An Economic History of West Africa by A. G. Hopkins
An Economic History of West Africa by A. G. Hopkins
AFRICA
This pioneering and celebrated work was the first, and remains the standard, account
of the economic history of the huge area conventionally known as West Africa.
The book ranges from prehistoric times to independence and covers the former
French territories, as well as those colonised by the British. It criticises conventional
beliefs about economic backwardness, offers an alternative account that explains the
particular configuration of poverty that characterised the pre-colonial period, and
assesses the consequences of the region’s interaction with the wider world – from
the growth of the Saharan and Atlantic trades to the rise and demise of colonial
rule. This edition contains a substantial new Introduction that discusses the develop-
ment of the subject during the past 50 years, evaluates the debate over the original
interpretation, and provides a valuable guide to additional reading, bringing the
reader up to date with current scholarship on the subject, as well as providing
avenues for further independent research.
Appearing at a time when the study of African economic history is enjoying
a revival and is engaging economists as well as historians, the book fills a large gap in
African studies, provides newcomers with a stimulating point of entry into the subject,
and contributes to our understanding of wider issues of global underdevelopment.
A. G. Hopkins
Second edition published 2020
by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon, OX14 4RN
and by Routledge
52 Vanderbilt Avenue, New York, NY 10017
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2020 A. G. Hopkins
The right of A. G. Hopkins to be identified as author of this work has
been asserted by him in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced
or utilised in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means,
now known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and
recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without
permission in writing from the publishers.
Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or
registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and
explanation without intent to infringe.
First edition published by Addison Wesley Longman Limited 1973
First edition published by Routledge 2014
Second edition published by Routledge 2020
British Library Cataloguing-in-Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Names: Hopkins, A. G., (Antony G.), author.
Title: An economic history of West Africa / A.G. Hopkins.
Description: 2nd edition. | New York, NY : Routledge, 2020. |
Includes bibliographical references and index. |
Identifiers: LCCN 2019025291 (print) | LCCN 2019025292 (ebook) |
ISBN 9780367002435 (hardback) | ISBN 9780367002442 (paperback) |
ISBN 9780429400582 (ebook) Subjects: LCSH: Africa,
West--Economic conditions.
Classification: LCC HC517.W5 H66 2020 (print) | LCC HC517.W5
(ebook) | DDC 330.966--dc23
LC record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2019025291
LC ebook record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2019025292
Typeset in Bembo
by Swales & Willis, Exeter, Devon, UK
CONTENTS
Bibliography 352
Index 381
MAPS
The publishers are grateful to the following for permission to base maps and
graphs used in this book on those appearing in the publications mentioned:
Methuen & Co. Ltd. for Maps 1, 2, 3, 4, 13, 15, 16 and 17, based on pages
209, 16, 101, 135, 473, 94, 578 and 672 of West Africa by W. B. Morgan and
J. C. Pugh (1969); the Controller of Her Majesty’s Stationery Office for Map 7,
based on page 151 of the Journal of Local Administration Overseas, Vol. 1. No. 3,
July 1962; Cambridge University Press for Maps 6 and 10, based on pages 69
and 131 of Colonialism in Africa, 1870–1960, Vol. I The History and Politics of
Colonialism, 1870–1914, ed. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan (1969), and for
Map 7, based on page 15 of A History of West Africa by J. D. Fage (1969); Yale
University Press for Figure 4, based on pages 136–7 of Government and Economic
Development, ed. Gustav Ranis (1971); Richard D. Irwin, Inc. for Figures 1 and
3, based on material compiled by G. K. Helleiner in Peasant Agriculture, Govern-
ment, and Economic Growth in Nigeria (Homewood, Illinois, 1966), pages 494–5
and 500; École Pratique des Hautes Études, VIe Section, Études et mémoires, 37,
for Figures 2 and 5, based on pages 24, 27 and 135 of Les relations économiques
extérieures des pays d’Afrique noire de l’union française, 1923–1953 by J. J. Poquin
(1957); and Jurisprudence Générale Dalloz for Figure 6, based on page 119 of
Essai sur la conjoncture de l’Afrique noire by H. Durand (1957).
PREFACE TO THE FIRST EDITION
In writing this book I have developed a close affinity with one of the more popular
figures of modern Scottish folklore, the man who, so the story goes, spends all his
life painting the bridge spanning the Firth of Forth. His job is never finished because
by the time he reaches one end, the other (by then barely visible) needs painting
again. My own task has also seemed an endless one: every time I put the finishing
touches to Chapter 7 I had to double back and start, once more, to cover the cracks
which were beginning to show in Chapter 2. Unlike my mythical Scots friend,
however, I have now decided to down tools, not because perfection has been
reached—far from it—but because there comes a time when the pursuit of unattain-
able goals threatens to undermine the sanity of the pursuer. My diary tells me that
I began work on the manuscript about six years ago, though there have been periods
when the job has seemed to me, and doubtless to my patient publishers too, to have
occupied a lifetime. The Forth Bridge painter, being a self-sufficient man as well as
a persistent one, always works alone. I, too, have wielded the brush, but my efforts
have been supported by skilled helpers who have mixed the paint, assisted me in
reaching into awkward corners, and, occasionally, used a blowlamp on my work.
I am indebted to John Fage, the Director of the Centre of West African Studies,
for encouraging the study of West African economic history at Birmingham, for
sharing with me his unrivalled knowledge of West African history, and for creating
in the Centre an atmosphere which has benefited the work of staff and students
alike. Two colleagues in the Centre, Marion Johnson and Douglas Rimmer,
answered a variety of questions during the writing stage, read substantial sections of
the manuscript, and suggested improvements covering matters of style, fact, and
logic. The sudden, premature death of another colleague, R. E. Bradbury, occurred
when the manuscript was still in an elementary state, but at a time when we had
entered on a series of stimulating discussions about the relationship between social
anthropology and economic history. This book would have gained considerably
Preface to the first edition xi
from Brad’s comments. I have tried to keep his high standards in mind, even if
I have not been able to match them.
I have also benefited greatly from my position as an attached member of the
Department of Economic and Social History. The late W. H. B. Court’s gentle
nature and catholic view of the study of economic history were particularly congen-
ial to me as a young and inexperienced apprentice to the craft. The present Head of
the Department, John Harris, encouraged me when I was beginning to flag, and
found time, despite severe pressure of work, to read a large part of the manuscript.
I am grateful, too, to Cyril Ehrlich of The Queen’s University, Belfast, and to
Stuart Bruchey of Columbia University, New York, both of who made valuable
comments on sizeable sections of an earlier draft of the manuscript.
All these scholars have helped to improve an imperfect work. The failings
which remain are entirely my own.
Specific debts to other writers, too numerous to record here, are acknow-
ledged in the footnotes and in the bibliography. Any clarity of argument and
presentation which this work now possesses owes a great deal to questions raised
by undergraduate and graduate students who have taken my courses at Birming-
ham since 1964. Their reward, belated though it is, is that they have helped to
ease the burden of learning for their successors.
In the academic year 1969–70, I had the good fortune to hold a Research
Fellowship at the University of Leicester. It was during this break from teaching
and administrative duties that I had time to appreciate the full extent of the
inadequacies of the first draft of the manuscript, and to begin work on what was
to become the final version. I am grateful to the University of Leicester for its
generosity, and to Ralph Davis and the other members of the Department of
Economic History for the warmth of their welcome. Happily, friendships made
in that year have survived my departure from Leicester.
The substantial task of compiling the bibliography was made easier by the
thorough assistance given by Robert Irving and Jocelyn Abbey. The equally
substantial task of typing the manuscript was undertaken, very willingly and
between other duties, by the secretarial staff of the Centre of West African Stud-
ies, by Helen Thompson of the School of Education, and, above all, by Cathy
Macartney of the Department of Economic and Social History, who, unlike the
author, remained calm and efficient even in the final, hectic stages.
My parents and my wife have been called on, over a period of years, to show
forbearance in the face of neglect, to believe in the hopelessly optimistic forecasts
which authors habitually make, and to remind me at times of depression that the
Economic History of West Africa is not the totality of life’s experiences. If this book has
sufficient merit, it is offered, in part compensation, to them.
A. G. Hopkins
Centre of West African Studies
University of Birmingham
PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION
It is unusual for the second edition of an academic book to appear almost 50 years
after it was first published. I anticipated revising my Economic History long ago, but
good intentions were not enough to subdue temptations that carried me in other
directions. Over the decades, I waylaid myself by becoming involved in several fas-
cinating but consuming subjects: British imperialism, globalisation, and American
Empire. Accordingly, I must admit to occupying a prominent place in a highly
competitive category: that of defaulting academic authors. In mitigation, I should
add that the evolution of the subject also erected scholarly obstacles. Economic History
is a book with an argument that has either to be defended or revised. As time
passed, it became clear that defending the interpretation against all-comers would be
time-consuming and might also be unprofitable. I had made my statement; it was
for others to use it to devise a superior alternative. The need to adjust to successive
historiographical trends added to my difficulty. Had I attempted to keep pace with
shifting priorities—from the dependency thesis to postmodernism—the resulting
new edition would have lost whatever unity and clarity the original had and would
have become a jumble of contending influences, each with its own appeal and fla-
vour, like a huge and indigestible club sandwich.
The most desirable outcome is one that is tempting, necessary, and available: to
produce an entirely new text that converts the massive volume of research produced
since the 1960s into a fresh and stimulating argument. The philosophers’ stone will
empower the successful author; the doors of Valhalla will be open to those who fall
in the attempt. The task will undoubtedly be accomplished, but it needs more time
and a fresher mind than the present author has at his disposal. A salutary Yoruba
proverb has guided this judgement: ‘a sculptor is summoned but a woodpecker
arrives’. It is wise not to apply skills you do not possess.
For these reasons, and in accord with advice of colleagues, I have adopted
the only realistic solution, which is to treat the book as being of its time, and to
Preface to the second edition xiii
1 Beginnings
I graduated in 1960, received an award to undertake research, and spent two
months trying to decide which part of the Rest of the World should benefit
from the combination of enthusiasm and ignorance I had to offer.1 There was
only one certainty: I wanted to move on from the study of British history that
dominated undergraduate courses at the time and explore somewhere different.
Indian history flourished at Cambridge but was focused on the politics of
nationalism, a topical theme but not one that fitted my own interests. Latin
America was an attractive prospect, but I was advised that there were only ‘one
and half’ possible supervisors in Britain at that time. I soon realised, too, that the
field had already been colonised by scholars in the United States. East Asia beck-
oned, mainly because the Japanese ‘miracles’ (one following 1868, another in
the 1950s) had inspired some pioneering studies in economic history.2 Accord-
ingly, I went to see Professor W. G. (‘Big Bill’) Beasley at the School of Orien-
tal and African Studies (SOAS), who received me kindly but left me daunted by
the number of years I would need to devote to learning Japanese and, ideally,
studying Mandarin as well.3 Could I be sure that the investment would be justi-
fied by any historical work I might eventually produce? I could not.
1 In those days, new graduates (in Britain) moved from final B.A. exams to Ph.D. research without
the intervention of a further year’s training.
2 I was especially impressed by Thomas C. Smith’s Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan (Stanford, 1959),
a remarkable work that influenced my approach to precolonial Africa.
3 William G. Beasley (1919–2006), another extraordinary scholar, had planned to write a new social
history of England that would replace G. M. Trevelyan’s standard works. Like a clutch of other
scholars, his experiences during the Second World War caused him to change course.
2 Introduction
4 John D. Fage (1921–2002); joined SOAS in 1959; Director of the Centre of West African Studies,
University of Birmingham, 1963–84.
5 John Fage records our first meeting in J. D. Fage, To Africa and Back (Centre of West African Studies,
Birmingham, 2002), p. 120. I have supplemented John’s account with my own record of our first
meeting.
6 For illustrations see A. G. Hopkins, ‘Fifty Years of African Economic History’, Economic History of
Developing Regions, 34 (2019), pp. 1–15.
Introduction 3
7 For an example of callow youth jousting with lofty authority (Geoffrey Elton, Regius Professor of
History at Cambridge), see A. G. Hopkins, ‘History at the Universities: Change without Decay’,
History, LIV (1969), pp. 331–7.
4 Introduction
I entered Lagos pondering the difference between what we want to see in the
past and what we find there, and how to manage the disparity when the two
appeared to be misaligned.8
My own inspiration, as John Fage noted in his autobiography, came neither
from the liberation movements nor from any family or fortuitous connection
with Africa, but from an abiding interest in the history of capitalism. As an
undergraduate, I had studied the economic and social history of Tudor and
Stuart England, when the subject was strongly influenced by such dominant fig-
ures as R. H. Tawney and Christopher Hill, and the central controversy of
the day turned on the question of when and to what extent feudalism had been
overtaken by a bourgeois system of political economy. In 1957, dissatisfaction
with the terms of this long-running debate prompted another noted historian,
F. J. Fisher, to suggest that it might be more illuminating to view the England
of the Tudors and Stuarts as an example of an underdeveloped economy.9
Fisher never developed his stimulating idea with the authority he undoubtedly
commanded, but he opened a line of enquiry that led me to some of the first
texts on underdevelopment, notably works by Arthur Lewis and Hla Myint.10
Lightly armed and without a detailed plan of campaign, I then launched my
own private invasion of Africa.
My distinctive contribution to knowledge, which I now feel free to record,
was to refrain from publishing my Ph.D. dissertation. In those days, ‘the book’
had yet to become totemic, whereas articles in good journals were highly
prized. My original idea, arising from my interest in capitalism, was to study
African merchants in Lagos. However, the advice I received from my seniors in
African studies suggested that this would be a risky project because I would be
unlikely to find the necessary documentation. Accordingly, I opted for
a cautious, externally oriented topic, which was eventually submitted under
a title that had the merit of honesty but the appeal of an insurance policy,
which in a sense it was: ‘An Economic History of Lagos, 1880–1914’. While
conducting fieldwork in Lagos during my second year of research, I realised that
enough evidence was available to make my initial plan feasible. By then, how-
ever, it was too late to change course. I ended by gathering material for two
dissertations, finishing one, and publishing neither. Nevertheless, all was not lost:
8 In 1961, I was Nigeria’s first Commonwealth Scholar from the United Kingdom, but my award
did not reach me until shortly before I was due to return to UK. One other scholar received the
award in that year: J. N. Matjei from South Africa. Unfortunately, we never met.
9 F. J. Fisher, ‘The Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries: The Dark Ages in English Economic
History?’, Economica, 24 (1957), pp. 2–18. This was Fisher’s inaugural lecture as Professor of Eco-
nomic History at the London School of Economics.
10 W A. Lewis, The Theory of Economic Growth (Homewood, IL, 1955); Hla Myint, The Economics of
the Developing Countries (New York, 1965). In default of available specialists in African economic
history, my Ph.D. was examined by F. J. Fisher and Fredrick Madden, with John Fage protectively
chairing the occasion.
Introduction 5
in the course of the 1960s, I published several articles in a range of history jour-
nals that played a modest part in advertising the potential of the subject.
More important still, my Ph.D. was a sufficient demonstration of competence
to land me a junior position in the new Centre of West African Studies at Bir-
mingham University in 1963. It was there, during the rest of the 1960s and into
the 1970s, that I scrambled to create courses and laboured to teach them. Never
was the phrase ‘one paragraph ahead’ more justly applied; never was inadequacy
more keenly felt. It was this obligation that drew me into producing my Eco-
nomic History. When approached by a publisher to write such a book, I declined
on the grounds that it was premature. We compromised: I agreed to produce
a set of readings and write an Introduction to the volume. The readings were
assembled; the Introduction became the book I said could not be written.
11 Robert Szereszewski, Structural Changes in the Economy of Ghana, 1891–1911 (London, 1965). The
literature on women and gender relations generally is now extensive. For one example, see Claire
C. Robinson and Martin A. Klein, eds. Women and Slavery in Africa (Madison, WI, 1983).
6 Introduction
scholars today, was the dominant paradigm of the time. Africa, the dark and
benighted continent, which occupied the lowest end of the league table of back-
ward regions, provided the supreme test of the credibility of the theory. Devel-
opment experts turned a portfolio of theoretical assumptions into policies aimed
at controlling extensive cultivation, reducing the size of the extended family,
and reforming cultures that perpetuated anti-modern values.12 Good intentions
affected lives. Historians had an opportunity to evaluate far-reaching assumptions
that were influencing development policies. It was a rare moment.
In what was still my innocence, which hindered my foresight, I failed to anticipate
several objections that were to appear in the 1970s and 1980s. Dependency theorists
and Marxists saw the word ‘market’ and concluded that my book was, in the words
of the distinguished economic anthropologist, Claude Meillassoux, a ‘bourgeois
textbook’.13 Critics were not to know that I had spent many hours in the 1960s dis-
cussing with Ken Post, a noted Africanist and formidable theoretician on the left,
whether a Marxist schema could be applied to the continent.14 Neither of us could
devise a satisfactory model. Admittedly, some commentators were later to see in the
past what I had failed to discern there, but in this respect their vision turned out to
be short-sighted. The limitations of the dependency thesis soon became apparent;
Marxist perceptions of modes of production were eventually caught on the barbed
wire of theory as they struggled to reach the irreconcilable facts of Africa’s past.
A number of anthropologists who were not part of the radical left accepted that
markets were present in precolonial Africa but denied that they operated according
to Western principles. The ensuing debate, summarised in the literature as formal-
ism versus substantivism, ran on through the 1960s and 1970s before receding in
the 1980s, by which time economists had also abandoned the notion of a traditional
society.15 The formalist approach rested on the assumption that principles regarded
12 I was a junior presence at the Volta River Conference in 1966 and listened in amazement as
‘experts’ explained, with the aid of maps and housing plans, how modern design would curtail the
extended family and encourage intensive cultivation. See now Peter A. Bloom, Stephen Miescher,
and Takyiwaa Manu, eds. Modernization as Spectacle in Africa (Bloomington, IN, 2014), Ch. 8, and
additional references given there.
13 As reported to me at the time. Henri Brunschwig, doyen of the traditional imperial historians, said
that the book contained too much ‘theory’. Whether for these or other reasons, the book has rarely
been cited in the French literature.
14 Ken Post (1935–2017), political scientist, historian, founding member of the Centre of West Afri-
can Studies at Birmingham University, and a prolific writer on West Africa, the Caribbean, Viet-
nam, and Marxist theory.
15 See Gareth Austin, ‘The Problem of Embeddedness and Global Economic History’, paper pre-
sented to the Third GEHN (Global Economic History Network) conference, Konstanz, (2004),
and the additional references given there; idem, ‘Development “Paths” and “Civilisations” in
Africa: Reflections on Strategies for Integrating Cultural and Material Explanations of Differential
Long-Term Economic Performance’, in Masahiko Aoki, Timur Kuran, and Gérard Roland, eds.
Institutions and Comparative Development (London, 2012), Ch. 12; Paul Collier and Jan Willem Gun-
ning, ‘Explaining African Economic Performance’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37 (1999), pp.
78–9.
Introduction 7
as Western were applicable to this case and perhaps universally too. This position
raised the awkward possibility that I might be imposing a form of intellectual neo-
colonialism at the moment when, supposedly, Africa was being liberated. Yet,
empirical research indicated that African markets functioned according to principles
of supply and demand, even after various qualifications had been included.16 Entre-
preneurial decisions were rational in the sense of matching inputs and outputs in
cost-effective ways; profit was pursued within the constraints imposed by risk,
imperfect information, and transaction charges. These findings could not account
for all facets of economic behaviour. They did, however, explain the greater pro-
portion of the variance over long stretches of time. In doing so, they tore a hole in
the concept of ‘traditional’ societies and suggested that, whatever else inhibited Afri-
ca’s economic development, it was not the stifling weight of inflexible institutions
or an absence of entrepreneurial spirit.
Nevertheless, my formulation undoubtedly lacked subtlety and my exposition
had an unremitting quality that I now attribute, perhaps indulgently, to my
focus on destroying some of the powerful myths that shaped attitudes and pol-
icies towards Africa at that time.17 I had no difficulty accepting that entrepre-
neurial decisions were embedded in society, but I was equally clear that taking
this step did not entail embracing the position adopted by substantivists. Rather,
it was to recognise that economic decisions in all societies, including the most
developed, were (and still are) shaped by a mix of motives. Western economic
theory itself has moved towards this reality, which helps to explain why Herbert
Simon’s notion of ‘satisficing’ won him a Nobel Prize.
At a less elevated level than this, I drew attention to ways in which Western
societies departed from textbook statements of rational, maximising behaviour
by condoning restrictive practices, failing to give opportunities to women, per-
petuating systems of patronage, endorsing principles of reciprocity, and pursuing
non-economic goals, such as power and prestige.18 The conclusion I drew was
that all societies, including the most developed, tolerate and often protect prac-
tices that are economically inefficient. Accordingly, an understanding of Africa’s
relative economic backwardness should be sought, not by measuring the
16 For a recent confirmation and additional references, Klas Rönnbäck, ‘Climate, Conflicts, and Vari-
ations in Prices on Pre-Colonial West African Markets’, Economic History Review, 67 (2014), pp.
1065–88.
17 I offered a more refined analysis in ‘Innovation in a Colonial Context: African Origins of the
Nigerian Cocoa-Farming Industry, 1880–1920’, in Clive Dewey and A. G. Hopkins, eds. The
Imperial Impact: Studies in the Economic History of Africa and India (London, 1978), Ch. 5.
18 Economic History of West Africa (hereafter EHWA), pp. 66–67, 98, 110 n.139, 111–12. And, I would
now add, by manifesting impressive levels of corruption. For the case of the USA, see: https://en
.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_American_state_and_local_politicians_convicted_of_crimes. Research
at the University of Chicago estimates that ‘one in seven US companies is engaging in some kind
of fraud, costing investors about a fifth of the value of those companies’. Chris Dillow, ‘Look a Gift
Horse in the Mouth’, Financial Times Money, 16 February 2019.
8 Introduction
19 Consequently, my illustrations were drawn more from southern coastal regions than ideally they
should have been and did not give sufficient attention to pastoralism. Subsequent research should
allow this imbalance to be corrected. See in particular, Paul Lovejoy, Caravans of Kola: The Hausa
Kola Trade, 1700–1900 (Zaria, 1980); idem, Transformations in Slavery (Cambridge, 1983); idem,
Salt of the Desert Sun: A History of Salt Production and Trade in the Central Sudan (Cambridge, 1985).
20 Philip D. Curtin made a much better start on the subject in Economic Change in Precolonial Africa:
Senegambia in the Era of the Slave Trade (Madison, WI, 1974), Ch. 2.
21 EHWA, pp. 53–54.
Introduction 9
ways that expressed competition and conflict as well as harmony and cohesion. The
mood of the moment, however, inclined commentators to put Africans on
a pedestal to compensate for the image of inferiority they had long suffered. Never-
theless, full decolonisation required full disclosure: the desire to recover African
agency obliged historians to accept realities that revealed the darker side of human
behaviour without also categorising them as evidence of racial prejudice, as had
happened when I made my first trip to Lagos.22
I based the chapter on the assumption that West Africa, like most of the
continent, could be categorised as having a land-surplus economy.23 This
approach provided a better fit with what was known of the region’s popula-
tion and natural resources than was available in most of the literature on eco-
nomic backwardness, which held, in the Malthusian tradition, that
underdeveloped countries were also likely to be overpopulated. In drawing
attention to the heterogeneity of what was then referred to, in the aggregate,
as the Third World, the concept of a land-surplus economy also provided
a way of describing the particular configuration of underdevelopment that
characterised West Africa.24
The argument joined some reasonably well-attested evidence of the
prevalence and longevity of extensive cultivation to some uncertain demo-
graphic data. Extensive forms of agriculture and pastoralism were adjust-
ments to a combination of poor resources and sparse population. Exceptions
proved the rule: intensive agriculture was found where these conditions
were absent, principally in the vicinity of towns, where population densities
were higher, in limited areas of irrigation, and in some upland regions,
where settlement was concentrated for reasons of security.25 Demographic
data, however, were shaky then and remain uncertain today. In 1973,
I cited semi-informed guesses suggesting that the population of the region
numbered around 25 million in 1800. One recent calculation has proposed
a figure of 46 million for 1790 and 41 million for 1890; another estimates
26 Patrick Manning, ‘African Population, 1650–2000: Comparisons and Implications of New Esti-
mates’, in Emmanuel K. Akyeampong, et al., eds. Africa’s Development in Historical Perspective (Cam-
bridge, 2014), Ch 4; Ewout Frankema and Morten Jerven, ‘Writing History Backwards or
Sideways: Towards a Consensus on African population, 1850–2000’, Economic History Review, 67
(2014), p. 926. Both studies apply backward projections but differ in their selection and treatment
of base years and assumptions about fertility.
27 EHWA, pp. 74–75. James C. McCann, Maize and Grace: Africa’s Encounter with a New World Crop,
1500–2000 (Cambridge, MA, 2005); J. D. La Fleur, Fusion Foodways of Africa’s Gold Coast in the
Atlantic Era (Leiden, 2012) draws attention to the drawbacks as well as the advantages of the new
crops.
28 For one view of the possibilities, see Morten Jerven, ‘African Economic Growth Recurring: An
Economic History Perspective on African Growth Episodes, 1690–2010’, Economic History of Devel-
oping Regions, 25 (2010), pp. 127–4. For my own speculations, see EHWA, pp. 122–24.
29 Joseph E. Inikori has supplied the additional emphasis in ‘Reversal of Fortune and Socioeconomic
Development in the Atlantic World: A Comparative Examination of West Africa and the Amer-
icas, 1400–1850’, in Akyeampong, et al., Africa’s Development in Historical Perspective, Ch. 2.
30 EHWA, pp. 55–58.
Introduction 11
31 Sharon E. Nicholson, ‘Climatic and Environmental Changes in Africa during the Last Two Cen-
turies’, Climate Research, 17 (2001), pp. 123–44; Ewout Frankema, ‘The Biogeographic Roots of
World Inequality: Animals, Disease, and Human Settlement Patterns in Africa and the America
Before 1492’, World Development, 70 (2015), pp. 274–85; Levi Boxell, ‘Droughts, Conflict, and the
African Slave Trade’, MPRA Paper (2017) at: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/81924;
Kostadis Papaioannou and Ewout Frankema, ‘Rainfall Patterns and Human Settlement in Tropical
Africa and Asia Compared. Did African Farmers Face Greater Insecurity?’ CEPR Discussion Paper,
DP11795 (2017); Michael Mortimore, Roots in the African Dust: Sustaining the Dry Lands (Cam-
bridge, 1998) underlines the resilience of ‘traditional’ institutions in dealing with desertification);
John Iliffe made demography the central theme of his historical study, Africans: The History of
a Continent (Cambridge, 1995). The most prominent dissenting voice is that of Joseph E. Inikori,
‘The Development of Commercial Agriculture in Pre-Colonial Africa’, African Economics History
Network Working Paper, 9 (2013); idem. ‘Reversal of Fortune and Socioeconomic Development in
the Atlantic World’.
On disease see Marcella Alsan, ‘The Effect of the Tsetse Fly on African Development’, American
Economic Review, 105 (2015), pp. 382–410; James L. A. Webb, The Long Struggle Against Malaria in
Tropical Africa (New York, 2014); David N. Weil,‘The Impact of Malaria on African Development
over the Longue Durée’, in Akyeampong, et al., Africa’s Development in Historical Perspective, Ch. 3,
confirms that ‘malaria imposed a heavy mortality burden’ (p. 122), but argues that the effect on
output was limited because the death rate was particularly high among children rather than (work-
ing) adults. However, since there were fewer children reaching adulthood, the future workforce
was correspondingly reduced, as was the total population, thus reinforcing the limits on the market
imposed by the land-labour ratio. Myron Echenberg, Africa in the time of Cholera (New York,
2011), provides a study of one of the major diseases introduced into Africa.
32 EHWA, pp. 55–58; the quotation is on p. 55.
33 EHWA, p. 68.
12 Introduction
34 EHWA, pp. 93–96. As Philip J. Shea has shown in ‘The Development of an Export-Oriented
Dyed Cloth Industry in Kano Emirate in the Nineteenth Century’, University of Wisconsin-
Madison Ph.D. dissertation (1975); idem, ‘Big is Sometimes Best: The Sokoto Caliphate and Eco-
nomic Advantages of Size in the Textile Industry’, African Economic History, 34 (2006), pp. 5–21.
Kano dye pits have been dated to 1498.
35 These topics have been further developed by J. S. Hogendorn and H. A. Gemery, ‘Continuity in
West African Monetary History? An Outline of Monetary Development’, African Economic History,
17 (1988), pp. 127–46. Jane I. Guyer and Endre Stiansen, eds. Credit Currencies and Culture: African
Financial Institutions in Historical Perspective (Uppsala, 1999).
36 At the time of writing (in the 1960s), I thought about ways of applying Nelson’s (1956) notion of
a low-level equilibrium trap. Among other objections (see Myint, Economics of the Developing Coun-
tries, Ch. 7), Nelson assumed that the standard condition was one of population pressure. In recent
years, the idea has been applied flexibly to describe one or more ‘poverty traps’. Jeffrey D Sachs,
et al., have listed a set of constraints in Ending Africa’s Poverty Trap (Brookings Institute Papers on
Economic Activity, 2004), pp. 130–1, that are very similar to those identified in EHWA, Ch. 2.
See also the special issue (1) of the Journal of African History, 59 (2018).
37 Subsequent advances include Gareth Austin, ‘Resources, Techniques, and Strategies South of the
Sahara: Revising the Factor Endowments Perspective on African Economic Development,
1500–2000’, Economic History Review, 61 (2008), pp. 587–624; idem, ‘A. G. Hopkins, West Africa,
and Economic History’, in Toyin Falola and Emily Brownell, eds. Africa, Empire, and Globalization:
Essays in Honour of A. G. Hopkins (Durham, NC, 2011), Ch. 2, especially, pp. 66–7.
Introduction 13
namely high capital costs and unsuitable conditions.38 The main reason offered
is that the lack of political centralisation made it hard to supply public goods.39
This claim is indeed likely to be part of the story. However, the idea that con-
centrations of wealth were a precondition of capital investment in West Africa
(as elsewhere) is not novel, and it also calls for an analysis that relates political
structures to underlying conditions. The land-labour ratio remains a central
element in the explanation because it suggests why investment in modern tech-
nology would have been unprofitable at prevailing rates of return. Furthermore,
the established list of unsuitable conditions is not easily discounted.40 Some cen-
tralised states in West Africa, such as Asante, maintained a network of roads for
administrative and commercial purposes. Heavy rainfall, however, encouraged
forest growth and made upkeep costly: overhanging branches had to be cut
back; stumps and roots were not easily removed. These conditions could be
negotiated better by porters than by wheeled traffic.41
The largest omission from my account of institutions was the role of precolo-
nial states in promoting or retarding economic development.42 My main purpose
was to establish a line of enquiry into the past through economic history, and
this limited the scope I allowed myself for looking at parallel political and cul-
tural themes, even though it was evident that they were entwined. Another
problem, one of analysis rather than scope, had a more respectable intellectual
justification. In the 1960s, most of the research needed to connect political
structures to the exercise of power lay in the future; much of it still does.43
Admittedly, by the time I was writing, historians had published maps showing
the boundaries of precolonial states, but the illustrations suggested a certainty
that was not always well founded. Consequently, it was not at all clear how pre-
colonial West African states could be categorised or what their relationship was
38 Isias Chaves, Stanley L. Engermann, and James A. Robinson, ‘Reinventing the Wheel: The Eco-
nomic Benefits of Wheeled Transportation in Early Colonial British West Africa’, in Akyeampong,
et al., Africa’s Development in Historical Perspective, Ch. 10.
39 Space precludes a consideration of the additional reasons given by Chaves et al., which relate to
specific political considerations in the late nineteenth century,
40 Robin Law, ‘Wheeled Transport in Pre-Colonial West Africa’, Africa, 50 (1980), pp. 249–62;
Emily Lynn Osborn, ‘Containers, Energy and the Anthropocene in West Africa’, in Austin ed.,
Economic Development and Environmental History, Ch .4; Michael Cardew, A Pioneer Potter (London,
1988), especially pp. 109–13. Cardew (1901–1983), one of Britain’s most noted potters, spent
many years in West Africa and understood why the wheel was not used. Ralph Austen and Daniel
Headrick provide a thoughtful survey in ‘The Role of Technology in the African Past’, African
Studies Review, 26 (1983), pp. 163–84. For the debate on manufacturing and technology see African
Economic History, 19 (1990–1991), pp. 1–54.
41 Michael Charney, ‘Before and After the Wheel: Precolonial and Colonial States and Transportation
in West Africa and Southeast Asia’, HumaNettern, 37 (2016), pp. 9–38.
42 Richard Roberts, ‘Linkages and Multiplier Effects in the Ecologically Specialized Trade of Precolo-
nial West Africa’, Cahiers, d’Études Africaines, 20 (1980), pp. 135–48; and the commentary by
Steven Baier, ibid., pp. 149–54.
43 Murray Last, The Sokoto Caliphate (London, 1967) was a rare and notable exception.
14 Introduction
to economic development. Fortunately, progress has been made on all these sub-
jects, which will now be considered in conjunction with a discussion of external
trade.
5 External trade
The account of West Africa’s external trade in Chapter 3 placed its trans-
Saharan and Atlantic branches in the same analytical category and began with
the assumption that international trade, whether across deserts or by sea, ought
to encourage economic development. I was conscious that this hypothesis,
though conventional, might seem perverse in the context of a trade in which
human beings featured prominently. The purpose of the approach, however,
was to introduce a measure of rigour into assessments that assumed too readily
that what was morally indefensible was also necessarily materially disastrous. The
parallel here is with beliefs, ancient and modern, that free labour is always more
efficient than slave labour.
The discussion of Africa’s external trade is far more detailed and discriminat-
ing today than it was when various political ideologies, ably supported by
limited evidence, coloured the subject.44 This is not to say that we have finally
reached a state of scholarly nirvana, where objectivity rules and collegial harmony
follows. Subtle assumptions can still operate. According to one Orientalist view,
trans-Saharan trade was an extension of the Middle Eastern and Muslim worlds,
which defined slavery in terms that were thought to apply explicitly to that
region. From an alternative standpoint, the sea-borne slave trade was part of a wider
Atlantic complex that incorporated a specifically Western view of the institution of
slavery.45 These intellectual presuppositions have the merit of placing West Africa
in a wider context, but they also run the risk of over-emphasising the importance of
external influences and underestimating the independence of African agency.
My own treatment of the subject began with trans-Saharan trade for the obvi-
ous and possibly artless reason that it antedated the Atlantic trade.46 Although
the Atlantic model had still to be fully constructed, my limited knowledge gave
me a coastal perspective on the interior that hindered me from giving due
weight to the Western Sudan. Nevertheless, it was evident that the Sahara had
long ceased to be a barrier to communication between West and North Africa
and that merchants from both regions had developed a sizeable trade, even
44 My own account drew attention, though briefly, to the diversity of the trades across both the
Sahara and the Atlantic: EHWA, pp. 134–36.
45 I am indebted here to Ann E. McDougall’s thoughtful and illuminating essay: ‘Discourse and Dis-
tortion: Critical Reflections on Studying the Saharan Slave Trade’, Revue francaise d’hjstoire d’Outre-
Mer, 89 (2002), pp. 55–87; and Ghislaine Lydon, ‘Saharan Oceans and Bridges, Barriers and Divides
in Africa’s Historiographical Landscape’, Journal of African History, 56 (2015), pp. 3–22.
46 For a detailed account that emphasises the antiquity of the trade, see Abdoulaye Bathily, Les portes
de l’or: le royaume de Galam (Sénégal) de l’ère musalmane au temps de negriers (Paris, 1989).
Introduction 15
though quantification was missing. Fortunately, too, I was able to sidestep two
errors that later became well documented: one, which looked at the region
from the perspective of Muslim North Africa, held that the Western Sudan des-
cended into a Dark Age following the Moroccan invasion of 1591; the other,
which adopted an Atlantic standpoint, asserted that competition from sea-borne
routes shortly afterwards accelerated the demise of the once golden trade with
North Africa and the world beyond. Trans-Saharan trade survived. Its value
increased, and decline did not set in until the close of the nineteenth century,
when the railway began to erode the protection that distance from the coast had
long provided.47
Several generations of enterprising researchers have now supplied much of the
information that was missing from my schematic account. Although my general
conclusions appear to stand, they look elementary when compared to current
knowledge. Very approximate estimates suggest that trade within and across the
Saharan complex was much larger than used to be thought. One provisional cal-
culation indicates that a total of about 4 million slaves were exported from West
to North Africa across Saharan routes between 800 and 1900 and that the traffic
reached its peak in the eighteenth century, as did the Atlantic trade.48 Studies of
other items, such as gold, salt, dates, cloth, and gum have established their diver-
sity and importance, and provided insights into what can now be seen to have
been an intricate multilateral trading system.49 We also have a better understand-
ing of the extensive Saharan-Sudan complex that connected nomads, pastoralists,
farmers, and merchants, whose energy and enterprise held this extraordinarily
risky commerce together over many centuries.
The accumulation of research suggests to me the importance of recognising
an enlarged conception of regional unity that extended from the coast into the
interior. Since only a proportion of the commerce made the complete desert
crossing, this revision implies that the study of the economic activities within
this vast region also needs to take the ‘trans’ out of a substantial segment of
Saharan trade.
47 EHWA, pp. 127, 180–81. In some cases the trade even survived the advent of the railway. See
Marion Johnson, ‘Calico Caravans: The Tripoli-Kano Trade after 1880’, Journal of African History,
17 (1976), pp. 95–117.
48 Ralph Austen has made a bold attempt to bring the subject into the research arena: ‘The Trans-
Saharan Slave Trade: A Tentative Census’, in Henk Gemery and Jan S. Hogendorn, eds. The
Uncommon Market: Essays in the Economic History of the Atlantic Slave Trade (New York, 1979), pp.
23–76. Paul E. Lovejoy, ‘Commercial Sectors in the Economy of the Nineteenth-Century Central
Sudan: The Trans-Saharan Trade and the Desert-Side Salt Trade’, African Economic History, 13
(1984), pp. 85–117, provides a valuable update of key data.
49 I am again indebted to Ann McDougall’s perceptive assessment: ‘The Sahara in An Economic History
of West Africa: Critical Reflection on Historiographical Impact and Legacy’, in Falola and Brownell,
Africa, Empire and Globalization, Ch. 4; also Ralph A. Austen and Dennis D. Cordell, ‘Trade, Trans-
portation, and Expanding Economic Networks: Saharan Caravan Commerce in the Era of Euro-
pean Expansion, 1500–1900’, in Alusine Jalloh and Toyin Falola, eds. Black Business and Economic
Power (Rochester, NY, 2002), pp. 80–113; Lovejoy, Caravans of Kola; idem, Salt of the Desert Sun.
16 Introduction
50 Ghislaine Lyden, On Trans-Saharan Trails: Islamic Law, Trade Networks and Cross-Cultural Exchange
in Nineteenth-Century Western Africa (Cambridge, 2009).
51 James, L. Webb, Desert Frontier: Ecological and Economic Change along the Western Sahel, 1600–1850
(Madison, WI, 1995); Paul E. Lovejoy, Jihād in West Africa during the Age of Revolutions (Athens,
OH, 2016). Michael Watts, Silent Violence: Food, Famine, and Peasantry in Northern Nigeria (Berke-
ley, CA, 1983), assembles valuable information but places it in a rigid analytical context.
52 Bruce E. Hall, A History of Race in Muslim West Africa, 1600–1960 (New York, 2011); Lovejoy,
Transformations in Slavery: A History of Slavery in Africa (New York, 1983; 3rd ed. 2012). Successive
prefaces to this book indicate how voluminous the literature has become.
53 See, for example, Patrick Manning, Slavery and African Life: Occidental, Oriental and African Slave
Trades (Cambridge, 1990).
54 David Eltis and Martin Halbert, Voyages: The Transatlantic Slave Trade Data Base (Atlanta, GA,
2010); David Eltis and David Richardson, Atlas of the Transatlantic Slave Trade (New Haven, CT,
2nd. ed. 2015).
55 Philip D. Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade: A Census (Madison, WI, 1969); Paul E. Lovejoy, ‘The
Impact of the Slave Trade on Africa in the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries: A Review of the
Literature’, Journal of African History, 30 (1989), pp. 365–94. The journal Slavery & Abolition pro-
vides bibliographical guides to the continuously expanding literature on this subject.
Introduction 17
which was published in 1969, was available to me, with the result that my sum-
mary of numbers, regional involvement, destinations, and periodicity requires
less revision than would otherwise be the case.56 I linked external demand to
supply, suggesting that, though slavery existed in West Africa, the expanding
market in the New World led, through African as well as European agency, to
the creation of much larger pools of enforced labour.57 My conclusion was that
‘fundamentally, the external slave trade existed only because the return on
exports was greater than on employing labour in the domestic economy’, and
that the difference ‘reflected the greater productivity of labour in the
Americas’.58
My predominantly Old Coaster’s view of West Africa led me to comment on
the development of forts and entrepôts, the import trade, the seasonality of
trade, the use of currencies, credit arrangements, and the evolution of Afro-
European relations. In addition, I added some preliminary remarks on the pro-
cess of slave-gathering in the hinterland and the part played by participating
African states, which, I suggested, could be seen either as businesses that
acquired political functions or as polities that acted like large corporations.59
Coincidentally, the publication of my book was followed by a string of out-
standing publications on the slave-trading forest states that amplified and greatly
improved my summary statement. Asante, Oyo, and Dahomey have now been
studied in great detail; the history of ports, such as Calabar and Ouidah, has
been reconstructed; the record of minor polities has been recovered.60 System-
atic studies of slave prices have provided a reliable guide to fluctuations in Atlan-
tic commerce.61 Knowledge of all these topics has now reached the point where
a range of certainties is now in view.
The problem of abolition has also seen considerable advances that make it
necessary to amend part of my interpretation. I weighed up the arguments
respecting moral and economic causes, criticised both, but settled for an explan-
ation that emphasised the upheaval affecting the French sugar islands and
development prospects. Klas Rönnbäck, Labour and Living Standards in Pre-Colonial West Africa: The
Case of the Gold Coast (London, 2016), suggests that living standards for some workers (canoe-men)
may have fallen between the 1660s and 1750.
68 And in particular to export more men than women: Joseph E. Inikori, ‘Export Versus Domestic
Demand: The Determinants of Sex Ratios in the Transatlantic Slave Trade’, Research in Economic
History, 14 (1992), pp 117–66.
69 See the formidable research and diverse views of Joseph Miller, Way of Death: Merchant Capitalism
and the Angolan Slave Trade, 1730–1830 (Madison, WI, 1988); John Thornton, Kingdom of the
Kongo: Civil War and Transition, 1641–1718 (Madison, WI, 1983); J. E. Inikori, ed. Forced Migra-
tion: The Impact of the Export Slave Trade on West African Societies (New York, 1982); Manning, Slav-
ery and African Life; and David Henige’s cautionary comments in ‘Measuring the Immeasurable:
The Atlantic Slave Trade, West African Population and the Pyrrhonian Critic’, Journal of African
History, 27 (1986), pp. 295–313.
70 For a stimulating positive answer to the question see Inikori, ‘The Development of Commercial
Agriculture in Pre-Colonial Africa’.
71 For the view that the trade retarded ‘industrial development’, see Joseph E. Inikori, ‘Slavery and
Capitalism in Africa’, Indian Historical Review, 15 (1988), pp. 137–51; idem, ‘The Development of
Capitalism in the Atlantic World: England, the Americas, and West Africa, 1450–1900’, Labor His-
tory, 58 (2017), pp. 138–53. To relate the argument to current thinking, it could be said that West
Africa was a labour-intensive economy with limited development potential. See, Austin and Sugi-
hara, Labour Intensive Industrialization.
72 Joseph E. Inikori, ‘Africa and the Globalization Process: Western Africa, 1450–1850’, Journal of
Global History, 2 (2007), pp. 63–86; Patrick Manning, ‘Africa and World Historiography’, Journal of
African History, 54 (2013), pp. 319–30; idem, ‘Locating Africans on the World Stage: A Problem in
World History’, Journal of World History, 26 (2015), pp. 605–37; Austin, Economic Development and
Environmental History.
20 Introduction
73 Kenneth Pomeranz, The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Econ-
omy (Princeton, NJ, 2000).
74 Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson, ‘Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions
in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117
(2002), pp. 1231–94.
75 Hopkins, ‘Fifty Years of African Economic History’.
76 Daron Acemoglu and James A Robinson, ‘Why is Africa Poor’, Economic History of Developing
Regions, 25 (2010), pp. 21–50. See Geoffrey M. Hodgson, ‘What are Institutions?’, Journal of Eco-
nomic Issues, 40 (2006), pp. 1–25; Alessandro Stanziani ‘Introduction: Comment mesurer l’efficacité
des institutions?’, Histoire & Mesure, 30 (2015), pp. 3–24; Denis Cogneau and Yannick Dupraz,
‘Institutions historiques et développement économique en Afrique. Une revue sélective et critique
de travaux récents’, Histoire & Mesure, 30 (2015), pp. 103–34.
77 Robert Bates, Essays on the Political Economy of Rural Africa (Cambridge, 1983), Ch. 2; Alberto Ale-
sina and Enrico Spolaore, ‘On the Number and Size of Nations’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112
(1997), pp. 1027–56.
