as a strategic
capability. MIT Sloan Management Review, 61-66.
Dutton, J.E., & Jackson, S.E. (1987). Categorizing strategic issues: links to organizational action.
Academy of Management Review, 12, 76-90.
Eugster, C.C., Kakkar, J.N., & Roegner, E.V. (2000). Bringing discipline to pricing. McKinsey
Quarterly, 1, 132-130.
Forman, H. & Hunt, J.M. (2005). Managing the influence of internal and external determinants
on international industrial pricing strategies. Industrial Marketing Management, 34, 133-146.
Forman, H., & Hunt, J.M. (2013). The effect of decision context on perceived risk in pricing
strategies: how managers view uncontrollable forces. Journal of Product and Brand
Management, 22, 79-86.
Fox, C.R., & Levav, J. (2000). Familiarity bias and belief reversal in relative likelihood
judgment. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 82, 268–292.
Frenzen, H., Hansen, A.-K., Krafft, M., Mantrala, M.K. & Schmidt, S. (2011). Delegation of
pricing authority to the sales force: an agency-theoretic perspective of its determinants and
impact on performance. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 27, 58-68.
George, J.F., Duffy, K., & Ahuja, M. (2000). Countering the anchoring and adjustment bias with
decision support systems. Decision Support Systems, 29, 195–206.
Gigerenzer, G. (1996). On Narrow norms and vague heuristics: A reply to Kahneman and
Tversky (1996). Psychological Review, 103 (3), 582-591.
Gigerenzer, G., & Gaissmaier, G. (2011). Heuristic decision making. Annual Review of
Psychology, 62, 451-482.
Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. G. (1996). Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of
bounded rationality. Psychological Review, 103, 650-669.
Griffith, D.E. & Rust, R.T. (1997). The price of competitiveness in competitive pricing. Journal
of the Academy of Marketing Science, 25, 109-116.
39
Hafenbrack, A.C., Kinias, Z., & Barsade, S. (2013). Debiasing the mind through meditation:
mindfulness and the sunk-cost bias. Psychological Science, published online December 6, 2013,
DOI: 10.1177/0956797613503853.
Hall, R.I. & Hitch, C.J. (1939). Price theory and business behavior. Oxford Economic Papers, 2,
12-45.
Hammond, J.S., Keeney, R., & Raiffa, H. (2006). The hidden traps in decision making. Harvard
Business Review, 76, 47-58.
Hawes, J.M. & Barnhouse, S.H. (1987). How purchasing agents handle personal risk. Industrial
Marketing Management, 16, 287-293.
Helps, B., & Saari, K. (2005). Relationship pricing for profitability. Commercial Lending
Review, 20, 3-6.
Hogan, J., & Lucke, T. (2006). Driving growth with new products: common pricing traps to
avoid. Journal of Business Strategy, 27, 54-58.
Howard, J.A., & Morgenroth, W.M. (1968), Information processing model of executive decision.
Management Science, 14, 416-428.
Huberman, G. (2001). Familiarity breeds investment. Review of Financial Studies, 14, 659-680.
Hunt, J.M., & Forman, H. (2006). The role of perceived risk in pricing strategy for industrial
products: a point-of-view perspective. Journal of Product and Brand Management, 15, 386-393.
Johansson, J.E., Krishnamurthy, C., & Schlissberg, H.E. (2003). Solving the solutions problem.
McKinsey Quarterly, 3, 116-125.
Johnston, W.J. & Lewin, J.E. (1996). Organizational buying behavior: toward an integrative
framework. Journal of Business Research, 35, 1-15.
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A., (Eds.). (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics
and biases. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk,
Econometrica, 47, 263-291.
40
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1996). On the reality of cognitive illusions. Psychological
Review, 103, 582-591.
Kauffman, R.G. (1996). Influences on organizational buying choice processes: future research
directions. Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing, 11, 94-107.
Kopalle, P., Mela, C.F., & Marsh, L. (1999). The dynamic effect of discounting on sales:
empirical analysis and normative pricing implications. Marketing Science, 18, 317-333.
Krishnamurthy, C., Johansson, J., & Schlissberg, H. (2003). Solutions selling: is the pain worth
the gain? McKinsey Marketing Solutions, April,
http://www.mckinsey.com/practices/marketing/ourknowledge/pdf/Solutions_SolutionsSelling.pd
f
Lancioni, R. (2005b). A strategic approach to industrial product pricing: the pricing plan.
Industrial Marketing Management, 34, 177-183.
Lancioni, R., Schau, H.J., & Smith, M.F. (2005). Intraorganizational influences on business-to-
business pricing strategies: a political economy perspective. Industrial Marketing Management,
34, 123-131.
Levinthal, D.A. (2011). A behavioral approach to strategy – what’s the alternative? Strategic
Management Journal, 32, 1517-1523.
Liozu, S.M. (2012). Complexity theory and pricing management. Journal of Professional
Pricing, Q3, 10-17.
Liozu, S.M., Boland, R.J. Jr., Hinterhuber, A., & Perelli, S. (2011). Industrial pricing orientation:
the organizational transformation to value-based pricing. Paper presented at the First
International Conference on Engaged Management Scholarship, Case Western Reserve
University, Cleveland, Ohio, June, [Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1839838].
Liozu, S.M., & Hinterhuber, A. (2013). CEO championing of pricing, pricing capabilities and
firm performance in industrial firms. Industrial Marketing Management, 42, 633-643.
Liozu, S.M., & Hinterhuber, A. (2014). Pricing capabilities: the design, development, and
validation of a scale. Management Decision, 52, 144-158.
41
Little, J.D.C., & Shapiro, J.F. (1980). A theory of pricing nonfeatured products in supermarkets.
Journal of Business, 53, s199-s209.
Lovallo, D., & Sibony, O. (2010). The case for behavioral strategy. McKinsey Quarterly, March,
1-14.
March, J.G. (1978). Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the engineering of choice. Bell Journal
of Economics, 9, 587-608.
March, J.G. (1994). A primer on decision making. New York: Free Press.
Miller, D. & Friesen, P. (1982). Innovation in conservative and entrepreneurial firms: two
models of strategic momentum. Strategic Management Journal, 4, 221-235.
Monroe, K.B., & Cox, J.L. (2001). Pricing practices that endanger profits. Marketing
Management, 10, 42-46.
Morris, M.H., & Calantone, R. (1990). Four components of effective pricing. Industrial
Marketing Management, 19, 321-329.
Morris, M.H., & Morris, G. (1990). Market-oriented pricing: strategies for management.
Westport, CT: Quorum Books.
Morris, M.H., & Schurink, C.v.E. (1993). Pricing behavior in industrial markets. Journal of
Business and Industrial Marketing, 8, 28-43.
Mowday, R.T., & Sutton, R.I. (1993). Organizational behavior: linking individuals and groups to
organizational contexts. Annual Review of Psychology, 44, 195-229.
Nagle, T.T., Hogan, J., & Zale, J. (2010). The strategy and tactics of pricing: a guide to growing
more profitably. (5th ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Nelson, R.R., & Winter, S.G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge,
MA: Belknap Press.
Noble, P.M., & Gruca, T.S. (1999). Industrial pricing: theory and practice. Marketing Science,
18, 435-454.
Nunes, P.F., & Hanson, J.G. (2012). Are you taking full advantage of the pricing window?
Outlook, 2, http://www.accenture.com/us-en/outlook/Pages/outlook-journal-2012-taking-full-
advantage-of-pricing-window.aspx
42
Oxenfeldt, A.R. (1973). A decision-making structure for price decisions. Journal of Marketing,
37, 48-53.
Ozer, O., & Zheng, Y. C. (2012). Behavioural issues in pricing management. In O. Ozer & R.
Phillips (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Pricing Management (pp. 415-460). Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press.
Powell, T.C., Lovallo, D., & Fox, C.R. (2011). Behavioral strategy. Strategic Management
Journal, 32, 1369-1386.
Prietula, M.J., & Simon, H.A. (1989). Experts in your midst. Harvard Business Review, 67, 120-
124.
Puto, C.P., Patton, W.E., III, & King, R.H. (1985). Risk handling strategies in industrial vendor
selection decisions. Journal of Marketing, 49, 89-98.