Introduction 21
78 . There are, however, some admirable case studies. For example, Robin Law, ‘Royal Monopoly
and Private Enterprise in the Atlantic Trade: The Case of Dahomey’, Journal of African History, 18
(1977), pp. 555–77. See also Martin Klein, ‘The Slave Trade and Decentralized Societies’, Journal of
African History, 42 (2001), pp. 49–65.
79 Starting points include: Robin Law, ‘Horses, Firearms, and Political Power in West Africa’, Past &
Present, 72 (1976), pp. 112–32; John Thornton, ‘Dahomey in the World: Dahomean Rulers and
European Demands, 1726–1894’, in Akyeampong et al, Africa’s Development in Historical Perspective,
Ch. 14; for additional information, see Toby Green, A Fistful of Cowries: West Africa from the Rise of
the Slave Trade to the Age of Revolution (London, 2019), Ch. 7. In this case, the devil is not so much
in the details as in the definition. In Western Europe, the variety of military-fiscal states suggests
that the term may be used too loosely to authorise useful comparisons. See Hopkins, American
Empire, Ch. 2.
80 See Law, The Slave Coast of West Africa, for the example of Dahomey. Recent points of entry
include: John K. Thornton, Warfare in Atlantic Africa (London, 1999); Richard J. Reid, Warfare in
African History (Cambridge, 2012); John K Thornton, ‘Placing the Military in African History’, Jour-
nal of African Military History, 1 (2017), pp. 112–19.
81 The phrase is from Marion Johnson, ‘The Economic Foundations of an Islamic Theocracy: The
Rise of Masina’, Journal of African History, 17 (1976), pp. 481–95. This is an opportunity to pay
tribute to my former colleague, whose pioneering research is well represented in David Henige and
T. C. McCaskie, eds. West African Economic and Social History: Studies in Memory of Marion Johnson
(Madison, WI, 1990).
82 I am indebted here to Ralph A. Austen, ‘Imperial Reach Versus Institutional Grasp: Superstates of
the West and Central African Sudan in Comparative Perspective’, Journal of Early Modern History,
13 (2009), pp. 509–41. A representative case is Law, ‘Royal Monopoly and Private Enterprise’. See
also Joseph E. Inikori, ‘The Struggle against the Atlantic Slave Trade: The Role of the State’, in
Sylviane A. Diouf, ed. Fighting the Slave Trade: West African Strategies (Athens, OH, 2003), pp.
170–98.
22 Introduction
83 For comparative examples of strong mercantile networks operating effectively in and across rela-
tively weak states, and of nomads creating political controls that fostered thriving economies, see,
respectively, Gagan D. S. Sood, India and the Islamic Heartlands: An Eighteenth-Century World of Cir-
culation and Exchange (Cambridge, 2016); Christopher J. Beckwith, Empires of the Silk Road (Prince-
ton, NJ, 2009).
84 See Catherine Coquery-Vidrovitch’s influential essay, ‘Recherches sur un mode de production
africain’, La Pensée, 114 (1969), pp. 61–78.
85 Kenneth Pomeranz is currently completing a book that deals with this question. I am grateful to
him for the discussion we had on this subject in Chicago in April 2018.
86 Mark Dincecco and Yuhua Wang, ‘The Monopoly over Violence in a Late Modernizer: Evidence
from Imperial China’ (2019). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3209556.
Introduction 23
87 The term used by contemporaries to describe trade in non-slave products after the slave trade
became illegal.
88 The main exception being expatriate mining operations that were established in a limited number
of colonies during the colonial period.
89 These points were made in EHWA, Ch. 4, which drew on A. G. Hopkins, ‘The Lagos Strike of
1897: An Exploration in Nigerian Labour History’, Past & Present, 35 (1966), pp. 133–55. See
Robin Law, ed. From Slave Trade to Legitimate Commerce: The Commercial Transition in Nineteenth-
Century West Africa (Cambridge, 1995), pp. 1–26; and the detailed account by Martin Lynn,
24 Introduction
the century, however, adaptation became increasingly difficult. When the external
trade in slaves was finally eliminated, vested interests lost overseas markets and
income; when the profitability of the new export staples declined during the last
quarter of the century, the fortunes of the households that had invested labour and
land in the new exports were jeopardised. These trends exacerbated the problem of
structural change, increased social tensions, and were translated into political
instability.
The general ‘crisis of adaptation’ within West Africa intersected with mounting
pressures on the European side of the African frontier as the profits of the expatri-
ate firms came under pressure during the last quarter of the century and inter-
national rivalries intensified. The intersection of these internal and external trends
prompted the partition and occupation of the region in the 1880s and 1890s.
Mercantile and associated interest groups exerted pressure on their home govern-
ments to take decisive action to restore the profitability of commerce. The
attempt to integrate West Africa into the international economy through the exer-
cise of informal influence had failed; formal means were required to resolve the
problems that had arisen as a result of the transition brought about by the abolition
of the overseas slave trade. The outcome was a form of structural adjustment
imposed by military force and supervised subsequently by colonial rule.
This interpretation has been much discussed and has generated a sizeable
number of detailed studies that have enlarged the stock of knowledge and
also complicated the interpretation I outlined.90 The European side of the
story has been elaborated but not transformed, and the subject has lost
some of its attraction for new researchers in recent decades.91 Accordingly,
the following comments will focus on West Africa and African perspectives,
which have continued to generate important new research. The central
criticism of the argument I advanced in 1973 is that continuity was more
important than change: African cultivators adapted readily to new exports
because they had long been producing them for domestic use; ‘big men’
adjusted by establishing plantations worked by slaves, by controlling access
to land, and by retaining their grip on the distribution system. Accordingly,
Commerce and Economic Change in West Africa: The Palm Oil Trade in the Nineteenth Century (Cam-
bridge, 1997).
90 The debate is now readily accessible: Law, From Slave Trade to Legitimate Commerce; Law, et al.,
Commercial Agriculture, the Slave Trade and Slavery; Gareth Austin, ‘A. G. Hopkins, West Africa, and
Economic History’, in Falola and Brownell, Africa, Empire and Globalization, Ch. 2; and Robin
Law, ‘The “Crisis of Adaptation” Revisited: The Yoruba War of 1877–1893’, in Falola and Brow-
nell, ibid., Ch. 6.
91 Selective examples of work written since 1973 include: Stig Förster, Wolgfang Mommsen, and
Ronald Robinson, eds. Bismarck, Europe and Africa: The Berlin Conference of 1884–1885 and the
Onset of Partition (Oxford, 1988); Olivier Pétré-Grenouilleau, ed. From Slave Trade to Empire:
Europe and the Colonisation of Black Africa, 1780s–1880s (London, 2004); Hubert Bonin, Catherine
Hodir, and Jean-François Klein, eds. L’esprit économique impérial (1830–1970): groups de pression et
réseaux du patronat colonial en France et dans l’empire (Paris, 2008).
Introduction 25
the decisive break came, not in the nineteenth century, but in the early
twentieth century with the advent of colonial rule.92
My argument needs to be adjusted to take account of new findings. The
most important amendment concerns the persistence of slavery within West
Africa. I acknowledged that slavery retained its vitality and that slaves were
employed for productive purposes within the region during the period of
legitimate commerce.93 I failed, however, to explore the variety of forms
taken by slave labour, including the fact that some slaves were employed in
what I termed ‘ordinary households’, and I underestimated their numbers.94
The problem is that the quest for precision runs into abundant evidence of
the complexities involved in defining the term ‘slave’. Some ‘slaves’, for
example, were effectively independent producers who paid rent to their
masters; others may have been ‘pawns’, or ‘slaves’ whose formal status had
been effectively altered by assimilation.95 Consequently, attempts to count
the number of slaves in West Africa are laden with difficulties. One of the
few serious calculations available suggests that in 1904 ‘slaves’ accounted for
over 30 per cent of the population of French West Africa. Even if the
problem of definition is put to one side, this figure still left up to
70 per cent of the population who, by default, were designated ‘free’.96
92 See Lynn, Commerce and Economic Change in West Africa, Ch. 2, though Lynn also accepts that ‘the
transition to export-oil production was marked by a shift to small-scale units’. Most of the discus-
sion in Ch. 2 of his book, however, relates to the first half of the nineteenth century. Part II of the
book, which deals with the period after 1850, focuses on relations between European merchants
and African brokers, and does not pursue the story of export production, which had expanded
greatly and faced new problems. Colin Newbury’s thorough investigation of trade relations gives
broad support to the interpretation put in EHWA: ‘On the Margins of Empire: The Trade of
Western Africa, 1984–1885’; in Forster, Bismarck, Europe and Africa, Ch. 2; see also the valuable
discussion of these issues in Gareth Austin, ‘Commercial Agriculture and the Ending of Slave-
Trading and Slavery in West Africa, 1780s–1920s’, in Law, et al., Commercial Agriculture, the Slave
Trade, and Slavery, Ch. 11.
93 EHWA, pp. 67–71, 192–95, 278–81.
94 Lovejoy, Transformations; Gareth Austin, ‘Cash Crops and Freedom: Export Agriculture and the
Decline of Slavery in Colonial West Africa’, International Review of Social History, 54 (2009), pp.
1–37. For one of many examples, see Martin Klein, ‘The Slave Trade in the Western Sudan during
the Nineteenth Century’, Slavery & Abolition, 13 (1990), pp. 39–60.
95 On the expansion of the practice of pawning during this period, see Paul E. Lovejoy, ‘Pawnship,
Debt, and “Freedom” in Atlantic Africa during the Era of the Slave Trade: A Reassessment’, Journal
of African History, 55 (2014), pp. 55–78; Raymond E. Dumett, Imperialism, Economic Development,
and Social Change in West Africa (Durham, NC, 2013), pp. 184–8, 192. On assimilation see EHWA,
p. 70, and now Gareth Austin, in David Eltis, et al., The Cambridge History of Slavery, Vol. 4 (Cam-
bridge, 2017), pp. 174–96.
96 Martin Klein, Slavery and Colonial Rule in French West Africa (Cambridge, 1998), pp. 252–6; Austin,
‘Commercial Agriculture and the Ending of the Slave Trade’, p. 260, n. 56, also notes that another
authority (James F. Searing) considers Klein’s estimates of 1904 to be too high. I am indebted to
Paul Lovejoy for guiding me though some of the intricacies of this subject.
26 Introduction
Difficulties of definition also apply to the claim that large ‘plantations’ employing
slaves were major producers in the nineteenth century.97 The most prominent
example is the Sokoto Caliphate, which has been studied in detail.98 Elsewhere,
however, it might be more accurate to refer to ‘great estates’, or simply ‘estates’, of
the kind found in Dahomey and Asante.99 Such estates or holdings were scattered
along the coast in the nineteenth century. At the same time, there is widespread
evidence that commoners and free households increased their participation in legit-
imate commerce during the second half of the century, with and without the assist-
ance of ‘slave’ labour.100 Simultaneously, the volume of exports of the main staples,
palm oil, palm kernels, and groundnuts, underwent a massive increase and the area
of land drawn into export production expanded correspondingly. Coastal entrepôts
that exported produce and imported cowries and silver coin provide evidence of
the growing monetisation of the economy and of rising demand among
a multiplicity of small producers and consumers.101
The unsatisfactory conclusion is that the proportion of total exports supplied
by large holdings worked by slave labour remains unknown, as is the proportion
that can be attributed to small households. The more positive finding is that the
emphasis I placed on innovation remains valid: new units of export production
operating on a small scale arose and became more numerous in the course of
the nineteenth century, even if some of them employed slaves and others
97 The term ‘plantation’, which has been imported into West Africa from the literature on slavery in
the New World, conjures up images of expansive and readily identifiable latifundia. Hacienda
might be a more appropriate term because it allows for a variety of forms of labour.
98 Lovejoy, Transformations in Slavery, Ch. 9; idem, Jihād in West Africa, Ch. 7; Mohammed Bashir
Salau, The West African Slave Plantation: A Case Study (Houndmills, 2011).
99 During the first half of the nineteenth century, Europeans on the Gold Coast used the term very
broadly to refer to ‘planted fields’ or ‘cultivated places’. Ray A. Kea, ‘Plantations and Labour in
the South-East Gold Coast from the Late Eighteenth to the Mid-Nineteenth Century’, in Law,
From Slave Trade to Legitimate Commerce, pp. 121–2.
100 See n.90. Credit should be given to Martin A. Klein’s pioneering study: ‘Social and Economic
Factors in the Muslim Revolution in Senegambia’, Journal of African History, 13 (1972), pp.
419–41; an advertisement should also be posted for an unjustly neglected work: Kenneth Swindell
and Alieu Jeng, Migrants, Credit and Climate: The Gambian Groundnut Trade, 1834–1934 (Leiden,
2006). See also Gareth Austin, ‘No Elders Were Present: Commoners and Private Ownership in
Asante, 1807–1896’, Journal of African History, 37 (1996), pp. 1–30. Toyin Falola, The Political Econ-
omy of a Pre-Colonial African State: Ibadan, 1830–1900 (Ile-Ife, 1989), provides a dramatic illustra-
tion of how the upheavals of the time gave opportunities to a new generation of freemen. The
difference between the first and second halves of the century is captured in complementary studies
by James F. Searing, West African Slavery and Atlantic Commerce: The Senegal River Valley, 1700–
1860 (Cambridge, 1993); idem, ‘“God Alone is King”: Islam and Emancipation in Senegal, the Wolof
Kingdoms of Kajoor and Bawol, 1850–1914 (Portsmouth, NJ, 2002).
101 Robin Law, ‘“Legitimate” Trade and Gender Relations in Yorubaland and Dahomey’, in Law,
From Slave Trade to Legitimate Commerce, p. 199; idem, ‘Cowries, Gold and Dollars: Exchange
Rate Instability and Domestic Price Inflation in Dahomey in the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Cen-
turies’, in Jane I. Guyer, ed. Money Matters: Instability, Values and Social Payments in the Modern
History of West African Communities (Portsmouth, NH, 1995), pp. 53–74; Strickrodt, Afro-European
Trade in the Atlantic World, pp. 216–17.
Introduction 27
competed with larger holdings. Structural change on this scale was unprece-
dented in West African history. The process undoubtedly accelerated under
colonial rule, but it began in the nineteenth century.
With regard to the connection between the ‘crisis of adaptation’ and the partition
of West Africa, it is worth repeating that the central argument advanced in Chapter
4 was not that new economic activities and institutions eliminated old ones, but
that there were mounting tensions between the two. Subsequent studies have
greatly improved my over-generalised interpretation by providing detailed illustra-
tions of the strains affecting Afro-European relations along the coast during the last
quarter of the century.102 The literature has now settled into a discussion of the bal-
ance to be struck between political and economic causes within Africa on the one
hand, and between African and European initiatives on the other.
The debate is well illustrated by the case of Senegambia, where the French deci-
sion, at the close of the 1870s, to advance inland is frequently cited as marking the
start of the partition of West Africa. The case is especially interesting because it has
attracted exponents of the new economic history of Africa.103 The strength of their
work lies in the construction of a new time-series showing that the net barter terms
of trade of staple exports rose between 1835 and 1885 before falling thereafter. This
assessment responds admirably to my appeal for research to improve my ‘provisional
and approximate analysis’ by correcting my judgement that the terms of trade
peaked in the mid-1860s.104 The authors conclude that their study ‘revises the view
that the scramble for West Africa occurred when its major export markets were in
decline’.105 The revision is not presented as an explanation of the scramble but as
a ‘rationale’ that made the advance into Senegal ‘politically defensible’.
Even so, the conclusion may exceed the evidence the authors presented. It
assumes that the causes of partition were in place by 1885, whereas historians see
partition as a phased process down to 1898. Subsequent phases had distinctive fea-
tures that need incorporating into an explanation (or a rationale) of the process,
including, among other variables, the decline in the terms of trade after 1885.106
The argument for the period before 1885 is also incomplete because an analysis of
102 In addition to the references given in notes 90 and 101, see Gareth Austin, ‘“No Elders Were
Present”: Commoners and Private Ownership in Asante, 1807–1896’, Journal of African History, 37
(1996), pp. 1–30; A. G. Hopkins, ‘Asante and the Victorians: Transition and Partition on the
Gold Coast’, in Roy Bridges, ed. Imperialism, Decolonization and Africa (Houndmills, 2000), pp.
25–64; Dumett, Imperialism, Economic Development, and Social Change, Chs 7, 12, 13–14.
103 Ewout Frankema, Jeffrey Williamson, and Pieter Woltier, ‘Economic Rationale for the West
African Scramble? The Commercial Transition and the Commodity Price Boom of 1835–1885’,
Journal of Economic History, 78 (2018), pp. 231–67. I should add that the phrase ‘new economic
history’ covers approaches that range from established quantitative procedures to technical innov-
ations, such as cross-country regression analysis.
104 EHWA, pp. 181–85, quotation on p. 181.
105 Fankema et al., ‘Economic Rationale’, p. 267.
106 For a thoughtful, rounded view that includes changes in currency values and the role of indebted-
ness, see Mark Metzler, ‘Revisiting the General Crisis of the Late Nineteenth Century: West
Africa and the World Depression’, in Falola, Africa, Empire, and Globalization, Ch. 16.
28 Introduction
net barter and income terms of trade excludes possible changes in agricultural costs
and productivity in the groundnut and palm oil industries, and does not measure
either net incomes or their social distribution.107 Although much of this information
is now probably irretrievable, other indicators show, for example, that French firms
exporting groundnuts from Senegal were adversely affected by declining profitabil-
ity, which dated from 1881 rather than from 1885.108
The terms of trade formed only part of the context that influenced policy at
this time. Minimally, an understanding of policy-making would need to include
the rivalry between Bordeaux and Marseilles for control of the export trades and
their relations with politicians in Paris, the growing participation of ex-slaves in
the gum and groundnut trades, and the problems of control this development
posed for established rulers in the region. Viewed from an African standpoint,
the French advance was part of a contest between local polities and resurgent
Islam that had its violent outlet in the long Wolof civil war that ran through
the second half of the century. Groundnuts were the new source of revenues
and wealth; competition between slave and free methods of production was
a central issue in the acquisition and extension of power. These considerations
are not just adjuncts to an analysis of the net barter terms of trade, they are cen-
tral to an understanding of wealth and welfare in Senegambia and to the politics
and policies of African states in a region that well illustrates the challenges
imposed by the ‘crisis of adaptation’.
My own brief comments on the Western Sudan need both revision and
amplification. I suggested that the region experienced a crisis of adaptation
comparable to that found along the West Coast as a result of the decline of
trans-Saharan trade after 1875 and the political upheavals brought by successive
jihāds.109 Recent research indicates that, with exceptions, trade across the
Sahara did not contract until after 1900, and that political movements in the
region included those that brought stability and not just disruption. The cur-
rent consensus, simply put, is that transport costs insulated the region from
problems of transition to ‘legitimate commerce’, while allowing it to develop
a thriving regional economy that rested heavily on slave labour.
These revisionist conclusions prompt further questions, not least because the
size and diversity of the region known as the Western Sudan allow room for
different responses to the challenges of the time. The jihādist movements that
spread in the course of the nineteenth century aimed at establishing a political
order that would be capable of resisting trans-Atlantic, Christian influences.110
107 A fuller analysis would need to add the factorial terms of trade (which measure the productivity of
different combinations of inputs).
108 Xavier Daumalin, ‘Commercial Presence, Colonial Penetration: Marseilles Traders in West Africa
in the Nineteenth Century’, in Pétré-Grenouilleau, From Slave Trade to Empire, Ch. 9.
109 EHWA, pp. 184–85.
110 I am particularly indebted here to Paul Lovejoy’s study, Jihād in West Africa, and for his generous
correspondence on this issue.
Introduction 29
The ‘Bible and the plough’ were to be kept at bay by the Koran and slave labour.
This combination focused, as far as possible, on internal development to ensure that
the Muslim community would retain its independence and purity. The Sokoto
Caliphate, the largest state in the Western Sudan, relied on slave labour and trade
taxes to generate the revenues needed to buy guns and horses, which were the
foundation of political power.111 The Caliphate responded to the decline of the
external slave trades by expanding regional alternatives, which included the large-
scale production of cloth in and around Kano, as well as slaves, salt, kola, and grain,
and by exporting ostrich feathers and hides across the Sahara in return for cotton
cloth. Arguably, however, the pursuit of this goal contained problems of adjustment
that complemented the difficulties faced by coastal states following the abolition of
the Atlantic slave trade. Continued slave-raiding was inconsistent with the needs of
a growing market economy; arbitrary taxation provoked resistance; provincial
assertiveness threatened the unity of the Caliphate.112 It is impossible to say at pre-
sent whether or how far these developments had weakened the Caliphate before
the arrival of the British. Nevertheless, the evidence suggests that the development
model based on slavery was ultimately unsustainable and that Sokoto had failed to
manage the transition to a society of free producers.
Just north of the Caliphate in central Niger, opportunities for commoners expanded
from the 1870s as the value of legitimate commodities, notably ostrich feathers and
cotton cloth, grew.113 As in coastal regions, the consequent shift in the distribution of
wealth increased social tensions, which were translated into political conflict. By con-
trast again, the link joining the western edge of the Western Sudan to Mauritania
seems to have remained largely insulated from the transformation of the Atlantic
economy.114 Not far away, however, the Tukulor and Mandinka states raided and
traded slaves and employed slave labour, but were unable to establish enduring political
unity. In this case, unlike the Sokoto Caliphate, the French subverted the process of
state-building.115 One result was that escaped slaves and refugees made their way to
coastal regions, where they found opportunities in expanding exports of groundnuts
and rubber.116 These speculations suggest that the Western Sudan had to make large
111 Lovejoy, Jihād in West Africa, Chs 3, 7; S. U. Lawal, ‘The Fiscal Policies of Amir Al-Muminin
Muhammadu Bello’, African Economic History, 20 (1992), pp. 65–75.
112 Idrissa Kimba, Guerres et sociétés: Les populations du ‘Niger’ occidentale au XIXe siècle et leurs réactions
face à la colonisation (1896–1906) (Niamey, 1981); Kabiru Chafe, ‘Challenges to the Hegemony of
the Sokoto Caliphate’, Paideuma, 40 (1994), pp. 99–109.
113 Stephen Baier, An Economic History of Central Niger (Oxford, 1980), pp. 38–43.
114 McDougall, ‘The Sahara’ in An Economic History of West Africa’, pp. 107–09.
115 A. S. Kanya-Forstner, The Conquest of the Western Sudan: A Study in French Military Imperialism
(Cambridge, 1969).
116 François Manchuelle, Willing Migrants: Soninke Labor Diasporas, 1848–1960 (Athens, OH, 1998);
Marie Rodet, ‘Escaping Slavery and Building Diasporic Communities in French Soudan and
Senegal, ca. 1880–1940’, International Journal of African Historical Studies, 48 (2015), pp. 363–86;
Emily Lynn Osborn, ‘Rubber Fever: Commerce and French Colonial Rule in Upper Guinée,
1890–1913’, Journal of African History, 45 (2004), pp. 445–65.
30 Introduction
117 Credit must be given to pioneers who were exploring the possibilities of quantifying African his-
tory long before the current boom in this branch of the subject. See particlarly: Patrick Manning,
Slavery, Colonialism, and Economic Growth in Dahomey, 1640–1960 (Cambridge, 1982); idem, ‘Afri-
can Economic Growth and the Public Sector’; Marion Johnson, ‘Commodities, Customs and the
Computer’, History in Africa, 11 (1984), pp. 359-66.
118 Work by Denis Cogneau, Yannick Dupraz, and Sandrine Mesplé-Somps, though currently con-
fined to fiscal matters, is moving in this direction. See, for example, ‘Fiscal Capacity and Dualism
in Colonial States: The French Empire 1830–1962’, PSE Working Papers, 27 (2018).
119 Manning, Slavery, Colonialism, and Economic Growth in Dahomey, emphasises the long-run import-
ance of the domestic economy.
120 Morten Jerven, ‘A West African Experiment: Constructing a GDP Series for Colonial Ghana,
1891–1950’, Economic History Review, 67 (2014), pp. 964–92. Stephen Broadberry and Leigh
Gardner provide a defence of the merit of using GDP: ‘Economic Development in Africa and
Europe: Reciprocal Comparisons’, Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History, 34 (2016),
pp. 11–37. For a cautionary tale see Morten Jerven, Why Economists Get it Wrong (London, 2015).
32 Introduction
121 Albert O. Hirschman, Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and
States (Cambridge, MA, 1970), pp. 16, 55. The phrase originated with John R. Hicks in an article
in Econometrica, 3 (1935), pp. 1–20.
122 EHWA, pp. 262–67, for reasons subsequent work has confirmed. See now Gareth Austin, ‘Mode
of Production or Mode of Cultivation: Explaining the Failure of European Cocoa Farmers in
Competition with African Farmers in Colonial Ghana’, in W. G. Clarence Smith, ed. Cocoa Pion-
eer Fronts: The Role of Smallholders, Planters, and Merchants (Basingstoke, 1996), pp. 154–75.
123 Fortunately, several key studies of export crops had appeared before 1973: EHWA, pp. 269–75.
Others followed including: Sara Berry, Cocoa, Custom, and Socio-Economic Change in Rural Western
Nigeria (Oxford, 1975); and Susan M. Martin, Palm Oil and Protest: An Economic History of the
Ngwa Region, South Eastern Nigeria, 1800–1980 (Cambridge, 1988).
124 EHWA, pp. 269, 272–74. This is an appropriate point to pay tribute to Jan S. Hogendorn
(1937–2017), whose generous and modest personality complemented his outstanding scholarship.
Nigerian Groundnut Exports: Origins and Early Development (Zaria and Ibadan, 1978), remains the
Introduction 33
Even this exception had origins in the precolonial period. Groundnuts had long
been grown in the region, and the initiative to expand production came from
Hausa traders who were searching for ways to compensate for the decline of
regional and trans-Saharan trade. They responded, in cooperation with the political
elite, by directing their slaves into groundnut production but suffered when their
slaves escaped and took to farming on their own account. The ‘crisis of adaptation’
affected landlocked regions, as it did the coast, even if it manifested itself slightly
later. Considered at a very general level, the historical evidence clearly contradicted
the central assumptions of modernisation theory regarding the supposed ‘backward-
ness’ of ‘traditional’ societies: Africans responded to positive incentives and resisted
attempts by colonial rulers to coerce them into unproductive activities.
The chapter ended with an assessment of how factors of production were
mobilised to secure the huge expansion of exports.125 The vent-for-surplus
thesis offered an explanation that was relevant to land-surplus regions, where
output could be increased by adding inputs of labour to available land.126 These
conditions applied to West Africa, where the decline of slavery combined with
new opportunities encouraged migration to areas of suitable land. Government
policy supported African initiatives by encouraging labour mobility, though its
attitude towards the abolition of slavery was constrained by fears of causing
social dislocation.127 Yet, as I pointed out, the vent-for-surplus thesis also suf-
fered from the economist’s ‘highly compressed view of history’.128 To add real-
ism to elegance, it was necessary to recognise that the innovations sponsored by
Africans required much more than simply reducing underemployment. They
involved the investment of capital from previous activities, the diversion of
labour from some existing goods and services, improvements in agronomic tech-
niques, and all the uncertainties that accompanied migration.129 By about 1930,
West Africa’s open export economies had been completed. Integration with
world markets put the region on a path of specialisation that reflected its com-
parative advantage. Whether the colonial economy was capable of further struc-
tural change was a key question but one that was not answered until after
the Second World War.
standard work. Fortunately, I was able to draw on his Ph.D. dissertation, which was completed in
1966.
125 EHWA, pp. 285–88.
126 Myint, Economics of the Developing Countries, especially Ch. 3.
127 EHWA, pp. 275–81. See now Paul E. Lovejoy and Jan S. Hogendorn, Slow Death for Slavery: The
Course of Abolition in Northern Nigeria, 1897–1936 (Cambridge, 1993).
128 EHWA, p. 287.
129 EHWA, pp. 287–88. For the most recent evaluation, see Gareth Austin, ‘Resources, Techniques,
and Strategies South of the Sahara: Revising the Factor Endowments Perspective on African Eco-
nomic Development’, Economic History Review, 61 (2008), pp. 587–624; idem, ‘Vent for Surplus
or Productivity Breakthrough? The Ghanaian Cocoa Take-Off, c.1890–1936’, Economic History
Review, 67 (2014), pp. 1035–64.
34 Introduction
Research completed since 1973 has filled numerous gaps in my account of the early
colonial period and supplied details drawn from depths beyond my reach. The macro-
economic picture, however, remains fundamentally unchanged, though substantial
revisions may follow from work now in progress. Studies published during the last
decade or so have focused particularly on applying quantitative techniques to time-
series collated from official sources. Preliminary results are broadly in line with the
general trends in the region’s external trade set out in my Economic History, though the
improved data base is far more satisfactory than the incomplete evidence I presented.
Export volumes and values rose over the colonial period as a whole, but the net barter
and income terms of trade experienced marked fluctuations, indicating a modest
recovery from about 1900 to 1913, a profound slump for much of the 1930s, and
a pronounced boom from 1945 to 1955.130 The two world wars disrupted the
region’s overseas trade, as they did in many other parts of the Western empires. The
First World War had political as well as economic consequences for West Africa but
did not change the course of colonial rule; after the Second World War, prospective
changes became irresistible. Complementary research linking export earnings to
domestic sources of income has produced estimates of fiscal capacity that, though
broadly in accord with established conclusions, are based on superior data and
analysis.131 Fiscal capacity increased in the course of colonial rule; French and British
policy was driven by pragmatism rather than by ideology; minimalism prevailed,
though French officials tended to be more interventionist because their colonies were
poorer; there was a substantial boost to public spending after 1945.
Other new work has greatly extended previous studies of the incidence and
consequences of seasonal hunger, the survival of handicrafts, the various forms of
forced labour, colonial policy towards land rights, and the record of large-scale
agricultural projects.132 Nevertheless, there are plenty of opportunities for a new
130 Ewout Frankema, ‘How Africa’s Colonial History Affects its Development’, World Economic
Forum, Agenda, 15 July 2015. Frankema’s data cover the whole of sub-Saharan Africa and cannot
be expected to fit West Africa precisely; Manning, Slavery, Colonialism, and Economic Growth in
Dahomey, App.5, pp. 394–401.
131 Jens Andersson, ‘Long-Term Dynamics of the State in Francophone West Africa: Fiscal Capacity
Pathways 1850–2010’, Economic History of Developing Regions, 32 (2017), pp. 37–70; Cogneau,
Dupraz, and Mesplé-Somps, ‘African States and Development in Historical Perspective’; Ewout
Frankema, ‘Colonial Taxation and Government Spending in British Africa, 1880–1940: Maximiz-
ing Revenue or Minimizing Effort?’, Explorations in Economic History, 48 (2011), pp. 136–48; Jutta
Bolt and Leigh Gardner, ‘Tax Compliance under Indirect Rule in British Africa’, AEHN Working
Paper, 40 (2018); Ewout Frankema and Marlous van Wijenburg, ‘Metropolitan Blueprints of
Colonial Taxation? Lessons from Fiscal Capacity Building in British and French Africa,
c. 1880–1940’, Journal of African History, 55 (2014), pp. 371–400.
132 Paul Shaffer, ‘Seasonal Hunger in the Northern Territories of the Gold Coast, circa 1900—1940’,
Economic History of Developing Regions, 32 (2017), pp. 1–31; Katharine Frederick, ‘A Comparative
Analysis of East and West African Cotton Cloth Production from the Early Modern to the Post-
colonial Era’, AEHN Working Paper, 37 (2018); Romain Tiquet, Travail forcé et mobilisation de la
main-d’oeuvre au Sénégal: de la civilisation par le travail à la loi du travail (Rennes, 2019); Austin,
‘Mode of Production or Mode of Cultivation’; Richard Roberts, Two Worlds of Cotton: Colonial-
ism and the Regional Economy in the French Soudan, 1800–1946 (Stanford, CA, 1996).
Introduction 35
generation of researchers: the history of urban wage labour following the decline
of slavery has not been the centre of attention since the 1970s; the construction
of the railway network and its precise consequences still await thorough investi-
gation; little work has been done on the financing and building of towns; the
literature on colonial monetary systems and the integration of precolonial cur-
rency zones needs updating; there is scope for a fresh account of the trials and
errors that eventually led to an improved understanding of tropical agriculture.
Despite a handful of admirable studies, expatriate business history has not
received the attention its importance warrants, though a promising case has been
made recently for taking a new view of the subject.133
Gaps remain on the African side of the story, too. By the early 1980s, detailed
case studies had already established the main features of the expansion of export
crops at the outset of the colonial period.134 Subsequent developments within
the exporting regions have attracted less attention, though some valuable studies
dealing with changes in land tenure, the decline of slavery, and shifting social
and gender relations have pointed the way forward.135 As yet, there is no single
overview of the fortunes of African middlemen and merchants during this for-
mative period, which suggests that my own generalisations may have survived
less because they are persuasive than because they have been overlooked.136
The vent-for-surplus thesis, which occupied the conclusion to Chapter 6, has
also ceased to engage the attention it attracted in the 1970s, when much of its
influence lay in recognising the heterogeneous character of underdevelopment.
133 My own attempt to put the subject on the agenda had only limited influence: ‘Imperial Business
in Africa. Part I: Sources’, Journal of African History, 17 (1976), pp. 29–48; ‘Imperial Business in
Africa. Part II: Interpretations’, ibid, pp. 267–90; ‘Big Business in African Studies’, Journal of Afri-
can History, 28 (1987), pp. 119–40. Exceptions now include: Hubert Bonin and Michel Cahen,
eds. Négoce blanc en Afrique noire. L’èvolution du commerce à longue distance en Afrique noire du XVIII au
XXe siècle (Paris, 2001); Hubert Bonin, CFAO 1887–2007. La réinvention permanente du commerce
outre-mer (Paris, 2008); Actes du Colloque, Entreprises et entrepreneurs en Afrique, XIXe et XXe siècles,
Vol. 2 (Paris, 1983); Peter Greenhalgh, West African Diamonds, 1919–1983 (Manchester, 1985);
David K. Fieldhouse, Merchant Capital and Economic Decolonization: The United Africa Company,
1929–1987 (Oxford, 1997); Gareth Austin and Chibuike Ugochukwu, ‘Collusion and Competi-
tion in Colonial Economies: Banking in British West Africa, 1916–1960’, Business History Review,
81 (2007), pp. 1–36; Robert L. Tignor, ‘The Business Firm in Africa’, Business History Review, 81
(2007), pp. 87–110. For the new approach, see Gareth Austin, Carlos Davila, and Geoffrey Jones,
‘The Alternative Business History: Business in Emerging Markets’, Business History Review, 91
(2017), pp. 537–69.
134 See notes 123 and 124 above. Gareth Austin, Labour, Land and Capital in Ghana: From Slavery to
Free Labour in Asante, 1807–1956 (Rochester, NY, 2005), is the most important of subsequent
studies. Thomas J. Bassett, The Peasant Cotton Revolution in West Africa: Côte d’Ivoire, 1880–1995
(Cambridge, 2001), provides a valuable case study.
135 Sara Berry, No Condition is Permanent: The Social Dynamics of Agrarian Change in Sub-Saharan Africa
(Madison, WI, 1993); Catherine Boone, Property and Political Order in Africa (New York, 2014),
deals mainly with contemporary Africa but her argument that varying land tenures have exerted
greater influence on the distribution of political authority than has that familiar causal standby
‘ethnicity’ suggests one way of reappraising the precolonial era.
136 EHWA, pp. 256–58.
36 Introduction
The distinction between what were then termed ‘peasant’ and ‘enclave’ econ-
omies is now understood and accepted, but the question of precisely how
export expansion took place has not been settled. My own account, which
adopted the argument but also listed qualifications, illustrates the ambiguity that
derived from uncertainty in the face of limited information. Fortunately, we
now have at least one important contribution that draws on improved evidence
to emphasise the role of opportunity costs and gains in productivity in explain-
ing the expansion of exports.137 The result shows that generalisations on this
subject need to be adjusted to take account of the particularities of different
cases.
137 Gareth Austin, ‘Explaining and Evaluating the Cash Crop Revolution in the “Peasant” Colonies
of Tropical Africa, ca. 1890-c.1930: Beyond “Vent for Surplus”’, in Akyeampong, et al., Africa’s
Development in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, 2014), Ch. 9. See also the further references on
pp. 315–16.
Introduction 37
in the most general terms, was of the adjustment and growth of ‘traditional’
institutions in response to conditions introduced and overseen by colonial rule.
The drawback to these developments was that they greatly increased the
dependence of the colonial order on the fortunes of external trade. Colonial
rule, it could be said, was a gamble on the success of export development,
which underpinned government revenues and African welfare, and acted as
a measure of the political support, or tolerance, expressed by African subjects. In
the 1930s, the gamble failed, as it did elsewhere in the colonial world. The
terms of trade turned decisively against export producers; import purchasing
power fell; discontent manifested itself in rural protests and urban strikes; radical
political demands made their noisy appearance.
The initial reaction of colonial governments, British and French, was to
reduce expenditure, increase the effectiveness of tax-gathering, and attempt to
control political protests. Expatriate firms implemented parallel measures that
combined retrenchment with consolidation. The extent of the economic crisis,
however, obliged both powers to depart from tradition: they intervened in the
open economy in the hope of managing it. Imperial preferences strengthened
bilateral ties; marketing boards controlled prices paid to farmers; official initia-
tives created cooperatives. Notions of economic planning made their appearance;
the walls of self-sufficiency were breached; additional funding from government
sources was discussed and, in the case of Britain, enacted. Recovery was not in
sight in 1939, when the Second World War disrupted external trade and
extended the long period of adversity that West Africa had endured. The barter
and income terms of trade declined further. By 1945, West Africa’s total import-
ing capacity had reached its lowest point since 1900.138
The restoration of peace and the needs of reconstruction provided a boost for
the established export economy, which expanded, as it had done in the past, by
bringing more land under cultivation.139 The terms of trade improved; import
purchasing power reached record levels. Colonial policy also expressed continu-
ity by carrying forward elements of the command economy that had originated
in the 1930s and had been reinforced during the war. After 1945, policy took
a parallel course in both British and French West Africa. The public sector
expanded: there was a massive increase in capital investment from official
sources; governments formulated development plans; the marketing boards con-
tinued their efforts to influence farmers’ incomes by controlling prices. The his-
toric link between export earnings and investment was greatly weakened,
allowing substantial sums to boost funding for education, health, and road
transport.
The expatriate firms also began to adjust to the post-war world. Economic
growth attracted new rivals, reduced profit margins, and encouraged established
of the Second World War have underlined its adverse economic effects on West
Africa.145 The opening of official records to public inspection has allowed the
evolution of colonial economic policy during and after the war years to be
examined more thoroughly than was possible in 1973.146 Research on official
attitudes towards nationalist movements and the prospect of decolonisation has
also benefited from access to official papers, though only a few accounts have
focused on economic issues.147
A small number of scholars have kept business history alive. Studies of
expatriate mercantile and mining companies and their relations with colonial
governments after the Second World War have opened possibilities for others
to follow.148 The growth and diversification of the domestic economy have
attracted some research into the history of African entrepreneurs and charted
their entry into local manufacturing.149 The contribution of African traders,
especially women, has attracted research from several disciplines.150 Research
into gender issues more generally has explored the consequences of changing
roles for export crops, food farming, and handicrafts.151
Some of the most stimulating recent initiatives have been in the field of quan-
titative history, where the application of statistical techniques to newly con-
structed time-series has brought fresh evidence and greater precision to
established topics and opened new approaches to old arguments. A selection of
these contributions has been cited in the discussion of Chapter 6; others, noted
‘Milieux d’affaires de l’Outre-Mer français et Grande Dépression des années 1930’, French Colonial
History, 10 (2009), pp. 209–43.
145 The starting point is now Judith A. Byfield and Carolyn A. Brown, et al., eds. Africa and World
War II (Cambridge, 2015), Chs 2, 3, 6, 8, 9, 11, and the further references given there.
146 Michel Margairaz, L’État, les finances et l’économie: histoire d’une conversion, 1932–1952 (Paris,
1991); Larry Butler, Industrialisation and the British Colonial State: West Africa, 1939–1951 (London,
1997).
147 Frank Heinlein, British Colonial Government Policy and Decolonisation, 1945–1963: Scrutinising the
Official Mind (London, 2002); Gerold Krozewski, Money and the End of Empire: British International
Economic Policy and the Colonies, 1947–58 (London, 2001), includes material on West Africa. See,
too, Tony Chafer, The End of Empire in French West Africa (Oxford, 2002); and at a macro-level,
Jacques Marseille, Empire colonial et capitalisme français. Histoire d’un divorce (Paris, 1984).
148 See note 133 above. Also Sarah Stockwell, The Business of Decolonisation: British Business in the
Gold Coast (Oxford, 2000).
149 Tom Forrest, The Advance of African Capital: The Growth of Nigerian Private Enterprise (Edinburgh,
1992).
150 See, for example, Gracia Clark’s admirable overview of a large part of the subject: ‘African Market
Women, Market Queens, and Merchant Queens’, Oxford Research Encyclopaedias, July 2018.
151 Jane I. Guyer, ‘Female Farming and the Evolution of Food Production Patterns Amongst the Beti
of South Central Cameroun’, Africa, 50 (1980), pp. 341–56; Barbara M. Cooper, ‘Cloth, Com-
modity Production, and Social Capital: Women in Maradi, Niger 1890–1989’, African Economic
History, 21 (1993), pp. 51–71; Martin, Palm Oil and Protest. Tribute should be paid to the remark-
able Ester Boserup, who pioneered this subject 50 years ago. See Woman’s Role in Economic Devel-
opment (London, 1965); and idem, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agrarian
Change Under Population Pressure (London, 1965).
40 Introduction
here, carry forward themes that span the whole of the colonial period.
A reassessment of the data on French investment in French West Africa, the
first since 1984, has concluded that it brought fewer net benefits than the
previous figures suggested and burdened colonial subjects more than French
taxpayers.152 Another study, which illustrates the revival of interest in poverty
and inequality, has looked at the way colonial rulers defined the concept of
hunger and shown that it was only after the Second World War that
informed ideas of nutrition entered official policy.153 Several researchers have
explored new ways of engaging with the old problem of evaluating the costs
and benefits of colonial rule. One approach, applying anthropometric tech-
niques, has shown that there was an increase in the heights of colonial sub-
jects during the colonial period; another measured the real wages of urban
workers and concluded that they rose during the colonial period.154
A different perspective on the problem of welfare has quantified the consid-
erable contribution forced labour made to government revenues.155 Although
these studies do not claim to be comprehensive, they are certain to cause
a review of long-standing generalisations about the effects of colonialism on
development and welfare.
These advances still leave plenty of opportunities for new research on this
period. One striking prospect, referred to earlier, is the beginning of struc-
tural economic change after 1945, which still awaits a full analysis, despite its
obvious relevance to understanding the record of colonial rule in the process
of development and its legacy for the independent governments that took
control in the 1960s. The last substantial boom in the literature dealing with
the role of colonialism in advancing or retarding West Africa’s development
dates from the 1970s and 1980s, when an awareness of the continuities that
joined the colonial era to the post-colonial order stimulated a wide-ranging
152 Elise Huillery, ‘The Black Man’s Burden: The Cost of the Colonization of French West Africa
for French and African Taxpayers’, Journal of Economic History, 74 (2014), pp. 1–38.
153 See the ‘Forum on Poverty’ in the Journal of African History, 59 (2018), pp. 39–48; Vincent Bonne-
case, ‘Avoir faim en Afrique occidentale française: investigations et représentations coloniales
(1920–1960)’, Revue d’Histoire Sciences Humaines, 21 (2009), pp. 151–74; Denis Cogneau, L’Afri-
que des inégalités: où conduit l’histoire (Paris, 2007).
154 Alexander Moradi, ‘Towards an Objective Account of Nutrition and Health in Colonial Kenya:
A Study of Stature in African Army Recruits and Civilians, 1880–1980’, Journal of Economic His-
tory, 69 (2009), pp. 719–54; Alexander Moradi, Gareth Austin, and Jörg Baten, ‘Heights and
Development in the Cash-Crop Economy: Living Standards in Ghana, 1870–1980’, Economic
Research Southern Africa, Working Paper 325 (2013); Ewout Frankema, ‘Structural Impediments to
Economic Growth? New Evidence from Real Wages in British Africa, 1880–1965’, Journal of Eco-
nomic History, 72 (2012), pp. 895–926; Denis Cogneau and Léa Rouanet, ‘Living Conditions in
Côte d’Ivoire and Ghana 1925–1985: What Do Survey Data on Height Stature Tell Us?’, Eco-
nomic History of Developing Regions, 26 (2011), pp. 55–82.
155 Marlous van Wijenburg, ‘Financing the African Colonial State: The Revenue Imperative and
Forced Labour’, African Economic History Network, 20 (2015). My own starting point was Sir Alan
Pim, Financial and Economic History of the African Tropical Territories (London, 1940).