Qualls, W.J. & Puto, C.P. (1989). Organizational climate and decision framing: an integrated
approach to analyzing industrial buying decisions. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 179-192.
Richards, K.A., & Jones, E. (2008). Customer relationship management: finding value drivers.
Industrial Marketing Management, 37, 120-130.
Robinson, P.J., Faris, C.W. & Wind, Y. (1967). Industrial buying behavior and creative
marketing. Boston, MA: Allyn & Bacon.
Roegner, E., & Gobbi, J. (2001). Effective solutions pricing: How to get the best premium from
strategic collaborations. McKinsey Marketing Solutions, May,
http://www.mckinsey.com/practices/marketing/ourknowledge/pdf/Solutions_SolutionsPricing.pd
f
Rust, R. T., Lemon, K. N., & Zeithaml, V. A. (2001). Where should the next marketing dollar
go? Marketing Management, 10, 25−28.
Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk
and Uncertainty, 1, 7-59.
Sawhney, M. (2006). Going beyond the product: defining, designing and delivering customer
solutions. In R.F. Lusch and S.L. Vargo (Eds.), The Service Dominant Logic of Marketing:
Dialog, Debate, and Directions (pp. 365-380). Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.
Senge, Peter (1994). The Fifth Discipline: The Art and Practice of the Learning Organization.
New York, NY: Doubleday Publishing.
43
Sharma, A., & Iyer, G.R. (2011). Are pricing policies an impediment to the success of customer
solutions? Industrial Marketing Management, 40, 723-29.
Sheth, J.A. (1973). A model of industrial buyer behavior. Journal of Marketing, 37, 50-56.
Simon, H.A. (1947). Administrative behavior. New York: The Macmillan Company.
Simon, H.A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69,
99-118.
Skouras, T., Avlonitis, G.J., & Indounas, K.A. (2005). Economics and marketing on pricing: how
and why do they differ? Journal of Product and Brand Management, 14, 362-374.
Smith, G.E. (1995). Managerial pricing orientation: the process of making pricing decisions,
Pricing Strategy and Practice, 3, 28-39.
Spender, J.-C. (1989). Industry recipes: the nature and sources of managerial judgment. Oxford,
UK: Basil Blackwell.
Tellis, G.J. (1986). Beyond the many faces of price: an integration of pricing strategies. Journal
of Marketing, 50, 146-160.
Tellis, G.J., & Johnson, J. (2007). The value of quality. Marketing Science, 26, 758-773.
Thaler, R. (1980). Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior
and Organization, 1, 39-60.
Thomas, J.B., & McDaniel, R.R., Jr. (1990). Interpreting strategic issues: effects of strategy and
the information-processing structure of top management teams. Academy of Management
Journal, 33, 286-306.
Thomas, J.B., Clark, S.M., & Gioia, D.A. (1993). Strategic sensemaking and organizational
performance: linkages among scanning, interpretation, action, and outcomes. Academy of
Management Journal, 36, 239-270.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases.
Science, 185, 1124–1130.
44
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference dependent
model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, (November), 1039-1061
Urbany, J. E. (2001). Justifying profitable pricing. Journal of Product & Brand Management, 10,
141-159.
van Dijk E, & Van Knippenberg D. (1996). Buying and selling exchange goods: loss aversion
and the endowment effect. Journal of Economic Psychology, 17, 517-524.
van Someren, M.W., Barnard, Y.F., & Sandberg, J.A. C. (1994). The think aloud method.
London: Academic Press.
Voeth, M., & Herbst, U. (2006). Supply-chain pricing – a new perspective on pricing in
industrial markets. Industrial Marketing Management, 35, 83-90.
Vonk, R. (1999). Effects of outcome dependency on correspondence bias. Personality and Social
Psychology Bulletin, 25, 382–389.
Webster, F.E., Jr., & Wind, Y. (1972). A general model for understanding organizational buying
behavior. Journal of Marketing, 36, 12-9.
Weick, K.E. (1979). The social psychology of organizing. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies. New York: Free Press.
Wilson, E. J. (1984). A case study of repeat buying for a commodity. Industrial Marketing
Management, 13, 195-200.
Wilson, E.J., McMurrian, R.C., & Woodside, A.G. (2001). How buyers frame problems:
revisited, Psychology and Marketing, 18, 617-655.