Introduction 41
156 Important exceptions include: Jan-Georg Deutsch, Educating the Middlemen: A Political and Eco-
nomic History of Statutory Cocoa Marketing in Nigeria, 1936–47 (Berlin, 1995); Rod Alence, ‘Colo-
nial Government, Social Conflict and State Involvement in Africa’s Open Economies: The
Origins of the Ghana Cocoa Marketing Board, 1939–1946’, Journal of African History, 42 (2001),
pp. 397–416; Federico Tadei, ‘Measuring Extractive Institutions: Colonial Trade and Price Gaps
in French Africa’, European Review of Economic History, forthcoming, https://doi.org/10.1093
/ereh/hey027.
42 Introduction
to explain the roots of poverty in Africa; historians have opened areas of research
that were either unconsidered or thought to be beyond recovery. The junction
between the two disciplines is incomplete. Historians who are familiar with the
new work of economists sometimes imagine that they can hear the grinding of
wheels being reinvented; economists suppose, with some justification, that estab-
lished historical methods lack rigour. In principle, the divide can be spanned;
the incentive for doing so requires no more than a recognition that large prob-
lems require multifaceted solutions.157
Thoughts that are self-evident sometimes need restating. The general conclu-
sion drawn here is that historians will miss important insights if they fail to
acquaint themselves with the new historical economics, but that their own
research techniques remain essential to understanding the full range of explan-
ations of underdevelopment. Fifty years ago, it was unclear whether the eco-
nomic history of Africa could be written; the impressive research completed
since then has disproved the sceptics. Nevertheless, the most difficult task
remains the one I started with and managed indifferently: reconstructing the his-
tory of precolonial economies.158 Quantitative skills have a role in this endeav-
our but most of the evidence will have to be assembled by traditional historical
methods. Gaps and uncertainties in the present state of knowledge translate into
opportunities for the next generation of researchers. Their trained enthusiasm
will carry the subject forward to horizons that, even now, we can scarcely
envisage.
11 Endings
Shortly after my book was published, in October 1973, Professor John Harris,
the Head of the Department of Economic and Social History, called me into his
office in the University of Birmingham. An appointment of this kind, though
not quite as forbidding as being summoned by the headmaster, was nevertheless
a semi-formal matter in the days when small departments had only one profes-
sor, who was both the senior manager and the principal judge of his junior
colleagues.159 John’s interests were far from mine: he specialised in industrial his-
tory in the eighteenth century and French technology in particular. But he was
an even-handed scholar and was notably generous in supporting his colleagues.
It was typical of him that he had already found the time to read my book,
which lay open on his desk. After some general and broadly favourable remarks,
he concluded with a pithy observation that passed several miles above my head:
‘it is the sort of book you could not have written ten years ago and would not
157 Randall Morck and Bernard Yeung, ‘Economics, History, and Causation’, Business History Review,
85 (2011), pp. 39–63.
158 This sentiment accords with Richard Reid, ‘Past and Presentism: The “Precolonial” and the
Foreshortening of African History’, Journal of African History, 52 (2011), pp. 135–55.
159 John R. Harris (1923–97); Head of Department, 1970–90.
Introduction 43
want to write in ten years’ time’. The first part of his statement was transpar-
ent and immediately persuasive, and I absorbed it gratefully. The second part,
however, baffled me. Surely, I thought, with an additional decade of reading
and reflection behind me, I ought to be able to scale new heights? However,
I could see that this was not the occasion to tangle with the unknown, so
I confined my response to a light laugh that was intended to convey both
my understanding of the subtlety of his remark and my respect for its
shrewdness.
A few years later, when John was giving me a lift to an economic history
conference, I took the opportunity to ask him to expand his gnomic obser-
vation, though without going so far as to admit that I still had no idea what
it meant. He did so with illustrations from his own work and that of others.
Young scholars can occasionally see a clear route through the past because
they have the confidence of innocence and lack enough knowledge to envis-
age alternatives. Older scholars have far more knowledge but also much
greater awareness of the complexities of causation, of the potential of other
approaches, and of the inadequacies of over-simple explanations. My aca-
demic lifecycle has now completed its slow rotation. My dialogue with my
younger self has confirmed that I saw a route from the past to the present
and took it, but also that I did not envisage other roads that might have
been travelled.160
My last ambitious synthesis, published in 2018, grappled with the problem of
maintaining a line of argument while trying to incorporate some of the innu-
merable complications that were inescapable consequences of the passage of time
and the accumulation of knowledge.161 By the end of the endeavour, I had
come to accept that the problem under review still towered above me and
remains insurmountable, despite prodigious efforts to reach its summit. For
every mountain climbed, as Alexander Pope observed long ago, others still
higher appear in the distance:
I can see why I could not understand the remark John Harris made in 1973,
and why now I understand it all too clearly.
160 Robert Frost, ‘The Road Not Taken’ (1920), hints at the uncertainties that follow, as well as pre-
cede, the choices we make. Historians cannot run controlled experiments; each scholar applies his
judgement without being entirely confident that he is on the right road.
161 Hopkins, American Empire.
162 Alexander Pope, ‘Essay on Criticism’ (1711). I make no apology for quoting this extract, which
appears in its context in the prelims to my American Empire, because I know of nothing that sum-
marises the scholarly lifecycle better than this does.
1
APPROACHES TO AFRICA’S
ECONOMIC PAST
Africa, though only part of the African continent, is itself almost as large as the
whole of Europe, excluding Russia, and its population is now approaching the
substantial total of 100 million. Admittedly, imperial history spanned the globe,
but it did so only by treating the inhabitants of other continents as extras in an
essentially European epic: they paraded on ceremonial occasions; they smiled
inscrutably in the mysterious East; and they conducted obscure ‘native wars’ in
darkest Africa. The limitations of the imperial perspective became apparent once
it was realised that Africans and Indians occupied a central place in the history
of their own continents. It is now clear that West Africa has a long and varied
history. To attempt to comprehend even the economic aspects of this history in
one volume is to stretch generalisations as far as safety will permit.
Although this book seeks to fill a gap in African studies, it would be mislead-
ing to suggest that it is entirely original. Without the labour of the early pion-
eers of West African economic history the present work could not have been
conceived, and without the detailed research which has been undertaken during
the past 10 or 15 years it could not have been completed.
The first sizeable landmark was undoubtedly Allan McPhee’s classic study,
The Economic Revolution in British West Africa, which appeared in 1926.1 In the
preface to his book McPhee justified his efforts by drawing attention to the fact
that the economic history of the empire in general, and of British West Africa
in particular, had been almost entirely ignored, just as the economic history of
England had been neglected before the work of Thorold Rogers and William
Cunningham. McPhee’s hope that his book would immediately point the way
for other scholars was unfulfilled. It was not until 1942 that some of the topics
he had dealt with were taken up again, this time by W. K. Hancock, whose
celebrated Survey of British Commonwealth Affairs included a penetrating study of
the traders’ frontier in West Africa. Between them, these two works established
a rather isolated, and often deserted, academic outpost. That they achieved even
this was mainly because they treated West Africa as part of the wider theme of
imperial history.2 The French were possibly even less concerned with the eco-
nomic history of their West African territories. Georges Hardy’s La mise en valeur
du Sénégal de 1817 à 1854, published in 1921, was another lone work cast in
the mould of imperial history. Only two books published before the 1950s
looked at West Africa’s economic past from an indigenous point of view. These
were E. W. Bovill’s Caravans of the Old Sahara, first published in 1933,3 and
George W. Brown’s neglected study, The Economic History of Liberia, which
appeared in 1941. These books, too, were very much products of their time:
1 A fuller appreciation of McPhee’s work can be found in the Introduction to the new edition of his
book published in 1971.
2 However, these books were also exceptionally skilled in their handling of the African side of the
imperial story.
3 A new, and extensively revised, version of this book is available as The Golden Trade of the Moors,
London, 1968.
46 Approaches to Africa’s economic past
Bovill’s scholarly, yet popular, account emphasised the more colourful and
adventurous side of African history; while Brown’s careful research was partly
inspired, like other works by African American intellectuals at that time, by the
ideal of African independence which Liberia represented.
The last 15 years have seen a marked increase in the number of scholarly publica-
tions on Africa, though relatively few of these have focused on economic history.
As will be clear from the footnotes and bibliography, a great deal of the evidence
and argument of this book rests on the work of economists, anthropologists and
geographers. Beginning in 1956, with the appearance of K. O. Dike’s Trade and Pol-
itics in the Niger Delta, 1830–1885, most of the work conventionally regarded as
economic history concentrated on Afro-European trade relations, chiefly because
this was a theme which presented relatively few research problems. During the
1960s the emphasis began to shift towards the study of indigenous economic activ-
ities, as explored, for example, in Polly Hill’s The Migrant Cocoa-Farmers of Southern
Ghana, published in 1963, and in the collection of essays edited by Claude Meillas-
soux entitled The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa (1971).
Research into production and exchange in the domestic economy will probably
become the chief preoccupation of economic historians of Africa during the 1970s.
Reliance on the work of scholars other than historians is not simply a matter of
necessity, but also of choice. History needs to be related closely to the social sciences
for two reasons. In the first place, both historians and social scientists are involved in
studying social stability and social change, though these themes are not, of course,
their sole interest. Secondly, their approach to these subjects has much more in
common than is often allowed. The assertion that historians are concerned with
unique events, while social scientists search for general laws, is an article of faith rather
than an accurate description of what both actually do. In practice, historians of Africa
have already moved some way towards achieving an inter-disciplinary approach. Stat-
istical analysis has been used to study the development of bureaucracy in the pre-
colonial period;4 econometric techniques have been employed to analyse structural
change in the more recent past;5 the concepts and tools of social anthropology have
been applied to social structures and to political systems;6 and explicit attention has
been paid to philosophical problems in historical causation.7 Historians who still regard
the study of Africa’s past as an unrewarding exercise,8 should consider whether, by
refusing to put their eyes to the telescope, they have failed, as Galileo’s critics failed, to
see that the world extends beyond Europe. They should also consider the possibility
4 Ivor Wilks, ‘Aspects of Bureaucratization in Ashanti in the Nineteenth Century’, Journal of African
History, 7, 1966, pp. 215–32.
5 R. Szereszewski, Structural Changes in the Economy of Ghana, 1891–1911, London, 1965.
6 See, for example, History and Social Anthropology, ed. I. M. Lewis, London, 1968.
7 R. S. Smith, ‘Event and Portent: The Fall of Old Oyo, a Problem in Historical Explanation’, Africa,
41, 1971, pp. 186–99.
8 For recent references to ‘unhistoric’ Africa, see H. R. Trevor-Roper, ‘The Past and the Present:
History and Sociology’, Past & Present, 42, 1969, pp. 3–17.
Approaches to Africa’s economic past 47
that they might learn from, as well as contribute to, the methodology and research
techniques used by historians of Africa.
The second justification for this volume is as a contribution to the study of the
underdeveloped world. This aspect of the book can be seen most clearly in the
treatment of themes such as the characteristics of ‘traditional’ societies, the nature of
pre-industrial exchange, the imperialism of industrial Europe, the economics of
colonialism, and the rise of nationalism, most of which will be familiar to historians
specialising in underdeveloped regions other than West Africa. It is worth pointing
out in this connection that hardly any comprehensive economic histories of coun-
tries in the underdeveloped world have been written. Books dealing with all sectors
of the economy tend to have a chronological limitation, being confined to the
period since the nineteenth century,9 while those relating to earlier periods tend to
concentrate on particular sectors of the economy.10 Africa is especially interesting
for comparative purposes because the continent occupies an important place in the
mythology of underdevelopment. Pre-colonial Africa is popularly regarded as form-
ing an economic Plimsoll line drawn to mark subsistence activities. Above this line
are placed the supposedly more advanced economies of other pre-industrial regions,
with the loftiest quarters being reserved for European countries. West Africa pro-
vides a good test of the accuracy of this ranking, and of the beliefs about ‘traditional’
societies which underlie it, because this part of the continent can be studied in some
depth from an early date, and without the complicating presence of white settlers.
Assuming that a case has been made out for undertaking a survey of West African
economic history, the problem now arises as to how to organise the great variety of
specialised research which forms the basis of this book. The issue is a complicated one
because the research in question covers several disciplines and is also uneven in its
treatment of subjects which require approximately equal emphasis in a study of West
Africa’s economic past. Furthermore, no chronology appropriate to economic history
has yet been advanced. In these circumstances, the temptation to let the facts ‘speak
for themselves’ is very strong. Unfortunately, the facts have no innate capacity for
ordering themselves. What we do not know and what we choose to omit may be as
important, or more important, than what we include, and what we include is deter-
mined partly by our assumptions about what is important. The narrative approach
adopted by many historians often smothers explanation in description and disguises the
assumptions which influence the selection of material. Economists would probably
9 Only a few studies can be cited here: Celso Furtado, Economic Development of Latin America: A Survey
from Colonial Times to the Cuban Revolution, Cambridge 1970; James C. Ingram, Economic Change in Thai-
land, 1850–1970, Stanford 1971; Frank H. H. King, A Concise Economic History of Modern China,
London, 1970; and W. W. Lockwood, The Economic Development of Japan, Princeton 1954.
10 Again, only a few examples can be noted: I. Habib, Agrarian System of Mughal India, Bombay, 1963;
D. H. Perkins, Agricultural Development in China, 1568–1968, Edinburgh, 1971; and Thomas
C. Smith, The Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan, Stanford, 1959. Studies in the Economic History of the
Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, ed. M. A. Cook, London, 1970, covers a longer
timespan and a variety of themes.
48 Approaches to Africa’s economic past
favour a solution which used the concepts and techniques of national accounting to
measure changes in national and personal income and expenditure. This procedure
also presents difficulties. The data needed for an investigation of this kind are not avail-
able before the twentieth century, and in any case there are conceptual problems relat-
ing to the definition of ‘national’ units in the pre-colonial period.11
An organising principle is required which is broad enough to cover the total-
ity of economic activities over many centuries, yet specific enough to provide
a coherent theme for the book as a whole. The organising principle which best
meets these criteria is that of the market. This concept, as defined here, has
three dimensions: the volume and value of goods and services transacted, which
determine the extent of the market in quantitative terms; geographical variations
in exchange activity, which fix the extent of the market in spatial terms; and the
number and social status of the parties engaged in exchange, which influence
the composition of the goods and services traded. The market is a theme that
can be followed with the help of both qualitative and quantitative evidence.
The former is predominant in the pre-colonial period, and the latter becomes
important in the twentieth century.
Two further observations need to be made about the way the concept of the
market will be used. In the first place, it is important to guard against the
assumption that there is a natural tendency towards development, and that devi-
ations from this trend require special explanation. Otherwise, the market can
easily become part of an evolutionist saga, which begins with subsistence econ-
omies and ends with industrialisation. The search for the origins of the market is
as fruitless as the quest once undertaken by political philosophers for the origins
of the state. Trade in Africa, as elsewhere, is as old as man himself, and the con-
cept of the market is appropriate to early as well as to more recent times. More-
over, exchange and subsistence activities were (and still are) integrated. An
explanation of the one involves a consideration of the other, for the size of the
market cannot be understood without reference to non-market activities.
Change occurs, but not necessarily in the direction of industrialisation. It is
important to identify the factors which enable the market to expand, but it is
equally important to remember that growth can be slowed, that the market can
contract and that future trends are more a matter of speculation than of accurate
prediction.
The second observation relates to the interpretation of exchange activities in
pre-industrial societies. When historians discuss markets and trade, they tend to
assume that prices are determined by supply and demand, and that the profitabil-
ity of various transactions influences the volume and type of goods placed on
11 Colonialism did not resolve this problem merely by establishing clearly marked boundaries.
A major weakness of Szereszewski’s book, Structural Changes in the Economy of Ghana, 1891–1911,
London, 1965, is that the national unit in question (the Gold Coast) was not an economic entity at
that time.
Approaches to Africa’s economic past 49
the market and the factor combination required to produce them. However, it
is possible that these rules may not apply universally. All societies have an eco-
nomic system, in that they provide material goods to satisfy biological and social
wants, but the code devised for operating this system may not centre on econo-
mising and maximising principles of the kind which are thought to predominate
in modern, industrial societies. In pre-industrial societies, transactional rules
other than price may be more important in determining the terms on which
goods are exchanged. The principles governing market activity in these societies
may be those of reciprocity (obligatory gift-giving among friends and kinsmen)
and redistribution (the reallocation of customary receipts by a socially deter-
mined authority).
The contrast between these two sets of behavioural rules is a prominent
theme in modern sociological thought and has formed the basis of a substantial
literature on rural-urban differences. Its origin can be traced to Tönnies’s dis-
tinction between Gemeinschaft and Gesellschaft, that is between a community
bound by kinship and an association held together by contract, and to Weber’s
distinction between substantive (traditional) and formal (modern) rationality.
The substantivist interpretation has been applied to Africa by writers such as
Polanyi and Dalton, who have contended that traditional exchange was con-
ducted according to the principles of reciprocity and redistribution.12 The for-
malist view has been advanced by a larger group of scholars, headed by Firth
and Jones, who have argued in favour of the selective applicability of Western
economic theory.13
To analyse market activities in Africa without considering the possibility
that the rules governing economic behaviour might be very different from
those prevailing in the industrial world, is to risk adopting an ethnocentric
and anachronistic approach. However, the substantivist viewpoint, stimulating
though it is, has less to recommend it than the modified formalism of Firth
and Jones. The reasons for this judgement will be elaborated in Chapter 2. At
this point, it is sufficient to note that the substantivists are mistaken in arguing
that the values and motivation of pre-industrial societies differ in kind rather
12 Trade and Market in the Early Empires, ed. K. Polanyi, C. W. Arensberg and H. W. Pearson, Glen-
coe, 1957. The best guide to Polanyi’s thought is S. C. Humphreys, ‘History,’ Economics, and
Anthropology: The Work of Karl Polanyi’, History and Theory, 8, 1969, pp. 165–212. References
to Dalton’s earlier, formative work can be found in his recent article, ‘Theoretical Issues in Eco-
nomic Anthropology’, Current Anthropology, 10, 1969, pp. 63–102. Dalton has also edited
a collection of readings, Tribal and Peasant Economies, New York, 1967, which presents the substan-
tivist viewpoint.
13 An excellent review of this controversy can be found in Themes in Economic Anthropology, ed. Ray-
mond Firth, London, 1967, which represents a qualified, formalist approach. A similar view is
expressed in Economic Anthropology, ed. Edward E. LeClair and Harold K. Schneider, New York,
1968. The first detailed statement of the formalist interpretation of African economic behaviour
was W. O. Jones’s important article, ‘Economic Man in Africa’, Food Research Institute Studies, 1,
1960, pp. 107–34.
50 Approaches to Africa’s economic past
than in degree from those of industrial societies. Indeed, even differences of degree
may be much smaller than is often assumed. Furthermore, the substantivist case fails
to meet the empirical test: the economy of pre-colonial West Africa simply did not
function in accordance with principles which are supposed to characterise ‘trad-
itional’ societies. Indeed, the concept of a ‘traditional’ society is an ideal-type which
is of questionable value in understanding reality.
The argument of the book is derived from its theme and relates to stability and
change in the market. The analysis of the pre-colonial domestic economy presented
in Chapter 2 is basic to the rest of the book. This chapter attacks the mythology
which has grown up about the characteristics of ‘traditional’ societies, demonstrates
that exchange was widespread, identifies the forces trying to expand the market and
reaches conclusions about internal constraints on growth. Chapter 3 investigates
West Africa’s external commercial relationships in the period before the Industrial
Revolution in Europe and makes use of a simple model of international trade to
explain why Saharan and Atlantic commerce failed to overcome existing barriers to
market growth. Chapter 4 shows how, for the first time, strong linkages were estab-
lished between external trade and the domestic economy as a result of the expansion
of ‘legitimate’ commerce in the nineteenth century. This development, it is sug-
gested, marks the beginning of the modern economic history of West Africa, and is
also central to an understanding of why the region was partitioned by European
powers. Chapter 5 provides a brief, perspective view of the colonial period. The
concepts of ‘open’ and ‘closed’ economies are employed to analyse the main struc-
tural features of colonialism, and quantitative data are used to chart the performance
of the colonial economies between 1900 and 1960. Chapter 6 assesses the contribu-
tions of expatriates and Africans to the completion of the open economies of West
Africa during the first half of the colonial era (1900–30). It is contended that the
open economy was a formalised version of the economy which was already begin-
ning to emerge in the nineteenth century before partition, and that export growth
resulted primarily from mobilising factors within the domestic economy. Chapter 7
deals with the modifications which were made to the open economies in
the second half of the colonial period (1930–60) and presents an interpretation of
the rise of nationalism and the beginnings of industrialisation based on an analysis of
developments in the export sector and in the domestic economy.
This prospectus is offered in the hope that it will guide the reader through
the details which now follow.
2
THE DOMESTIC ECONOMY
Structure and function
To begin at the beginning is logical. It is also particularly desirable in the present con-
text, given the now widespread recognition of the importance of writing the indigen-
ous history of Africa. It is precisely at this point, however, that the historian of Africa
faces the greatest difficulty with regard to source material. In the first place, there is
a shortage of evidence, especially in the case of the forest zone, where indigenous writ-
ten records were virtually unknown before the nineteenth century. Secondly, the
sources which do exist have rarely been used to study the history of the domestic
economy in the pre-colonial period, that is before about 1900.1 Possessing only a bare
patchwork of data, it is hard to avoid presenting a composite picture of the ‘traditional’
economy. Lacking a coherent chronology, it is harder still to escape a static, timeless
account of the local economy in the centuries before the coming of European rule.
These remarks, though necessary as a guide to the limitations of the present chap-
ter, are not intended to strike an immediate note of anti-climax, still less to set the
tone for the whole of the discussion which follows. On the contrary, there is some
room for optimism, even within the bounds set by the current state of knowledge.
There is a certain amount of evidence, though it may not measure up to the
Domesday Survey;2 there is a variety of secondary sources, some of which have
1 Raymond Mauny’s, Tableau géographique de l’ouest africain au moyen âge, Dakar, 1961, is a valuable
exception, but even this work says more about trade than about agriculture, though the latter was
the basis of the economy in most parts of West Africa.
2 Briefly, it can be said that for the period down to the eighth century the historian is reliant on arch-
aeological, linguistic and botanical research. From the eighth century onwards the flow of informa-
tion begins to increase, mainly as a result of records kept by Arab travellers, though this evidence is
patchy and refers chiefly to the region known as the Western Sudan. After the fifteenth century,
with the arrival of Europeans, the volume of material relating to the forest zone also starts to grow,
but is confined, before the nineteenth century, largely to the coastal area.
52 The domestic economy
suffered an extraordinary and totally unjustified neglect;3 and there is a great deal
which historians can learn from the pioneering work carried out by scholars in
other disciplines.4
It is possible, simply by making use of existing knowledge, to advance some
way towards achieving two aims. To begin with there is sufficient evidence to
reconstruct at least an outline of the pre-colonial economy, and to note a few
of the more important chronological developments and regional variations. At
the same time, it must be emphasised that this chapter is no more than
a beginning. Those who are provoked, quite rightly, by its shortcomings, are
invited to undertake the research needed to eliminate them.5 Next, this out-
line, though incomplete, leads to a reappraisal of the myths, ancient and
modern, which have grown up about the African past, and, indeed, about
underdevelopment in general. Unfortunately, neither a lack of evidence nor
a failure to consult work already published has inhibited the expression of
views about the economic backwardness of Africa in the period before Euro-
pean rule. On the contrary, opinions have been stated with a degree of convic-
tion which sometimes appears to be inversely related to the amount of historical
knowledge acquired. It is hoped that the conclusions reached here will produce
a more accurate appreciation of the constraints operating on the West African
economy in the pre-colonial period. They should also have a wider relevance, for
generalised versions of the myths associated with Africa can be found in books
which purport to explain economic backwardness in many other parts of the
underdeveloped world today.
An amalgamated version of the beliefs about the economic backwardness
of Africa in the pre-colonial period would include the following major
points. The domestic economy was a subsistence economy, which was uni-
form, unchanging and therefore uninteresting. Such an economy is worthy
of only cursory attention because the obstacles impeding its development
can readily be identified and are familiar enough—at least to experts. The
dominant agricultural sector, so it is alleged, was virtually immobilised by
a combination of primitive technology, communal land tenure and the
extended family. The development of key entrepreneurial groups was
inhibited by the prevalence of an anti-capitalist value system. This ideology
was reinforced by African political systems, which were either conservative
gerontocracies based on ascribed status, or were so egalitarian that it was
3 One book in particular must be accorded, quite undeservedly, the title of the least used secondary
work in the field of West African economic history. This is Lars Sundström’s The Trade of Guinea,
Lund, 1965, which is a mine of information about the internal trade of West Africa in the eighteenth
and nineteenth centuries. This study has hardly been noticed even by specialists.
4 Valuable contributions have been made to the study of ‘traditional’ agriculture and markets by geog-
raphers, anthropologists and field economists, though, understandably, their work lacks the chrono-
logical dimension which is central to the writing of history.
5 Some possible research topics will be suggested in subsequent sections of this chapter.
The domestic economy 53
under the dominion of custom and impulse; scarcely ever striking out new
lines for themselves; never forecasting the distant future; fitful in spite of
their servitude to custom; governed by the fancy of the moment; ready at
all times for the most arduous exertions, but incapable of keeping them-
selves long to steady work.6
This state of affairs prevented what Western observers regarded as progress, both
moral and material. According to this interpretation, Africa’s release from barbar-
ism waited until the close of the nineteenth century, when the Europeans came,
like cavalry over the hill, to confer the benefits of Western civilisation on
Kipling’s
On the other hand, there is the newer, more fashionable, myth of Merrie Africa,
which has come to the fore during the past ten or fifteen years. On this view the
pre-colonial era was a Golden Age, in which generations of Africans enjoyed con-
genial lives in well-integrated, smoothly functioning societies. The means of liveli-
hood came easily to hand, for foodstuffs grew wild and in abundance, and this good
fortune enabled the inhabitants to concentrate on leisure pursuits, which, if some
sources are to be believed, consisted of interminable dancing and drumming.7 The
6 Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics, 8th ed., London, 1938, pp. 723–4.
7 Films and travel brochures provide an important and neglected source for those interested in the
history of ideas, for both reflect, and in some cases reinforce, stereotypes. For example, Horizon
Travel Ltd invited those thinking of taking a foreign holiday in 1972 to visit the Gambia, where ‘the
drum beat of black Africa captivates and enthrals you as you watch the happy-go-lucky natives
dance at the drop of a hat, as twilight descends on Bathurst’. Similarly, films designed to encourage
foreign tourists to England give the impression that the population is divided roughly equally
between Yeomen of the Guard and Morris dancers.
54 The domestic economy
8 Herbert Butterfield in The Whig Interpretation of History, London, 1931, was the first to identify the
historical school which made use of past events in order to justify and reinforce the current political
regime. The True Whig Party was founded about 1870 and has been in power in Liberia more or
less continuously since then.
The domestic economy 55
a preface to a story of interaction that can be followed later on in this and subsequent
chapters.9 The brevity of the present outline is intended to lend support to its main
purpose, which is to deny that the physical environment is immutable, or that it has
determined the course of African history.
From Dakar to Lake Chad, a distance of over 2,000 miles, there extends
a belt of undulating grassland studded with trees. This area, known as the West-
ern Sudan, forms a corridor about 600 miles wide. To the north lies the Sahara
Desert, which reaches out about 1,000 miles towards North Africa. To the
south, and almost touching the sea, stretches a belt of tropical forest, again run-
ning from west to east, but covering no more than 200 miles from north to
south even at its widest, and punctuated in the middle (roughly between Accra
and Porto Novo) by the savanna. Winter never comes to West Africa, so low
temperatures are no obstacle to plant growth, and rainfall is the chief physical
determinant of the character and extent of the vegetation. The amount of rain-
fall decreases from the south, where it might exceed 100 inches a year, to the
north, where it might be non-existent in some years. It is this variation which
largely explains the great contrast between the humid forest and the dry, bare
desert, and also the tendency for vegetation zones to run in parallel bands from
west to east. This alignment is not seriously modified by changes in altitude, for
only rarely does the land rise much above 2,000 feet. The main vegetation
zones have been present since about 3000 B.C. and are the product of a drying-
out process which started 10,000 or 12,000 years ago. Before then, and begin-
ning approximately 70,000 years ago, there was an era of reduced temperatures
and higher rainfall that encouraged Mediterranean vegetation and human settle-
ment in parts of West Africa which are now desert.
It used to be thought that this environment was naturally well endowed and
potentially very rich. Huntington, whose theories achieved considerable popu-
larity in the 1920s and 1930s, incorporated this belief into his explanation of the
economic backwardness of the tropics. According to him, ‘low mentality, iner-
tia, disease or the relative ease of life in a tropical climate may prevent people
from having new ideas or putting them into execution’.10 There were two main
reasons why opinions of this kind came to be held about West Africa. In the
first place, early European observers seem to have regarded the luxuriance of the
tropical forest as an indication of the general fertility of the region. Secondly,
the long association between the Western Sudan and the gold trade encouraged
the view that the savanna was a rich and desirable area.11 In the 1940s and
1950s, however, a different interpretation began to emerge, partly, it is
9 Readers who require more geographical information are referred to the monumental work of
scholarship by W. B. Morgan and J. C. Pugh, West Africa, London, 1969, which should also be
consulted with reference to subsequent sections of the present chapter and to Chapters 6 and 7.
10 Ellsworth Huntington, Mainsprings of Civilisation, New York, 1945, p. 4.
11 The gold trade is dealt with in Chapter 3. The alleged wealth of the Western Sudan played a part in
shaping European attitudes towards West Africa in the nineteenth century, as is noted in Chapter 4.
20°N
Lake Chad
12°N
Desert
Sub-desert Steppe
Steppe
Dry Savanna
Savanna
Montane-undifferentiated Moist Forest 0 800 kilometres
Forest- Savanna Mangroves 0 500 statute miles
12°W 0 12°E
Mosaic
15 The approach adopted in the foregoing paragraphs owes a great deal to two complementary art-
icles: June Helm, ‘The Ecological Approach in Anthropology’, American Journal of Sociology, 67,
1962, pp. 630–9, and W. B. Morgan and R. P. Moss, ‘Geography and Ecology: The Concept of
the Community and Its Relationship to Environment’, Annals of the Association of American Geog-
raphers, 55, 1965, pp. 339–50.
16 J. D. Clark, The Prehistory of Africa, London, 1970, pp. 164–9.
17 For further details see the classification adopted by Morgan and Pugh, West Africa, pp. 17–32,
which seems to be the most helpful one for economic historians.
18 E. A. Wrigley, Population and History, London, 1969, p. 36.
19 The implications of this observation are considered, from an economist’s point of view, by Gerald
K. Helleiner, ‘Typology in Development Theory: The Land Surplus Economy (Nigeria)’, Food
Research Institute Studies, 6, 1966, pp. 181–94. For an exhaustive, geographical study of the
The domestic economy 59
terms there was more land available than there was labour to cultivate it. Even
today, when the population is well over twice as great as it was at the begin-
ning of the twentieth century, land shortage has yet to become a major prob-
lem, except in certain localities.
The foregoing generalisations require amplification. To begin with, it is import-
ant to recognise that sparse population and underpopulation are not necessarily
identical. The small number of people in a given area may well be accounted for by
the inadequacy of its natural resources. The population of the Sahara is sparse, but
the region cannot be said to be underpopulated. There is some evidence that in
West Africa low population densities, especially in parts of the Western Sudan,
were related to poor soils and to a lack of biological essentials, such as water and
salt.20 In areas where the land could have supported greater densities, an explanation
of underpopulation is to be sought primarily in the influences affecting rates of fer-
tility and mortality, though it is also likely that political constraints on the move-
ment of peoples played a part in preventing the colonisation of particular localities.
Little is known about the factors which governed fertility in African societies,
though it does seem that child-rearing practices reduced the number of possible
births in some communities, but there is evidence to indicate that mortality from
diseases such as malaria, smallpox and trypanosomiasis (sleeping sickness) was high.
It has been established that these diseases are of great antiquity in West Africa,21 and
that there were severe epidemics of smallpox, meningitis and plague. It has been
suggested, for example, that epidemics and famine greatly reduced the population in
the central part of the Western Sudan in the seventeenth and eighteenth
centuries.22
Next, it is necessary to correct the impression, which is still widespread out-
side the ranks of demographers, that underpopulation is an exceptional condition
requiring special explanation. This view derives from the assumption that there
is a normal tendency for population to press against the limit of resources in
accordance with the principle that ‘nature abhors a vacuum’. This idea was first
popularised by Malthus, and it has received support in recent years because the
population in many underdeveloped countries is undoubtedly growing rapidly.
However, the population ‘explosion’ is a comparatively modern event in world
history. Pre-industrial populations were small: underpopulation was at least as
common as overpopulation down to the nineteenth century and was certainly
MOORS UNOCCUPIED
ARABS
To
uco
ule
16°N ur 16°N
TUAREG
u r TUAREG
Wolof ule TUBU
co SARAKOLE
Lebou T ou Dogon Songhay
Serer r Malinke Fulani & Fulani & Daza
Fulan Sere Khassonke
i Wolof or Ke Bozo Sara Zerma Dagera Kanuri Kanembu
uri
Kagoro HAUSA & FULANI Manga & Hausa
Diola Samo
Ma
Fulani T
en Bass a ri BAMBARA Sa Dendi Mo Kanuri
Balante & da Koyam
Malin Bobo MOSSI GOURMA So
n
Manjak Dialonke Dendi Bede Magumi & Lera Shuwa
-Ke 8 MALINKE Dioula Da Nie
Brames gar Bou Afa & Bol Shuwa
9 Samo i Kas Banga & Dak Nin Ni Gamergu
Nalou Nou Be Tienga Wa Ful Ch
Bailo Ka
Fulani Margi
Nanou Dr Di Bu Ku Busa Duka
D
Sia da Pb
la
Susu Yalunka a n Mam M
D Lamba Kambera Kamuku ra 5 Hausa Tera Fali
G
Lo
Birifor
Baga Limba Dagomba Kn BARIBA Basa Gwari 2 & Gerumawa Ta Gheke
ro
Isa agaba
Koranko Konianke SENOUFO K
n
g
Saharan Loko Nupe Koro 3 Nda Bu Wot B Bata
an
Goma NaBA Kotokoli
Gana 6 Id
ul
Temne Ko Kissi Tagouana Djimini Na K W Kabrar 4 Chamba
Ko
Toma Dioula Dioula l a Adele Mano Jukun &
Fulani na
Ntribu
Igbus Basa Koro Fulani
J
Bu Mende lle YORUBA lgala
llo pe Dan Gouro BAOULE Buem Tiv Kyato ibu Kotoro
m Gola K G Mana Fon
West Sudanic be Nuache Aizo Idoma Mambila
Krim S AKAN Ewe EDO Boki Tikar
Basa ikon Gere Bete
Agni Egede
Vai i e Fon Ekoi
Central Sudanic Kra Dida Att Popo Ijaw IBO
Sapo Anyang 0 300
KRU Ga-Adangme Itsekiri Ibibio Balundu kilometres
Voltaic Lagoon Ijaw
Mongo statute miles
Grebo 0 200 4°N
4°N KALABARI Mboko Kpe
East Sudanic
1. Dakha Afa Afawa Bur Burumawa Gana Ganagana Ku Kusasi Nie Nienige Son Songhay
Sub-Sudanic & 2. Mama A Afu Ch Chibuk G Gwa L Lobi Nin Ningawa Ta Tangale
Sub-Guinean 3. Mada B Bachama Dak Dakakari Id Idomo Mam Mamprusi N Nioniose Ti Tiefo
Refugees 4. Basa Ba Bassari Di Dian J Jera M Moba Nou Nounouma T Tienga
5. Birom
Be Berba Dr Dorosie Kas Kasena Mo Mober Pb Pabia & Bura W Warjama
Southwestern 6. Ankwe
7. Bolewa Bol Bolewa D Dye Kn Konkomba Na Nanumba P Pilapila Wi Winjiwinji
Guinean & Sub- 8. Landuma Bou Bousansi E Ekuri Ko Kono Nda Ndara Sa Sara Wo Wobe
Guinean 9. Diola BU Builsa F Fulse K Kotokoli Ni Ngama S Son Wur Wurkun
23 See, for example, D. C. Coleman, ‘Labour in the English Economy of the Seventeenth Century’,
Economic History Review, 8, 1956, pp. 280–95.
24 Rowena M. Lawson, ‘The Traditional Utilisation of Labour in Agriculture in the Lower Volta,
Ghana’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 12, 1968, pp. 54–61.
25 P. G. Phillips, ‘The Metabolic Cost of Common West African Agricultural Activities’, Journal of
Tropical Medicine and Hygiene, 57, 1954, pp. 12–20.
26 J. M. Hunter, ‘Seasonal Hunger in a Part of the West African Savanna: A Survey of Bodyweights
in Nangodi, N.E. Ghana’, Institute of British Geographers Transactions, 41, 1967, pp. 167–86. On the
need for caution in discussing the so-called ‘hungry gap’, see the earlier article by Marvin
P. Miracle, ‘Seasonal Hunger: A Vague Concept and an Unexplored Problem’, Bulletin de l’IFAN,
23, 1961, pp. 273–83. The ‘hungry gap’ is less serious in root-growing forest areas, where seasonal
variations in the availability of foodstuffs are not so marked.
62 The domestic economy
27 A tragic variation on this principle has been studied by Hunter, who has shown how hunger drives
migrants into fertile and inviting riverine areas, where they contract river blindness and are forced
to leave after a few years—with their numbers greatly reduced. See J. M. Hunter, ‘River Blindness
in Nangodi, Northern Ghana’, Geographical Review, 56, 1966, pp. 398–416.
28 In contrast to the popular view of the desert oasis as consisting of a few palm trees surrounding
a small pond of clear water. For a detailed study of one large Saharan settlement, see J. Laufray,
‘Chronique de Ghadames’, Ibla, 32, 1945, pp. 367–85; 33, 1946, pp. 343–71.
29 These settlements have been studied by M. B. Gleave, whose work is listed in the bibliography for
Chapter 6.
30 J. Richard-Molard, ‘Les densités de population au Fouta-Djallon’, Présence Africaine, 15, 1952, pp.
95–106.
31 For further information see Raymond Mauny, Tableau géographique de l’ouest africain au moyen âge,
Dakar 1961, pp. 495–503, though the figures quoted here reflect the results of more recent
research.
The domestic economy 63
northern Nigeria) lived in towns in the period before 1900, the most prominent
example being Kano, whose population in the middle of the nineteenth century
was reckoned by the famous traveller, Barth, to be about 30,000, a figure that
doubled at the height of the trading season. The Yoruba, further south and
partly in the forest zone, were also highly urbanised. In the nineteenth century
Yorubaland contained about a dozen towns with populations of over 20,000,
the largest being Ibadan, which had about 70,000 inhabitants and an outer wall
measuring 24 miles in circumference.32 Further east, the forest city of Benin was
reckoned to have a population of 15,000 at the end of the eighteenth century,
and was thought to have been much larger two or three centuries earlier. At the
beginning of the seventeenth century a Dutch visitor to Benin recorded the fol-
lowing impressions:
The towne seemeth to be very great, when you enter into it, you goe
into a broad street, not paved, which seemeth to be seven or eight times
broader than the Warmoes street in Amsterdam, which goeth right out,
and never crooketh, and where I was lodged … it was at least a quarter of
an houres going from the gate, and yet I could not see to the end of the
street.33
It is impossible here to enter into a general discussion of the origin and structure
of pre-industrial towns.34 However, it is important to point out that the view
that urbanisation becomes quantitatively significant only after industrialisation
needs to be stated carefully if the contrast between ‘traditional’ and ‘modern’
societies is not to be overemphasised. Towns and large villages were a common
feature of the West African landscape in the pre-colonial era. Admittedly, their
occupational structure differed from that of modern cities in that they were pri-
marily places where agriculturalists gathered for non-agricultural purposes, above
all for defence and trade. Many African urban dwellers commuted daily to their
farms outside the town walls, whereas in the Western world suburban man
travels into the city centre to work in industry and commerce. This evidence
shows what is not in dispute, namely that West African towns were not indus-
trial towns in the modern sense, but it cannot be used to argue that they were
essentially different from the towns which existed, for instance, in late medieval
Europe. African towns not only sheltered farmers, they housed specialised per-
sonnel, such as craftsmen, transport contractors, hoteliers and merchants; they
were focal points for the exchange of goods of all kinds; and they were
32 William R. Bascom, ‘Urbanism as a Traditional African Pattern’, Sociological Review, 7, 1959, pp.
29–43.
33 Quoted in Thomas Hodgkin, Nigerian Perspectives, 1960, pp. 119–20. The visitor was the anonym-
ous ‘D.R.’ possibly Dierick Reuters.
34 For further consideration of this question see Gideon Sjoberg, The Preindustrial City, Glencoe,
1960.
64 The domestic economy
35 Ife and Benin brass work is thought to date from the thirteenth century. Timbuctu, founded in the
twelfth century, had become a noted seat of learning by the fourteenth century.
36 See the studies by Dorjahn and Tholley, Guèye, Holas, Kup, Niane, Pageard, Perie and Sellier, and
Riad listed in the Bibliography.
The domestic economy 65
The most important economic unit in virtually all West African societies
was, and still is, the household. The household was not always identical with
the family and was quite capable of adapting its size and skills to meet chan-
ging circumstances and to create new opportunities. Each household approximated
to the optimum size for the conditions in which it operated. A large household could
divide itself into several smaller units, though without necessarily breaking up the
family too. Netting’s research has demonstrated that small households predominated
among the Kofyar of central Nigeria because they were best suited to the
system of intensive agriculture which prevailed in the area.37 The household
was also capable of expanding. Reyburn’s study of Cameroon, for example,
has suggested that the demand for extra labour was a principal cause of the
existence and growth of polygymous families.38 Households of all sizes were
usually in a position to mobilise additional labour at times of peak demand.
Communal labour was used by the Yoruba (in Nigeria) to prepare and weed
farms, and by the Adioukrou (in the Ivory Coast) to exploit groves of palm
trees. Many African societies distinguished between the labour of men and
women, though the line was not always drawn at the same point. In
Bamenda (Cameroon), women were especially important in farming, whereas
in Yorubaland, they spent much more of their time trading. However, there
was a considerable degree of occupational specialisation, both seasonal and
permanent, which cut across divisions of sex. In any case, it is by no means
clear that the division of labour between men and women represented
a serious misallocation of human resources. Although the spread of Islam
from the eighth century onwards encouraged a more restrictive attitude
towards the activities of females, African women adjusted to this situation
with characteristic ingenuity by devising a marketing system which was based
on the compound rather than on the village square.39
There is no evidence to show that the household labour force was inefficient,
and it is hard to envisage organisational changes which would have cut production
costs or greatly improved the range, quality or volume of output. It is noteworthy
that the household, far from dissolving under the impact of Western capitalism in
the twentieth century, or for that matter surviving to obstruct economic progress,
became a dynamic agency for the development of new export crops and for the
expansion of internal trade. Households could change their size and suffer serious
losses, but they rarely went out of business. It is suggested, speculatively, that the
tenacity of the household as a unit of production can be explained partly by viewing
37 Robert McC. Netting, Hill Farmers of Nigeria, Seattle, 1968. A similar thesis is developed by Irene
B. Taeuber, ‘The Family of Chinese Farmers’, in Family and Kinship in Chinese Society, ed. Maurice
Freedman, Stanford, 1970, pp. 63–85.
38 William D. Reyburn, ‘Polygamy, Economy and Christianity in the Eastern Cameroun’, Practical
Anthropology, 6, 1959, pp. 1–19.
39 Polly Hill, ‘Hidden Trade in Hausaland’, Man, 4, 1969, pp. 392–409, has studied this system as it
operates today.
66 The domestic economy
its labour force as a fixed overhead rather than as a variable cost.40 In practice over-
heads were kept low because all members of the household began working at a very
early age and remained in employment until they became infirm or died, while
those who were unemployed could be maintained relatively cheaply. The house-
hold was highly competitive because family labour was costless (in the formal sense
of not receiving a wage) and could be used to the point where its marginal product
was zero.41 Traditional roles proved to be flexible. In the twentieth century, for
example, men became more involved in farming than they had in the past. Further-
more, the much-maligned extended family, far from being a ‘drag on development’,
often provided the funds which enabled enterprising individuals and groups to
launch new undertakings, and it offered them a refuge if their ventures failed. The
large household and the extended family undoubtedly placed obligations on success-
ful entrepreneurs, but they usually had the skill to balance private interest against
the claims of their kinsmen.42
Allegations about the inefficiency of the traditional labour force are the prod-
uct not only of an inadequate appreciation of the historical evidence relating to
Africa, but also of an exaggerated sense of the superiority and modernity of
labour organisation in Europe. Yet it is not hard to show that Western reality
diverged from the Western ideal, though it is the latter rather than the former
which has been used to judge the performance of the underdeveloped countries.
The household firm, for instance, remained an important unit of production in
England long after the Industrial Revolution. In the late nineteenth century the
vast majority of manufacturing firms continued to be family businesses, though
they also used contracted labour.43 Today, the family firm is prominent in retail-
ing and farming, and often employs little or no additional help. The extended
family also proved to be a dynamic force in Europe, as the examples of the
Rothschilds (in banking) and the Cadburys and Pilkingtons (in industry) make
clear.44 Restrictive practices based on ‘tradition’ were still enforced in the 1960s.
Female labour may well be underused to a greater extent in England than in
West Africa. It is the practice among certain social classes, Christians and agnos-
tics alike, to ‘confine’ their women to the home mainly for cultural reasons, it
40 As was the case with the Russian peasant farm in the late nineteenth century. See James R. Millar,
‘A Reformulation of A. V. Chayanov’s Theory of the Peasant Farm Economy’, Economic Develop-
ment and Cultural Change, 18, 1970, pp. 219–29.
41 The Europeans who tried to establish plantations in West Africa in the early years of the twentieth
century found themselves at a disadvantage because they had to employ paid labour, and they could
operate profitably only while the marginal product of labour was greater than the wage which had
to be paid.
42 E. Wayne Nafziger, ‘The Effect of the Nigerian Extended Family on Entrepreneurial Develop-
ment’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 18, 1969, pp. 25–33.
43 P. L. Payne, ‘The Emergence of the Large-scale Company in Great Britain, 1870–1914’, Economic
History Review, 20, 1967, p. 520.
44 Even in America, the heartland of advanced capitalism, the extended family is still an important, if
neglected, institution. See R. Hill, Family Development in Three Generations, New York, 1970.
The domestic economy 67
being considered an adverse reflection on the husband if his wife has to go out
to work. Those women who do try to make use of their abilities still experience
discrimination. In 1971, about 200 years after the beginning of the Industrial
Revolution, the London Stock Exchange voted for the third time in four years
not to admit women to membership.45
Not all labour was organised on the basis of multifunctional domestic units. Add-
itional labour was provided mainly by slaves, though a small number of hired hands
were used as well. Travellers to African states in the pre-colonial period estimated
the numbers of slaves at between a quarter and one half of the total population, but
little credence can be given to guesswork of this kind. Many of these figures relate
to the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, when the number of domestic slaves
had been swollen by the development of the notorious Atlantic trade. The problem
of numbers is complicated by the difficulty of defining terms. Many of the ‘slaves’
recorded by foreign visitors may well have been, like the ‘slaves’ of the Tsars of
Russia, loyal, if subordinate, citizens of the state, while others, though formally of
slave status, were in practice integrated into the household and were virtually indis-
tinguishable from free men. At the same time, it is important to recognise that slave
labour was present in West Africa long before the rise of the Atlantic trade,46 and
that some slaves were bought, sold and otherwise used like the chattel slaves of the
Americas. A substantial minority of the population in certain areas occupied
a position of legal subordination and practical dependence which was less advanta-
geous than that enjoyed by free men. Not all slavery was a misnomer.
If it is accepted that slavery in West Africa was not simply a European invention,
then it becomes necessary to explain the existence, longevity and variety of the
institution, and to consider whether the presence of slave labour qualifies or sup-
ports the argument advanced so far regarding the efficiency of labour organisation
in the pre-colonial period.47
The main concentrations of slaves were in areas where the development of
domestic exchange activities created employment opportunities which could not be
met by local, free labour. In West Africa, as in many other parts of the pre-
industrial world, such as Greece and Rome, it was large states, such as Mali and
Songhai in the savanna and Ashanti and Dahomey in the forest, which had the
greatest need for slaves and also the means to buy or capture them. Slaves were
commonly specialised workers, though they were found in a variety of occupations.
A few privileged slaves held senior civil and military positions. These powerful
‘trusties’ often possessed numerous slaves of their own. Others were found in skilled
jobs, such as craft manufacture. The majority, however, performed work which was
48 There was no sharp division of labour between male and female slaves, but it is probably true to say
that women were used principally in domestic work, craft production and agriculture. However,
not all women occupied subordinate positions. Some, such as the famous Madam Tinubu of Abeo-
kuta, struck a blow for women’s equality by buying large numbers of male slaves.
49 Charles Toupet, ‘La vallée de la Tamourt en Naaj: problèmes d’aménagement’, Bulletin de l’IFAN,
B, 20, 1958, pp. 68–110.
50 As has been suggested was the case in North America in the nineteenth century. See
H. J. Habakkuk, American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century, Cambridge, 1962.
51 This explanation is essentially that advanced by H. J. Nieboer, Slavery as an Industrial System: Ethno-
logical Researches, The Hague, 1900. There are signs now of a revival of interest in this classic. See
Evsey D. Domar, ‘The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A Hypothesis’, Journal of Economic History, 30,
1970, pp. 18–32. A word of caution should be added here. Nieboer’s theory is neither a necessary
nor a sufficient condition for the existence of slavery, though it so happens to fit the African case.
Slavery and serfdom can exist without there being a labour shortage. Conversely, a labour shortage
does not always lead to enslavement; the decline of population in fourteenth-century England
enabled labourers to increase their bargaining power, and so hastened the end of serfdom.
The domestic economy 69
52 Cedric A. Yeo, ‘The Economics of Roman and American Slavery’, Finanzarchiv, 13, 1951–2, pp.
445–85.
53 Alfred H. Conrad and John R. Meyer, Studies in Econometric History, 1965, Chapters 3 and 4. Also
Stanley L. Engerman, ‘The Effects of Slavery upon the Southern Economy: A Review of the
Recent Debate’, Explorations in Entrepreneurial History, 4, 1967, pp. 71–97.
54 The decline of slavery and the rise of a wage labour force are dealt with in Chapter 6, Section 2.
70 The domestic economy
Africa faced a labour shortage during the early part of the colonial period, and
they resorted to the use of forced labour, even though they were committed to
the abolition of slavery. The colonial mind resolved this paradox by declaring
slavery to be uncivilised and forced labour to be a necessary way of instructing
primitive people about the advantages of modernity.
The diverse nature of slavery reflected prevailing conditions of supply and
demand in West Africa. Since labour was relatively scarce, the cost of replacing
slaves was high, and owners had a strong motive for maintaining at least
a proportion of their slaves in reasonable condition and encouraging them to
breed. Where supplies were abundant, as was to be the case in the Caribbean,
employers had little incentive to invest in the long-term welfare of their slaves.
The result was that slaves were ‘run’ at full capacity and treated as chattels. The
demand for labour in West Africa was also much more varied than in the Carib-
bean, and the differential treatment which slaves received was related to some
extent to the roles assigned to them. Moreover, slaves in West Africa, besides
being inputs in the productive system, performed an important political func-
tion. Africans measured wealth and power in men rather than in acres; those
who exercised authority were man-owners rather than landowners. In some cir-
cumstances obedience could be coerced, but in others it was judged advisable to
secure support by offering slaves a modest stake in the existing political system.
Societies which made extensive use of slave labour exhibited two concurrent
tendencies. On the one hand, the influx of new slaves and the presence of slaves
whose ethnic origins limited their chances of integration, created a dispossessed
and potentially disaffected group. Discontented slaves occasionally rose against
their masters: one of the earliest known slave revolts in West Africa occurred in
1591, when the ruler of Songhai’s slaves asserted themselves after their owner
and his troops had been defeated by the Moroccan army. On the other hand,
there was a trend towards assimilating slaves into society by offering them cer-
tain rights in return for loyalty. The Hausa (in northern Nigeria) distinguished
between the bayi, who had been captured or bought, and who had few rights,
and the cucenawa, who, as second generation slaves, occupied a position that was
closer to serfdom than to chattel slavery. In attempting to strike a balance
between total exploitation and an entirely free community of farmers, employers
were expressing their appreciation of the need to develop a subtle form of
dependent labour, one which was more profitable than hired labour, yet which
was also capable of fulfilling extra-economic functions.
The foregoing assessment of slavery points to amendments to three common
assumptions concerning the nature of pre-industrial societies. Contrary to the
belief of the substantivist school of anthropologists, there was a long-established
labour market in Africa. The fact that this market took the form of slave labour
rather than wage labour was the result of a deliberate choice based on an elem-
entary, but broadly accurate, cost–benefit analysis, that is to say on principles
which the substantivists regard as peripheral or non-existent in ‘traditional’ soci-
eties. To interpret slave-raiding as an expression of what Balandier has called
The domestic economy 71
2 Production
This section will begin to examine the productive activities which resulted from
the interaction of natural and human resources in the pre-colonial period. The
aim of the discussion is both descriptive and analytical. Description is needed
because general histories of West Africa scarcely mention domestic production,
55 Manning Nash, Primitive and Peasant Economic Systems, San Francisco, 1966, p. 35.
56 Manning Nash, ‘The Social Context of Economic Choice in a Small Society’, Man, 219, 1961,
p. 190.
57 E. F. Gauthier, L’Afrique noire occidentale, Paris, 1943, p. 171.
58 For a clear statement of economic and social inequalities at the beginning of the sixteenth century
see Walter Rodney, A History of the Upper Guinea Coast, 1545–1800, Oxford, 1970, pp. 34–8. The
system of pawning, by which debts were repaid by providing free labour for a specified period, is
one which needs further research.
72 The domestic economy
and deal only with trade, especially foreign trade. Analysis is required to relate the
information presented here to the myths (outlined at the beginning of the chapter)
of a static, inflexible, uniform and essentially simple, subsistence economy. It will be
argued that the indigenous economy experienced major historical changes; that it
was capable of accepting and initiating novel types of activity; that it exhibited
regional and occupational diversity; and that its organisation was complex. This ana-
lysis, it is suggested, points to the need to revise a number of standard explanations
of economic backwardness in ‘traditional’ societies.
Throughout their history, most West Africans have won their living from the
land. Agriculture was the chief activity in the greater part of the region, as it
was in other pre-industrial societies, and today foodstuffs still account for the
largest share of the value of the goods and services produced each year by West
African countries. Moreover, agriculture remains, as in the past, the ‘matrix in
which all other indigenous economic activity is set’.59 It is not, and it was not,
necessary to give up farming in order to enter occupations such as craft manu-
facture and trade, which are frequently undertaken on a part-time or seasonal
basis. On the contrary, an agricultural surplus often made it possible to finance
additional types of productive enterprise.
For the past five centuries the staple foodstuffs have been grains, such as millet
(mainly sorghum and pennisetum), maize, rice and fonio (hungry rice), and roots,
chiefly yams, cocoyams, cassava (also known as manioc) and plantains. These crops
are grown in association with a variety of legumes, bulbs and fruit. Cereals tend to
predominate in the savanna, and roots in a large part of the forest, a division which
reflects the physical requirements of the crops and the geographical differences
between the two regions. Rainfall is particularly important in this context. In the
savanna, rainfall is sparse and falls in a period of three to five months, which explains
why the main crops are annuals, such as cereals. In the forest, rainfall is greater and
spreads over about seven months of the year, which means that perennials, such as
tree crops and a number of roots, can be grown. These generalisations require quali-
fication. There is a considerable overlap between these regions, where combinations
of cereals and roots are grown. Additionally, there are local variations within the
two major regions themselves, the most important being in the forest, where there
is a distinction between the predominantly rice-growing area in the west, and the
predominantly yam-dominant area in the east, the dividing line being the Bandama
River in what is now the Ivory Coast. The reasons for this distinction are not fully
understood. It may have a physical basis, the soils and lower rainfall of the eastern
region being better suited, perhaps, to yams than to rice, and it may be the result of
cultural differences between the peoples of the forest.60 If the latter interpretation is
59 Polly Hill, ‘Some Characteristics of Indigenous West African Economic Enterprise’, Economic Bul-
letin of Ghana, 6, 1962, pp. 3–14.
60 This suggestion has been made by J. Miège, ‘Les cultures vivrières en Afrique occidentale’, Cahiers
d’Outre-Mer, 7, 1954, pp. 25–50.
The domestic economy 73
correct, then the distinction between the western and eastern parts of the forest can
be said to represent a striking example of the variable nature of human reactions to
broadly similar environmental conditions.
Agriculture is such a pervasive and long-established activity in West Africa
that it is easy for economists, and even historians, to take its existence for
granted. Yet the domestication of plants and animals, the Neolithic Revolution
which Gordon Childe did so much to elucidate,61 was one of the great events
in world history, and one of the outstanding achievements of the indigenous
inhabitants of Africa. Agriculture provided more assured supplies of food; it
made possible the creation (and appropriation) of a surplus; it stimulated
a degree of urbanisation and specialisation; and it permitted an increase in popu-
lation, since the maximum size no longer depended on the numbers that could
be supported at the leanest time of the year by hunting and gathering.
The origins of the food-producing revolution in West Africa have been the sub-
ject of considerable controversy among specialists.62 The established view of the
majority of archaeologists, headed by Clark, is that agriculture began in the savanna
around 2000 B.C., following the diffusion of ideas and plants from Egypt. However,
objections to this interpretation have been raised from several quarters during the
last 10 or 15 years. Murdock, an ethnographer, has argued that agriculture began
independently in West Africa about 5000 B.C. Portères, a botanist, has also suggested
that West African agriculture was an independent development, but considers that
it originated between 2800 and 1500 B.C. Wrigley, a historian, has advanced a case
to show that certain kinds of agricultural practices originated in West Africa, and
that the forest may have been an independent centre of origin. These arguments,
though often speculative with regard to dates and evidence, have brought to the
fore hypotheses which are beginning to receive serious attention. The diffusionist
theory, once unquestioned, is no longer stated with confidence, and the latest arch-
aeological research has tended to stress both the antiquity and the variety of prehis-
toric agriculture in West Africa.63
If, as seems likely, new archaeological discoveries are made in the near future,
current views will almost certainly need radical revision. At the moment, and
for present purposes, it can be said that West African agriculture, besides being
of prehistoric origin, did not lag far behind primary centres of origin, such as
the Near East; that at this early date the main staples were millet, rice and fonio
in the savanna, and yams and the oil palm in the forest; that while external con-
tacts were of great importance there is evidence to suggest that there was an
indigenous, West African Neolithic agriculture; and that the assumption that
agriculture developed earlier in the savanna than in the forest must be regarded
as dubious.
The development of agriculture was not a sudden event, nor did it place such
demands on the allegedly limited capacities of the indigenous people as to cause
them to drift through subsequent centuries in a state of lassitude, bereft of initia-
tive and ripe for colonial rule. Connections with other parts of the world
remained strong, and the flow of plants and seeds continued. Asian yams, coco-
yams, bananas and plantains reached West Africa by way of the Near East
between the first and the eighth centuries A.D. By the time the first written
records become available, it is clear that agriculture was well established
throughout West Africa. In the tenth century al-Muhallabi, writing of the King-
dom of Kanem (north-east of Lake Chad) reported that
the length of their land is a fifteen days’ journey through habitations and
cultivations all the way … Millet chiefly is cultivated in the land, and
beans, also wheat. Most of the ordinary people … spend their time culti-
vating and looking after their cattle.64
64 Quoted in Roland Oliver and J. D. Fage, A Short History of Africa, Harmondsworth, 1962, p. 47.
65 Quoted in Basil Davidson, The African Past, Harmondsworth, 1966, p. 205.
The domestic economy 75
The effect which these crops had on the local economy, though more
important than the precise timing of their arrival, has yet to attract serious his-
torical attention. The spread of Asian and American crops was undoubtedly
a lengthy process, and is still going on today, but the slow pace of change
should not be taken as evidence that indigenous farmers were unreceptive to
new opportunities. It took time for knowledge of foreign seeds and plants to
spread throughout the region as a whole. New crops were tried out cautiously
because no community was going to place its established food supplies at risk
through the hasty adoption of untested novelties. Moreover, the rate of diffusion
was sometimes inhibited by technical problems. Cassava, for example, though
introduced in the sixteenth century, did not begin to spread rapidly until the
close of the eighteenth century, when it became known how to process the
crop in such a way as to remove the prussic acid which some varieties con-
tained. Finally, the speed of adoption was related to the growth of demand for
foodstuffs. In the twentieth century, for instance, the rise of a wage labour force
and the development of specialised export producers encouraged farmers in cer-
tain areas to concentrate on producing food for the internal market.
Where new plants and seeds were adopted, it was not because they caught
the fancy of a primitive people, but because they were seen as useful additions
to the existing range of foods, being worth more than the extra cost of produ-
cing them; or alternatively because they were regarded as good substitutes, yield-
ing a higher return for the same input than the crops they displaced. Thus,
maize has spread in areas formerly dominated by yams and sorghum because it
gives two crops a year, both of which have fairly good yields, while cassava has
become common in yam-producing regions because it is easy to grow and pro-
duces food throughout the year. Yams are still the preferred food and they have
greater nutritional value, but they make heavy demands on the soil and they
need a great deal more labour. The host communities also showed themselves
willing and able to adapt existing forms of agricultural organisation where neces-
sary. Three types of alteration were called for. The length of time particular
plots were farmed often had to be increased in order to accommodate a greater
number of new crops. New techniques of cultivation had to be adopted on
occasion. For instance, the spread of swamp rice in Sierra Leone during the
nineteenth century was associated with a new method of transplanting the seed-
lings from nursery beds to underwater fields.66 Finally, a certain amount of
occupational change was required. The spread of cassava among the Yoruba, for
example, meant that women became more involved in agricultural production,
for they were allocated the task of processing the crop.
The foregoing analysis suggests the following conclusions. Agricultural history
in the pre-colonial period is a story of innovation rather than stagnation. The
66 This technique is thought to have originated in Casamance, on the southern coast of present-day
Senegal.
76 The domestic economy
assumption that the economy was static, having been frozen at the very dawn of
African history, is untenable, and the timeless concept of the ‘traditional’ society
needs to be used with care, or, better still, not used at all. Although contact
with other continents led to the introduction of some troublesome weeds, such
as spear grass, there is no doubt that on balance the import of seeds and plants
was of great benefit to West Africa. The new crops offered the means of
improving nutrition, they reduced the risk of famine and they made it possible
to support a larger population.67 A study of pre-colonial history offers a new
perspective on the rapid and well-publicised expansion of export-crop produc-
tion in the twentieth century. Export growth should be seen not as the miracu-
lous reaction of a backward people to wholly novel external demands, but as
one further development in a long history of agricultural experiment and
adaptation.
To demonstrate that African farmers were flexible in their attitude towards
the adoption of new crops is certainly a step forward. Nevertheless, it could still
be argued that the indigenous system of cultivation was primitive, that technol-
ogy remained crude, that the rules governing land tenure shackled enterprise,
and that for these reasons agriculture was stuck virtually at subsistence level. An
examination of these beliefs, which have been nourished by repetition in text-
books of economic development, will show that they rest on evidence which is
either incomplete or misinterpreted.
Colonial officials formed a generally unfavourable impression of the capabil-
ities of African farmers. They looked at unoccupied land and thought that it
was unused or spare territory, which Africans, through lack of skill or initia-
tive, were incapable of developing. They noted the absence, especially in the
forest, of the neat, hedged fields which were so familiar to them at home and
concluded that the standard of farm management was poor. They pointed to
the lack of the plough and decided that local farmers were uninventive. These
observations, recorded in reports over many years, influenced policies during
the colonial era, and can still be found in some secondary works today. How-
ever, an account of traditional farming which is confined to shifting cultivation
and to allegedly wasteful slash and burn techniques, though it accords well
with Trevor-Roper’s notion of African history as the story of the ‘unrewarding
gyrations of barbarous tribes’,68 scarcely does justice to the complex reality
revealed by geographical research. Indeed, according to Morgan and Pugh’s
authoritative work, no less than seven headings are needed to classify the lead-
ing systems of cultivation practised in West Africa.69 These are: shifting culti-
vation; rotational bush fallow; rotational planted fallow; mixed farming;
67 Other continents gained in similar ways. Another South American export, the potato, became
a staple food in Europe in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries.
68 Hugh Trevor-Roper, The Rise of Christian Europe, 1965, p. 9.
69 W. B. Morgan and J. C. Pugh, West Africa, p. 100.
The domestic economy 77
permanent cultivation; tree cultivation; and floodland and irrigated farming. All
seven systems were in use by about the sixteenth century and were almost cer-
tainly present long before then.
Shifting cultivation involves the periodic movement of settlement. Virgin
land, or land having abundant secondary vegetation, is cleared with the aid of
fire, and the resulting irregular, tree-studded plots are cropped for one or two
years before being abandoned, as the community moves on to new land else-
where. Shifting cultivation may well have been the principal system of agricul-
ture in West Africa during prehistoric times, but today (and contrary to
a common assumption) it is dominant in only a few areas. The chief method of
cultivation in recent centuries has been rotational bush fallow, which is wide-
spread in savanna and forest, and is used for growing both cereals and roots. In
this system settlement is fixed, and the land under cultivation rotates over
a defined area of fallow grasses or woody plants, though the woodland itself is
not allowed to regenerate. Cleared land is usually cropped for between three
and six years (though in the rice-growing forest lands of the west one or two
years is the norm), and the period of fallow ranges from four to ten years. The
relatively long cropping period entails careful farm management and the use of
annual rotations, crop mixtures and successions.70 Rotational planted fallow is
a distinct, but comparatively unimportant, system, which differs from rotational
bush fallow in that the fallow cover is selected and deliberately planted. Mixed
farming involves a combination of cultivation and animal husbandry. Only a few
communities, such as the Serer of Senegal, employ mixed farming as their prin-
cipal system of production, though other groups, such as the Fulani, may keep
cattle and cultivate the land without fully integrating the two activities. Where
permanent cultivation is practised, the same land is farmed annually and is rarely
allowed to revert to fallow. Few communities rely on permanent cultivation for
the greater part of their supplies of food, but most have some small plots near
the village or compound, which are kept under crops continuously.71 Tree cul-
tivation, like permanent cultivation, is found in conjunction with other systems,
especially rotational bush fallow. The most important tree crops in the pre-
colonial period were the oil palm, the kola tree and the shea tree, all of which
are indigenous to West Africa. Floodland and irrigated cultivation is found in
restricted areas, such as the south-west coast, where swamp rice is grown, and
70 Rotations make certain that demands on the soil are varied from year to year; mixtures, that is
growing several crops on the same plot and in the same season, ensure a high density of plants and
economy of weeding; and successions, that is planting crops one after another during the same
season, spread labour requirements and provide a more even flow of foodstuffs by staggering the
harvests.
71 For a study of the ways in which communities combine various systems of land use, including per-
manent agriculture, see W. B. Morgan, ‘The Zoning of Land Use around Rural Settlements in
Tropical Africa’, in Environment and Land Use in Africa, ed. M. F. Thomas and G. W. Whittington,
London, 1969, pp. 301–19.
12°W 12°E
16°N
ROTATIONAL
BUSH FALLOW
Bulrush Millet Dominant
Northern Cereals Shifting Cultivation 4°N
Guinea Corn Dominant
Upland Rice Dominant Grass Fallows “Mixed Farming”
Cereals Dominant Permanent Cultivation
Mixed Cereals and Roots
Roots Dominant Floodland Cultivation
Pastoralism including Oasis and Sahel Fringe
Cultivation
Roots Dominant Woody 0 800 kilometres
Plantain and Cocoyam Dominant Fallows 0 500 statute miles
on the flood-plains of the Niger and Senegal rivers, where millet, maize and
rice are cultivated.
The question now arises as to whether there is any unifying principle linking
these different methods of agriculture. Gourou’s contention that the system of
land use is determined chiefly by soils and climate is unsatisfactory because rota-
tional bush fallow, the dominant system in West Africa, is practised over a wide
range of geographical conditions, while shifting cultivation was used in parts of
Europe, a temperate zone, as late as the nineteenth century.72 Boserup’s stimu-
lating argument that systems of cultivation are determined basically by popula-
tion density also needs qualification, for different systems can be found in parts
of West Africa which do not show marked demographic variations.73 It is sug-
gested here that land use is best understood in terms of a continuum ranging
from virgin land to permanent cultivation, and containing a number of subdivi-
sions at intervening points, these being decided by the length of the fallow
period. Rotational bush fallow occupies one of these intermediate spaces. The
length of the fallow period represents an adjustment to some or all of the fol-
lowing variables: population density; the availability of fertiliser; and the range of
crops. The concept of a continuum of land use is best illustrated by the two
extremes of shifting cultivation and permanent cultivation.
Shifting cultivation and other forms of extensive agriculture were found
where some or all of the following conditions prevailed: a low population dens-
ity; a shortage of fertiliser; and an insufficient variety of crops. Where population
was sparse and land abundant, farmers realised that it was important to maximise
output per person rather than output per acre. European observers, obsessed by
the notion (derived from their own experience) that output per acre was
a priority of universal applicability, failed to grasp the principles underlying shift-
ing cultivation. Yet clearing the land by burning the undergrowth was the
quickest and cheapest method in terms of labour costs and had the added advan-
tage of returning mineral matter to the soil rapidly. Output per man hour under
this system was extremely high, which partly explains its tenacity in the face of
alternative methods which, though technically superior, increased overall costs
and reduced net returns to the farmer. Where there was a shortage of manure,
a long period of fallow was needed to restore nutrients to the soil. This defi-
ciency was common in various parts of West Africa, but was particularly marked
in the forest, where disease and the difficulty of maintaining pasture severely
restricted animal husbandry. Where there was a lack of variety in the crops
available, the number of rotations was limited, the soil soon became exhausted,
and farmers were forced to move on to new land. European commentators
were scandalised by this ‘wasteful’ means of cultivation because they failed to
appreciate that unused land was an integral part of a method of cultivation
which involved the maintenance of long fallows, and that to use it for another
purpose (such as European plantations) was to risk dislocating the indigenous
system of production.
Permanent cultivation, at the other end of the continuum, was found chiefly
in areas where population was relatively dense, where there was a regular supply
of fertiliser and where a considerable variety of crops was available. This system
was geared to achieving high returns per acre rather than (or as well as) per
man hour, and it demonstrates the ability of African farmers to adjust factor pro-
portions in order to achieve optimum results with the resources at their disposal.
Animal manure and household refuse were used as fertilisers, and crop mixtures,
rotations and successions were employed to ensure that as much use as possible
was made of cleared land. Intensive agriculture was not an important mode of
production in what, in terms of economic and political development, are usually
regarded as the most advanced areas of West Africa. On the contrary, it was
dominant among some of the most underprivileged and least powerful of West
African peoples. For example, the inhabitants of the Mandara uplands (on the
border between Nigeria and the Cameroons) developed a system of intensive
agriculture which included soil conservation, the use of fertilisers, crop rotations,
the planting and protection of trees and animal husbandry. A British official,
who was sent to inspect the area in 1939 with a view to improving its agricul-
ture, reported that the methods in use already included ‘practically every prin-
ciple that Agricultural Departments throughout Africa are trying to instil into
the “backward” peoples’.74 What is particularly interesting about this case is that
permanent agriculture was not a result of favourable soils or climate in the
microenvironment, but was the outcome of political pressures, for the dense
settlement and the relative immobility of the inhabitants were brought about
originally by a desire to escape the predatory attentions of more powerful slave-
raiding neighbours.
Historians and economists are inclined to rank agricultural systems in linear
progression from ‘backward’ to ‘advanced’. However, the idea of an agricultural
league table can be very misleading. Different systems of cultivation, including
those commonly regarded as advanced, co-existed in pre-colonial West Africa,
as they did in pre-industrial Europe. None was anachronistic, for each was
subtly adapted to particular circumstances. Furthermore, to equate permanent
agriculture with market activity, and shifting cultivation with subsistence farm-
ing, is tempting, but mistaken. The methods varied, but the economic goals of
both systems were often the same.
It is hoped that enough has been said to indicate that Africans were expert
farm managers. Nevertheless, it could still be argued that agriculture remained
stuck in a subsistence groove because indigenous farmers failed to invent or
74 Stanhope White, ‘The Agricultural Economy of the Hill Pagans of Dikwa Emirate, Cameroons
(British Mandate)’, Empire Journal of Experimental Agriculture, 9, 1941, pp. 66–7.
The domestic economy 81
75 Lynn White, Medieval Technology and Social Change, Oxford, 1962, pp. 39–57.
76 Jack Goody, Technology, Tradition, and the State in Africa, London, 1971, pp. 25 and 76.
77 Boserup, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth, pp. 32–4.
78 Peter M. Weil, ‘The Introduction of the Ox Plow in Central Gambia’, in African Food Production
Systems, ed. Peter F. M. McLoughlin, Baltimore, 1970, pp. 251–2.
82 The domestic economy
Farmers’ incomes need to rise some way above the level needed for subsistence
before they can afford to adopt new techniques, such as the plough. Even so, a more
advanced technology will be used only if it is more profitable than existing methods
of production, or if it is essential to ensure survival. Neither of these conditions
appears to have applied to pre-colonial West Africa, which, like India, developed
a relatively simple technology, but one that was well suited to its requirements.79 If
ploughs had been available in West Africa in the pre-colonial era, they would have
been treated as conversation pieces rather than as agricultural implements. Indeed,
that is just what many of them became during the colonial era, when officials tried to
convert Africans to the use of technically superior, but economically unrewarding,
farm implements. It is as well to remember that virtually the whole of the massive
expansion of domestic foodstuffs and export crops which occurred during the twenti-
eth century was produced with the aid of traditional tools. To suppose that the failure
to adopt a more complex agricultural technology was a cause of underdevelopment
in Africa is to put plough before ox, and invention before need.
It remains to see whether or not the system of land tenure which prevailed in the
pre-colonial period inhibited the development of natural resources. According to
Pedler, ‘land, an essential factor of production, has been prevented by custom and
law from coming under the influence of economic forces’;80 and it is still common,
especially in non-specialist works, to find indigenous land law summarised simply as
‘communal’ ownership, measured against the presumed advantages of individual
tenure and finally condemned as a primitive obstruction to economic development.
A full review of African land laws is impossible here, but some general observations,
based on recent research, need to be made in order to correct a few of the more
widespread and mistaken assumptions.81
The conventional dichotomy between backward, communal ownership and
advanced, individual tenure is very misleading. African land laws, no less than indigen-
ous systems of cultivation, varied greatly even within restricted areas and ranged from
land that was indeed communally owned and worked, to land that was held virtually
as freehold.82 Households frequently made use of common land and individual
79 For a comparative analysis on similar lines, see Irfan Habib, ‘Potentialities of Capitalistic Develop-
ment in the Economy of Mughal India’, Journal of Economic History, 29, 1969, pp. 62–4. Lack of
space has confined this discussion to the case of the plough. However, the argument developed
here could also be used to explain the relative unimportance of irrigated agriculture in West Africa.
Geographical considerations aside, irrigated agriculture will not be widespread in areas where
extensive agriculture is possible because of its high capital and maintenance costs. The wells and
irrigated works found in parts of the Sahara and savanna were operated by slave labour. When slav-
ery declined in the twentieth century, so, too, did the wells and oases because of the high cost of
employing wage labour.
80 F. J. Pedler, Economic Geography of West Africa, 1955, p. 215.
81 Readers who wish to consider this subject further should begin by looking at the excellent collec-
tion of papers in African Agrarian Systems, ed. Daniel Biebuyck, London, 1963.
82 For two of many cases where individual tenure was common, see Ronald Cohen, ‘From Empire to
Colony: Bornu in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries’, in Colonialism in Africa, 1870–1960,
3, ed. Victor Turner, Cambridge, 1971, p. 100, and Olga Linares de Sapir, ‘Agriculture and Diola
The domestic economy 83
Society’, in African Food Production Systems, ed. Peter F. M. McLoughlin, Baltimore, 1970, pp.
207–8.
83 Youssouf Guèye, ‘Essai sur les causes et les conséquences de la micropropriété au Fouta-Toro’, Bul-
letin de l’IFAN, B, 19, 1957, pp. 28–42.
84 It would be interesting to know whether there was a connection between these migrants and the
development of groundnut farming in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. For a comparative
study of the relationship between dispossessed heirs, migration and innovation (among the Basques)
see Leonard Kasdan, ‘Family Structure, Migration and the Entrepreneur’, Comparative Studies in
Society and History, 7, 1965, pp. 345–57.
84 The domestic economy
85 The role of camels, horses, oxen and donkeys will be considered in Section 3 of this chapter.
86 Tadeusz Lewicki, ‘Animal Husbandry among Medieval Agricultural People of Western and Middle
Sudan’, Acta Ethnographica, 14, 1965, pp. 165–78.
16°N 16°N
no
data
12°W 12°E
values. These beliefs, which themselves rank high among the ‘sacred cows’ of
development theory, need revision.
Migration was a well-ordered and necessary feature of animal husbandry in
West Africa. The movements of pastoralists, far from being aimless, are divisible
into analytically distinct categories: transhumance, which involved a regular,
annual trek from the Saharan margins down to the savanna and back again;
migratory drift, which involved a shift in the orbit of transhumance; and full
migration, which entailed a transfer to a completely new area and the creation
of a fresh orbit of transhumance.87 The nature and extent of pastoral migration
are explicable in terms of a combination of three factors. First, the size of the
herd owned by a particular community had an important influence on the
amount of land required. An increase in numbers, through breeding or purchase,
meant that more land was needed. A decrease, through disease or sale, had the
opposite effect. Loss of cattle was a disaster for the herdsman, as loss of crops
was for the farmer. The threat of disaster explains why the annual trek into the
savanna was reversed when the onset of the rainy season spread fly-borne
diseases. Second, the extensive character of animal husbandry was partly
a reflection of the natural distribution of essential foodstuffs. Water and salt were
scarce, and pasture tended to be poor and sparse. Hence the herdsmen moved
down into the savanna during the dry season in search of better grazing land.
Third, migration was undertaken for purposes of trade. Pastoralists and cultiva-
tors in West Africa, as in other parts of the world, developed a symbiotic rela-
tionship. Each needed the products of the other, and one of the main purposes
of transhumance was to exchange animal products for grain. Yet farmers feared
the destructive effects of livestock on their crops, and conflicts between the two
parties sometimes led to a shift in the orbit of transhumance, or to migration to
an entirely new area. In this way pastoralists became colonists too. Successive
changes in the pattern of their migratory movements created new economic and
sometimes political frontiers, as in the case of the Fulani, who spread across the
Western Sudan between the eleventh and seventeenth centuries.
Livestock were kept for their meat, milk, manure, hides and, in the case of
sheep, for their wool. The belief that Africans refused to sell their cattle rests on
a misunderstanding of the way in which the pastoral economy operated. It is
clear from numerous sources that the cattle trade long antedates the coming of
the Europeans in the fifteenth century and was certainly not a result of the pre-
sumed disintegration of ‘tribal’ values in the twentieth century. Admittedly, only
a small proportion of the herd was sold, but this was not because of limitations
imposed by a pre-capitalist value system. Cattle in pastoral societies were not
simply a consumption good, but were also its main stock of capital. Returns on
capital took the form of sales of milk and manure to farming communities. It is
not surprising that the herdsman took care to conserve his capital, for cattle
were a long-term investment, and one which could easily be lost through dis-
ease, as happened for instance in the late nineteenth century, when rinderpest
decimated herds in many parts of the continent. Cattle were indeed highly
prized, but their function as a status symbol derived from society’s appreciation
of their economic worth. The man who possessed a large number of cattle was
respected not for his unthinking devotion to ascribed values, but for his skill in
controlling a major resource.88
The concept of a Neolithic Revolution is useful for focusing attention on
developments which are of fundamental importance in world history, but the
term ‘revolution’ can be misleading if it is interpreted to mean that previous
ways of securing a livelihood, notably by gathering, hunting and fishing, speedily
became redundant. All three means of subsistence survived and were adapted to
the new, agricultural economy. Gathering was the least specialised and most
widespread of these activities. However, it would be wrong to envisage
a situation where, as one nineteenth-century explorer put it, the ‘fruits of the
earth grow spontaneously, or with little cultivation; so that wherever rivers run,
the land may be truly said to overflow with milk and honey’.89 Equally, it
might truly be said that wherever rivers ran there was a danger of water-borne
diseases and of serious flooding during the rainy season. The stereotype of the
contented tropical dweller gathering his daily breadfruit and then relapsing into
a state of chronic lethargy until roused by a passing foreign explorer (or now-
adays by a television crew) has no basis in fact and should be banished from
book and screen alike. Collecting wild grains, roots and fruit was usually no
more than an occasional supplement to agriculture. Where gathering was
important to the local economy, as in parts of the savanna during the dry
season, it was an indication not of luxury but of hardship—the inhabitants being
driven by necessity to seek additional food supplies.90
Hunting and fishing were more specialised activities than gathering because
they required a greater degree of skill. Hunting was especially important in the
forest, where there was a shortage of meat, and it reached a seasonal peak during
the dry season, when the demand for farm labour was at its lowest, and when
restricted water supplies made it easier to locate game. Little is known about the
historical development of hunting in West Africa. There are examples of
88 For a similar viewpoint on East Africa see the valuable essay by Harold K. Schneider, ‘Economics
in East African Aboriginal Societies’, in Economic Transition in Africa, ed. Melville J. Herskovits and
Mitchell Harwitz, 1964, pp. 53–75. It is hoped that these comments will lead to further study of
the economic history of animal husbandry (including goats and sheep, as well as cattle) in the pre-
colonial period.
89 John Whitford, Trading Life in Western and Central Africa, Liverpool, 1877, p. 334.
90 This is still true today. See Edmond Bernus, ‘Cueillette et exploitation des resources spontanées du
Sahel nigérien par les Kel Tamasheq’, Cahiers ORSTOM, 4, 1967, pp. 31–52.
88 The domestic economy
91 And to produce ivory for export as well as meat for domestic consumption.
The domestic economy 89
occupations, and the volume and character of demand for manufactured goods.
Furthermore, indigenous manufactures are worth considering in the context of cur-
rent industrialisation policies. Modern manufacturing in West Africa began not with
heavy industries, but with relatively simple import-substituting activities, some of
which can be based (with suitable modifications) on established crafts.92
Iron, gold and salt were the most important minerals produced in pre-
colonial West Africa, though copper, tin and silver were also mined in small
quantities.93 The region has few deposits of coal, and the principal domestic and
industrial fuels were wood and charcoal.
Knowledge of iron working reached West Africa during the first millennium.
Iron was being smelted at Nok, in what is now northern Nigeria, around 500 B.C.,
and iron-producing techniques had spread throughout the region by about the
fourth century A.D. Iron implements, chiefly hoes, knives, spearheads and swords,
marked a great advance on stone and wooden tools: they improved the efficiency of
hunters; they made it easier to clear the forest; and they placed more power in the
hands of the builders (and destroyers) of towns and states. Relatively accessible
deposits of iron ore were distributed fairly widely in West Africa, though mostly on
a small scale. However, there were a few large centres, such as Oumé in the south-
ern Ivory Coast, where the remains of 100 furnaces and about 10,000 tons of slag
were discovered in the 1920s, and also around Oyo in south-west Nigeria, where
a complex of highly specialised mining villages flourished during the pre-colonial
period. In 1904 one of these settlements had a population of between 100 and 120,
all of whom (including women and children) were engaged in the various stages of
iron mining and manufacturing. The output of this settlement supplied an area
which covered several hundred square miles. It is no coincidence that these large
centres were located in well-wooded regions, for the greater part of total produc-
tion costs was accounted for by timber, which was needed to make charcoal.
Pig iron was produced by digging lumps of ironstone out of shallow pits and
quarries, and heating them with a flux in a clay furnace fired by charcoal. How-
ever, the methods in use were neither simple nor uniform. In the eighteenth
century the Mandingo used a circular kiln about 10 feet high and 3 feet in
diameter with seven vents at the base.94 The kiln was filled with alternate layers
of ironstone and charcoal and heated for three days. The contents were allowed
to cool and then reheated again until pig iron of an acceptable quality was pro-
duced. The miners near Oyo used a rather different method in the nineteenth
century.95 To begin with, they prepared the ironstone by heating it over an
92 Archibald Callaway, ‘From Traditional Crafts to Modern Industries’, Odu, 2, 1965, pp. 28–51.
93 For copper, see Lars Sundström, The Trade of Guinea, Lund, 1965, pp. 217–51; on tin, see
A. O. Anjorin, ‘Tin Mining in Northern Nigeria during the Nineteenth and Early Part of the
Twentieth Centuries’, Odu, 5, 1971, pp. 54–67.
94 Naval Intelligence Division, French West Africa, 1, 1943, pp. 236–7.
95 C. V. Bellamy, ‘A West African Smelting House’, Journal of the Iron and Steel Institute, 11, 1904, pp.
99–126.
90 The domestic economy
open fire. It was then pounded, washed and screened before being placed in the
kiln. In this case the kiln was about 4 feet high and 7 feet in diameter and had
six vertical vents. The kiln was charged for about 36 hours and fed with ore ten
times during this period. At least a dozen tools were used in the course of fill-
ing, regulating and emptying the kiln. The pig iron was allowed to cool, and
then sold to smiths, who puddled it and fashioned implements of various kinds.
An analysis of samples carried out in 1904 showed that producers had selected
the best possible flux, and that the finished product was puddled or forged steel,
and not simply wrought iron.
The smiths in Oyo had crude iron brought to them. Similarly, Bambara
smiths, who were settled among communities along the middle Niger, pur-
chased iron from traders. Sometimes, however, the smiths themselves travelled
to the mining centres, worked pig iron with portable tools and then returned
home to peddle their wares. The Awka and Nkwerri, for example, were itiner-
ant smiths who served between them virtually the whole of Ibo country. Future
research on pre-colonial mining operations will clarify the reasons underlying
these variations in production and distribution. Meanwhile, it seems clear that
‘primitive’ mineral production, no less than ‘primitive’ agriculture, was a more
complex and a more efficient undertaking than a superficial assessment of the
techniques employed would suggest.
Gold was mined in West Africa as early as the first millennium, but it was not
until about the eighth century A.D., with the development of commercial con-
tacts with the Arab world, that production underwent a marked expansion. The
greater part of total output was exported, though a proportion entered the
domestic economy in the shape of ornaments and as currency. Output is com-
monly assumed to have reached a peak in the late Middle Ages, when West
Africa became the principal source of supply for Western Europe. However, the
quantitative basis for this judgement is virtually non-existent,96 and it is interest-
ing to note that as late as 1937 there were still many thousands of independent
African producers, whose total output in French West Africa was estimated in
that year to be 3.5 tons. Gold was found in four main areas: around Bambouk,
Boure and Lobi in the Western Sudan, and in Ashanti in the forest. The chief
methods of production were panning alluvial streams, which was a simple,
though time-consuming, task, and quarrying gold-bearing ore, which was
a more complex operation. Akan miners in the eighteenth century dug slanting
pits with broad steps to a depth of as much as 150 feet. The miners at the
bottom dug out the ore and loaded it on trays, which were then passed up to
the surface by means of a human chain. At Bouré, by contrast, parallel vertical
shafts were sunk to a depth of about 40 feet and then joined underground by
a horizontal tunnel. The miners at the face used picks to dislodge the ore,
96 Manny’s oft-quoted estimate of total production (Tableau géographique, p. 301) is best treated with
caution.
15°W 10°W 5°W 0° 5°E 10°E 15°E 20°E
* Teghaza
* Idjil
* Taoudeni
20°N 20°N
*
* Awlil
R. * Bilma
Se
neg
15°N al 15°N
*
R.
N
Bambouk
ig
er
Boure
*
*
10°N Lobi 10°N
*
e
Jos nu
. Be
Ashanti R
* Salt
Gold *
Tin * * * 5°N
*
0 kilometres 1000
which was then put in a calabash and hauled to the surface. This system required
a considerable degree of specialisation and coordination within each unit of pro-
duction, and involved, typically, miners, carriers, washers, a smith to maintain
tools in good condition, and a foreman, who directed operations, sold the gold
to smiths and traders, and bought necessary supplies of foodstuffs. The ore
extracted by these means was either pounded, washed, screened and packaged in
the form of gold dust, or placed in a furnace and heated with a flux in order to
purify it, in which case the final product was made up into bars or wires.
Rulers who were fortunate enough to have gold deposits in their territories sought
either to control production or to tax the sales of independent producers. The extent
of the wealth which a privileged minority was able to acquire by these means is illus-
trated by the famous pilgrimage of Mansa Musa, the ruler of the Mali empire, who left
West Africa for Mecca in 1324. His splendid passage through Cairo had an unsettling
effect on exchange rates, as al-Omari noted: ‘the people of Cairo earned incalculable
sums from him whether by buying and selling or by gifts. So much gold was current
in Cairo that it ruined the value of money’.97 Such profligacy also nearly ruined
Mansa Musa, who experienced serious political troubles on his return to West Africa.
Salt was in many ways the most interesting and important of the minerals produced
in West Africa. Salt, like water, is a biological requirement of both humans and live-
stock, a regular intake being necessary for survival. Salt deprivation is a particularly
acute problem in hot areas, where salt resources are limited or far from the centres of
demand, where the consumption of meat or fish is generally low, and where the diet
is based largely on cereals. Much of West Africa, and especially parts of the Western
Sudan, fell into this category.98 In Gao, the capital of the Songhai, salt was so rare that
it was kept in the stores of the royal treasury in the tenth century. Security arrange-
ments are understandable because salt sometimes exchanged at par with gold on
a weight for weight basis. No wonder Arab travellers of the period remarked that to
avoid waste, rock salt was always licked and never ground and sprinkled!
Along the coast of West Africa salt was obtained by boiling sea water and
occasionally by natural evaporation. In the interior, however, salt was harder to
come by because the main sources lay far from the centres of demand. The
Western Sudan drew its supplies from five major deposits situated in, or close
to, the Sahara. At Awlil in the west and Bilma in the east, salt was obtained by
leaching saline soils. Production at Awlil, which was close to the sea, was
a seasonal and ancillary occupation of local fishermen. The resources at Bilma
were in the hands of the Tuareg, who controlled the oases of the area. In
the second half of the nineteenth century Bilma exported over 50,000 camel
loads of salt annually, and the trade continues today, though on a reduced scale.