Woodside, A. G., & Wilson, E. J. (2000). Constructing thick descriptions of marketers’ and
buyers’ decision processes in business-to-business relationships. Journal of Business &
Industrial Marketing, 15, 354-369.
45
Figure 1
A Conceptual Framework for Understanding the Interpretation of Context on Pricing Strategy
Environmental Context
Issue Interpretation
Cognitive Biases
Heuristics
46
Table 1: Putative Behavioral Biases and Implications for Pricing
Pricing Stage Putative Behavioral Biases Implications for Pricing Sample Research on Reducing bias
in Pricing
Selecting the Loss Aversion: Managers may choose less Inappropriate pricing setting Perspective Taking. Taking the
Pricing Objective risky objectives to avoid losses (Tversky & (considered safe) may be chosen in perspective of others or thinking of
Kahneman 1991; van Dijk & van Knipenberg pricing. For example, instead of a decisions as making them for others
1996) product leadership strategy for quality reduces biases (c.f., Andersson, Holm,
Good Enough Returns: Managers may satisfy products, managers may undervalue Tyran & Wengström (2013).
on their objective rather than optimize quality and choose a safer objective Adaptive Learning – learn through
(Kahneman & Tversky 1979). (Tellis & Johnson 2007). Managers feedback on previous decisions (Al-
Endowment Effect: What is owned is may be more focused on current Najjar, Baliga & Besanko, 2008).
preferred to what can be obtained (Thaler markets rather than pursue strategies of
1980) gaining customers from competitors
through pricing.
Estimating and Overconfidence: Managers may believe Managers may incorrectly estimate Information sharing within the firm,
Determining strongly in their own knowledge and demand for their products. Current outside the firm (suppliers) and the use
Demand information (Barber & Odean 1999; Daniel & consumers and markets may be valued of industry experts reduces demand
Titman 1999; Coval & Shumway 2005) more in order to maintain a positive determination biases (c.f., Ozer &
Correspondence Bias: Errors are made when self-image (Beggan 1992). Zheng, 2012, p5).
inferring dispositions from behaviors of Managers may wrongly infer Adaptive Learning (as above).
customers (Vonk 1999) purchasing managers’ preferences and
Representativeness Bias: Desirable qualities intentions.
are overvalued (De Bondt & Thaler 1985) Managers may assume that good
companies are also good customers.
Estimating and Sunk Costs Fallacy: Past costs and Managers may be focused on the Mindfulness - Mindfulness can be
Determining Costs investments influence future choices (Arkes & recovery of past investments and increased by meditation that reduces
Blumer 1985) include these in costs for pricing. the sunk cost bias (Hafenbrack, Kinias,
Also, the purchase of an input under a & Barsade 2013).
long-term contract may be treated as a
sunk cost rather than something that
can be resold (Al-Najjar et al. 2008)
Competitive Anchoring and Adjustment: Adjustments are Despite adjustments, managers’ Feedback mechanisms on pricing
Analysis of Cost, made from some known information so as to perceptions of competitive actions may decisions reduces biases (Al-Najjar,
Price Tactics, and arrive at values that are acceptable. However, not change much. Therefore, prices Baliga & Besanko, 2008; Ozer &
47
Discounts/Rebates the final values are close to the anchor may change despite new competitive Zheng, 2012). Use of Decision
(Tversky & Kahneman 1974) information. Support Systems reduces biases
(George, Duffy & Ahuja 2000)
Determining a Familiarity Bias: Managers may prefer tools Familiar and currently used cost-plus Improving understanding of managers'
Pricing and techniques that they know more than ones approaches may be used even though information environment and how
Methodology that are more appropriate (Huberman 2001) the situation may call for other uncertainty should be dealt with
methods. (Urbany, 2001). Use probabilities to
make decisions (Fox & Levav 2000).
Setting the Price Status Quo Bias: Doing nothing when faced Managers rely on current approach to Revisit the pricing decision and create
& Deviating from with choices (Samuelson & Zeckhauser 1988) price setting and also do not deviate a new decision tree, highlighting
List Prices from list prices even when the situation customer preferences. Match data with
changes. external customer data.
48