Rock salt was obtained from Idjil, Teghaza and Taoudeni. The resources at
Idjil, seven layers deep, were developed between the eleventh and fifteenth
centuries. Teghaza, east of Idjil, was probably the leading source of supply from
the eighth century until its capture by the Moroccans in 1585. Taoudeni, about
100 miles to the south, began to expand after the decline of Teghaza, but may
not have been an adequate substitute, for the period following 1585 also saw an
increase in the production of an inferior type of vegetable salt in the area of the
middle Niger. Nevertheless, the biannual caravans which set out from Timbuctu
to Taoudeni in the late nineteenth century commonly had a combined total of
25,000 to 30,000 camels and carried about 4,000 to 5,000 tons of salt on the
return journey. Slaves were employed at Idjil, Teghaza and Taoudeni to cut and
load salt bars. The work was arduous and had to be performed in the most
gruelling conditions; it was so dry at Teghaza that even some of the buildings
were made of salt. Historians of Africa who are apt to praise great states and
famous men should remember that the glittering courts of Ghana, Mali and
Songhai were maintained at a considerable cost in human life.
Non-specialists may be surprised to learn that pre-colonial West Africa had
a range of manufacturing industries which closely resembled those of pre-
industrial societies in other parts of the world.99 The composition of the
manufacturing sector in West Africa, as in pre-industrial Europe, reflected the
embryonic nature of the market, and was based on clothing, metal working,
ceramics, construction and food processing.
The most important of these manufactures was clothing, which consisted
chiefly of cotton cloth, though silks, woollens and raffia cloth were produced in
some localities. Cotton, a long-established crop in West Africa, was manufac-
tured at a very early date, though it seems probable that the expansion of the
industry began with the spread of Islam from the eighth century onwards.
Muslim influence led to greater contact with the markets of the Arab world and
Europe, and also stimulated domestic demand by introducing new and more
exacting standards of dress. By the twelfth century cotton goods from the West-
ern Sudan had become well known in Europe, so much so that the terms bour-
acan or bougran, which were derived from Mandingo words, were being used
there to describe certain types of cloth.100 All stages of the manufacturing pro-
cess—ginning, carding, spinning, dyeing and weaving—were performed locally.
At the close of the sixteenth century the city of Timbuctu, on the southern
border of the Sahara, had 26 master tailors, many of whom employed between
50 and 100 apprentices and workers. By the middle of the nineteenth century
Kano (in what is now northern Nigeria) had become in influence, if not in
organisation, the Manchester of West Africa. The famous traveller, Barth, adver-
tised the town’s achievements in the following way:
99 See, for example, L. A. Clarkson, The Pre-industrial Economy in England, London, 1971, pp. 75–85.
100 F.-J. Nicolas, ‘Le bouracan ou bougran: tissu soudanais du moyen âge’, Anthropos, 53, 1958, pp.
265–8.
94 The domestic economy
Barth estimated that Kano’s cloth sales amounted to at least 300 million cowries
a year in the 1850s, which was equivalent to about 40,000 pounds sterling.
There were, in addition, many smaller centres besides Timbuctu and Kano, each
known for its speciality, which was based on producing cloth of a particular
weight, design and colour.102
Hides and skins, and the leather goods made from them, were produced
mostly in the Western Sudan, where the main centres of animal husbandry lay.
Many of these products were exported and became known in Europe as
‘Moroccan’ leather, though in fact a proportion of the goods passing under this
name originated in West Africa. Metal working, as noted earlier, was a long-
established craft, and blacksmiths were especially important. At the beginning of
the seventeenth century Jobson, an English traveller on the Gambian coast,
observed that the smith
makes their Swords, Assegay heads, Darts and Arrow heads barbed; and
instruments of Husbandry, without which they could not live. Hee hath
his Bellowes, small Anvill, and Cole of a red wood, which alone will give
the heat to our Iron.103
Pottery was also a widespread craft, and provided the majority of the containers
needed for liquids and foodstuffs. The elements of a construction industry
existed too. Most dwellings were probably built by the household concerned
with some assistance from neighbours and other kinsmen, but the erection and
maintenance of substantial dwellings in large towns created a demand for more
specialised groups of builders, plasterers and woodworkers. Finally, it is worth
noting that the processing of staple foods and drinks for sale outside the
101 H. Barth, Travels and Discoveries in North and Central Africa, centenary ed., 1, 1965, p. 511. Barth
was in Kano in 1851.
102 For a comprehensive list of centres of cloth production in West Africa, see Sundström, The Trade
of Guinea, pp. 147–86.
103 Quoted in Basil Davidson, The African Past, Harmondsworth, 1966, p. 204.
The domestic economy 95
104 For a detailed case study see P. C. Lloyd, ‘Craft Organisation in Yoruba Towns’, Africa, 23, 1953,
pp. 30–44.
105 Every generalisation has its exceptions, and it should be noted that there were specialised women
potters in some areas.
96 The domestic economy
industry provides a good example of the application of these two conditions. Concen-
trated employment was favoured by the presence of the two principal raw materials,
cotton and indigo, both of which were grown in the area, by proximity to a large
domestic market in and around Kano itself, and by the highly efficient distributive net-
work organised by Hausa traders, which secured access to markets in other parts of
West Africa. In these circumstances the Kano cloth industry could support a number
of specialised artisans and some sizeable units of production. Nevertheless, it would be
a mistake to contrast the organisation of the Kano textile industry too sharply with that
of smaller centres. Kano producers used the same narrow loom as was found in other
parts of West Africa, and most cloth workers were semi-specialists, who operated
independently or were coordinated in a putting-out and collection system. In the
absence of cost-reducing technical innovations, Kano’s prominence derived from the
external economies which it enjoyed, together with the product differentiation (based
on colour and pattern) which it achieved, rather than from genuine economies of
scale within the manufacturing firm itself.
106 Evidence representing a variety of disciplinary approaches is contained in Paul Bohannan and
George Dalton, eds., Markets in Africa, Evanston, 1962; Elliott P. Skinner, ‘West African Eco-
nomic Systems’, in Economic Transition in Africa, eds. Melville J. Herskovits and Mitchell Harwitz,
London, 1964b, pp. 77–97; Lars Sundström, The Trade of Guinea, Lund, 1965; Centre of African
Studies, Markets and Marketing in West Africa, University of Edinburgh, mimeo., 1966;
B. W. Hodder and U. I. Ukwu, Markets in West Africa, Ibadan, 1969; Marvin P. Miracle, ed.,
The domestic economy 97
plentiful, though a few estimates are available for the nineteenth century.107 In the
1850s Barth reckoned that the trade of Kano amounted to about £10,000 a year; at
the close of the nineteenth century the commerce of Timbuctu, then in decline, was
estimated to be worth roughly £80,000 a year; and in 1900 Baillaud published a map
showing some 50 towns (excluding those in Nigeria and the southern part of the
Gold Coast) which between them had an annual trade of £1 million. The majority of
households undoubtedly produced the greater part of the goods they required as con-
sumers, but the pure, subsistence economy was an exception rather than the rule.
Most households regarded trade as a normal and an integral part of their activities and
planned their production strategy accordingly. To grasp this point is also to reformu-
late the question of market growth in at least some underdeveloped societies. The
problem ceases to be one of introducing exchange to closed, self-sufficient communi-
ties, where wants are limited and commercial institutions non-existent, and becomes
the more realistic and interesting issue of identifying the constraints inhibiting the fur-
ther development of an already established exchange sector.
Social scientists have given considerable thought to the problem of under-
standing the internal trade of pre-colonial Africa. The most publicised analysis of
this subject is that proposed by Bohannan and Dalton, which is based on
a distinction between the market place and the market principle.108 Bohannan
and Dalton have advanced a three-fold classification: societies which lack mar-
kets and in which market principles are hardly present; societies which have
market places, but in which market principles operate peripherally; and societies
in which the market place has declined, but in which market principles have
become dominant. The first two categories are said to apply to Africa, while the
last is typical of industrial societies. Communities of the first two types can be
thought of as being multicentric, having distinct transactional spheres distin-
guished by different goods and services, and operating according to discrete
principles of exchange. In multicentric economies the laws of supply and
demand are less important in determining the terms of exchange than are prin-
ciples of reciprocity and redistribution. The aim of economic endeavour is to
‘convert’ goods from one sphere (such as subsistence) to another (such as pres-
tige) in order to achieve goals which are essentially social in character.
This is a subtle analysis, and it has stimulated, directly and indirectly, a great
deal of further research. However, Bohannan and Dalton’s classification will not
be used here for the following reasons (which, because of limitations of space,
will have to be stated briefly). The chief criticism is one, curiously, which has
not been stressed before, possibly because most commentators have been eco-
nomic anthropologists rather than historians. Although Bohannan and Dalton
‘Markets and Market Relationships’, African Urban Notes, 5, 1970, pp. 1–174; and Claude Meillas-
soux, ed., The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa, London, 1971.
107 I am grateful to Marion Johnson for the examples which follow.
108 ‘Introduction’, to Markets in Africa, eds. Paul Bohannan and George Dalton, Evanston, 1962, pp.
1–26.
98 The domestic economy
claim that their first two categories are applicable to ‘traditional’ societies in Africa,
neither author has made more than brief use of sources which historians would regard
as necessary to the analysis of the pre-colonial period. It so happens that during the
past ten years historical research has shown that both the market place and the market
principle were more important than Bohannan and Dalton allowed in their publica-
tion of 1962. Their claim that peripheral markets do not influence production deci-
sions is at variance with the evidence. The extent to which market activity failed to
mobilise the factors of production fully is better explained in terms of economics
(technological limitations and constraints on demand) than in terms of social con-
trols based on anti-capitalist values. Even if it is assumed that the market principle
was in some sense peripheral, this insight turns out to be less helpful than it appears
at first. The crucial problem is to find a way of measuring the degree of peripheral-
ity, but this, admittedly daunting, task is not one which Bohannan and Dalton have
attempted. Their case rests on the assumption that there is a sharp contrast in the
values governing multicentric and unicentric economies. However, this belief is
based on ideal types rather than realities. It is not values and goals which distinguish
pre-industrial from industrial societies so much as the structure of the two types of
economy, which provide different means of achieving what, in general terms, are
similar ends. Principles of reciprocity and redistribution undoubtedly operated to
some extent in Africa,109 but they can also be found in industrial societies both in
private and in public sectors. Moreover, industrial societies are concerned with
social as well as economic values. The American millionaire remains at his desk not
to make money, but to exercise power and to maintain his prominence in the com-
munity, or, in African parlance, to be regarded as a ‘big’ man. Similarly, a successful
English businessman may well put money into a football club instead of opening
a new factory. In short, all societies are to some extent multicentric, but until means
are devised of distinguishing differences of degree this observation is of limited use.
The classification adopted here is a simple one based on a distinction between
local and long-distance trade. Local trade refers to transactions which took place
within a radius of up to about 10 miles of the area of production. This was the
range which could be covered in one day by foot or by donkey, while still
allowing time to exchange products and return home. Beyond this radius it was
necessary to make arrangements for overnight stops, to reallocate work in the
household, and sometimes to make use of professional carriers and commercial
intermediaries. This distinction has been criticised, though mainly by those who
have been influenced in varying degrees by the substantivist viewpoint.110 How-
ever, it is worth pointing out, in anticipation of an additional objection, that
109 See, for example, Ronald Cohen, ‘Some Aspects of Institutionalized Exchange: A Kanuri
Example’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 5, 1965b, pp. 353–69.
110 Richard Gray and David Birmingham, ‘Some Economic and Social Consequences of Trade in
Central and Eastern Africa in the Pre-Colonial Period’, in Pre-Colonial African Trade: Essays on
Trade in Central and Eastern Africa Before 1900, eds. Richard Gray and David Birmingham,
London, 1970, pp. 2–5, and Claude Meillassoux, ‘Introduction’ to The Development of Indigenous
The domestic economy 99
Trade and Markets in West Africa, pp. 67–8. However, it should be noted that these authors also
qualify the argument advanced by Bohannan and Dalton.
111 B. W. Hodder, ‘Some Comments on the Origins of Traditional Markets in Africa South of the
Sahara’, Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 36, 1965, pp. 97–105.
112 Richard Gray and David Birmingham, eds., Pre-Colonial African Trade: Essays on Trade in Central
and Eastern Africa before 1900, London, 1970.
100 The domestic economy
was traded. This type of trade can be thought of as a system of compensation, equal-
ising losses experienced elsewhere. A surplus was planned, but trade was unpre-
meditated. This example has been cited to show that exchange potential was
present even where production levels were governed by the siege mentality associ-
ated with pure, subsistence economies. A more typical case was that of households
which regularly planned their production of foodstuffs and crafts with a certain
amount of exchange in mind. Trade of this kind was made possible by the presence
of complementary needs within regions which are sometimes regarded, wrongly, as
being uniform. Variations in natural resources did not have to be profound for local
trade to develop, though marketing activity was especially intense on the borders of
ecological zones. Usually, it was not a question of sharply contrasting specialisms,
but of a subtle shift of emphasis between adjacent areas with very similar economies.
For example, one village might grow foodstuffs of a different variety or better qual-
ity than the next, or produce a particular colour or design of cloth. Human
resources also lacked the homogeneity claimed in textbook generalisations about
‘traditional’ societies. The concept of the average household disguises the possibility,
discussed earlier in this chapter, that wealth could be distributed in an unbalanced
way even in a small community in an underdeveloped region. Inequalities meant
that some members of the community could afford to trade, while others needed to
secure goods which they had failed to produce for themselves.113
Most local exchange was conducted in the market place, though Muslim
women frequently traded within their compounds. A typical example of a local
market near the Senegal River was described by Cadamosto, a Venetian sailor,
in the fifteenth century:
Hither repaired, with their wares, both men and women, for four or five
miles about; and those who lived at a greater distance went to other markets
nearer them. The great poverty of this people appeared in the goods found in
these faires; which were, a few pieces of cotton-cloth, cotton-yarn, pulse, oil,
millet, wooden tubs, palm mats, and everything else for the use of life.114
Towns were capable of generating a greater and more varied demand for local
products. The expansion of the port of Lagos, for instance, set up demands
which stimulated production in the hinterland.115 This ‘spread effect’ is illus-
trated by the following list of African goods on sale in the nearby market of
Ejirin in September 1892:116
113 Polly Hill, ‘The Myth of the Amorphous Peasantry: A Northern Nigerian Case Study’, Nigerian
Journal of Economic and Social Studies, 10, 1968, pp. 239–60.
114 Thomas Astley, ed., A New General Collection of Voyages and Travels, London, 1745, p. 587.
115 This example may be compared with that of London at an earlier date. See F. J. Fisher, ‘The
Development of the London Food Market, 1540–1640’, Economic History Review, 5, 1935, pp.
46–64.
116 C.O. 147/86, Carter to Ripon, 4 Oct. 1892, Public Record Office.
The domestic economy 101
Of these 31 items, only two (palm oil and palm kernels) were important in
overseas trade.
Markets were not distributed at random, nor was the timing of market
days a matter of ‘custom and impulse’. Continuous markets, that is markets
which were in almost permanent session, were found mainly in large towns.
Elsewhere, markets were held at intervals of between two and eight days,
and occasionally longer.117 Today, seven-day markets are the most common
in West Africa as a whole, though four-day markets are more typical of the
forest east of Ghana. Periodic markets were usually formed into rings or
cycles, though the arrangement was by no means rigid and it also changed in
the course of time, as some markets fell into disuse and others were founded.
The frequency with which any one market was held depended on the
number of markets in a particular ring. For example, in a ring containing
just two markets, each met on alternate days, and a two-day market week
operated. The sequence of meetings was decided by the principle that ‘prox-
imity in space implies separation in time’.118 That is to say, two markets
which were part of a larger ring were unlikely to meet on consecutive days
if they were only a short distance apart, because to do so might lead to
needless duplication. Periodic markets were often held at places which were
convenient to several settlements, but which did not coincide with any one
117 On periodic markets, see Polly Hill, ‘Notes on Traditional Market Authority and Market Period-
icity in West Africa’, Journal of African History, 7, 1966a, pp. 295–311; B. W. Hodder, ‘Periodic
and Daily Markets in West Africa’, in The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West
Africa, pp. 347–58; and the comprehensive study by Robert H. T. Smith, ‘West African Market-
Places: Temporal Periodicity and Locational Spacing’, in ibid., pp. 319–46.
118 Vernon G. Fagerlund and Robert H. T. Smith, ‘A Preliminary Map of Market Periodicities in
Ghana’, Journal of Developing Areas, 4, 1970, p. 343.
102 The domestic economy
of them. It was possible for a local market to attract several thousand people
on the day it met, yet to be almost completely deserted during the rest of
the week.
Periodicity was primarily a function of the volume and spatial distribution of
purchasing power. Where effective demand was strong and concentrated in
a small area, such as an urban centre, continuous markets predominated. Where
demand was weaker and spread over dispersed settlements, periodic markets
were the rule. The formation of market rings provided each community in
a given area with easy and regular access to goods and services which it needed.
At the same time the device which ensured that each market met at a specified
interval kept the costs of collection and distribution to a minimum. Rotating
markets, like systems of shifting and rotational cultivation, were an expression of
the principle that the costs of permanence were not justified by the returns.
The traders involved in local exchange tended to be predominantly female, part
time, small scale, mobile and numerous. They were mainly female because local
trade was a convenient adjunct to household and, in some societies, farming activ-
ities; they were part time because trade was regarded as a supplement, though often
an important one, to primary, domestic occupations; they were small scale because
they lacked the capital to be anything else; they were mobile (except in the towns)
because the most efficient way of connecting buyers and sellers was by bringing
them together in periodic, rotating markets; and they were numerous because local
trade was a generally accessible way of adding to farm incomes, since it required
few managerial or technical skills and little capital.
It used to be thought that the employment of many hands increased distribu-
tion costs unnecessarily. During the colonial period expatriate officials and com-
panies often complained about the large number of local traders, believing, with
their Tudor predecessors, that ‘middlemen’ (by which they meant other middle-
men) were ‘Marchauntes of myschyefe that go betwixt the barke and the
tree’.119 However, it is now agreed that the distributive system was efficient,
even if it did employ a multiplicity of intermediaries. There was no cheaper way
of serving a market in which most consumers had low per capita incomes and
were scattered in dispersed settlements. Competition in local trade was fierce
because there were hardly any barriers to entry and few alternative employment
opportunities. Consequently, profit margins were slender. Of course, there were
some imperfections in the market, but these should be seen not as evidence of
the ‘primitive’ nature of pre-colonial exchange, but as a reminder that perfect
competition is an ideal which is rarely found in the real world, even in industrial
societies. A variety of traders’ organisations existed in West Africa, and these
tried to exert a measure of control over prices and competition.120 However,
the indications are that the prices of most goods in local markets were
119 R. H. Tawney and Eileen Power, eds. Tudor Economic Documents, 3, London, 1924, p. 49.
120 There is scope for further work on these organisations, especially those involving women traders.
The domestic economy 103
determined mainly by supply and demand, and that the haggling skills of the
parties concerned played an important part in deciding the exact price agreed in
any single transaction. Traders’ organisations had greater success in representing
the interests of their members in negotiations with state authorities, and in help-
ing to enforce regulations regarding weights and measures, and laws governing
debt, contract and agency.121 The indigenous distributive system was not made
redundant by the ‘impact of modern capitalism’. On the contrary, the skill, effi-
ciency and adaptability of local traders assisted the rapid expansion of internal
trade during the colonial era.122
The conditions which gave rise to local trade also set limits to its expansion.123
On the supply side, pre-industrial costs of production meant that there was no way
of reducing the selling prices of foodstuffs and crafts to the point where consumers
could have afforded significantly greater quantities without any change taking place
in average per capita incomes. It seems likely that a greater volume of goods could
have been produced at constant unit prices with the factors already available, but
constraints on the demand side meant that this happened only sporadically. The
‘primitive’ consumer was perfectly willing to depart from established consumption
levels but lacked the means of doing so. Variations in the resource base enabled
a certain amount of trade to take place, but limitations to complementarity in
a small area meant that it was usually possible for households to supply acceptable
substitutes for most of the goods offered for sale. In other words, the kinds of goods
which farmers were best able to produce and trade were already being produced
and traded equally cheaply by those who were their potential customers. Conse-
quently, the scope for exchange was limited and per capita incomes remained low.
If per capita incomes had risen markedly, the proportion of the increase spent on
foodstuffs would have declined, while that spent on manufactures, such as cloth,
would have grown. As this development did not occur, the effective demand for
craft products remained small. Consumers with net incomes above the average
were able to spend more on manufactures, but there were too few of them in any
one locality to induce producers to specialise and to introduce cost-reducing
techniques.
Long-distance trade can be regarded as an attempt by African entrepreneurs to
overcome the limitations of local commerce. Constraints still existed on the supply
side, because it was just as expensive to produce goods for long-distance trade as for
sale locally. On the demand side, however, long-distance trade presented an oppor-
tunity of connecting social islands of purchasing power, that is consumers who,
121 For a study of the most famous weights, see Brigitte Menzel, Goldweights from Ghana, Berlin,
1968. For information on indigenous commercial law in one area see A. G. Hopkins, ‘A Report
on the Yoruba, 1910’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 5, 1969, pp. 88–92.
122 As is shown in Chapter 7, Section 2.
123 With more space and more information, it would be possible to construct a detailed flow chart of
local goods and services along the lines developed by Frederick Barth, ‘Economic Spheres in
Darfur’, in Themes in Economic Anthropology, ed. Raymond Firth, London, 1967, pp. 149–74.
104 The domestic economy
though only a small proportion of the total population, had sufficient wealth
between them to support a market which was greater than that available to local
traders in any one area. The less-affluent majority participated in this commerce to
a certain extent by using profits accumulated from local trading activities to purchase
cheaper types of cloth and small quantities of essential items, such as salt. In general,
however, long-distance trade tended to cater for the needs of relatively high-
income groups because only prosperous consumers could afford to pay prices which
took account of the scarcity value of items that were unavailable locally, and the
greater handling costs and risks of carrying goods beyond the area of production.124
These principles help to explain the composition and organisation of long-distance
trade not only in Africa, but also in other parts of the world, as the examples of the
fur trade of pre-industrial Europe and the silk trade of the Far East clearly
demonstrate.125
A complex network of trade routes had to be created in order to reach these
geographically dispersed islands of relatively wealthy consumers. Some of the
most important long-distance routes were aligned on north–south axes, because
these crossed major geographical zones, which, as noted earlier, ran from west
to east in roughly parallel bands. Thus, the pastoralists of the Sahara-savanna
border traded livestock, dairy produce and salt with the cultivators of the
savanna in return for millet and cloth. In turn, the savanna region traded live-
stock, salt, dried fish, potash and cloth with the peoples of the forest, from
whom they received slaves, kola nuts,126 ivory, ironware and cloth. Finally, pro-
ducers in the forest sold various foodstuffs and manufactures to coastal settle-
ments in exchange for fish and sea salt. There were other routes, however,
which ran in a west–east direction, for complementary needs could arise quite
easily within regions as large as the savanna and the forest. Slaves, dried fish and
Kano cloth, for instance, were sold throughout the Western Sudan. There was
also some movement of foodstuffs outside the locality of production: the great
entrepôt of Timbuctu imported grain, vegetables and livestock from the twelfth
century onwards, and in the fifteenth century there was a considerable trade in
millet, rice, cotton and livestock within the empire of Mali. Similarly, slaves,
rare beads and Yoruba and Ashanti cloth were traded throughout the forest.
The foregoing list of commodities and inter-regional connections makes it
clear that simple, bilateral exchanges were the exception rather than the rule.
124 The assumption (criticised earlier in this chapter) that there were no marked inequalities of wealth
in pre-colonial African societies makes it extremely difficult to explain the existence and longevity
of long-distance trade.
125 See T. S. Willan, The Early History of the Russia Company, 1553–1603, London, 1956, and
C. G. F. Simkin, The Traditional Trade of Asia, London, 1968.
126 Kola nuts are a mild stimulant containing caffeine. They were (and still are) chewed to relieve
tiredness and to overcome thirst. The most popular variety was cola nitida, which was grown in
the forest from Guinea east to the Gold Coast. The main centres of demand lay in the Western
Sudan, a dry region, and also one in which Muslim influence prohibited the consumption of
alcohol.
The domestic economy 105
R.
Djenne Bandiagara
N
Bakel
ig
Bafoulabe
er
Bathurst Kita Segou San Sokoto
R. Gambia Say
Bamako Jegga Kano
Siguri Ouagadougou Yakoba
Labe
Bolamo Sikasso Bobo Zaria
Sansanne
Kankan Dioulasso Yola
Timbo Tengrela Mango
10°N
Gt. Scarcies R. Falaba Keruan Yendi Nikki Bida Kebbi
Kong
Mussardu Ilorin e
Salaga nu
Freetown Kani Ibadan . Be Mbum
Mango Bondoukou R
Sherbro I. Abeokuta Banyo
ATLANTIC OCEAN Monrovia Kumasi Tibati
Lome Lagos
5°N Grand Bassam Accra
Cape
Coast Bonny
BIGHT OF BENIN
0 kilometres 800
statute miles GULF OF GUINEA
0 500
MAP 6 Major trade routes of the Western Sudan in the nineteenth century
The domestic economy 107
operation, particularly since these farmer-traders had to leave their land during
the rainy season, a time of maximum inconvenience, and entrust the harvest to
relatives and slaves so that they could secure the highest price for their tobacco.
These examples demonstrate that production strategies were influenced by
market principles during the pre-colonial period.
Third, there were highly specialised and substantial professional traders. These
men had no direct control over the production of the goods they handled, but
they did establish a degree of horizontal integration with respect to particular
staples, partly by using kinsmen and slaves to staff a network of ‘branches’ along
the main trade routes. In the nineteenth century the merchants of Djenne,
a large town on the middle Niger, were said to have
organised ‘business firms’ in the European sense of the word, which were
provided with a routine and staff similar to our own. They established
representatives in important centres and opened branches at Timbuctu.
They sent out travelling agents who received percentages of the business
they accomplished, and were, in fact, none other than ‘commercial
travellers’.131
The leading professional, long-distance traders were the Dioula and the Hausa.
The former were of Mande origin and were especially important in the western
part of West Africa, though they traded south-east as far as the forests of the
Ivory Coast, selling livestock, fish and cloth, and buying kola nuts and slaves.
Hausa traders were dominant in the eastern part of West Africa, spreading out
from their base in northern Nigeria as far south-west as the Gold Coast, where
they exchanged salt, cloth and livestock for gold, kola nuts and slaves.132
Fourth, there were official traders, who transacted business on behalf of the
state. Given that the need for revenue was a common preoccupation of all gov-
ernments, it is not surprising that some states tried to raise money by participat-
ing in long-distance trade. In Ashanti official trade was conducted by
functionaries such as the batafo; in Dahomey royal rights over trade were dele-
gated to a group of quasi-official merchants in return for a share of the profits; and
in the Mossi states large caravans were organised by senior officials. In their com-
mercial dealings, these states can be thought of as substantial firms. Public enterprise
had access to the capital needed for long-distance trade, and it was also in a position
to secure privileges which, in theory at least, gave official traders a competitive
advantage over private merchants. State enterprise was sometimes responsible for
major commercial innovations, as, for example, in the case of the Ashanti
government, which played a leading part in the development of the kola trade in
the nineteenth century.133 Nevertheless, it seems unlikely that state traders con-
ducted a larger share of long-distance trade than did independent merchants.
Indeed, in some cases, as among the Akan states of the southern Gold Coast, public
authorities deliberately refrained from engaging in trade directly, not because they
were insensitive to commercial opportunities, but because they judged it more
advantageous to encourage private traders and then to tax them.134 The imposition
of tolls and market dues was undoubtedly a widespread means of raising revenue,135
and being a relatively simple and virtually riskless exercise, it may well have been
preferred, on the whole, to direct trading.
Directly or indirectly, trade seems to have been an important source of state
income, particularly since ‘feudal’ rents derived from land were far less common in
Africa than they were in medieval Europe. All West African states had a keen inter-
est in encouraging trade. Prudent rulers kept in close touch with leading traders and
mercantile organisations, and commercial policy formed a large part of state policy
as a whole. Pre-industrial states in other continents may well have hindered the
expansion of the market, as is sometimes alleged, by imposing bureaucratic controls
on private enterprise, and by directing policy towards the attainment of spiritual
rather than economic goals. These arguments have little relevance for West Africa.
It is worth while looking more closely at the organisation of long-distance com-
merce to see how African businessmen dealt with the problems of handling goods,
of dealing with ‘foreign’ customers, and of raising the capital required to invest in
costly, long-term ventures. A study of the solutions devised for these difficulties
should provide some indication of the capabilities of indigenous entrepreneurs.
Long-distance traders of all types banded together in caravans, which resem-
bled armed convoys, having guards, porters and drovers, as well as a leader,
a guide, a treasurer and a quartermaster.136 Hausa caravans in the nineteenth
century consisted of 1,000 to 2,000 people, most of whom were armed, and an
equal number of donkeys. They travelled for five or six hours each day on well-
established routes, where water and food were known to be available, and sent
out scouts to search for brigands and to negotiate for supplies. The round trip
from Sokoto to Ashanti (a total of about 1,200 miles) took between six months
and one year. Caravans were like slowly moving markets, selling some of their
goods on the route and paying for foodstuffs and services as they went. Without
them, long-distance trade would have been impossible. However, there were
133 Ivor Wilks, ‘Asante Policy Towards the Hausa Trade in the Nineteenth Century’, in The Develop-
ment of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa, pp. 130–33.
134 Kwame Y. Daaku, ‘Trade and Trading Patterns of the Akan in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth
Centuries’, in The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa, pp. 168–81.
135 Sundström, The Trade of Guinea, pp. 5–13, 61–5.
136 For further information see N. Levtzion, Muslims and Chiefs in West Africa, Oxford, 1968, pp.
23–5, and Paul E. Lovejoy, ‘Long-Distance Trade and Islam: The Case of the Nineteenth-
Century Hausa Kola Trade’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 5, 1971, pp. 537–47.
The domestic economy 109
diseconomies of scale which became apparent during the colonial period. With
greater freedom of movement and more secure markets, long-distance traders
began to travel in small groups, an arrangement which gave them flexibility in
timing departures and arrivals, offered them a wider choice of routes and
reduced their overheads, since it was no longer necessary to contribute towards
the cost of guards and guides. Large caravans became redundant in the twentieth
century, but long-distance trade survived: it was merely reorganised in ways
which were less readily identifiable.
The caravans of the pre-colonial period commuted ponderously between large
entrepôts, many of which were located at points of overlap between different eco-
logical zones. A line of these markets ran from west to east along the Sahara-savanna
border, and included towns such as Segou, Djenne, Timbuctu, Gao, Sokoto,
Katsina and Kano. A similar chain existed in the south on the borders between the
savanna and the forest, and included Bouna, Bondoukou, Begho, Onitsha and the
Ashanti markets of Salaga and Kintampo. These entrepôts were bulking and bulk-
breaking centres, and also places where goods were transferred from one mode of
transport to another. On arrival at the entrepôts, the caravan broke up and the
traders made contact with specialised agents, who helped them dispose of their
goods and buy other products for the return journey. The two most important
agents were landlords and brokers.137 The former were wholesalers, who provided
storage for goods, pasture for livestock and accommodation for traders. The latter
were commission agents and interpreters, who played a crucial role as intermediaries
between buyers and sellers, though sometimes they traded on their own account as
well. Many goods were sold in the market place, but negotiations over some of the
more valuable items, such as gold and salt, usually took place in the house of the
landlord or broker concerned. Landlords and brokers based their business on per-
sonal connections and were concerned to build up a reputation for fairness and hon-
esty. Clapperton, who visited Kano in the 1820s, noted that
if a tobe or a turkadee [cotton garments for men and women respectively] pur-
chased here is carried to Bornu or any other distant place, without being
opened, and is there discovered to be of inferior quality, it is immediately sent
back, as a matter of course—the name of the dylala, or broker, being written
inside every parcel. In this case, the dylala must find out the seller, who, by the
laws of Kano, is forthwith obliged to refund the purchase money.138
137 Sundström, The Trade of Guinea, pp. 57–60; Polly Hill, ‘Landlords and Brokers: A West African
Trading System’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 6, 1966b, pp. 349–66. It should be noted that some
agents acted both as landlords and as brokers.
138 Quoted in Thomas Hodgkin, Nigerian Perspectives, London, 1960, p. 217.
110 The domestic economy
The chief requirements of long-distance trade were capital, credit and secur-
ity. These needs encouraged a trend towards the control of a particular staple,
market or trade route by a family, by a lineage or even by a whole ethnic
group. This tendency resulted partly from the fact that mobilising funds and
securing credit depended largely on personal, face-to-face relationships,139 and
partly from a recognition that integration had advantages of spreading risks over
a number of investors, of providing reliable agents in distant places, and of
strengthening the bargaining position of traders in relation to landlords and bro-
kers. At the same time, it seems likely, though this is hypothetical, that this
method of raising funds ultimately limited the growth of a firm, for it was not
always possible for a family, still less for larger units, to cooperate successfully.
A shortage of capital in any one firm would tend either to increase the total
number of firms engaged in a particular trade, or (if new competitors were
excluded) to keep the volume of trade below the level of effective demand.
Even where cooperation was achieved, expansion could still be impeded by rival
organisations. For example, Hausa merchants were encouraged to buy kola nuts,
but were prevented by the Ashanti from entering the areas of production. Lack
of capital, combined with political interference, often meant that goods had to
be handed over by one group of merchants to another at staging posts and
entrepôts, thus giving rise to a system of relay trading.140
Successful integration required a formal moral code to sanction and control
commercial relationships. The ‘blueprint’ for the formation of a moral commu-
nity of businessmen was provided by Islam, which was closely associated with
long-distance trade in West Africa from the eighth century onwards.141 Islam
helped maintain the identity of members of a network or firm who were scat-
tered over a wide area, and often in foreign countries; it enabled traders to rec-
ognise, and hence to deal readily with, each other; and it provided moral and
ritual sanctions to enforce a code of conduct which made trust and credit pos-
sible. It was through Islam that Dioula and Hausa merchants established the
commercial networks, or diasporas,142 which made them so prominent and suc-
cessful in long-distance trade. Diasporas of various kinds have been an important
feature of migration and innovation in many parts of the world besides Africa, as
the contrasting examples of Chinese traders in south-east Asia and white settlers
in the British Empire illustrate.
139 The successful businessman demonstrated his importance and credit worthiness by his open-
handed manner and conspicuous generosity. It is typical of the ethno-centric judgements made
about the underdeveloped world that these characteristics are regarded as evidence of improvi-
dence, whereas in the European context they are cited as examples of shrewd business sense.
140 Sundström, The Trade of Guinea, p. 54; Jean-Louis Boutillier, ‘La cité marchande de Bouna dans
l’ensemble économique Ouest-Africain pré-colonial’, in The Development of Indigenous Trade and
Markets in West Africa, pp. 240–52.
141 See Abner Cohen’s outstanding contribution, ‘Cultural Strategies in the Organization of Trading
Diasporas’, in The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa, pp. 266–81.
142 In Cohen’s phrase, a diaspora is ‘an ethnic group in dispersal’.
The domestic economy 111
143 Frederick Jackson Turner, The Frontier in American History, New York, 1920.
144 W. K. Hancock, Survey of British Commonwealth Affairs, 2, part 2, London, 1942.
145 Stewart Macaulay, ‘Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study’, American Socio-
logical Review, 28, 1963, pp. 55–67.
146 Hugh Thomas, ed., The Establishment: A Symposium, London, 1959.
112 The domestic economy
needed in later life are those which encourage members of the group to play
together (to express social solidarity against outsiders), yet also to play competi-
tively (to permit the emergence of leaders). The finished products can be recog-
nised by their dress and accent, which provide a generally reliable guide to their
behaviour. The identity of the group is reinforced by inter-marriage, which
ensures that kinship ties remain significant in business relationships.
Social, as well as educational, entry qualifications severely limit the extent to
which merit is rewarded by promotion in twentieth-century Britain. A recent study
has shown that over 100 years after the beginning of the Industrial Revolution ‘lead-
ership by inheritance applied in a great range of industrial activities’, and that new-
comers often found their advance blocked by family control.147 In the case of the
City of London recruitment is still restricted to members of the upper and middle
classes, and preference is given to those who have been brought up in the home
counties. Commercial leaders are chosen from within this minority group, not from
outside it. In pre-colonial West Africa there was no lack of the will to achieve, and
there was scope for traders of ability to make their way in commerce. Admittedly,
those who became successful tried to entrench themselves and to ensure that their
families had advantages which others lacked, but such aims are scarcely a peculiarity
of the pre-industrial world.
Finally, it is worth noting that there is no evidence that businessmen were
accorded a low status in pre-colonial Africa, or that they suffered from any other
form of social discrimination. The indications are that successful merchants were
highly regarded, as indeed they are today. Furthermore, it is mistaken to suppose
that businessmen enjoy a notably superior status in advanced capitalist societies. Busi-
ness occupations do not rank at the top of the status hierarchy even in the United
States, and it is now clear that similarities in the occupational-prestige rankings of
pre-industrial and industrial societies are much greater than used to be thought.148
Local trade, as explained earlier, had its own rationale, but it was also con-
nected to long-distance commerce through the sale of supplies to passing cara-
vans and, to a small extent, through the distribution of the goods which they
delivered. The network of long-distance trade routes thus gave West Africa
a tenuous economic unity, linking, and partially integrating, different geograph-
ical zones and ethnic groupings, and crossing many state boundaries. However,
there were limitations to the development of a ‘national’ West African economy.
The unity achieved through long-distance commerce was incomplete because
the trade itself was restricted in volume and because its principal effects were felt
by a minority of the total population. Further consideration will be given to the
147 P. L. Payne, ‘The Emergence of the Large-scale Company in Great Britain, 1870–1914’, Economic
History Review, 20, 1967, p. 538.
148 Robert W. Lodge, Donald J. Treiman, and Peter H. Rossi, ‘A Comparative Study of Occupa-
tional Prestige’, in Class, Status, and Power, eds. Reinhard Bendix and Seymour Martin Lipset,
London, 1967, pp. 309–21; and Robert W. Hodge, Paul M. Siegel, and Peter H. Rossi, ‘Occupa-
tional Prestige in the United States’, in ibid., pp. 322–34.
The domestic economy 113
question of constraints on the growth of this market in the final section of the
present chapter, after the two remaining features of the distributive system,
money and transport, have been examined.
It is often supposed that West Africa failed to develop a monetary system
which was designed to facilitate exchange and could succeed in doing so.
According to one view, ‘primitive’ trade was conducted by barter. Another
interpretation admits that currencies of various types existed but argues that they
did not have the same properties or perform the same functions as modern
money. In neither case was it possible for a capital market to develop, nor was
there any need for a sophisticated institutional device of this kind. If one or
other of these arguments is correct, then an explanation of the limitations on
commercial expansion must attach some weight to deficiencies in pre-colonial
monetary systems.
There is no doubt that a proportion of the goods entering the market were
exchanged by barter. A number of books refer to the so-called ‘silent’ trade or
‘dumb’ barter, which, supposedly, was an arrangement whereby goods were
exchanged by altering quantities, but without verbal consultation as to price. This
curious behaviour is in accord with the European image of quaint native life, and it
is easy to believe that these tribal traders, having kept silent for so long, compensated
by dancing and drumming even more vigorously than before. Reality, however,
must intrude: the only scholar to investigate the various accounts of ‘dumb’ barter
decided that the supporting evidence was so weak that it was necessary to resort to
Gestalt psychology to explain why Europeans continued to believe in it!149 Barter
aided by verbal communication was common, but it was not the dominant means
of effecting exchange. Despite the evolutionist assumption that barter is the first
stage in the emergence of a market economy, this method of trade is not necessarily
associated with ‘simple’ societies, and it works efficiently if goods can be ‘paired’
easily. It is as well to remember that a substantial, and increasing, proportion of
world trade today is conducted on a modified barter basis, whereby goods such as
locomotives are exchanged for products such as coffee, and deficiencies are made
up by cash payments or by vouchers redeemable elsewhere.150 Africans were more
familiar with this system in the pre-colonial period than they were with pure barter.
Since trade was widespread and involved multilateral relations, goods were not
always readily interchangeable, and money was needed to facilitate exchange.
A variety of currencies was in circulation in the centuries before colonial rule, the
most important being gold, cowries, strips of cloth and copper and iron rods.
Gold was current throughout much of the Western Sudan and also in central
parts of the forest, such as Ashanti, from the eleventh century onwards and
probably earlier. Gold currencies took two main forms: gold dust, which was
transported in small bags and measured on a portable balance, and mithqals (an
alternative name for dinars), which were in use both as coins and as units of
weight for gold dust.151 The mithqals minted at Nikki, in what is now northern
Dahomey, are thought to have had an extensive circulation in the eastern half of
the Western Sudan in the early nineteenth century.
Cowrie shells, for centuries the major export of the Maldive Islands, were
used as currency in several parts of the world, including much of Africa.152
They were first imported into West Africa via an overland route from North
Africa and the Middle East, and were in use in the chief markets of the middle
Niger from at least the eleventh century. Cowries spread west to Mauritania
before the fifteenth century; east to Hausaland early in the eighteenth century,
reaching Bornu in the second half of the nineteenth century; and south to the
forest between the Ivory Coast and the Niger Delta, where they merged with
cowries imported by European traders by sea from the sixteenth century
onwards. Cowries were the most widespread currency in West Africa, and they
continued to expand in area and in volume until the late nineteenth century, by
which time they were used in all parts of the region except the Upper Guinea
coast and its hinterland (from Senegal to Liberia), and eastern Nigeria.
Cloth money and metal currencies other than gold were found in many parts
of West Africa, but were dominant only in areas where cowries had failed to
penetrate. Cotton strips were especially important in Bornu in the fourteenth
century and in parts of Senegambia, particularly among the Wolof, in the nine-
teenth century. Iron money of various kinds was used on the Upper Guinea
coast, and copper rods and wires circulated in the eastern part of the Niger
Delta and, before the eighteenth century, in Bornu.153 The origins of these
metal currencies have been the subject of a discussion which is noteworthy princi-
pally as a further illustration of the diffusionist hypothesis that all complex social
phenomena found in sub-Saharan Africa must have originated elsewhere unless
there is very clear proof to the contrary. However, it seems unnecessary to resort to
theories of the Egyptian or Eastern provenance of metal currencies, since these
could easily have been, and probably were, developed in West Africa itself.
The problem now arises as to how to interpret the function of these pre-colonial
currencies. To classify them as ‘transitional’ currencies is useful in drawing attention
to a category which lies between pure barter on the one hand and the monetary sys-
tems of advanced industrial societies on the other, but it has the disadvantage of
grouping a wide range of currencies which may not share quite the same properties.
A more helpful classification is that which divides transitional currencies into two
types. General-purpose currencies are intended to assist liquidity and can be
151 Marion Johnson, ‘The Nineteenth-Century Gold “Mithqal” in West and North Africa’, Journal of
African History, 9, 1968, pp. 547–69.
152 The authoritative study on West Africa, is Marion Johnson, ‘The Cowrie Currencies of West
Africa’, Journal of African History, 11, 1970, pp. 17–49 and 331–53.
153 Manillas—horseshoe-shaped currencies made of copper and brass—are noted in Chapter 3, Sec-
tion 2, in connection with external trade.
The domestic economy 115
exchanged readily for all goods and services irrespective of the social status of the par-
ties concerned. The usefulness of these currencies can be judged by their efficiency in
promoting ‘modern’ exchange. Special-purpose currencies, which are designed to
control liquidity, can be used to purchase only a limited range of goods and are not
freely convertible with other currencies. These currencies should not be analysed as if
they were agents of modernity, for they dominated societies where market principles
were unimportant, and their main purpose was to solidify the social structure.
The chief problem is an empirical one; whether West Africa’s pre-colonial curren-
cies should be classified as general-purpose or as special-purpose money. According to
the substantivist school, the transitional currencies of Africa were special-purpose cur-
rencies. This conclusion follows from the assumption that market principles were per-
ipheral, and is also, so it is claimed, supported by historical evidence. The substantivist
interpretation deserves close attention because it has been stated often and, on occa-
sion, forcefully. Perhaps the best test of its accuracy is to see whether it meets Polanyi’s
own precept that ‘the fount of the substantivist concept is the empirical economy’.
Judged by this criterion, the basis of the substantivist case seems rather slender.
Dalton’s generalisations are derived mainly from a re-examination of a previous
scholar’s study of shell money on the Pacific island of Rossel.154 It is relevant to
observe in this connection that Pospisil and Epstein have shown that shell
money did function as a general-purpose currency in the Pacific.155 Bohannan’s
argument is drawn largely from his fieldwork among the Tiv, an important and
interesting people, but one who number less than 1 per cent of West Africa’s
present population.156 Latham’s investigation of the historical sources relating to
copper money demonstrates that Bohannan’s interpretation does not apply to
eastern Nigeria as a whole, and suggests that he may also have been mistaken
with regard to the much smaller area occupied by the Tiv.157 Copper rods were
valid for all goods and services, and were split into small denominations (wires)
in order to facilitate exchange. Polanyi’s study of cowries is confined to southern
Dahomey in the eighteenth century, and uses a limited selection of available
sources.158 Marion Johnson’s comprehensive study has revealed important short-
comings in his work.159 Cowries and gold formed a single currency system over
154 George Dalton, ‘Primitive Money’, American Anthropologist, 67, 1965, pp. 44–65.
155 Leopold Pospisil, Kapauku Papuan Economy, Yale, 1963, and T. Scarlett Epstein, Capitalism, Primi-
tive and Modern, Canberra, 1968, pp. 19–26.
156 Paul Bohannan, ‘The Impact of Money on an African Subsistence Economy’, Journal of Economic
History, 19, 1959, pp. 491–503.
157 A. J. H. Latham, ‘Currency, Credit and Capitalism on the Cross River in the Pre-Colonial Era’,
Journal of African History, 12, 1971, pp. 599–605.
158 Karl Polanyi, Dahomey and the Slave Trade, Seattle, 1966, pp. 173–94. Polanyi’s discussion contains
a number of ambiguities, but it is only fair to note that his book had to be prepared for publication
after his death.
159 And also that Polanyi’s views on the related question of the ounce trade need revision. See
Marion Johnson, ‘The Ounce in Eighteenth-Century West African Trade’, Journal of African His-
tory, 7, 1966, pp. 197–214.
116 The domestic economy
a large part of West Africa, the exchange rate between them sometimes being
fixed and sometimes being left to float. The system was designed to assist trade,
and it is no coincidence that it served an area where long-distance commerce
was particularly active. The success of the cowrie is readily explicable. Its size
and shape made it easy to handle, convenient to count and impossible to coun-
terfeit, while its durability meant that it could be stored safely for many years.
Moreover, cowries, though often used as small change for gold, could be multi-
plied for accounting purposes by standardised units (strings, ‘heads’ and bags).
Finally, it is worth noting that Ames has shown that Wolof cloth currency was
available in standardised multiples and was acceptable as payment for ‘subsist-
ence’ and ‘prestige’ items.160
The foregoing review makes it clear that the major currencies of pre-colonial
West Africa functioned as general-purpose currencies and had the attributes of
modern money. Each one acted as a medium of exchange, as a common meas-
ure of value, as a store of wealth and as a standard for deferred payment. This
interpretation is fully consistent with the argument advanced earlier in this chap-
ter that trade and market principles were more common in the pre-colonial era
than some writers have thought. The concept of special-purpose money still
retains its value as a theoretical tool, and doubtless examples can be found to
illustrate the ways in which it operated.161 Furthermore, it is only fair to point
out that the general-purpose currencies of West Africa did not share precisely
the same attributes: there is room for considering the merits of, say, cowries in
relation to cloth; for examining the reasons underlying the boundaries between
different currency areas; and for analysing the varied monetary functions of the
state. However, the main conclusion still holds: the principal currencies of West
Africa served to extend trade, not to obstruct it. The indications are that these
currencies were adequate for the needs of the time. It was only in the nine-
teenth century, when they became less efficient, that they were replaced by the
currencies of the industrial world.
The presence of extensive trade and general-purpose currencies provides grounds
for supposing that pre-colonial West Africa also had a capital market. Sundström’s evi-
dence confirms that this was indeed the case.162 It is suggested here (though mainly to
prompt others to consider this neglected subject in more detail) that West African
credit institutions can be divided, on the basis of their primary functions, into two
types. Small credit associations, such as the Yoruba esusu, were organised by kinsmen
or by groups of friends, and were devoted mainly to social purposes, such as raising
money for funerals. In addition, there was a commercial capital market, which served
economic needs at local and inter-regional levels. As far as local needs were concerned,
160 D. W. Ames, ‘The Use of a Transitional Cloth-Money Token among the Wolof’. American
Anthropologist, 57, 1955b, pp. 1016–23.
161 Ration coupons and trading stamps are examples of special-purpose currencies in industrial
societies.
162 The Trade of Guinea, pp. 34–44.
The domestic economy 117
it is important to emphasise, once again, that small communities were not necessarily
homogeneous and that it was possible for poorer members of society to become
indebted to wealthier neighbours. The extent and causes of local indebtedness (espe-
cially its relationship to the availability of land) are subjects which require further
research. At the inter-regional level, it is clear that professional traders often needed to
finance their activities by securing credit, because their initial investment was substan-
tial and returns were long delayed. Commercial capital was obtained from fellow mer-
chants and from specialised bankers and money lenders. The large entrepôts had
bankers who invested money on behalf of depositors and operated a system whereby
credits could be transferred to third parties; exchange brokers, who also speculated in
currency values; and a futures market in the main staples of long-distance trade. Inter-
est rates reflected the scarcity of capital and the risks involved in most lending oper-
ations and were rarely less than 100 per cent per annum. Security was given in various
ways, though most credit agreements were based on personal connections of the kind
noted already with reference to the Dioula and Hausa. Usually, credit facilities were
arranged in the presence of witnesses and were guaranteed either by depositing bonds
supplied by third parties, or by offering property (livestock, houses and land) as secur-
ity. Poorer members of society often resorted to pawning as a means of guaranteeing
the repayment of a debt. Pawning was a system by which the debtor or a nominee
(usually a kinsman) worked for his creditor without payment until the debt was
cleared. Legal sanctions were also employed, and most societies had rules which
defined various types of loan and laid down regulations for recovering debts. This was
true both of Muslim states in the Western Sudan, where the Koranic injunction
against usurious loans had little influence on the operation of the commercial money
market, and of the ‘pagan’ states in the forest zone, as, for example, among the Yoruba
kingdoms.163
The remaining feature of the distributive system to be considered is transport.
It is easy to locate sources which dismiss pre-industrial means of transport as
primitive, but harder to find those which support this judgement by defining
terms and by examining the costs and benefits of various means of carriage in
the pre-railway age. As usual, the Dark Continent has suffered particularly in
this respect, and the familiar statement that ‘Africa south of the Sahara has never
invented the wheel’164 is commonly used as an index of the region’s backward-
ness in comparison with other parts of the world. It will be contended here that
general pronouncements about the primitive nature of pre-colonial transport dis-
guise complex and important problems: in the first place, various meanings can
be given to the adjective ‘primitive’ in the context of transport, and not all of
them apply to Africa; secondly, since Europe did not invent the wheel either, it
is not the independent origins of this device which require investigation so
163 A. G. Hopkins, ‘A Report on the Yoruba’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 5, 1969, pp.
90–2.
164 P. T. Bauer, Economic Analysis and Policy in Underdeveloped Countries, London, 1965, p. 47.
118 The domestic economy
much as the factors governing the spread and adoption of technical innovations;
finally, it is worth observing that to possess advanced technical knowledge is not
necessarily to be on the road to economic development, as Needham’s remark-
able study of China has demonstrated.165
Communications by land were based entirely on animal and human power.
One of the greatest transport innovations of the pre-colonial era was the intro-
duction of the camel. This extraordinary animal was the principal means of
transport in the desert for almost 2,000 years. It was present in North Africa in
the first century B.C., and it became known throughout the Sahara during the
early centuries of the Christian era. The camel was more efficient in desert con-
ditions than were horses and oxen, which had been used previously, and its
supremacy remained unchallenged until the coming of the motor car in the
1920s. Camels were bred specially for desert transport by nomads, such as the
Tuareg, and could carry between 3 hundredweight (cwt) and 5 cwt across the
Sahara. The camel did not travel very far into the Western Sudan partly because
it preferred the poorer fodder of the desert, and partly because it was susceptible
to diseases, such as sleeping sickness. At northern entrepôts, such as Timbuctu,
goods were transferred to donkeys and oxen, which were better suited to
savanna conditions. Donkeys were the chief pack animal in the Western Sudan.
They carried about 100 pounds in weight, which was substantially less than the
amount carried by oxen, but donkeys were cheaper to buy and feed, they were
faster and they were more effective over rough terrain. Donkeys, like camels,
were bred specially for transport purposes. Those raised by the Mossi had
a particularly high reputation in long-distance trade, and were bought in Salaga
by Hausa traders, who used them to carry kola nuts on their journey home. At
the savanna-forest border markets, such as Salaga, goods travelling further south
were transferred to porters, because the use of pack animals in the forest was
restricted by a combination of trypanosomiasis and lack of pasture. Professional
carriers, who were often slaves, could head-load 55 to 65 pounds and cover an
average of 20 miles a day.
Water transport was used where possible, for it was known to be the cheapest
means of transporting bulky commodities over long distances. However, many
West African rivers were hard to navigate: a number had dangerous rapids; some
were flooded during the rainy season; and others lacked water in the dry season.
Canoes were better able to deal with these difficulties than were other types of
craft. West African canoes varied in size. Some were 80 feet or more in length
and could carry as many as 100 men.166 Most canoes were propelled by paddles,
though small sails were used in some areas. Commercial water transport was
165 Joseph Needham, Science and Civilisation in China, 1, Cambridge, 1954. Other volumes have been
published, and this immense study is still in progress.
166 Robert Smith, ‘The Canoe in West African History’, Journal of African History, 11, 1970, pp.
515–33.
The domestic economy 119
particularly important on Lake Chad, the Niger, the Senegal, sections of the
Volta and numerous smaller rivers in the forest, and along the coast, especially
where estuaries and lagoons provided shelter from ocean waves and storms. The
busiest inland waterway was the middle section of the Niger, which linked Tim-
buctu to the commercial and administrative centres of Djenne (250 miles
upstream) and Gao (about the same distance downstream).167 Hundreds of craft
were in use on this stretch of the river from the thirteenth century onwards and
probably earlier. Some of these canoes carried 20 to 30 tons of merchandise,
including foodstuffs as well as the more luxurious items of long-distance trade.
Water transport enabled the middle Niger complex to become one of the great
centres of pre-colonial trade in Africa. It encouraged the growth of specialised
occupations, such as building and operating canoes; it led to the development of
specialised ports, such as Kabara, which served Timbuctu; and it contributed to
the political and economic unity of the empires of Mali and Songhai.
The efficiency of a transport system can be analysed in three ways. By follow-
ing this procedure, it is possible to arrive at a clearer understanding of what is
meant by backward or primitive means of communication. The physical avail-
ability of transport fixes the size of the market in geographical terms. West Afri-
can transport certainly provided a wide coverage, joining caravans to periodic
markets and offering, via head-loading, what was virtually a door-to-door ser-
vice. The freight capacity of the system determines the volume carried. At first
sight it might seem that African transport was defective in this respect. Fortu-
nately, this hypothesis can be tested against the example of the nineteenth cen-
tury, when there was a massive increase in the volume of goods carried without
any change taking place in established modes of transportation. Therefore, it
seems unlikely that there was a shortage of freight capacity. Finally, the cost of
transport defines the depth of the market in social terms. In this instance there is
no doubt that African modes of transport were deficient. Evaluating transport
costs is a difficult task, but it is clear that the value added in long-distance trade
was considerable.168 Head-loading was particularly expensive, and goods could
be taken only a short distance by this means before the cost of transport
exceeded the profit on sales. This explains why head-loading was used in long-
distance trade only in parts of the forest, where there was no alternative, and in
cases where the carrier was a slave who was destined to be sold at the end of
the journey. Foodstuffs and other items of everyday use could rarely be trans-
ported far beyond the area of production by any means of carriage. The case of
167 M. Tymowski, ‘Le Niger, voie de communication des grands états du Soudan occidentale jusqu’à
la fin du XVIe siècle’, Africana Bulletin, 6, 1967, pp. 73–95.
168 To assess transport costs accurately it is necessary to take account of the capital cost of a particular
form of carriage, maintenance costs, the life expectation of a vehicle and its resale value, if any.
Moreover, goods in transit in West Africa paid numerous tolls. This expenditure was reflected in
the price of a product at its final destination and needs to be differentiated from the cost of
transport.
120 The domestic economy
Timbuctu is an exception which proves the rule, for the city was able to use the
relatively cheap Niger route and could also pay for imported supplies from for-
eign trade earnings. Even so, in the nineteenth century the price of imported
cloth at Timbuctu was two to three and a half times as great as it was on the
coast. Kola nuts, which today are common items of consumption, were a luxury
enjoyed by the relatively wealthy in the pre-colonial period. In the late nine-
teenth century one kola nut bought at Gonja, in the area of production, for five
cowries sold for 250 to 300 cowries by the time it reached Lake Chad (about
1,250 miles away).169
The main deficiency of African transport was its high cost. The question to
be considered now is whether this drawback was made more serious by the
absence of the wheel. It is possible to attribute the lack of wheeled transport to
ignorance. However, there is now evidence that horse-drawn chariots or carts
were crossing the Sahara some five centuries before the birth of Christ, and
since West Africa remained in contact with the Arab world in subsequent cen-
turies, it seems improbable that this explanation will suffice. Alternatively, it
could be argued that Africans knew of the existence of the wheel, but, being
rather slow-witted in comparison with the inhabitants of other continents, were
unable to devise ways of using it to advantage. It will be contended here that
this view is also inaccurate. It seems more likely that wheeled transport was not
adopted either because it was inappropriate to West African conditions or
because its greater cost was not justified by proportionately greater returns.
In two areas of West Africa environmental circumstances meant that there
was little scope for wheeled transport. On the sand and rock of the Sahara the
camel was a more efficient means of carriage, so much so that it replaced the
wheel at an early date. In the forest the difficulty of keeping draught animals
greatly reduced the value of wheeled vehicles. In the Western Sudan, however,
both horses and oxen were present and wheeled transport would have been pos-
sible. The problem in this case was that the gain from greater traction would
have been nullified by the capital and maintenance costs of carts, wagons and
draught animals, and by the slower rate of progress of wheeled vehicles. Since
draught animals were not used on the farm, the cost of keeping them solely for
transport purposes during the dry season was much higher than in other parts of
the world, where there was scope for combining the two functions. The horse,
the most powerful draught animal, was very expensive, needed a high intake of
fodder and water, and succumbed easily to disease.170 Horses were used in West
Africa as cavalry and on ceremonial occasions, and they remain symbols of pres-
tige today. The poor quality of the roads would have greatly reduced the
169 C.O. 879/49, H. J. Reid, ‘Memorandum on the British Possessions in West Africa’,
12 May 1897, Public Record Office.
170 On the relative merits of horses and oxen, see A. Burford, ‘Heavy Transport in Classical
Antiquity’, Economic History Review, 13, 1960, pp. 1–18.
The domestic economy 121
efficiency of wheeled vehicles, and the cost of improving the road system would
have been prohibitive, especially in an area where population was, in general,
rather sparse. Pack animals predominated because they were relatively cheap to
buy, inexpensive to operate and well suited to the terrain.
The foregoing argument can be tested against the evidence provided by one
of the earliest systematic attempts to introduce wheeled transport into part of the
Western Sudan:
In January 1905 the first cart convoy arrived at Zaria from Zungeru, and
the difficulties due to having to rely solely on human porterage were tem-
porarily obviated, though the carts were not able to continue running
when once the rainy season set in. Every effort was made to organise an
efficient system during the dry season of 1905–1906. Artificers and drivers
had even been imported from India, and proved to be of greatest use;
depots were established for supplies of fodder along the road; a veterinary
surgeon was attached to the Department. In spite of all these efforts, how-
ever, the cart transport proved little less expensive than carriers.171
It seems reasonable to conclude that the absence of the wheel was a matter of
decision rather than of chance or ignorance, and that the presence of wheeled
vehicles in West Africa would not have reduced transport costs during the pre-
colonial period.
Although the wheel is commonly regarded as a symbol of economic progress,
it is as well to remember that wheeled vehicles did not achieve a decisive advan-
tage over other forms of transport until the Industrial Revolution, with the
development first of the railway and then of the motor car. Before that time,
the use of wheeled vehicles in Europe was inhibited by many of the problems
experienced in Africa. In eighteenth-century Spain, for example, pack animals,
especially donkeys, were by far the most important means of transport, though
ox-carts were available and were used to a certain extent.172 The ox-cart carried
three to four times as much as a large pack animal, but since it was costly to
purchase and operate, and travelled at half the speed, it could not compete with
donkey transport. Wagons did not become numerous in northern Europe until
the sixteenth century, and even then they were used mainly for short-haul
work. Until the roads were improved, pack animals remained the leading form
of long-distance commercial transport on land. ‘Long trains of these faithful ani-
mals, furnished with a great variety of equipment … wended their way along
the narrow roads of the time, and provided the chief means by which the
exchange of commodities could be carried on’. This statement could well apply
171 Sir Charles Orr, The Making of Northern Nigeria, London, 1911, pp. 184–5.
172 David R. Ringrose, ‘Transportation and Economic Stagnation in Eighteenth-Century Castille’,
Journal of Economic History, 28, 1968, pp. 51–79.
122 The domestic economy
to the Western Sudan in the pre-colonial period, though in fact it refers to Eng-
land in the early eighteenth century.173 The evidence suggests that while Africa’s
transport system was costly in relation to modern forms of transport, it was no
more expensive than that which operated in other pre-industrial societies.
173 W. T. Jackman, The Development of Transportation in Modern England, 2nd ed., London, 1962,
p. 141.
174 This conclusion is in line with that advanced by Theodore W. Schultz, Transforming Traditional
Agriculture, New Haven, 1964, with the important qualification that ‘traditional’ agriculture in
West Africa was not as changeless as Schultz suggests was generally the case.
The domestic economy 123
present throughout the area as a whole. The greater part of total output con-
sisted of foodstuffs and other everyday necessities. These commodities could
be traded locally, but not over long distances because transport costs pre-
vented them from competing with acceptable substitutes, which could be
produced on the spot in other areas. Local trade, by definition, served
a market which was too small in terms of numbers of consumers and pur-
chasing power to justify the introduction of cost-reducing innovations and
greater specialisation. Moreover, the income elasticity of demand for food-
stuffs was low: if per capita incomes had risen, demand would have shifted
away from foodstuffs and towards manufactured goods, such as textiles. In
the absence of a general expansion of incomes, trade in commodities with
the greatest growth potential depended on connecting social and geographical
islands of purchasing power by means of long-distance trade. The problem
here was that the costs of carriage were too great and the number of rela-
tively affluent consumers was too small to permit the development of a mass
market in manufactured goods. Consequently, the multiplier effects of long-
distance commerce were limited. Freight charges per ton/mile were no more
expensive in Africa than they were in other parts of the world, but transport
costs were higher for each consumer served than in many other areas because
the population was small and scattered. Underpopulation was critical in pre-
venting market growth because it encouraged extensive cultivation, favoured
dispersed settlement and generated strong tendencies towards local self-
sufficiency. Where population was concentrated, it was partly for defensive
reasons, and so was not indicative of developed exchange activities, and
partly for commercial motives, in which case it was usually associated with
slavery, and with a low level of purchasing power.
There were two possible escape routes from this situation. The first was
through an increase in population, which would have altered the land–labour
ratio, encouraged the adoption of more intensive forms of agriculture and pro-
vided a larger and more concentrated market. This is exactly what happened in
Western Europe during the Middle Ages, though the reasons governing popula-
tion changes in that period are little better understood than they are in the case
of pre-colonial Africa.175 The second escape route was through technical innov-
ation, which would have increased the size of the market by reducing production
costs. Technical innovation might have occurred in response to an increase in
demand brought about by population growth (or by a rise in incomes among the
existing population), or else to overcome shortages of supply, such as a lack of raw
materials or of labour. In Africa no pressures or incentives existed on the demand
side, while on the supply side the main deficiency, a shortage of labour, was dealt
with by using slaves. This solution met the needs of the time, for though labour was
175 Douglass C. North and Robert Paul Thomas, ‘An Economic Theory of the Growth of the West-
ern World’, Economic History Review, 23, 1970, p. 11.
124 The domestic economy
scarce in relation to land, the capital required for technical innovation was even
scarcer. Moreover, a reduction in production costs would not have cut distribution
costs significantly because transport charges accounted for a large proportion of the
retail price of goods entering long-distance trade. Africa needed to make a huge and
virtually impossible leap: the continent required not merely the wheel, but steam
and internal combustion engines as well.
To suggest these possibilities is not to argue that population growth and
technical innovation would have brought about an indigenous industrial
revolution in Africa. An expanding population might well have caused more
problems than it solved, and West Africa might have been faced, ultimately,
with a Malthusian situation. Technical advances might have been misapplied
or used merely to arrest a fall in living standards brought about by an
increase in population. Cumulative economic growth allied to technical
advance occurred in only one part of the pre-industrial world, namely north-
west Europe. A unique departure from normality took place not because the
economic and social structure of this small region possessed attributes which
were totally lacking in other continents, but because, by a fortunate coinci-
dence, long-run changes in factor prices made continuous innovation both
necessary and rewarding. It was possible, from an early date, to begin to
build a ladder to economic progress by means of small-scale, and interacting,
technical inventions.176 Other societies possessed much the same ingredients
but were unable to mix them in quite the same way. Commercial capitalism
in West Africa failed to promote industrialisation because there was little
scope for the development of an intermediate technology. Surplus trading
profits were invested in slaves and luxuries, not because Africans were dog-
gedly pursuing non-economic goals, but because of a lack of more profitable
alternatives.
176 See, for example, E. M. Carus-Wilson, ‘An Industrial Revolution of the Thirteenth Century’,
Economic History Review, 11, 1941, pp. 39–60.
3
EXTERNAL TRADE
The Sahara and the Atlantic
Africa, like China, was not well known to the outside world before the nineteenth
century, and information about the interior was the product of occasional visits from
hardy travellers, such as Ibn Battuta—the Marco Polo of the tropics. However, the
assumption that the continent was also isolated from external contacts, though it has
served a useful purpose here in focusing attention on internal checks on the develop-
ment of the market, is historically inaccurate and must now be discarded. In reality,
West Africa had well-established and highly organised external commercial links across
the desert and the ocean. These highways, though slow and hazardous, connected the
region to the international economy centuries before the Industrial Revolution
enabled the major European powers to increase their penetration of the underdevel-
oped world. The fact that West Africa conducted an extensive foreign commerce is
clearly relevant to the theme of stability and change in the market, for it is a matter of
historical experience that societies which have been inhibited by domestic constraints
have sometimes discovered a path to economic development through international
trade.
The theory of economic growth through international trade is basically an applica-
tion to nations and continents of the concept of specialisation, as set out originally by
Adam Smith.1 Where foreign trade has acted as an engine of growth, it has done so by
establishing a link between societies whose resource endowment, whether natural or
acquired, differs in certain important respects. In this situation, each of the societies
concerned can supply goods which the other requires, yet cannot produce itself, or
at least cannot produce as cheaply. Of the numerous factors affecting relative costs,
1 For expositions of the classical theory, and the elaborations made to it subsequently, see
G. Harberler, International Trade and Economic Development, Cairo, 1959, and Ragnar Nurkse, Patterns
of Trade and Development, London, 1961. Some problems of current interest are considered in Hla
Myint, Economic Theory and the Underdeveloped Countries, London, 1971.
126 External trade
1 Trans-Saharan trade
Trans-Saharan trade between West and North Africa began as early as 1000 B.C.,
when the desert crossing was made by oxen and by chariots or carts drawn by
horses. The trade was developed by the Carthaginians from about the fifth century
B.C., and was given further impetus by the Romans three centuries later, following
their expansion into North Africa and the subsequent introduction of the camel.2
2 R. C. C. Law, ‘The Garamantes and Trans-Saharan Enterprise in Classical Times’, Journal of African
History, 8, 1967, pp. 181–200.
External trade 127
With the collapse of Roman rule in the fourth century A.D., the trade diminished
and may even have ceased altogether. It was not revived until after the Byzantine
re-conquest of North Africa in 533–35. The rise of Arab power from the seventh
century onwards, though at first a destabilising influence on North African politics,
eventually contributed substantially to the growth of trans-Saharan commerce. Arab
merchants and missionaries were present in the Western Sudan from about
the second half of the eighth century,3 and their influence grew after the Almoravid
invasion of the empire of Ghana in 1077. The period which corresponds to the
Middle Ages in European history was a flourishing time for trade on the Saharan
routes, particularly from the middle of the thirteenth to the end of the sixteenth
centuries. This period saw an upswing in demand for West African products in
Europe and the Middle East, and at the same time a substantial increase in supply,
which was greatly assisted by an era of settled government in North Africa and the
Western Sudan.
The golden age of trans-Saharan trade is usually thought to have ended in the six-
teenth century, as the expansion of sea-borne commerce led to a reorientation of
trade routes towards the coast, and as the Western Sudan entered a long period of
political instability following the overthrow of the Songhai empire by the Moroccan
army in 1591. ‘The story of the Moorish conquest’, concluded Bovill, ‘remains one
of the darkest chapters in the history of the continent’.4 Indeed, in partial deference
to this weight of authority, the Western Sudan disappears from many history text-
books after 1591, and only emerges two centuries later, when (the Moors having
been suitably discomfited) the jihāds (movements of spiritual renewal) of the early
nineteenth century noisily claim attention. There are grounds for thinking that this
interpretation exaggerates reality. There is little evidence to show that the arrival of
the Europeans on the West Coast had a dramatic or even an immediate impact on
the economy of the interior. Trans-Saharan trade survived, and its value actually
increased during the nineteenth century. The final decline did not set in until after
1875, as will be shown in Chapter 4. Furthermore, research now in progress5 makes
it possible to suggest that the events of 1591 were not as traumatic as has been
thought, and that the period which followed was not one of unchecked political
anarchy and irreversible economic decline. It is likely that too much attention has
been paid to changes in personnel among the rulers—a common bias in the writing
of African history. For the great majority of the population, life probably went on
very much as before; they merely exchanged one set of tax collectors for another.
It is worth underlining three points arising out of this historical survey. To begin
with, it must be said that the deficiency of statistics is a serious handicap to any
3 Tadeusz Lewicki, ‘L’état nord-Africain de Tahert et ses relations avec le Soudan occidentale à la fin
de VIIIe et au IXe siècle’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 2, 1962, pp. 513–35.
4 Bovill, The Golden Trade, London, 1968, p. 195. The Moors, presumably, took a rather different:
view. See also Mauny, Tableau géographique de l’Ouest Africain au Moyen Âge, Dakar, 1961, p. 441.
5 Notably by N. R. Laurent of the School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London, and
J. R. Willis of the University of California, Los Angeles.
128 External trade
satisfactory interpretation of the rise and fall of trans-Saharan trade, and there is
a need for caution over the use of what little information of this kind is available.
Next, interpretations of fluctuations in the prosperity of trade at present rest on an
incomplete understanding of the determinants of booms and slumps in this unusual
commerce. Current explanations stress the importance of political factors, particu-
larly stability and instability at the southern and northern ends of the trade routes.
These explanations require qualification and elaboration. There are many examples
in West African history (as in medieval Europe) where, contrary to all reasonable
expectations, long-distance trade managed to steer a way through even the most
extreme political disturbances. Finally, as far as the initial effects of the European
presence were concerned, it is more likely that new areas of production were stimu-
lated near the coast than that the economy of the Western Sudan was undermined.
The economic effects of the coming of the Europeans now require detailed investi-
gation with reference to particular areas and specific items of trade, and the history
of the Western Sudan in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries needs to be res-
cued from its inappropriate association with the Dark Ages.
The variety of commodities traded was limited by two main considerations, apart
from the low level of purchasing power in West Africa. The length of the journey,
which lasted from 70 to 90 days and sometimes longer, meant that highly perishable
goods could not be taken across the desert. In addition, all goods had to have a high
value in relation to their weight. Freight charges across the Sahara added about 100
to 150 per cent to the cost of most items but formed a much smaller proportion of
the asking price of goods with a high value-weight ratio. Slaves, it is true, trans-
ported themselves, but they still had to be guarded and fed, and an allowance made
for the fact that a proportion of them—an estimate for the nineteenth century sug-
gests 20 per cent—died on the route. Trans-Saharan commerce reached its opti-
mum point of organisational efficiency at an early date with the introduction of the
camel, and no further internal or external economies were possible (or at least were
achieved) until the coming of the motor car in the 1920s.
The commodities traded can be divided into two categories, though the line
between them is not easily drawn. First, there were state necessities such as gold and
slaves, which were sent north, and cowries, salt6 and weapons,7 which journeyed
south. These items played an essential part in maintaining the economic and political
structures of the states which purchased them, whether in Europe, North Africa, the
6 As noted in Chapter 2, much of the salt imported into West Africa was brought by special caravans
which were not involved in trans-Saharan trade. However, some salt was picked up on the way by
south-bound caravans from North Africa.
7 Foreign trade enabled West Africa to keep abreast of the main European developments in the tech-
niques of warfare. Between the thirteenth and the sixteenth centuries, Tlemcen (in North Africa)
was the main entrepôt for the trade in sword blades, which came mostly from Marseilles, Bordeaux
and Genoa. Guns were certainly present in parts of the Western Sudan before the Moroccan inva-
sion of 1591, for they were used to guard caravans early in the sixteenth century. The military super-
iority which enabled Pizarro to topple the empire of the Incas in 1533 was not achieved with
respect to West Africa until the nineteenth century.
External trade 129
Middle East or West Africa. Gold and cowries were major currencies; slaves formed
a sizeable proportion of the labour force and military strength in certain areas; salt
was a dietary necessity; and military equipment, including cavalry horses, was vital
to the preservation and extension of political power. Second, there were luxury
items, such as expensive cloth, pepper, ivory, kola nuts, leather goods and, in the
nineteenth century, ostrich feathers, which were carried north, and high-quality
textiles (especially those coloured with dyes not available locally), copper, preserved
foodstuffs, glassware, beads and miscellaneous ‘fancy goods’, which were sent south.
A proportion of the slaves exported from West Africa should also be classified as
luxuries, and so should the valuable foreign slaves who were imported into the
Western Sudan and kept in wealthy households mainly for prestige reasons.
Gold and slaves were important enough to require additional comment. The pre-
cise origin of the gold trade is uncertain, but it may date back to Carthaginian times
or even earlier. Exports increased during the eleventh century, following the adoption
of gold coinage throughout the Muslim world, and they received a further boost after
1252, when gold began to replace silver as Europe’s main currency.8 Between the
eleventh and the seventeenth centuries, West Africa was the leading supplier of gold
to the international economy. West African gold flowed to Cairo and the Middle
East, where it helped to sustain Arab power until the end of the thirteenth century,
when the basis of the monetary system changed to silver. African gold contributed to
the functioning of the domestic economy in Europe, and also helped to settle inter-
national debts. In the later Middle Ages, Europe needed bullion to pay for imports
from the Far East because most of her exports were too bulky to be worth transport-
ing such a long distance overland. The Italian merchants of Genoa, Florence and
Venice had a favourable trade balance with North Africa from the end of the twelfth
century, and so were able to import gold. This advantage, together with their geo-
graphical situation, enabled them to become the magnificent brokers of international
trade. Control over the gold trade also assisted the expansion of Portugal and Spain in
the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, when Seville became, for a while, Europe’s ‘cap-
ital of gold’. Finally, the gold trade was important in Africa itself: it assisted the rise of
the ports of North Africa from the end of the twelfth century, and it contributed to
the wealth of the great states of the Western Sudan. On present evidence it would be
unwise to conclude that there was a sharp decline in the trans-Saharan gold trade in
the seventeenth century, even though gold was being sent to Europe by ocean
routes. The overland trade, though greatly reduced, continued in the nineteenth cen-
tury, when new sources of supply had been discovered and other means devised to
settle the accounts of international trade.
With regard to the trade in slaves, it is important to note first of all that human
beings were exported from West Africa long before the rise of the more publicised
Atlantic traffic in the late fifteenth century. The trans-Saharan trade even antedates the
8 R. S. Lopez, ‘Back to Gold, 1252’, Economic History Review, 9, 1956, pp. 219–40; Andrew M. Watson,
‘Back to Gold—and Silver’, Economic History Review, 20, 1967, pp. 1–34.
130 External trade
spread of Islam in the seventh century, though it is unlikely to have been very large
much before then, for in Carthaginian and Roman times demand was modest and
other sources of supply more popular. The expansion of Arab power led to an
increased demand for slaves in North Africa and the Middle East for use as soldiers,
labourers and servants.9 This north-bound trade continued without serious disruption
until the late nineteenth century, and in a clandestine way and on a much reduced
scale it survived well into the twentieth century. The size of the trade is hard to assess.
Mauny has estimated that the trans-Saharan routes may have carried as many as
2 million slaves in each century during the late Middle Ages.10 Lewicki has concluded
that 12 million to 15 million slaves passed through Cairo in the sixteenth century.11
Since the majority came via Algiers and Tripoli, it is likely that a proportion of the
total was sent across the desert from West Africa. These figures are astonishing, for, as
Lewicki himself points out, his estimate for the sixteenth century alone approximates
to that usually suggested for the whole of the Atlantic slave trade! Malowist, however,
feels that Mauny’s figures are exaggerated,12 and Adu Boahen, dealing with the early
nineteenth century, has suggested that only about 10,000 slaves per annum were being
exported north across the Sahara compared with approximately 70,000 being shipped
west by the Atlantic routes.13 Judgement on Lewicki’s claim must await the full publi-
cation of his research. At present, the general assumption is that the trans-Saharan slave
trade was never as important as the Atlantic trade. If this view is to be proved false, it
will also be necessary to explain what happened to such large West African communi-
ties (assuming that they existed), for they appear virtually to have disappeared from
North Africa and the Middle East today.
The expansion of trade, following the introduction of the camel and the subsequent
spread of Islam, led to the development of a complex network of routes across the
desert. Moving from west to east, the most important of these were as follows: Ghana
to Mogador and Fez via Awdaghost; Timbuctu to Mogador and Fez via Teghaza;
Timbuctu to Tunis and Tripoli via Wargla, Ghadames and Ghat; Kano to Tunis and
Tripoli via Agades, Ghat and Ghadames; and Bornu to Tripoli via Bilma and Murzuk.
The most important route in Carthaginian and Roman times was that centred on
Murzuk, the capital of Fezzan, which joined Tripolitania and Egypt with the Niger
bend. In the period following the rise of Islam, the ‘golden road’ from Timbuctu to
Morocco was considered, notably by Bovill, to have been outstanding. However,
other authorities, such as Mauny, Ol’derogge and Adu Boahen, are of the opinion
9 On this subject see the useful articles by Norman R. Bennett, ‘Christian and Negro Slavery in
Eighteenth-Century North Africa’, Journal of African History, 1, 1960, pp. 65–82, and L. Valensi,
‘Esclaves chrétiens et esclaves noirs à Tunis au XVIIIe siècle’, Annales, 22, 1967, pp. 1267–88.
10 Mauny, Tableau géographique, p. 379.
11 Tadeusz Lewicki, ‘Arab Trade in Negro Slaves up to the End of the XVIth Century’, summary of
an unpublished paper in Africana Bulletin, 6, 1967, pp. 109–11.
12 Marian Malowist, ‘Le commerce d’or et d’esclaves au Soudan occidental’, Africana Bulletin, 4, 1966,
p. 60.
13 A. Adu Boahen, Britain, the Sahara, and the Western Sudan, 1788–1861, Oxford, 1964, p. 128.
External trade 131
that no single route achieved permanent dominance, and that there was a progressive
shift of emphasis from western to eastern routes. This interpretation appears to be
more acceptable, though care should be taken not to exaggerate either the rapidity or
the extent of the eastward movement. On this basis it can be said that the road from
ancient Ghana was supreme up to about the thirteenth century; that the routes from
Timbuctu predominated during the time of the empires of Mali and Songhai; and that
those from Kano and Bornu became important from the seventeenth century
onwards, the Kano route attaining particular prominence in the nineteenth century.
The organisational needs of trans-Saharan trade encouraged the development
from very early times of centres which were designed to minimise the difficulties
of desert trade and to increase the efficiency of the distributive system.14 First,
there were the southern termini, such as Timbuctu, Kano and Kukawa. At these
centres, which lay close to the desert, north-bound goods were packed and
loaded, and south-bound goods were transferred and divided among smaller
caravans for redistribution in other parts of West Africa. If camels were the
‘ships or the desert’, then these towns were their ports, and their hinterlands in
the south stretched almost to the coast. Second, there were halting places on the
routes, such as Teghaza, In Salah, Ghat and Agades (until it was replaced by
Iferuan in the nineteenth century). These were desert oases, where camels, food
and fresh water could be obtained. Third, there were points such as Sijilmasa
(until it was destroyed in the late eighteenth century), Tenduf (which replaced
it), Wargla and Ghadames, where caravans travelling north unloaded their goods
and those bound for the south gathered before departure. These places were
located close to the northern fringe of the desert, where provisions could be
bought and guards, guides and camels hired. Finally, there were the great north-
ern termini, such as Mogador, Fez, Algiers, Tunis and Tripoli. These entrepôts
were situated on or near to the North African coast, where sales and shipments
to Europe and the Middle East were arranged.
Trans-Saharan commerce also required specialised and experienced personnel.
It is sometimes said that the trade was dominated by Arab merchants, but this
view needs to be treated with care because pre-colonial writers tended to refer,
inaccurately, to all Muslims as Arabs. At present there is little precise information
about the relative significance of various religious or ethnic groups. Arab mer-
chants, properly defined, were undoubtedly very important, but Berbers, Jews
and West Africans also played a major part in the trade, and on the north coast
European merchants were to be found. Many of the large entrepôts, like ‘free’
ports in the other parts of the world, reserved quarters for foreign merchants,
guaranteed their security and granted them special privileges. Thus, expatriate
firms were present in both North Africa and the Western Sudan long before
14 I should like to acknowledge my debt here to Professor Adu Boahen’s book, Britain, the Sahara, and
the Western Sudan, 1788–1861, Oxford, 1964, which contains a most detailed and reliable study of
the trans-Saharan caravan trade.
20°W 10°W 0° Algiers 10°E 20°E 30°E
Tunis
Tlemcen IFRIQIYA
Fez
Tripoli
MOROCCO
30°N Wargla
Mogador Sijilmasa 30°N
Marrakech EGYPT
TAFILELT Ghadames
Tenduf TUAT
Aujila
In Salah FEZZAN
Murzuk
Taghaza Ghat
Taodeni HOGGAR
20°N Wadan 20°N
Djado
Tadmekka Iferuan
Arawan Bilma NUBIA
Walata Takedda
Timbuctu Agades
Gao AIR
Awdaghost
GHANA GH
ON A KANEM
S
DARFUR
Djenne
Kukawa
Kano BORNU
10°N MALI 10°N
HAUSALAND
0 kilometres 800
0 statute miles 500
10°W 0° 10°E 20°E 30°E
they came to the West Coast. Of the other specialists who made a living out of
trans-Saharan trade, the most important were desert colonists such as the
Tuareg, whose livelihood was based on the camel and on the plunder or control
of the trade routes. The exploitation of the opportunities presented by desert
trade encouraged the development of marked economic and social inequalities
in Tuareg society.15 In the sultanate of Air (on the route north of Kano),
Tuareg clans were divided into two basic groups: the nobles, who controlled
the ownership and use of camels, and their vassals, who were restricted to herd-
ing goats. As early as the fifteenth century, specialisation and the division of
labour had destroyed the pristine ‘democracy of poverty’ in this remote area,
assuming, that is, that it had ever existed.
Long-distance trade, with its considerable capital requirements and slow turn-
over, called for extensive credit facilities and careful investment. In 1825 Laing
observed that the merchants of Ghadames ‘calculate with profound nicety the
expense of carriage to distant countries, duties, customs, risk, trouble, the per-
centage that their goods will bear, and even do business by means of Bills and
unwritten agreements or promises’.16 It is interesting to note that business
arrangements, which were very similar to the better-known and much-criticised
‘trust system’ of West Coast trade, also operated in trans-Saharan commerce, and
for the same reasons.17 The need to mobilise capital and credit on a large scale
was a barrier which tended to favour large firms in Timbuctu as in Whydah. It
is likely that historians of Islam in Africa will soon add to their important work
on religious and political matters by investigating the little-known merchant
princes of the caravan trade.
Clearly, the Sahara was not, as once used to be thought, an impenetrable bar-
rier isolating West Africa from the rest of the world. On the contrary, by a feat
of daring the more impressive because it was repeated annually over many cen-
turies, African and other merchants succeeded in creating an overland trade
which, in size and organisation, deserves to rank with the most famous achieve-
ments of merchant venturers in the era before industrialisation removed the
physical hardship from international commerce.18 The desert crossing was
extremely dangerous, and could be made only at certain times of the year. The
traveller had to be prepared to risk sandstorms, lack of water, sharp variations in
temperature (from day to night) and attacks from armed marauders. If he was
15 Johannes Nicholaisen, ‘Political Systems of Pastoral Tuareg in Air and Ahaggar’, Folk, 1, 1959, pp.
67–131, and ‘Ecological and Historical Factors: A Case Study from the Ahaggar Tuareg’, Folk, 6,
1964, pp. 75–81.
16 Quoted in Adu Boahen, Britain, the Sahara, p, 113.
17 These arrangements were to be found in other parts of the world too. See, for example,
E. S. Crawcour, ‘The Development of a Credit System in Seventeenth-Century Japan’, Journal of
Economic History, 21, 1961, pp. 342–60.
18 For purposes of comparison, see Owen Lattimore’s essay ‘Caravan Routes of Inner Asia’, in his
Studies in Frontier History, London, 1962, pp. 37–72.
134 External trade
19 Ibn Battuta, Travels in Asia and Africa, 1325–1354, translated and selected by H. A. R. Gibb,
London, 1927, p. 318.
20 Though whether the African quest was undertaken by a Portuguese nobility anxious to rescue its
declining fortunes, or whether it was wealth won from the trans-Saharan gold trade which encour-
aged an expanding Iberia to expand even further, is a matter which must be left for historians of
Europe to decide.
21 Richard Jobson, The Golden Trade or the Discovery of the River Gambra, London, p. 112.
22 For further details see Marian Malowist, ‘Les fondements de l’expansion européenne en Afrique au
XVe siècle: Europe, Maghreb et Soudan occidentale’, Acta Poloniae Historica, 18, 1968, pp. 156–79.
External trade 135
Before the rise of legitimate commerce in the nineteenth century, the main
exports from West Africa, apart from slaves, were gold, ivory, timber, dye-
woods, gum, beeswax, leather and spices, notably peppers. These commodities
sometimes supplemented the trade in slaves, but they were also treated as viable
exports in their own right. Initially, the main aim of the European merchant
mariners was to gain control of the gold resources of West Africa. Hence some
of the earliest and busiest coastal bases were in Senegal and the Gold Coast,
close to the main centres of mining activity. In addition to their keen interest in
minerals, the Europeans paid some attention to the agricultural resources of the
continent.23 An attempt was made to use West African products as substitutes
for those from Asia, whose exports to Europe had fallen under Muslim control
in the later part of the Middle Ages. It was for this reason that the Portuguese
began to ship pepper from Benin in the fifteenth century. From the sixteenth
century onwards, efforts were made to develop the production of crops such as
sugar, cotton and tobacco. These ventures anticipated experiments which were
to be tried again, and on a greater scale, in the nineteenth century, but which
meanwhile were to achieve much greater success in the West Indies and North
America.
Even after the Atlantic slave trade had become well established, some parts of
West Africa, particularly areas west of the Volta River, continued to conduct an
important export trade in other commodities. Detailed information about the
size and value of this commerce is hard to find at present, though according to
one estimate about two-fifths of the income of the Royal African Company at
the end of the seventeenth century came from sales of goods other than slaves.24
Gold was by far the most valuable of these products, and was still the principal
overseas export of the Gold Coast at that time, even though the region had also
become a major supplier of slaves. It was only in the latter part of the eighteenth
century that the situation changed, and Gold Coast exporters then sold slaves to
European merchants in exchange for gold. Further west still, in Sierra Leone,
exports such as camwood, ivory and beeswax were worth more than shipments
of slaves until at least the middle of the eighteenth century. Another prominent
example of an area where trade in natural products was of considerable import-
ance was Senegambia, which developed initially as a centre for the gold trade.
Later on, slaves were exported, but significant quantities of other goods were
handled as well, as Abdoulaye Ly has made clear.25 Gum was the major export
from the Senegal Valley and the Mauritanian coast in the seventeenth and eight-
eenth centuries,26 and beeswax was as important as slaves in the overseas trade
23 Marian Malowist, ‘Les debuts du système de plantations dans la période des Grandes Découvertes’,
Africana Bulletin, 10, 1969, pp. 9–30.
24 K. G. Davies, The Royal African Company, London, 1957, pp. 179–80.
25 Abdoulaye Ly, La compagnie du Sénégal, Paris, 1958.
26 This question has been dealt with by André Delcourt, La France et les établissements français au Sénégal
entre 1713 et 1763, Dakar, 1952.
136 External trade
of Casamance (southern Senegal) during the same period. Both products had
pharmaceutical and industrial uses, gum being especially significant as a raw
material in the manufacture of textiles. It is interesting to note that Europeans
sometimes acted as middlemen in African interregional trade, employing their
ships to expand existing local markets and occasionally to create markets where
none existed before. In the fifteenth century, for example, the Portuguese
exported slaves from Benin and sold them on the Gold Coast for gold. Two cen-
turies later they were using kola nuts from Sierra Leone to buy slaves in Senegam-
bia. In the seventeenth century, too, the Dutch shipped cloth and beads from
Benin to the Gold Coast, and in the eighteenth century Bristol slavers bought and
sold rice, guinea corn, millet and yams as they made their way along the coast.
It is worth summarising the comments made so far, as they have often been
underplayed in the past,27 and they need to be borne in mind during the discus-
sion of the Atlantic slave trade which follows. The Europeans who came to
West Africa in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries were interested mainly in
goods other than slaves. This commerce continued even after the overseas slave
trade was well under way. There were marked regional differences in West
Africa depending on the nature of trade with the Europeans. European shipping
services encouraged the growth of a new kind of long-distance coastal trade in
West Africa. It may be useful to point out that further research is needed into
the subject of trade in non-slave products. Future work will undoubtedly lead to
a more varied view of what is now considered as the era of the Atlantic slave
trade, and it will also modify the way historians interpret developments in the
nineteenth century, when an export economy based entirely on ‘legitimate’
goods was created.
The Atlantic slave trade is perhaps the most discussed episode in the economic
history of West Africa and is certainly the only one known to that notional
being, the general reader. Unfortunately, most of the popular books which
appear regularly on this subject, though they may succeed in giving the more
dramatic aspects appropriately epic treatment, rarely contribute anything new in
the way of facts or ideas. Few make full use of the available secondary sources,
and some perpetuate old-fashioned views of Africa among a reading public
which, understandably, is not in touch with the latest developments in African
studies.28 Age and repetition have combined to entrench both myths and truths
to such an extent that it is hard now to tell one from the other. Fortunately,
some valuable studies of particular aspects of the Atlantic slave trade have been
carried out recently, and it is certain that this subject will look very different in
a few years’ time. In the pages which follow an attempt will be made to
27 An important exception is the study by Walter Rodney, A History of the Upper Guinea Coast,
1545–1800, Oxford, 1970, Ch. 6.
28 An outstanding exception to these critical generalisations is Basil Davidson’s, Black Mother, London,
1961, though inevitably this book has been overtaken to some extent by research carried out
during the last ten years.
External trade 137
summarise and comment on the main themes as they appear at present, and to
explore a few of the problems which, hopefully, future research will reveal as
significant. The discussion will begin by briefly outlining the main sources of
demand for labour and will then consider how the supply of slaves was organ-
ised, dealing first with the European side of the trade, and second with the situ-
ation on the West Coast itself. No apology is made for mentioning regions
other than Africa, for the slave trade cannot be understood without reference to
the international setting within which it grew, flourished and declined.
Some Africans had been bought by Europeans from the beginning of their
contact with the West Coast in the fifteenth century, notwithstanding Jobson’s
lofty indifference towards this type of commerce. In the sixteenth century a few
slaves were used by the Portuguese to work sugar plantations on islands just off
the coast of West Africa, and others were exported to South America to mine
the silver which was discovered there in the 1520s. However, the demand for
slave labour was not very great at this time, and the export trade was unimport-
ant. The rapid expansion of the Atlantic trade began only in the middle of the
seventeenth century, as a result of the rise of sugar plantations in the West
Indies.29 This development revolutionised the economy of the Caribbean. Until
about the 1650s, the main export from the West Indies had been tobacco,
which was grown on a small scale by a few European settlers.30 Sugar, however,
was pre-eminently a planters’ crop, and it required land, capital and labour on
a large scale. The land was there already; the capital came from Europe; and, in
the event, the labour came from Africa, not because the continent was over-
populated, but because no other cheaper source of suitable manpower was read-
ily available. The indigenous inhabitants of the Americas had been tried and
found wanting, and many of the European pioneers on this particular frontier of
the New World chose to cultivate land for themselves elsewhere, especially in
Virginia and Carolina, where tobacco was becoming an important export crop.
To retain a free labour force where there was abundant land and alternative
employment opportunities would have meant paying high wages. Cheap and
subservient labour was preferred and was probably essential. Besides being rela-
tively inexpensive and readily available (thanks to the efficiency of the Afro-
European delivery system), African labourers had a higher survival rate in the
West Indies, and therefore had a cost advantage over potential competitors in
the labour market. The advantage was a result of their greater immunity from
diseases such as yellow fever and malaria, and had nothing to do with the alleged
inability of the white man to work in a tropical climate.31 And so the venturers
29 D. A. Farnie, ‘The Commercial Empire of the Atlantic, 1607–1783’, Economic History Review, 15,
1962, pp. 205–18.
30 A. P. Thornton, ‘The Organization of the Slave Trade in the English West Indies, 1660–1685’,
William and Mary Quarterly, 12, 1955, pp. 399–409.
31 This point has been elaborated by Philip D. Curtin, ‘Epidemiology and the Slave Trade’, Political
Science Quarterly, 83, 1968, pp. 190–216.
138 External trade
who had originally sailed to West Africa primarily to trade in gold stayed on to
supply labourers for the new sugar plantations of the Caribbean.
The eighteenth century was the golden age of prosperity for the West Indies,
the time when the Islands became the chief suppliers of sugar to Europe. The
leading centres of production were Jamaica, a British possession, and St Dom-
ingo, which belonged to France. According to Sheridan, about two-thirds of all
the slaves shipped to the Caribbean worked on sugar plantations, and in the
highly specialised economy of Jamaica no less than 84 per cent of the slaves
(160,000 out of 190,000) were employed in the sugar industry in the 1770s.32
Other crops, such as coffee, cotton, indigo and tobacco, were grown, but sugar
remained by far the most important export. The expansion of sugar production
was stimulated by a rise in demand in Europe following an increase in the con-
sumption of tea and coffee; by a growth in the capacity of the sugar processing
industry, which had caught up with supply by about the middle of the eight-
eenth century; and by government support, which underpinned the structure of
Atlantic trade. From 1651 to 1854, for example, producers in the British col-
onies in the West Indies were protected by the imposition of heavy duties on
foreign sugar entering the United Kingdom. In the second half of the eighteenth
century, the French government offered bounties to slave ships leaving France
for Africa and made an additional payment for every slave they landed in the
French West Indies. This concern is understandable when it is realised that by
1789 about two-thirds of French maritime exports went to her colonies in the
West Indies, and that sugar was the most valuable commodity sent to France
from overseas. Sugar was also the largest single item imported into England in
the eighteenth century. The average annual value of sugar imports rose nearly
four times from £630,000 sterling in the period 1699–1701 to £2,364,000 in the
period 1772–74. Between 1714 and 1773, imports from the West Indies aver-
aged about 20 per cent of the annual value of all imports into England. Com-
mercially, the Caribbean had become more important to England than Asia and
was second only to trade with Europe. To Malachi Postlethwayt, a spokesman of
mercantilist orthodoxy, the British Empire was a ‘magnificent superstructure of
American commerce and naval power on an African foundation’.33 His summary
cannot be bettered.
The importance of the various Western powers engaged in trade with Africa
was largely a reflection of their changing political positions in Europe.34 Portugal
was the leading foreign power in West Africa in the fifteenth and sixteenth cen-
turies; the Dutch presence became significant in the seventeenth century; and
32 R. B. Sheridan, ‘The Commercial and Financial Organization of the British Slave Trade,
1750–1807’, Economic History Review, 11, 1958, p. 249, and ‘The Wealth of Jamaica in the Eight-
eenth Century: A Rejoinder’, Economic History Review, 21, 1968, p. 49.
33 Quoted in Eric Williams, Capitalism and Slavery, 2nd ed., London, 1964, p. 52.
34 Further information about the political rivalries of the great powers in West Africa can be found in
J. D. Fage, A History of West Africa, London, 1969, Chs 3 and 4.
External trade 139
England and France dominated the eighteenth century. One useful index of the
relative positions of the major powers is provided by the number of slaves han-
dled by each at the height of the Atlantic trade.35
Slave exports from West Africa by the three major powers, 1701–1810
England 2,009,700
France 613,100
Portugal 611,000
3,233,800
England’s supremacy is clearly demonstrated: she alone was responsible for about
two-thirds of the total number of slaves shipped by the three leading powers. Her
pre-eminence in West Africa was one striking illustration of the more general
growth of her foreign trade in the eighteenth century, and of the global dominance
of her navy. Britain’s ascendancy was not seriously challenged until the close of the
nineteenth century, when French troops began their long, dusty march across what
Lord Salisbury was to refer to, ironically, as the ‘light’ soils of the Western Sudan. It
is sometimes said that French power in West Africa deteriorated in the second half
of the eighteenth century. However, it is important to realise that England’s
supremacy was the result of the relatively fast pace of her commercial expansion and
was not brought about by an absolute decline in French commerce with West
Africa, though France still relied on Holland and Britain for many of her trade
goods. Indeed, the tempo of French activity in this part of the world actually
increased after 1763, following Choiseul’s efforts to develop Africa to compensate
for the loss of Canada, and to free the French West Indies from dependence on
British ships for supplies of slaves. The position of the Portuguese is especially note-
worthy. Far from declining in the early seventeenth century, as is commonly sup-
posed to be the case, their commercial hold remained strong long afterwards.
Admittedly, Portugal’s share of slave shipments declined as the eighteenth century
progressed, but it revived again during the first half of the nineteenth century, when
the trade entered its final, and far from negligible, phase.
Before the nineteenth century the European powers were represented in
West Africa by large, state-chartered companies and by individual traders rather
than by regular soldiers and professional administrators. Chartered companies
were prominent during the early phase of sea-borne trade with West Africa, and
especially during the seventeenth century. These companies were given trading
monopolies over various sections of the African coast in return for fulfilling cer-
tain obligations. In the Netherlands the leading officially sponsored firm was the
Dutch West India Company (1621), which, besides having interests in the
35 Philip D. Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade: A Census, Madison, 1969, p. 211.
140 External trade
Caribbean, was also active along the West African coast during the seventeenth
century. The most important French companies were the Compagnie des Indes
Occidentales (1664), founded by Colbert on ideas formulated by Richelieu, the
Compagnie du Sénégal (1673) and the Compagnie du Guinée (1684). The prin-
cipal English concern was the Royal African Company (1672), which succeeded the
aptly named and unbusiness-like Royal Adventurers into Africa (1660). The presence
of joint-stock companies in some branches of foreign commerce was mainly a result
of the desire of subscribers to share the risks of African trade, which was notorious for
its uncertainty, though in part it was also a response to the capital requirements of
long-distance trade, especially the need to invest in fixed capital, such as forts and
ships. The state issued charters because it saw the companies as useful agents of for-
eign policy, and, hopefully, as a means of enriching the rulers too. The promoters
sought government patronage as a means of attracting capital and eliminating compe-
tition. Interdependence was the basis of mercantilism: the power of the state was
increased by measures designed to achieve a favourable balance of trade; at the same
time particular interest groups sought to use state power as a means to private gain.36
In the context of the international rivalries of the seventeenth century, the chartered
companies can be seen as protagonists in the struggle between conflicting national,
mercantilist policies which aimed at controlling not only African trade, but the com-
merce of the Atlantic, and, ultimately, of Europe.
The chartered companies were more impressive in their plans than in their
achievements. It is clear from the specialist works of Davies, Delcourt and Ly
that the companies shared much the same defects. They were unable to attract
sufficient capital. French merchants were traditionally wary of putting their
money into government companies, which consequently required subsidies from
public and court funds. English merchants were more prepared to invest in char-
tered companies, but they rarely acquired large holdings and were quick to
switch their money to alternative uses if more profitable opportunities arose.
The companies had large overheads in the shape of officials and forts, and they
sometimes had to carry extensive burdens of defence. They were unable to
secure staff of sufficient quality, and their employees also failed to identify their
interests with those of the firm, with the result that mismanagement and private
trading by company servants seriously hindered the efficient conduct of business.
Moreover, the companies were required to meet specific obligations, such as
supplying a fixed number of slaves each year, and so had to continue trading
irrespective of the conditions operating at the time. It was this problem which
led the Compagnie du Sénégal into difficulties after 1679. In addition, the com-
panies were under attack from a variety of interests which opposed their mon-
opoly powers. These included traders who were kept out of the areas under the
jurisdiction of the companies; manufacturers, who were dissatisfied with
36 Charles Wilson, Profit and Power: A Study of England and the Dutch Wars, London, 1957, p. 153. On
mercantilism, see D. C. Coleman, ed., Revisions in Mercantilism, London, 1969.
External trade 141
restricted outlets for their goods; colonists (especially in the West Indies), who
objected to the terms on which they exchanged their products for consumer
imports; and the political opponents of monarchical power, who saw the char-
tered companies as symbols of the royal prerogative. By about 1700 it was clear
that the chartered company, though not yet eliminated, had little future in West
African trade. Financially, the chartered companies were failures. They were
asked to perform the most difficult of all commercial feats, the reconciliation of
the capitalist ethic with public duty, an expectation which survives today only
in certain nationalised industries. Their main achievements were as frontier
agencies of the old colonial system, opening up markets which others were to
exploit more effectively later on.
It used to be customary for historians to contrast the mercantilist restrictions
of the seventeenth century with the development of free trade in the eighteenth
century. This interpretation can no longer stand without qualification. It is true
that the monopoly powers of the chartered companies were dismantled during
the course of the eighteenth century, but the process was a gradual one, and
most of the companies managed to struggle on until about the middle of the
century or even later. At the same time, it should be noted that, in practice,
private traders had played an important part in West African trade even in the
seventeenth century. From the outset the companies had been unable to make
exclusive use of their monopoly powers. They had found it necessary to issue
‘passports’ or licences to private traders, and they had also been forced to tolerate
interlopers, who traded in their territories without permission. In more general
terms, it would be quite wrong to equate the decline of the chartered companies
with the rise of free trade, at least in the sense that this concept came to be used
in the nineteenth century. It has been shown that the eighteenth century saw
a marked increase in high-level duties on goods imported into England, and that
this change in the tariff structure had the effect of protecting domestic
manufactures.37 Whether they realised it or not, at the close of the eighteenth
century Adam Smith and his disciples were attacking a comparatively recent
development in commercial policy, and not a tariff structure inherited from the
era of mercantilism.
The shift to free trade was therefore somewhat limited. As far as West African
commerce was concerned, it took the form of a relative increase in the import-
ance of private traders and a relative decline in the position of the chartered
companies. This change was not the outcome of a mighty confrontation
between conflicting economic philosophies but was made for practical business
reasons. The chartered companies, which had not been successful even in the
conditions of the seventeenth century, were quite unable to cope with the
expanded scale of the slave trade in the eighteenth century. The private traders
37 Ralph Davis, ‘The Rise of Protection in England, 1689–1786’, Economic History Review, 19, 1966,
pp. 306–17.
142 External trade
prospered because they had smaller overhead costs (a lower ratio of staff to turn-
over and less money tied up in overseas bases); they enjoyed a much greater
degree of personal supervision on the West Coast, which meant they could
respond more quickly to changing circumstances; and they were unhampered by
public obligations and government directives, and so could trade when, where
and on what terms they chose.
The success of the private traders was to be seen in the spectacular rise of the
two greatest European centres of the slave trade, Liverpool and Nantes. In the
eighteenth century English ships carried about two-thirds of the total number of
slaves sent across the Atlantic from West Africa, and French ships roughly one-
fifth of the total. Liverpool and Nantes each accounted for no less than half of
these national totals and sometimes considerably more. In view of the marked
concentration of trade on these two ports it is worthwhile saying a little more
about them, especially since Liverpool’s role in the Atlantic slave trade has been
curiously neglected by modern scholars (the most recent study being an unpub-
lished and little used M.A. thesis),38 while the part played by Nantes, though
well covered by the researches of Gaston Martin, Jean Meyer and Père
Rinchon, is usually by-passed in works by English historians.39
By 1712 the Royal African Company was in an advanced state of decay, and
London, the headquarters of the company and the main English slave port in
the seventeenth century, was fast losing control of the African trade. Bristol,
which began slave trading in the 1690s, was the chief beneficiary of the decline
of her rival, but her own supremacy lasted for only three decades, reaching
a peak between 1725 and 1735.40 Liverpool’s participation in the slave trade also
began in the late seventeenth century, but it was not until the 1730s that her
involvement became significant. Within ten years Liverpool had become the
leading slave-trading port in Europe, a position which she retained until 1807,
when it became illegal for British subjects to engage in the African slave trade.
By 1750 Liverpool’s ships were carrying over half the slaves exported from
Africa in English vessels, and from then on the trade expanded until the Ameri-
can War of Independence (1776–83), which struck the port a hard blow. In
1779 only 11 ships left Liverpool for Africa, which figure was the lowest in the
history of the trade (1730–1807). With the conclusion of peace there was
a revival of trade: in the 1790s Liverpool’s merchantmen were transporting
between 25,000 and 50,000 slaves across the Atlantic each year, which was
38 J. E. Merritt, The Liverpool Slave Trade from 1789 to 1791, University of Nottingham M.A. thesis,
1959.
39 Gaston Martin, Nantes au XVIIIe siècle: l’ère des négriers (1714–1744), Paris, 1931; Jean Meyer, ‘Le
commerce négrier nantais (1774–1792)’, Annales, 15, 1960, pp. 120–9; and Père D. Rinchon,
Pierre-Ignace-Liévin van Alstein, capitaine négrier, Dakar, 1964. Other work on Nantes by Meyer and
Rinchon, and by Everaert and Maugat is listed in the Bibliography.
40 Bristol’s role in the slave trade has been well covered by P. D. Richardson, The Bristol Slave Trade
in the Eighteenth Century, University of Manchester, M.A. thesis, 1969.
External trade 143
41 Lower wages may also have reflected a difference in the supply price of labour in the two regions.
144 External trade
42 Information about these ports can be found in the following works, all of which deserve to receive
more attention from historians of Africa: J. Cl. Bénard, ‘L’armement honfleurais et le commerce
External trade 145
des esclaves à la fin du XVIIIe siècle’, Annales de Normandie, 10, 1960, pp. 249–64; Pierre Dardel,
Navires et marchandises dans les ports de Rouen et du Havre au XVIIIe siècle, Paris, 1963; G. Rambert,
Histoire du commerce de Marseilles, 6, de 1660 à 1789, les colonies, Paris, 1959; and H. Robert, ‘Les
trafics coloniaux du port de La Rochelle au XVIIIe siècle’, Mèmoires de la Société des Antiquaires de
l’Ouest, 4, 1960, pp. xii–211.
146 External trade
savings, past profits, local credit and—in the case of the French port—capital
from Paris. In the middle years of the century the slave trade was concentrated
in a few hands. Scarcely 50 merchants were engaged extensively in the trade,
and three families alone were responsible for financing over half the vessels leav-
ing Nantes on slaving expeditions. However, in the second half of the century
there was a movement away from specialisation, and the pattern became one of
a larger number of merchants equipping proportionately fewer slaving ventures.
This trend was partly a result of the Seven Years War (1756–63), which greatly
increased the risks of the trade, and partly a reflection of the reorientation of
commerce at Nantes towards the close of the century, when slaving became just
one aspect of a merchant’s business rather than his sole concern.
Research into the organisation of Europe’s overseas trade in the eighteenth
century has led to a revival of interest in the routes followed by slave ships. His-
torians of Africa have not shown much awareness of the debate on this subject
and have tended to adhere to the traditional notion of the triangular trade, as
established in the earliest textbooks of imperial history. According to the con-
ventional view, the African trade was organised in three stages, in which vessels
left Europe for the West Coast to sell consumer goods and to buy slaves, then
sailed to the West Indies to exchange slaves for sugar, and finally returned home
to dispose of sugar and to settle their accounts. The accuracy of this description
has been questioned, and it has been suggested that the triangular trade existed
only in the early days of the Atlantic slave trade, when relatively little sugar was
being sent to Europe, and that for the greater part of the eighteenth century
slaves and sugar were two distinct trades.43 This suggestion has encouraged his-
torians to re-examine the conventional approach, which certainly oversimplifies
reality. At the same time, however, the revised interpretation cannot be accepted
as it stands because it rests on a set of prima facie arguments rather than on empir-
ical evidence.
The view adopted here is that Merritt and others are mistaken in claiming
that the triangular trade was exceptional in the eighteenth century but correct in
implying that it was far from being the only, or always the most important,
means of conducting Atlantic commerce. Evidence from Bristol, Nantes and
Honfleur, in particular, shows that the classical triangular trade was still quite
normal in the eighteenth century. It is equally clear that the transportation of
slaves and sugar cannot be understood simply in terms of the triangular trade
alone. A number of direct routes were very important, though they have rarely
been sufficiently emphasised. A direct route between Europe and Africa was fol-
lowed by ships trading in non-slave products, notably gold and gum. In add-
ition, there were direct routes to the West Coast across the Atlantic from North
America, the West Indies and Brazil, which were used by colonists trading rum
43 J. E. Merritt, ‘The Triangular Trade’, Business History, 3, 1960, pp. 1–7, provides a summary of
views expressed earlier by other writers.
External trade 147
and tobacco for slaves.44 Finally, there was a very busy route between Europe
and the West Indies. This was used by fleets of merchantmen, which came from
Europe with supplies for the Islands, and returned home carrying a substantial
proportion of the sugar crop. The volume of traffic on this route is indicated by
the fact that, in 1789, 116 ships left English ports for Africa, whereas no fewer
than 449 left for the West Indies. Liverpool, which was dominant in the slave
trade, had roughly equal shares with London and Bristol in the sugar trade.
Nantes was the chief importer of sugar into France, but several other ports,
including Rouen, Le Havre, Marseilles and St Malo, conducted a considerable
direct trade with the Caribbean. In the case of St Malo, Le Corre has estimated
that for every ship engaged in the triangular trade in the late seventeenth cen-
tury, 50 went straight to the West Indies.45
Whether a vessel returned home from the West Indies with ballast or sugar
was a decision which, from the slaver’s point of view, depended largely on the
availability and price of produce. At the same time, there were good reasons
why an additional, specialised fleet was required to carry sugar on the last leg
of the triangular voyage. Slave ships were not entirely adequate as transporters
of tropical produce. They were not built to carry hogsheads of sugar; they
were often in an unseaworthy condition when they reached the Caribbean;
the irregularity of their arrival meant that planters could not be certain of
evacuating their crop at the right time; and, perhaps most important of all, the
expansion of the sugar industry set up a demand for freight which exceeded
the physical capacity of the ships arriving from Africa. By the middle of the
eighteenth century, too, the increasing use of bills of exchange enabled
accounts to be settled quickly, and made the exchange of sugar for slaves less
of a necessity.46 There is some evidence that the slave traders put up the price
of slaves to compensate for returning in ballast, but they also gained from the
new arrangement to the extent that payment in bills enabled them to make
a faster turnaround. The development of close ties between planters and
metropolitan sugar merchants during the eighteenth century tended to
reinforce direct trading links, with the result that captains of slave ships often
found that the planters had made alternative arrangements for shipping produce
to Europe. Increasing specialisation in the slave and sugar trades lowered the
investment requirements for entry into Atlantic commerce, reduced the risks
of trade and speeded the turnover of capital, since the direct trip to the Carib-
bean could be completed in about six months, whereas the triangular trade
took a year or even longer. It was for these reasons that the merchants of
44 On the latter see Pierre Verger, ‘Mouvements de navires entre Bahia et le golfe de Bénin (XVIIIe–
XIXe siècles)’, Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 55, 1968, pp. 5–36.
45 A. Le Corre, ‘Le grand commerce malouin en 1686–1687’, Annales de Bretagne, 3, 1958, pp.
275–331.
46 On the use of bills of exchange in Atlantic commerce, see S. G. Checkland, ‘Finance for the West
Indies, 1780–1815’, Economic History Review, 10, 1958, pp. 461–469.
148 External trade
47 Philip D. Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade: A Census, Madison, 1969. But for the timely publication
of Curtin’s book, the present writer would also be counted among the unquestioning majority.
48 Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade, p. 86.
49 Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade, p. 87.
50 Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade, p. 268
120° 100° 80° 60° 40° 20° 0° 20° 40° 60° 80° 100°
ool ondon
erp
Liv istol L
Br s
nte
Na eaux illes
r d e
Boston Bo Mars
40°
New York Toba c c o ds
Ru in Lisbon
m .W Tob
W ac s
S. co tu re
Charleston tton
s
Manufac
Go
Co
r
ld
od
ga
d go
Rum
Su
Cuba St.
re
20°
tu
Domingo
ac
Gum
uf al
Jamaica an ds
M in Se
neg one
M a nu
.W a Le st
.E rr a t st st
fac
Sie
t
Ivo N a i n Co oas oa Coa s
C C
ur
e er
e
ry s Gr vory Gold Slav Riv
I l
Timb Oi
S er 0°
la
ve
co
s
b ac es
es To Slav
av Slaves Luanda
Sl
Benguela
Bahia
ves
Rio de Janeiro S.
E. 20°
S la
Tobacco W
in
ds
0 kilometres 3200
W. Winds Cape Town
0 Statute Miles 2000
These lower totals are consistent with the emphasis given in this chapter to
trade in products other than slaves, and they confirm that the boom in slave
exports coincided with the expansion of sugar production in the Caribbean
during the eighteenth century. No less than 80 per cent of all slaves landed in
the New World were transported between 1701 and 1850. The figures for the
nineteenth century demonstrate that the slave trade remained significant even
after it had been outlawed by Britain, the greatest slave-trading nation, a point
which the imperial school of history, with its emphasis on Wilberforce’s triumph
in 1807, never really explained.
With regard to areas of supply, Curtins figures indicate that rather more slaves
were exported from places south of the Cameroons, especially the Congo and
Angola, than is customarily assumed. A calculation made on the basis of Curtin’s
data suggests that about 6,300,000 slaves (55 per cent of the total shipped across
the Atlantic from Africa) came from West Africa.51 Slaves were not exported in
identical proportions from all parts of the West Coast. Indeed, in the eighteenth
century the region between Senegal and the Ivory Coast played a relatively
unimportant part in the Atlantic slave trade, and the principal area of export was
the shorter stretch of coast running from the Gold Coast east to the Cameroons.
In the 1780s, when the Atlantic trade was at its peak, annual exports from vari-
ous sections of the coast were as follows:
From these figures it can be seen that the area from the Gold Coast to the
Cameroons accounted for 82 per cent of all slaves shipped from West Africa at
this time. The region west of the Gold Coast may have been rather more prom-
inent in the early days of the trade, but it should also be remembered that far
fewer slaves were exported before 1700 than later. There were successive shifts
of emphasis within the major regions of supply. Thus, the slave trade tended to
spread eastwards from the Gold Coast after the middle of the seventeenth cen-
tury, with the result that by 1800 the most important section of the coast was
the sub-division from Benin to the Cameroons. The Atlantic slave trade pro-
vides further evidence of regional economic differences in West Africa during
the pre-colonial era.
Figures relating to the destinations of slaves shipped across the Atlantic confirm
that the Caribbean and South America were the two leading reception areas.52
However, the extent of the dominance of the Caribbean and South America
has not been appreciated: these areas between them accounted for 91 per cent
of all slaves shipped across the Atlantic, the leading importers being Brazil, Haiti,
Jamaica and Cuba. North America, notwithstanding its current racial problems,
received less than 7 per cent of the total.
The Atlantic slave trade remains one of the greatest migrations of all time.
However, it is clear that many of the generalisations commonly made about this
controversial phase of African history will need to be reassessed in the light of
Curtin’s evidence. His research is bound to stimulate a lively debate; it is to be
hoped that it will also be a profitable one.
The production, or, more accurately, the harvesting of slaves was one of the
biggest commercial ventures launched in Africa during the pre-colonial era.
Unfortunately, detailed information about this appalling form of business enter-
prise is lacking at present, and as yet little attention has been paid to the eco-
nomics of the slave-producing firm. Many of the remarks which follow are
deliberately speculative and are designed to prompt others to consider this sub-
ject at greater length than is possible here.
To begin with, little is known about the geographical and social origins of
the slaves shipped from Africa. The few pioneering attempts to grapple with
the former problem have confirmed the broad regional divisions noted earlier,
and have stressed the impossibility of generalising further at this stage.53 For
the moment, all that can be said is that the sources of supply included well-
populated regions in the immediate hinterland of the ports of shipment, and
sparsely populated areas located far from the major centres of trade. The
importance of the latter may well have been exaggerated in the past, for
a study has shown that in one prominent case the sparseness of the population
was the result not so much of slave raiding as of the general inhospitality of
the environment.54 It is probable that the relative significance of both types of
catchment area changed through time, as it seems likely that their initial selec-
tion was related to features such as the size, distribution and defensive capabil-
ity of the population, which were bound to alter. It is even possible that major
producers established a regional cycle of exploitation, in much the same way as
farmers alternate arable and fallow land, though this suggestion may exaggerate
the extent to which slaving was an operation amenable to long-term ‘develop-
ment’ planning.
As to the social origins of the Africans shipped across the Atlantic, it used to
be thought that the Europeans simply drew on an existing pool of slave labour
in Africa. Originally, this interpretation appears to have gained currency as
a half-hearted justification of the slave trade, the argument being that, if slaves
were already present in Africa, it was not quite so wicked merely to transfer
them to another continent. This view appears to imply that Africans kept pad-
docks full of slaves in the fourteenth century in the hope that one day the West
Coast would be discovered by the Europeans, who would then purchase this
carefully accumulated and superfluous labour force. However, Walter Rodney’s
study of the Upper Guinea coast has shown that there was no servile class
simply waiting to be exported,55 and work carried out on the more important
slave-exporting area east of the Ivory Coast tends to support this view. Admit-
tedly, there were various economically and socially subordinate groups, includ-
ing slaves, in many West African societies long before the coming of the
Europeans, but these developed, as was shown in Chapter 2, in response to local
needs and were not surplus to domestic requirements. With the advent of the
Europeans, members of these groups may well have been among the first to be
sold, though of course this would have happened only if the profit on their sale
abroad exceeded their value to their owners or employers in Africa. As the trade
expanded, however, it became necessary to secure a massive increase in the
numbers of slaves and other saleable subordinates. The indigenous rulers then set
about creating a class of unfree Africans, with the result that by the close of the
eighteenth century there was indeed a servile group which was more numerous
and more closely defined than in the sixteenth century. It seems reasonable to
suppose that the bulk of the 11 million people shipped from Africa were not
members of an established slave population, but ordinary farmers and their fam-
ilies, who were deprived of their liberty by fellow Africans in response to exter-
nal demand.
54 Michael Mason, ‘Population Density and “Slave Raiding”: The Case of the Middle Belt of
Nigeria’, Journal of African History, 10, 1969, pp. 551–64. See also the further discussion
by M. B. Gleave and R. M. Prothero, ‘Population Density and “Slave Raiding”: A Comment’,
Journal of African History, 12, 1971, pp. 319–24, and Mason’s reply, ibid, pp. 324–7.
55 Walter Rodney, A History of the Upper Guinea Coast, 1545 to 1800, Oxford, 1970.
External trade 153
There were various ways of securing slaves, including raiding, warfare, col-
lecting tribute, kidnapping, purchasing and disposing of criminals, real and
alleged. It appears that the majority of slaves were gathered through raids, war-
fare and tribute, all methods which impinged on other societies. Raiding and
warfare were effective means of direct action, while tribute was a type of extor-
tion used by a dominant power to secure a specified number of slaves from
a satellite state or village. The methods employed by the latter varied, but usu-
ally included raiding. By the standards of the time, slave raiding and trading
were operations which required considerable labour and capital, and so tended
to be financed and directed by a few, substantial entrepreneurs who concen-
trated their efforts in carefully planned drives. As Barbot noted in the late seven-
teenth century, slaving was ‘the business of kings, rich men, and prime
merchants, exclusive of the inferior sort of blacks’.56 Labour was needed to
assemble a band of raiders, and capital to pay for equipment, guides, agents, tolls
and for the maintenance of retainers and captives. Moreover, a slave was indivis-
ible, and his value was such that transactions were handled by large dealers, and
not by petty traders. Firms which were only just big enough to overcome these
barriers can be thought of as marginal; they had no reserves for dealing with
unforeseen circumstances, and they were more likely to be liquidated. Once the
minimum conditions for entry had been met, the optimum size of the firm
could vary to some extent according to the number of slaves required, the distri-
bution of settlement and the defensive capacity of the people who were to be
raided.
Fundamentally, the external slave trade existed only because the return on
exports was greater than on employing labour in the domestic economy. If this
had not been the case a much larger number of slaves would have been retained
for use in Africa itself. The cost of gathering slaves was the same for both mar-
kets, and the cost of moving them to local markets was often as high as the cost
of transferring them to coastal entrepôts. It was mainly the price paid for them
which differed, and this difference reflected the greater productivity of labour in
the Americas. The export price of slaves never rose to the point where it
became cheaper for Europeans to turn to alternative sources of supply, and it
never fell to the point where it caused more than a temporary check to the
trade. Consequently, Africa was able consistently to undercut all other potential
suppliers. Production and wholesaling remained in indigenous hands mainly
because the African delivery system, despite inevitable disputes and occasional
breakdowns, was flexible and efficient enough to supply the slaves required at
a price the Europeans were prepared to pay. The remarkable expansion of the
slave trade in the eighteenth century provides a horrific illustration of the rapid
response of producers in an underdeveloped economy to price incentives. The
interaction of supply and demand merits further consideration because it raises
some interesting questions about the historical development of the trade. For
example, it is possible that part of the increase in the price paid for slaves in the
eighteenth century resulted from a growing scarcity of labour resources and
from better defensive arrangements on the part of those who had become fre-
quent targets of slave gathering expeditions. In other words, slave suppliers may
have experienced increasing marginal costs as a result of the growth of external
diseconomies which, given the extent of slaving, were inevitable. It is hard to
see how producers could have adjusted successfully to this situation: once the
minimum conditions of entry had been met, there appear to have been few
important economies of scale to slaving operations, and consequently little scope
for reducing the internal costs of the firm.
The political implications of economic activities are not a major concern of
this book. Nevertheless, two aspects of this question need to be mentioned
here. To begin with, it is clear that the growth of foreign trade encouraged the
expansion of some states, such as Dahomey and Oyo, and also changed their
structure, with the result that contractual relationships became more important
than kinship.57 In these states slaving was either in the hands of a small, wealthy
oligarchy, or else was a state monopoly. The firm acquired political functions;
conversely, the state acted like a huge corporation. The chartered companies
operated by Europeans in the seventeenth centuries must have been easily rec-
ognisable to Africans, whose own export activities were organised in much the
same way. The parallel draws attention to an important general point, namely
that the Atlantic slave trade was made possible by an alliance of two groups,
European shippers and African suppliers, who agreed, in effect, to exploit the
less powerful peoples of the continent. The trade may have been initiated by
Europeans, but it cannot be understood simply in terms of their role alone.
Next, care must be taken not to over-simplify the relationship between trade
and politics. It would be a mistake to imply that the slave trade was a necessary
condition for the formation of large, centralised states in West Africa.58 Benin,
for example, developed independently of the slave trade,59 while other areas,
such as the Niger Delta, conducted a substantial foreign trade, yet did not produce
major states, still less empires.60 Clearly, additional motives and means, non-
economic as well as economic, need to be explored if African state-building move-
ments are to be understood.
57 This point has been developed by I. A. Akinjogbin, Dahomey and its Neighbours, 1708–1818, Cam-
bridge, 1967. On Oyo see Peter Morton-Williams, ‘The Oyo Yoruba and the Atlantic Trade,
1670–1830’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1964, pp. 25–45.
58 E. J. Alagoa, ‘The Development of Institutions in the States of the Eastern Niger Delta’, Journal of
African History, 12, 1971, pp. 269–78.
59 James D. Graham, ‘The Slave Trade, Depopulation, and Human Sacrifice in Benin History’,
Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 5, 1965, pp. 317–34.
60 This question has been explored by Patrick Manning, ‘Slaves, Palm Oil and Political Power on the
West African Coast’, African Historical Studies, 2, 1969, pp. 279–88, and E. J. Alagoa, ‘Long-distance
Trade and States in the Niger Delta’, Journal of African History, 11, 1970, pp. 319–29.
External trade 155
When enough slaves had been collected, they were marched to coastal entre-
pôts and sold to dealers, who held them pending shipment. Between Senegal
and the Gold Coast the exchange of slaves was irregular; ships put in at various
places where they had access to the shore, in the hope of buying slaves rather
than in the certain knowledge of being able to do so. From the Gold Coast
eastwards, however, the trade was highly organised and the slavers usually made
for recognised centres. These included European forts on the Gold Coast, where
many of the chartered companies had their headquarters, and large African ports
of call, such as Whydah, Badagri, Lagos, Bonny and Old Calabar. In purpose
and organisation, the West Coast entrepôts may be compared not only to the
great ‘ports’ of the desert, such as Timbuctu, but also to the great European
centres, such as Liverpool and Nantes. Their chief function, whether controlled
by Africans or Europeans, was to act as wholesaling depots, though they also
performed the subsidiary, but necessary, task of supplying slave vessels with pro-
visions for the long voyage across the Atlantic. The entrepôts helped to syn-
chronise exchanges between slave gatherers, shippers and employers, so that
slaves were delivered to the West Indies at harvest time (December to June),
when they were most wanted. The majority of slavers visited the West Coast
between October and March, which was when the entrepôts were at their
busiest.61 By holding stocks in anticipation of demand, the wholesaling centres
attracted a regular business and enabled slave ships to achieve a rapid turnaround.
Naturally, this service was not provided free of charge, and it was accepted that
trade at the entrepôts involved paying either customs duties or higher prices for
slaves, and sometimes both. However, excessive charges could be countered by
transferring to another port or by trading outside the entrepôts. These possibil-
ities helped to stabilise relations between wholesalers and shippers.
Two of the leading entrepôts were Whydah and Old Calabar. Whydah
achieved prominence in the last quarter of the seventeenth century and
remained a centre of the slave trade until about the middle of the nineteenth
century.62 As an entrepôt without any profound natural advantages, Whydah
was particularly susceptible to external influences. Trade suffered after 1727,
when the town was captured by Agaja, the King of Dahomey, and again after
1774, when Oyo decided to send its slaves to the nearby market of Porto
Novo. Whydah was also seriously affected, along with many other entrepôts, by
interruptions caused by the American War of Independence and by the Napo-
leonic Wars. English vessels shipped 14,000 to 15,000 slaves a year from the
port in the 1680s, and exports remained at about this level until 1727. There-
after, a gradual decline set in. In 1776 about 10,000 slaves were exported, and
61 This was also the dry season, when Europeans experienced fewer health risks.
62 For further information see Rosemary Arnold, ‘A Port of Trade: Whydah on the Guinea Coast’, in
Trade and Market in the Early Empires, eds. Karl Polanyi, C. M. Arensberg, and Harry Pearson, Glen-
coe, 1957, pp. 154–76, and Simone Berbain, Le comptoir français de Juda (Ouidah) au XVIIIe siècle,
Paris, 1942.
156 External trade
this figure was halved by the end of the century. However, business revived
after 1810, when England and Portugal agreed to allow Whydah to continue as
a centre of the slave trade.
The Dahomeyan conquest was important because it led to the integration of pro-
ducing and wholesaling activities, though Whydah still depended on additional sup-
pliers, such as Oyo. This merger was not planned, for Agaja’s initial aim in 1727
was to stop the slave trade.63 However, Agaja soon discovered that he needed Euro-
pean support to counter the political threat from Oyo, and it was then that he
became involved in slaving. Under Dahomeyan rule the slave trade became a state
monopoly, and a governor was installed at Whydah to see that business conduct
conformed to official regulations and to ensure that the prescribed taxes were paid.
In practice, however, the slave trade was dominated by an oligarchy headed by the
king, and not simply by the monarch alone. Dahomeyan kings found it advanta-
geous to lease some of their royal privileges to senior chiefs, just as European rulers
found it politically advisable to grant concessions to their nobles. Some chiefs were
allowed to participate directly in slave raiding and trading, while others received
a percentage of the taxes derived from foreign commerce.
Old Calabar was a leading slave port for nearly 200 years (1650–1841), and as late
as 1828 was said to be shipping 6,000 to 8,000 slaves a year.64 Its history was less
spectacular than Whydah’s because it was never dominated by a large state, such as
Dahomey, a kingdom which achieved notoriety in Europe as a result of publicity
given to the allegedly unenlightened despotism of its rulers and to the exotic
exploits of its Amazonian warriors. Old Calabar was founded by Efik settlers in the
sixteenth century, before trade with Europe began. The economy was by no means
self-sufficient even at that time, and the local inhabitants exchanged fish and salt for
yams and palm produce, which were obtained from the north. When the external
demand for slaves reached the eastern edge of West Africa, the Efik established
themselves as wholesalers, exploiting the natural advantages of their estuarine site
and excluding all rivals from direct trade with the Europeans. The Efik occasionally
launched slave raids, but mostly bought slaves from other suppliers, especially the
Aro, and by the eighteenth century they had a network of market contacts which
stretched 200 miles inland.
The development of the slave trade had a profound effect on Efik institutions.
Economic inequalities became more pronounced as a result of the varying success
rates of households participating in foreign trade. The accretion of immigrants,
mostly slaves who were used as retainers, led to an unequal numerical expansion of
the original Efik household units. There was a trend towards greater social differen-
tiation as freemen took steps to secure the superiority of their status over that of
slaves and other subordinate newcomers. Because slave buying and wholesaling
63 However, it should be noted that there is not complete agreement over this interpretation.
64 The best study of Old Calabar is A. J. H. Latham, Old Calabar, 1600–1891: The Economic Impact of
the West upon a Traditional Society, University of Birmingham Ph.D. thesis, 1970.
External trade 157
65 V. R. Dorjahn and C. Fyfe, ‘Landlord and Stranger: Change in Tenancy Relations in Sierra
Leone’, Journal of African History, 3, 1962, 391–7.
66 Margaret Priestley has made a careful and most useful study of one such family, the Brews, in West
African Trade and Coast Society, Oxford, 1969.
158 External trade
67 Yen-p’ing Hao, The Comprador in Nineteenth-Century China: Bridge between East and West, Oxford,
1970.
68 Quoted in Christopher Fyfe, Sierra Leone Inheritance, London, 1964, p. 74.
External trade 159
The leading import was cloth, which was in steady demand in an underdevel-
oped economy.69 Textiles of all kinds accounted for between half and three-
quarters of the goods sent to West Africa from Rouen and Le Havre in the
eighteenth century, and it is likely that shipments from other leading European
ports were of much the same order of magnitude. In the seventeenth and eight-
eenth centuries cotton goods from Bengal were particularly prominent, and it is
interesting to reflect that on the eve of the Industrial Revolution, Europe still
conducted a sizeable re-export trade in Indian manufactures. In the second half
of the eighteenth century, however, this trade was adversely affected by the dis-
order which followed the collapse of the Mogul Empire, and by competition
from imitations produced in Holland, France and England. By the late eight-
eenth century European textiles, especially cottons, which had become more
important both in volume and value than woollen goods, were replacing Bengal
cloth, though it was not until about the 1820s that the latter became insignifi-
cant in West African trade. Guns and gunpowder were probably next in import-
ance after cloth and represented about one-fifth of the value of cargoes shipped
from England to Africa in the eighteenth century. The demand for munitions
was partly a function of their role as inputs in the ‘production’ of slaves, and
partly a result of the need to make adequate defensive arrangements against slave
raids. However, guns and gunpowder were not causally related to the begin-
nings of the Atlantic slave trade, for imports of these items did not become sub-
stantial until after the trade was well established. Initially, the Dutch were the
principal suppliers, but after the middle of the eighteenth century English manu-
facturers became dominant. Hardware, principally utensils and tools, was prob-
ably third on the list of leading imports. Other well-known trade goods were
salt, beads, bar iron, gin and brandy, all of which came from Europe, and
tobacco and rum, which were shipped from the Americas. Contrary to popular
belief, cheap gin, though it may have been the drink of the English poor, was
not a widespread stimulant, solace or currency in Africa at this time.
There was considerable variety within these main categories of imports
because there were many different types of cloth, guns and hardware. At the
end of the seventeenth century, Bosman, the distinguished Dutch trader, esti-
mated that at least 150 items were required for trade on the Gold Coast alone.
The variety of the import trade has often been seen as proof of the unpredict-
able psychology of ‘primitive’ consumers. Yet there were sound commercial
reasons why ships entering West Coast entrepôts resembled floating supermar-
kets. The trade was highly competitive, and the Europeans found it necessary,
and often to their advantage, to bargain for slaves by varying the goods offered,
as well as by altering their price. Slavers were unable to predict the state of the
African market in any detail, and by the time they had reached the West Coast
69 J. Fourneau and L. Kravetz, ‘Le pagne sur la côte de Guinée et au Congo du XVe siècle à nos
jours’, Bulletin de lnstitut d’ Études Centrafricaines, 7–8, 1954, pp. 5–21.
160 External trade
they were a long way from their sources of supply. There was no point arriving
with a boatload of guns, for instance, and nothing else, if these had just been
delivered by a previous vessel. European critics often overlooked the fact that
African purchasers on the coast were not final consumers, but wholesalers, who
required a wide range of goods because they had to supply a sizeable market
over a long period of time. Finally, the absence of an internationally acceptable
currency on the West Coast made it relatively difficult to substitute one item for
another, so having as many goods as possible (and having them in different
quantities) increased the facility of transactions.
It would be wrong to suppose that exchange at the entrepôts was conducted
simply by barter. Imports into West Africa also included a number of currencies, such
as cowries, manillas, iron bars, copper rods and silver dollars, and these, together with
gold, were used in part or full exchange for slaves. The difficulty of evaluating slaves
in terms of assorted trade goods and commodity currencies led to the development of
various units of account, such as the mythical ‘bar’, the ‘sorting’ and the ‘ounce’.70
The bar became a unit of account in the seventeenth century, principally in Sene-
gambia and eastern Nigeria; the sorting made its appearance at the same time, and
was used mainly between the Gold Coast and the Cameroons, though it was also
found in some western parts of the coast, such as Sierra Leone; the ounce was intro-
duced into the Gold Coast early in the eighteenth century, and was adopted at
Whydah in the 1760s. These units were adapted from indigenous systems of currency
and accountancy, and provide a further illustration of the way in which Europeans
fitted in with African trading customs. Originally, the bar was simply an iron bar of
differing lengths and weights, while the trade ounce was applied to goods exchanged
on the Gold Coast for one ounce of gold. At the same time, the slavers were anxious
to adapt these units to the needs of external trade because they offered a solution to
one of the main problems of barter, that is calculating in advance the likely profitabil-
ity of a particular transaction. By adding the proposed selling prices of diverse trade
goods together and expressing them in units of account, the European traders could
begin to build a margin of profit into the import trade.
European traders were content to remain on the coast not only because of
the difficulty and cost of moving inland, but also because the system of slave
gathering and wholesaling devised by Africans proved efficient and was therefore
acceptable. The African response to external demands has been explained here
in terms of universalist or formalist assumptions because African economic
behaviour in the export sector is recognisable as approximating to that of con-
temporary western economic man. This approach contrasts with the substantivist
viewpoint, and in particular with Karl Polanyi’s stimulating analysis in Dahomey and
the Slave Trade.71 Space does not permit a lengthy review of Polanyi’s account of
70 Marion Johnson, ‘The Ounce in Eighteenth-Century West African Trade’, Journal of African His-
tory, 7, 1966, pp. 197–214.
71 Seattle, 1966.
External trade 161
what he calls an ‘archaic’ economy. It must suffice to say that his book has serious
omissions in its historical sources, and that it does not satisfactorily define or apply
certain characteristics of the archaic economy, particularly the concepts of ‘adminis-
tered’ trade and ‘redistribution’. Nevertheless, Polanyi’s work, as always, provokes
further thought. One idea, which others might like to consider, is that the principles
of administered trade and redistribution be more typical of independent African
states today than of states in the pre-colonial era. Administered trade (in the shape
of large public corporations) has become an ideological commitment, while redistri-
bution (in the shape of patronage and job creation) has grown to be a political
necessity since the rise of the mass party.72
72 For some perceptive reflections on parallel lines, see Aristide R. Zolberg, Creating Political Order,
Chicago, 1966, pp. 134–45.
73 The anti-slavery squadron freed only about eight per cent of the total number of slaves shipped
from Africa in the period after abolition. However, the navy’s presence had a deterrent effect
which was much greater than this figure indicates. A recent study suggests that about 825,000 add-
itional slaves (an increase of 43 per cent) would have been transported from Africa to the Americas
between 1811 and 1870 had there not been an African squadron. See E. Phillip LeVeen, British
Slave Trade Suppression Policies, 1821–1865: Impact and Implications, University of California at
Berkeley, Ph.D. thesis, 1971.
162 External trade
Not until the close of the 1860s was the Atlantic slave trade suppressed and the
trans-Saharan slave trade reduced to negligible proportions.
The problem of why Britain, the most important slave-trading nation, took
the lead in condemning the Atlantic traffic is a matter of considerable contro-
versy. For a long time, this radical change of policy was attributed to the influ-
ence of a group of dedicated reformers led by Granville Sharp, Thomas
Clarkson and William Wilberforce. The classic statement of this view was pre-
sented by Sir Reginald Coupland in The British Anti-Slavery Movement, first pub-
lished in 1933.74 Coupland explained with great lucidity, and with that sense of
the onward march of history which characterised the ‘Whig’ school of history,
just how vested interests were destroyed by a combined non-conformist and
humanitarian pressure group. Coupland and the other imperial historians, ‘the
chaplains on the pirate ship’, were given a rough passage by Eric Williams,
a West Indian historian (now prime minister of Trinidad and Tobago) in his
book Capitalism and Slavery, which appeared in 1944. According to Williams,
the slave trade was abolished primarily for economic reasons. When the indus-
trial capitalism of the nineteenth century began to replace the purely commercial
capitalism of the eighteenth century, it became necessary to destroy the sugar
monopoly of the West Indies as a step towards dismantling the ancien régime of
mercantilist restrictions and establishing a new order of free trade and economic
efficiency. The role of the humanitarians, he claimed, had been ‘grossly exagger-
ated by men who have sacrificed scholarship to sentimentality and, like the
scholastics of old, placed faith before reason and evidence’.75
Both interpretations are open to criticism. Coupland was stronger on narrative
than on explanation; he made no serious attempt to understand the economic
aspects of abolition; he failed to account adequately for the continuation of the
slave trade after 1807; and he had a rather simplistic view of the composition
and operation of the abolitionist pressure group. Against Williams it has been
said that he failed to fit his argument into an acceptable chronological pattern;
that he exaggerated the importance of industrial interests as a compulsive force
demanding, and achieving, abolition; and that he misinterpreted the part played
by Pitt and, later, by Palmerston, and also the attitude of the abolitionists
towards the sugar duties.76 Nevertheless, the general thesis put forward in Capit-
alism and Slavery, though it requires modification, comes much closer to under-
standing the problem than does Coupland’s book. An examination of abolition
in France and England shows that anti-slavery agitation was able to succeed
when it did only because by the end of the eighteenth century the basis of the
74 Although in many ways Frank J. Klingberg’s The Anti-Slavery Movement in England, New Haven,
1926, is a superior book.
75 Eric Williams, Capitalism and Slavery, London, 1944, p. 178.
76 Roger T. Anstey, ‘Capitalism and Slavery: A Critique’, Economic History Review, 21, 1968, pp.
307–20.
External trade 163
old colonial system had been undermined by developments which were primar-
ily economic in character.
In France, as in England, there was a long history of propaganda against slav-
ery and the slave trade.77 Montesquieu, for example, had advanced an economic
argument against slavery (based on its alleged inefficiency) as early as 1748. In
1788 the French ‘humanitarians’ founded the Société des Amis des Noirs in
order to press for abolition more effectively. Yet the decline of the French slave
trade was the result of changes which were largely independent of domestic agi-
tation. A profound split developed in the second half of the eighteenth century
between French planters and the metropolis. The colons, in debt and resenting it,
dissatisfied with the French tariff system and suspicious of policies which pre-
vented the development of colonial manufactures, could no longer be relied on
to stand firm, even against abolitionist forces. There was also a relative decline
in the importance of the slave trade at Nantes in the late eighteenth century,
with the result that the town was less committed to defend the trade than it had
been 50 years earlier. It is true that other French ports had become involved in
the trade but slaving remained a very minor part of their total activities. Most
important of all, in 1792 there was a major slave revolt in St Domingo which
disrupted production in what, by that time, was the most important sugar island
in the Caribbean. Two years later, France abolished slavery in her colonial pos-
sessions in a vain attempt to bring the revolt under control. These events led to
the rapid decline of the French slave trade. Napoleon restored the institution of
slavery in 1802, and he also tried to re-establish the slave trade, but this reversal
of policy proved unsuccessful. Indeed, the Napoleonic Wars disrupted French
Atlantic commerce still further.78 In 1815 the restored monarchy agreed, under
pressure from Britain, to stop French subjects from trading in slaves, though
Nantes, the last of the great French slaving ports, still carried on a clandestine
traffic in slaves until the close of the 1820s. It is not surprising that the anti-
slavery movement in France gained so little momentum when it was also
regarded as being anti-patriotic.79 Not until 1822, when the energetic Duc de
Broglie took command, did the French ‘humanitarians’ begin to acquire political
influence.80 Even so, it was only in 1848 that slavery was abolished, this time
permanently, in all French colonial possessions.
The case of England was analogous to that of France to the extent that chan-
ging economic circumstances in the West Indies and in the metropolitan slave
77 David Brion Davis, The Problem of Slavery in Western Culture, Cornell, 1966.
78 François Crouzet, ‘Wars, Blockade, and Economic Change in Europe, 1792–1815’, Journal of Eco-
nomic History, 24, 1964, pp. 567–88.
79 This theme is developed in a neglected article by Y. Debbasch, ‘Poésie et traite; l’opinion française
sur le commerce négrier au début du XIXe siècle’, Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 48, 1961,
pp. 311–52.
80 Serge Daget, ‘L’abolition de la traite des noirs en France de 1814 à 1831’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines,
11, 1971, pp. 14–58.
164 External trade
81 The profitability of the cotton trade, for example, compared favourably with the slave trade by the
end of the century. See F. E. Hyde, B. B. Parkinson, and S. Marriner, ‘The Cotton Broker and the
Rise of the Liverpool Cotton Market’, Economic History Review, 8, 1955, p. 80.
82 Jean Trepp, ‘The Liverpool Movement for the Abolition of the English Slave Trade’, Journal of
Negro History, 13, 1928, pp. 265–85.
83 Peter Marshall, The Anti-Slave Trade Movement in Bristol, Bristol, 1968, pp. 21–4.
External trade 165
followed by the formation of a cabinet which was prepared to press ahead with
anti-slavery legislation, and the act prohibiting British subjects from engaging in the
slave trade was passed in the following year. Those who expected the immediate
extension of this measure were to be disappointed. At length, the abolitionists, no
longer prepared to wait in hope, reorganised their movement in 1830. The bill pro-
viding for the abolition of slavery was presented to a reformed Parliament and was
passed in 1833. Duties on sugar imports were equalised in 1851 in accordance with
Russell’s Sugar Act of 1846. The British West Indies then entered a long and diffi-
cult period of economic and social reconstruction.
It would be wrong to think that the political opportunities presented by these
economic changes were grasped simply and solely by a group of ‘humanitarians’,
defined rather vaguely as men of goodwill seeking to alleviate the suffering of
others, or else, as in many books, not defined at all. Some of the anti-slavery agita-
tors were far from disinterested, and few of the selfless men were radicals espousing
the cause of the downtrodden. Scrupulous in their concern for property rights,
adamant in their defence of the social and political status quo, and totally unmoved
by the industrial ‘slavery’ which existed around them, Wilberforce and the aboli-
tionists were a less romantic and more complex band than they have often been
depicted.84 Yet, precisely because of the kaleidoscopic nature of the movement,
there was room in it for some who did stand for reform of a more fundamental
kind. James Cropper, for example, a Quaker businessman and the greatest importer
of East Indian sugar into Liverpool in the early nineteenth century, found in the
abolitionist cause a perfect fusion of his idealistic and material aspirations.85 He, and
others like him, representatives of a developing industrial society and of a new eco-
nomic philosophy, stood in sharp opposition to the old order of bounties and mon-
opolies, and, to some extent, to the royal authority which upheld them. Abolition
was not, as Fox told the House of Commons in 1789, ‘a question between human-
ity on the one side and interest on the other’, but an issue between two opposing
coalitions of interests, each with its own ideology.
84 Indeed, it has been argued by Ford Brown in Fathers of the Victorians, Cambridge, 1961, that the
abolitionist movement became dominated by evangelical reformers who selected an issue (slavery)
which would arouse support for their moral crusade, without at the same time involving them in
domestic issues.
85 See the excellent articles by David B. Davis, ‘James Cropper and the British Anti-Slavery Move-
ment, 1821–1823’, Journal of Negro History, 45, 1960, pp. 241–58, and ‘James Cropper and the Brit-
ish Anti-Slavery Movement, 1823–1833’, Journal of Negro History, 46, 1961, pp. 154–73.
166 External trade
of the goods traded and the organisation of production and wholesaling, were
more important than their differences, which were mainly of direction and size.
The external effects will be outlined first of all, and then the repercussions on
Africa itself will be examined.
The chief effect of the overseas slave trade in the New World was to populate
and develop the abundant land resources of the Americas and the West Indies.
The trade in Africans was the first great human migration across the Atlantic; as
such, it provides a striking historical example of international factor mobility,
albeit of an enforced kind. The subsequent fortunes of these reluctant colonists
are closely identified with the social and political history of the Americas. The
type and degree of assimilation achieved in the nineteenth and twentieth centur-
ies varied greatly from region to region.86 In some countries, such as Argentina
and Brazil, the absorption of ‘strangers’ was harmonious and fairly complete,87
while in others, notably the United States, the passage of time served to
entrench marked economic, social and political distinctions between settlers of
different races. The legacy of the African slave trade remains the major domestic
issue facing the world’s richest and most powerful state.
With regard to Europe, most attention has been focused on the profits of the
slave and sugar trades, and on the economic consequences of the re-investment
of these profits. Nevertheless, at present there is little precise information about
the amount of capital accumulating from African and Atlantic commerce or
about its subsequent investment role. Many voyages, triangular and direct, were
outstandingly successful, and these have tended to attract the eyes of historians.
However, it must be remembered that the rate of profit had to take account of
the slow turnover of capital and the very real risk of total loss in the future.88 It
is clear that large investors could easily lose as well as win a fortune in the slave
trade, and that small subscribers tended to make modest gains by steady, but
slow, accumulation, on much the same scale and in much the same way as in
other branches of commerce. When these qualifications have been made, it
remains true that the slave and sugar trades brought great wealth to the principal
entrepôts, such as Liverpool and Nantes, and to many of their leading citizens.
It is impossible to account for the economic vitality of these ports in the eight-
eenth century, their physical and demographic expansion, and the remarkable
overflow of money into cultural activities, without stressing the causative, though
not exclusive, role of Atlantic commerce. It is equally clear that the prosperity of
the ports had beneficial linkage effects in their hinterlands. Examples of investment
in the domestic production of goods for the export sector were to be found in
86 Herbert S. Klein, Slavery in the Americas: A Comparative Study of Virginia and Cuba, Oxford, 1967.
87 For an interesting account of continuing cultural interaction following the resettlement of Africans
in the Americas, see Pierre Verger, ‘Nigeria, Brazil and Cuba’, Nigeria Magazine, October 1960, pp.
113–23.
88 F. E. Hyde, B. B. Parkinson, and S. Marriner, ‘The Nature and Profitability of the Liverpool Slave
Trade’, Economic History Review, 5, 1953, pp. 368–77.
External trade 167
the impetus given to the cotton industries of Manchester and Nantes, to the gun
trade of Birmingham and to the production of linen and hardware in Rouen.
Examples of the expansion of industries which made use of imports of raw mater-
ials were to be seen in the sugar refineries of Liverpool, London, Bristol, Nantes
and Orleans, and in the gum processing works of Nantes and Paris. It should be
noted, too, that importing and exporting activities provided a stimulus to service
industries, such as shipping and banking.
African and Atlantic commerce undoubtedly brought substantial gains to indi-
viduals and to certain regions. It does not follow, however, that the ‘triangular
trade made an enormous contribution to Britain’s industrial development’, or
that the ‘profits from this trade fertilized the entire productive system of the
country’.89 Any stimulus which foreign trade gave to domestic production
resulted from links with other parts of the world besides Africa and the Amer-
icas. It is as well to remember that Europe alone accounted for over half the
value of England’s foreign commerce in the eighteenth century. Furthermore, it
is mistaken to suppose that there was a simple, one-way relationship between
trade and industry. The connection between Liverpool and Manchester shows
not only that overseas trade assisted the growth of manufacturing, but also that
manufacturers helped to finance trade. By concentrating on foreign trade,
Williams and others have tended to underestimate the part played by the home
market, which was of central importance in the early phase of industrialisation as
a source of factor supply and of consumer demand.90 An additional objection
has been raised recently in a criticism of R. B. Sheridan, whose approach is
broadly in accord with that of Eric Williams.91 It has been suggested that the
profits of the British sugar trade came from the high prices which resulted from
tariff preference, and that if the trade had not been subsidised in this way, con-
sumers would have been better off and capital attracted to the West Indies
would have been invested more profitably at home. On this view colonies
were, as Adam Smith alleged, a drain on the mother country. The first part of
the argument is well founded. It seems probable that the British taxpayer was
indeed subsidising an imperial venture which mainly benefited a relatively small
interest group. However, the second part of the argument breaks down, as do
many other stimulating counterfactual, or hypothetical, propositions, because it
is impossible to know now what the position would have been if tariff protec-
tion had not existed, and it is easy to think of plausible alternatives to those sug-
gested by Professor Sheridan’s critic.
92 The question of size is particularly relevant in considering trade in goods other than slaves. Ship-
ments of commodities such as gum and ivory were potentially more fruitful than exports of human
beings, but it was not until the nineteenth century, after the Industrial Revolution, that world
demand for tropical raw materials underwent a marked expansion. The consequences of this devel-
opment are considered in the next chapter.
170 External trade
to physical deterioration, they did not depreciate very rapidly. If, meanwhile,
they reproduced, their owner reaped an unexpected and usually ill-deserved
profit. It is often claimed that the import trade consisted of shoddy goods. Evi-
dence in support of this proposition is limited mainly to imports of guns, some
of which were not proved or bored. However, it is improbable that the bulk of
imported goods was sub-standard, and it is even less likely that Africans would
have put up with poor quality wares for very long. Concern over the terms of
trade and the quality of imports derives partly from a feeling that consumer
goods were not items of ‘real’ value, the implication being, presumably, that
African states should have taxed foreign luxuries and adopted a vigorous policy
of import substitution. This, to say the least, is an unhistorical point of view, for
it ignores both the aims of the rulers themselves and the domestic obstacles to
the development of a different kind of commerce.
It is also alleged that foreign imports led to the decline of local industries.
This claim will be familiar to historians of the underdeveloped world, and
especially to those with knowledge of India, which has been the subject of
a long debate on this question. Just as the European middle classes are always
rising, so, too, traditional crafts in other parts of the world are continually
being ousted. In the case of West Africa, no general evidence has been pre-
sented in support of the claim. Many indigenous manufactures, such as cloth
and pottery, remained important, and it seems more likely that the market
was enlarged (in terms of the volume and range of goods) than that foreign
imports replaced domestic craft products. It is sometimes stated, too, that
slaving expeditions caused widespread devastation. It is indeed highly likely
that slave raids increased the number of wars and made life insecure, but
again little research has been carried out to indicate the extent of the resulting
disruption. Meanwhile, the continuous history of internal trade, the regional
variations in the incidence of slave raiding and the recent, lower estimates of
the volume of slave exports suggest that this point should not be made with-
out qualification.
Finally, it is necessary to consider the effect of the export of labour on the
course of African development. Once again, the information necessary for judg-
ing this issue, as opposed to guessing about it, is not available at present. It is
obvious enough that the immediate and most acute losses were suffered person-
ally by the 6 million or so unwilling West Africans who were shipped across the
Atlantic, by the much smaller number who were exported across the Sahara,
and by those who were killed or maimed in the process of slave-gathering oper-
ations. However, emigration, even on this scale, was not necessarily a serious set-
back for the economy. The main difficulty in analysing this question is that so
little is known about the size of the population during the pre-colonial period.
One estimate, based on the admittedly suspect procedure of using twentieth-
century data to reconstruct the distant past, suggests that the total population of
West Africa may have been around 25 million in 1700, in which case the rate
of loss during the eighteenth century, when the overseas slave trade was at its
External trade 171
height, was about 0.2 per cent per annum.93 As this figure was roughly equal to
the rate of natural increase, it can be said that in numerical terms the chief effect
of the export of labour between 1700 and 1800 was to keep the population
static. What would have happened if the Africans shipped abroad had remained
in Africa is a matter for speculation. For the external slave trade to have pre-
vented a major economic breakthrough before the nineteenth century, it is
necessary to argue that West Africa would have achieved such a breakthrough if
the supply of manpower had not been diminished by the amount specified. The
evidence available does not support this hypothesis, and it is hard to see how
the retention of those slaves sent abroad would have caused the economy to
develop along significantly different lines. In the late nineteenth and early twen-
tieth centuries, however, when the economy began to expand very rapidly,
there was undoubtedly a serious shortage of labour in many part of West Africa,
and it could be argued that at that point the pace of advance would have been
faster if the slave trade had not retarded the growth of population.
It is possible that the aggregate approach disguises some of the consequences
of the export of labour. It is conceivable, for example, that those regions which
were most involved in slaving operations were affected particularly severely. In
practice, however, areas such as Senegambia and the seaboard between the Gold
Coast and the Cameroons, though prominent in the slave trade, were the lead-
ing zones of export growth during the era of ‘legitimate’ commerce. Alterna-
tively, it could be held that shipments of slaves involved qualitative losses which
are masked by the figures for total exports. Since about two-thirds of the slaves
exported were males, it is possible that their removal might have affected female
occupational roles. However, generalisation on this issue is difficult, partly
because of lack of information and partly because the division of labour between
the sexes was by no means the same in all West African societies. If those sold
abroad possessed scarce technical or entrepreneurial skills, then the consequences
of their emigration might have been far greater than a consideration of numbers
alone would suggest. However, it seems probable that the majority of enslaved
Africans were ordinary farmers, who were engaged mainly in subsistence and
local exchange activities. Their removal would have reduced total output, but
by an amount which was matched by a fall in demand. Nevertheless even if
these qualifications are allowed, it remains the case that the removal of labour
from a land-surplus economy would have reduced the level of aggregate eco-
nomic activity and depressed the domestic market, and that the disorder and
insecurity associated with slaving would have further damaged the region’s eco-
nomic prospects.
Although some of the more extreme claims regarding the destructive effects
of Atlantic and Saharan commerce have yet to be proved, it is quite clear that
93 J. D. Fage, A History of West Africa, pp. 85–7, and the same author’s article ‘Slavery and the Slave
Trade in the Context of West African History’, Journal of African History, 10, 1969, pp. 393–404.
172 External trade
94 Benjamin Higgins, ‘The Dualistic Theory of Underdeveloped Areas’, Economic Development and
Cultural Change, 4, 1955, pp. 99–115.
95 The West African case can be compared, in this respect, to the cotton plantations of the American
South in the nineteenth century. See Alfred H. Conrad and John R. Meyer, Studies in Econometric
History, London, 1965, pp. 223–33.
96 R. Caillié, Travels to Timbuctu, London, 1830, 2, p. 53.
4
THE ECONOMIC BASIS OF
IMPERIALISM
Once the European powers had decided to abolish the external slave trade, West
Africa was faced with the problem of developing alternative exports. The outcome
was a period of transition and experimentation, which is customarily referred to as
the era of ‘legitimate’ commerce in order to distinguish it from the illegal trade in
slaves. This chapter will try to establish two conclusions about West African history
in the nineteenth century. First, it will be argued that the structure of legitimate
commerce marked an important break with the past and signified a new phase in
the growth of the market, a phase which can be seen as the start of the modern
economic history of West Africa. This argument contrasts with the traditional view,
which stresses continuities with the past and the ease of the transfer to legitimate
trade. Next, it will be suggested that the strains involved in creating this economy,
combined with fluctuations in its performance, are central to an understanding of
the partition of West Africa in the last quarter of the nineteenth century. This prop-
osition, too, is intended to be set against current interpretations, most of which hold
that imperialism was the product of political motives stemming from Europe. For
these two reasons the analysis of legitimate commerce and partition has been com-
bined in one chapter.
These are large claims, and they require some initial elaboration before the
historical evidence is presented. The main structural features of the new com-
merce will be outlined first of all. The foreign trade statistics will then be used
to support the theoretical argument, and to indicate the relationship between
commercial fluctuations and the economic and political history of West Africa
in the nineteenth century. Finally, the development of legitimate commerce will
be considered with reference to specific African and European interests in order
to demonstrate how the interaction of these groups produced the partition of
West Africa. The economic theme is emphasised here partly because this book
174 The economic basis of imperialism
1 A good introduction to staple theory can be found in Melville H. Watkins, ‘A Staple Theory of
Economic Growth’, Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 29, 1963, pp. 141–58.
2 It should be added that staple theory is generally thought to be inapplicable in cases where export
growth occurs in indigenous, subsistence economies. However, the reasons given in support of this
view rest on assumptions about ‘traditional’ societies which have been criticised earlier in this study
(Chapter 2).
The economic basis of imperialism 175
3 The discussion which follows should be compared with the conclusions reached in the previous
chapter, pp. 119–23.
4 Kew Bulletin, 1892, p. 208.
5 Female labour appears to have been particularly important in preparing groundnuts and palm pro-
duce for export. The division of labour between the sexes is a subject which merits further research.
176 The economic basis of imperialism
Although the details of the transition to legitimate commerce are not yet
known, it would seem that on the whole West Africa did not experience an
immediate economic crisis because many areas were able to export legitimate
goods and slaves side by side down to about the middle of the nineteenth cen-
tury. There was a remarkable expansion in the value of overseas trade in
the second quarter of the century. Newbury, who has carried out some much-
needed research on West African trade in the nineteenth century, has estimated
that the total value of the overseas commerce of the region in legitimate goods
alone amounted to a minimum of £3.5 million a year in the early 1850s.8 This
figure may be compared with Fage’s estimate that at the end of the eighteenth
century, at the height of the Atlantic slave trade, West Africa’s overseas com-
merce was worth about £4 million a year.9 In the second half of the century
trade expanded roughly four times, and by 1901–05 amounted to about
£15 million a year. The rate of growth was uneven throughout this period, and
it was to be dwarfed by the expansion which occurred during the colonial era.
Nevertheless, it was great enough to support the proposition that the new econ-
omy was also a much bigger economy. It is worth emphasising that European
commercial involvement in West Africa was expanding rather than diminishing,
as this is a factor which has not been taken into account by historians who have
argued that economic motives were of little significance in the partition of West
Africa.
No useful comparison of volumes can be made between legitimate commerce
and the slave trade. However, the main point to note with regard to the
volume of trade in the nineteenth century is that West African societies had to
adjust in a relatively short time to the immense physical task of transporting
huge quantities of low value, bulky commodities. Imports of palm oil into the
United Kingdom from West Africa reached 1,000 tons in 1810, 10,000 tons in
1830, over 20,000 tons in 1842, over 30,000 tons in 1853 and over 40,000 tons
in 1855. Even this expansion was dwarfed in the second half of the century,
when there was a rapid growth in shipments of groundnuts, and a still more
dramatic rise in overseas trade in palm kernels. Two examples will illustrate the
size of the increase. Exports of groundnuts from Senegal rose from virtually
nothing in the 1840s to an average of 29,000 tons a year in the period 1886–90,
while exports of palm kernels from Lagos, one of the great slave ports in the
1840s and 1850s, reached an average of 37,000 tons in the same period. The
palm oil trade failed to maintain its early rate of progress, but exports still aver-
aged about 50,000 tons a year between 1860 and 1900. The organisation
required for moving, let alone producing, tonnages of this magnitude provides
8 C. W. Newbury, ‘Trade and Authority in West Africa from 1850 to 1880’, in Colonialism in Africa,
1870–1960, eds. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan, The History and Politics of Colonialism,
1870–1914, Cambridge, 1969, pp. 76–9.
9 J. D. Fage, A History of West Africa: An Introduction, Cambridge, 1969, pp. 91–2.
178 The economic basis of imperialism
10 The subject of internal transport in the pre-colonial period still awaits investigation.
11 Calculated from C. W. Newbury, ‘Credit in Early Nineteenth-Century West African Trade’, Jour-
nal of African History, 13, 1972, pp. 83–4.
12 Quoted in Allan McPhee, The Economic Revolution in British West Africa, London, 1926, p. 31, n. 2.
13 Though some were used in Africa for fuel.
The economic basis of imperialism 179
Four items accounted for about three-quarters of the value of all imports into
West Africa. These were textiles (a classification covering a wide range of
cotton and woollen goods), spirits (especially rum and gin), salt and iron. Other
prominent items were hardware, tobacco, guns and gunpowder.14 Textiles
remained the leading commodity, as in the eighteenth century. In Senegal, for
example, one popular variety alone (known as ‘guinea’ cloth) accounted for no
less than 25 per cent of the value of total imports during the third quarter of the
nineteenth century. At Lagos (about 1,800 miles away) textiles of all kinds aver-
aged 44 per cent of total imports in the period 1880–92. Similarities between
the types of goods imported before and after the end of the external slave trade
should not be allowed to disguise some important differences: by the middle of
the nineteenth century the quantity had increased greatly, and (as will be
pointed out) the price per unit had declined.
On the European side of the trade, Britain and France continued to be the
most important foreign powers on the West Coast, as they had been in the
eighteenth century. Liverpool dominated the new trade, just as it had the old,
and was by far the largest importer of palm oil in Europe. Nantes underwent
a decline in the nineteenth century, but Bordeaux and Marseilles, the ports
which took its place, both had longstanding connections with Africa. Most of
West Africa’s groundnut exports were shipped to France, where they enjoyed
tariff advantages over certain other vegetable oils, including palm oil. The most
striking aspect of the national distribution of trade was the pre-eminence of
Britain.15 In 1868 a French consul estimated that Britain and France shared
four-fifths of Europe’s trade with West Africa, and that two-thirds to three-
quarters of this total was in the hands of Great Britain. Furthermore, as much as
70 per cent of Britain’s trade in the period 1860–80 was conducted with areas
outside her few, small colonies. France’s trade, by contrast, was centred on her
traditional base and colony of Senegal, which accounted for between half and
three-quarters of her total trade with West Africa during the same period.
A new feature of the second half of the century was the rapid growth of
German commerce. By the 1880s, Hamburg was said to handle nearly one-third
of all West Africa’s overseas trade.16 This expansion was the result of three fac-
tors: the rise of the palm kernel market, which was dominated by Hamburg
because German farmers were the main buyers of cattle cake and because the
Dutch were the largest manufacturers of margarine; the ability of Hamburg to
14 Rum and tobacco imports dwindled in the last quarter of the nineteenth century following the
decline of trade with America and Brazil, the two principal suppliers.
15 Newbury, ‘Trade and Authority in West Africa from 1850 to 1880’ in Colonialism in Africa,
1870–1960, eds. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan, The History and Politics of Colonialism, 1870–1914,
Cambridge, 1969, pp. 79–80.
16 K. Vignes, ‘Étude sur la rivalité d’influence entre les puissances européennes en Afrique équatoriale
et occidentale depuis l’acte général de Berlin jusqu’au seuil du XXe siècle’, Revue Française d’Histoire
d’Outre-Mer, 48, 1961, p. 14.
180 The economic basis of imperialism
supply cheap liquor; and the development of steamship services between Ger-
many and West Africa.
The abolition of the Atlantic slave trade and the rise of legitimate commerce
were events which undoubtedly favoured Britain, the first industrial nation. She,
above all others, was in a position to cater for the mass market which was begin-
ning to emerge in West Africa, though her supremacy was being challenged in
the late nineteenth century by new competitors. No other foreign powers were
of any account in West Africa, apart from Britain, France and Germany. The
Danes sold their Gold Coast forts to the British in 1850, and the Dutch fol-
lowed suit in 1872. The Portuguese, once the great innovators of European
enterprise in Africa, had difficulty in maintaining even one tiny colony (Portu-
guese Guinea). All three countries had been overtaken by a world in which
industrialisation had become the basis of commercial and political power.17
The rapid expansion of overseas commerce has tended to overshadow the his-
tory of West Africa’s external trade across the Sahara. It is commonly supposed
that by the nineteenth century this trade was only a fraction of the value it had
attained in the golden age of the sixteenth century. Professor Adu Boahen, for
example, has suggested that total trade on the trans-Saharan routes amounted to
no more than about £125,000 a year in the first half of the nineteenth
century.18 However, the deficiencies in the evidence for both the sixteenth cen-
tury and the early nineteenth century are so great as to make calculations and
comparisons a matter of guesswork. Recent research indicates that the old cara-
van routes still had a surprising amount of life left in them in the second half of
the nineteenth century. To begin with, it is now apparent that trans-Saharan
trade was not seriously affected by competition from goods brought by sea until
the very end of the century. Indeed, Manchester textiles were carried across the
Sahara and achieved a wide distribution. As late as 1869, for example, the town
of Ilorin was said to be commercially nearer the Mediterranean (some 2,000
miles to the north) than it was to the Bight of Benin, even though the port of
Lagos was only about 160 miles away.19 Secondly, in the most detailed examin-
ation of the trade figures yet attempted, Newbury has shown that the total value
of trans-Saharan trade actually increased from the 1840s, and reached a peak in
1875, when it was worth around £1.5 million.20 It was only after this date that
a slow and final decline set in. Thus, the Sahara developed its own brand of
‘legitimate’ commerce. Because of transport limitations, however, the overland
17 Shortage of space has caused this rather cavalier treatment of minority expatriate interests, each of
which is worthy of study in some detail. There was also an interesting trade between North Amer-
ica and West Africa which has been investigated and, indeed, virtually discovered by George
E. Brooks, Yankee Traders, Old Coasters and African Middlemen, Boston, 1970.
18 A. Adu Boahen, Britain, the Sahara, and the Western Sudan, 1788–1861, Oxford, 1964, p. 131.
19 A. Millson, ‘Yoruba’, Manchester Geographical Society Journal, 7, 1891, p. 92.
20 C. W. Newbury, ‘North African and Western Sudan Trade in the Nineteenth Century: A Re-
evaluation’, Journal of African History, 7, 1966, pp. 233–46.
The economic basis of imperialism 181
routes failed to develop a sizeable export trade in bulky, low-value goods, and
the boom in the third quarter of the century was based partly on the ephemeral
demand of the Victorian world for ostrich feathers.21 Even with this boost to
the trade, trans-Saharan commerce was worth only one-fifth of the value of the
West Coast’s seaborne trade in 1875.
Economic development by way of staple exports can be a precarious and
lengthy process. Changes in supply and demand can set back the progress of the
staple, retard the development of the economy as a whole and have serious
social and political repercussions. West Africa’s raw material exports entered
a wide range of manufacturing processes, and the price paid for them and the
volume required tended to vary in accordance with the level of business activity
in industrial Europe. West African producers had to accept the world price as
given because they were unable to control the volume of palm produce and
groundnuts placed on the market, and because the industrial countries could buy
alternative, competing products from other underdeveloped regions. By the mid-
nineteenth century the days when West Africa enjoyed a monopoly as the sole
supplier of labour to the plantations of the Americas were over, and the silent
imperialism of the steamship was beginning to bring vegetable oils and substitute
products from other continents besides Africa.
The identification of fluctuations in West Africa’s external trade is a matter of
considerable historical importance. The progress of the new economy of legitim-
ate commerce is best charted by changes in the terms of trade of West African
export producers: the net barter terms provide an index of the import-
purchasing power of a unit of exports, and the income terms measure the
import-purchasing power of total exports.22 Insufficient data are available at pre-
sent to enable precise calculations to be made, but the general trends are clear
enough and are confirmed by the evaluation of contemporary observers. It is
hoped that others will find this subject important enough to carry out the
research needed to improve the provisional and approximate analysis presented
here.23
Information on the early nineteenth century is particularly sparse. However,
as far as the main staple, palm oil, was concerned, prices on the West Coast and
in Europe appear to have pursued an upward trend, with the exception of falls
in 1844–46 and 1851–52, reaching a peak in 1854–61, when the Liverpool
price stood at around £45 per ton. At the same time, the prices of manufactured
21 These decorated the hats of Victorian ladies in much the same way as they had adorned the
ostriches themselves. African traders may well have wondered at the strange values of the white
man, who was prepared to sell manufactured cloth for such an item, and for such a purpose!
22 These terms are introduced here briefly and are dealt with at greater length in Chapter 5, where
the data available are sufficient to justify more extended treatment.
23 Mention should be made of Patrick Manning’s excellent special study, An Economic History of South-
ern Dahomey, 1880–1914, University of Wisconsin Ph.D. thesis, 1969, which contains a thorough
investigation of the overseas trade of that particular region.
182 The economic basis of imperialism
goods imported into West Africa fell dramatically as a result of the Industrial
Revolution. By 1850 staple items cost half and, in some cases, only a quarter of
what they had at the start of the century. Consequently, the barter terms of
trade moved in favour of primary producers. Since the volume of exports was
rising during the first half of the century, the income terms also improved. The
result was a period of prosperity for West African trade. Indeed, since 1800
West Africa has experienced only three periods when both barter and income
terms have moved sharply in favour of producers for at least ten years. The first
period played an important part in establishing the new commerce; the second,
from 1900–13, helped to install the colonial rulers; and the third, from 1945–55,
was a phase of expanding expectations and economic diversification which was
associated with the end of the colonial era.
In all situations of historical change there are elements of continuity. During
the first half of the nineteenth century, when legitimate commerce was in its
infancy and was also comparatively prosperous, producers and traders were
encouraged to believe that the transition from the slave trade would be an easy
one. Initially, various features of commerce on the West Coast were simply car-
ried over from the eighteenth century. For example, a number of established
European traders and African producers managed to adapt from the old trade to
the new; some of the minor exports of legitimate commerce continued to be
shipped after abolition just as they had been before; the credit or trust ‘system’
survived and expanded, in spite of repeated complaints from those who thought
that it was morally reprehensible and economically risky; sailing ships remained
in use on routes between Europe and Africa; and business was still transacted by
means of barter and ‘transitional’ currencies, such as cowries and manillas.
Above all, the effort to stop the slave trade and to establish legitimate commerce,
though it led to voyages of exploration, to missionary enterprise and to a slightly
greater degree of official activity on the West Coast, did not bring about any
major alterations to the political map. Because an adjustment was made to the
economy without causing an immediate and total upheaval, traders and officials
felt confident that casual and limited political commitments could be maintained,
much as they had been in the eighteenth century. The European frontier did
not extend inland; it did not even cover all parts of the coast. There was no
partition of Africa in 1807 or 1833.
The position changed considerably in the second half of the century. The
boom came to an end in 1861, and there was a depression between 1862 and
1866, when the European price for palm oil fell to around £32 per ton.
Although prices revived in 1866–67, they never again reached the peaks of
1854–61. On the contrary, they underwent a serious decline from an average of
£37 per ton in 1861–65 to £20 a ton in 1886–90, the lowest on record since
the early days of the trade. Thus, in 25 years prices were cut by nearly
50 per cent. There was a very slight improvement in the 1890s, but it was not
until 1906 that prices regained the levels achieved in the 1850s. Palm kernel
prices fell by about a third from roughly £15 per ton in the 1860s to just over
The economic basis of imperialism 183
£10 in the period 1886–90. Groundnut prices at Rufisque in Senegal also fell by
roughly a third from 25 to 27½ francs per 100 kilos in the period 1857–67 to
around 15 francs in the period 1877–1900. In both cases, there was no recovery
until after the turn of the century. There were two main causes of this fall,
though there were several contributory factors, such as reduced ocean freight
rates. There was an increase in the supply of mineral and vegetable oils follow-
ing the discovery of petroleum resources in the United States in the 1860s, and
the entry into the market of Indian groundnuts and Australian tallow after the
opening of the Suez Canal in 1869. At the same time, European demand for
a wide range of raw materials, including oils and fats, was checked in the last
quarter of the nineteenth century with the advent of the so-called Great
Depression.24
There is little systematic information available about the local prices of goods
imported into West Africa in the second half of the nineteenth century. The
trend was probably a downward one, reflecting the fall in freight rates, an
increase in competition on the West Coast and continuing improvements in
industrial efficiency. However, it is certain that the substantial price reductions
of the early nineteenth century were not repeated, and that any decline which
occurred was relatively slight and also gradual.25 In the third quarter of the nine-
teenth century, when export prices fell particularly sharply, the barter terms of
trade moved decisively against primary producers.
The question now arises as to what extent and in what sense an increase in
the volume of exports can be said to have compensated for this adverse move-
ment in the barter terms of trade. The broad trend, as noted earlier, was a rising
one, but with few exceptions expansion levelled off in the late 1870s and in the
1880s, and in some cases the volume of exports actually declined. A few
examples will illustrate how widespread this experience was: in the Niger Delta
palm produce exports showed no clear upward movement in the 1870s and
1880s, and there was a decrease at Opobo during the period 1887–93; at Lagos,
one of the major centres of legitimate commerce, there was a slight, but indeci-
sive, trend towards expansion in the 1870s and 1880s; on the Gold Coast oil
and kernel exports were almost static from 1886–1900; on the Ivory Coast palm
oil exports fell sharply in the mid-1880s; and in Sierra Leone the picture was
much the same. The position with regard to groundnuts was very similar; ship-
ments from Gambia declined in the 1870s and 1880s; and in Senegal exports
reached a plateau in the late 1870s which was not substantially exceeded until
about the turn of the century. Even in cases where the volume of exports rose
to the extent that total earnings were maintained, producers were still not as
24 The best recent analysis of what in some respects was a non-event, is S. B. Saul’s The Myth of the
Great Depression, 1873–1896, London, 1969, though this study analyses the problem from a British,
rather than from a European, point of view.
25 See Lars G. Sandberg, ‘Movements in the Quality of British Cotton Textile Exports, 1815–1913’,
Journal of Economic History, 28, 1968, p. 19.
184 The economic basis of imperialism
well off in the 1880s as they had been earlier. In the absence of technical
improvements in agriculture or in internal transport during the second half of
the century, a rise in the volume of exports could be achieved only in one of
two ways: by existing producers deciding to increase their labour inputs, thus
reducing net incomes by cutting down on leisure or other activities, or by
paying for additional labour services; and by expanding the total number of
independent producers, thus causing the average per capita incomes of export
producers to fall.
It seems likely that the income terms of trade either declined or maintained
a precarious stability during the last quarter of the century. Even in the latter
case there is a strong probability that the real income of the average export pro-
ducer was reduced.
The foregoing analysis has referred to the major staples of overseas trade.
However, it is important to realise that the late nineteenth century was also
a time of crisis for minor staples and for trans-Saharan trade. The Senegalese
gum trade declined in the second half of the century as a result of the develop-
ment of chemical substitutes and the growth of competition from Egyptian
gum. Gold exports from the Gold Coast were static, cocoa exports were negli-
gible and rubber exports did not expand until the 1890s. The Western Sudan
was affected in the nineteenth century by a series of political upheavals stem-
ming from the jihāds, which were launched by the protagonists of a revived
Islam. The nature of these revivalist movements is still a subject of dispute.26
Their economic influence appears to have been conservative, except, possibly in
the case of Senegal. At best they preserved traditional agricultural and trading
activities; at worst they perpetuated archaic economies based on plunder, tribute
and slavery. To these troubles was added another, namely the decay of trans-
Saharan trade, which declined after 1875 and was reduced to a trickle by 1900.
Initially, this slump was the result of slackening demand in Europe, but by the
end of the century the desert trade had also been seriously affected by the disin-
tegration of the slave system which supported the oases, and by competition
from ocean routes, which could deliver manufactured goods more cheaply.
The evidence indicates that West Africa’s external trade experienced a crisis in
the last quarter of the nineteenth century. Export producers had become caught
in a staple trap: the barter terms of trade had turned against them, and attempts
to increase the volume of exports had either failed or, where successful, had
contributed to a further decline in the terms of trade, with the result that
26 The Russian scholar, D. A. Ol’derogge, has argued that the jihād in northern Nigeria was primarily
a protest of Hausa and Fulani commoners against oppression by the ruling class. So far, this view
has not made much impression, at least on British scholars. However, Ol’derogge’s interpretation
deserves attention, not least because testing his theory involves writing the history of ordinary Afri-
cans, as opposed to that of prominent religious and political figures, and this is surely highly desir-
able. On the jihād in Senegambia see Martin A. Klein, Islam and Imperialism in Senegal, Edinburgh,
1968.
The economic basis of imperialism 185
growth had become self-defeating. Within a relatively short space of time primary
producers and traders came under severe pressure to develop alternative exports and
to adopt cost-reducing innovations. This ‘general crisis’ of the late nineteenth cen-
tury led to strains, misunderstandings and conflicts between all those, Europeans as
well as Africans, who in varying degrees had become dependent on legitimate com-
merce for their livelihood. The expansion in the volume of overseas commerce in
the second half of the nineteenth century, combined with the adverse movement in
the terms of trade, led to the modification or abolition of many of the early features
of legitimate commerce that had been inherited from the time of the external slave
trade, and also caused the European powers to discard the assumptions governing
their traditional policy of limited intervention in West Africa. Just as pronounced
booms have had a marked effect on the course of West African history, so, too,
have serious slumps. Since the beginning of legitimate commerce there have been
two periods of ten years or more when the barter terms of trade have moved against
export producers and when the income terms have either fallen or remained static.
The first period of depression was in the last quarter of the nineteenth century and
helped to bring the Europeans into Africa. The second period, covering the years
1930–45, helped create the movement which was to expel them.
27 In this respect the analysis is a response to the plea made by J. D. Hargreaves in an important article
written more than ten years ago, ‘Towards a History of the Partition of Africa’, Journal of African
History, 1, 1960, pp. 97–109. For the most recent statement of Professor Hargreaves’s own view see
his contribution ‘West African States and the European Conquest’, in Colonialism in Africa,
1870–1960, ed. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan, 1, The History and Politics of Colonialism,
1870–1914, Cambridge, 1969, pp. 199–219. I should like to acknowledge my debt to Dr Martin
Klein, Dr Patrick Manning and Dr C. W. Newbury, who (though they may not be fully aware of
it) have caused me to re-think my ideas on this subject over the past few years.
186 The economic basis of imperialism
effect on intra-group relations on the African side of the frontier; the second
will focus on problems of demand and their effect on intra-group relations on
the European side of the frontier; the third section will examine how the eco-
nomic crisis of the late nineteenth century affected inter-group relations at the
national level, and led to the decisions to move the established frontier inland,
that is to partition West Africa.
It was by no means easy to develop satisfactory substitutes for the Atlantic
slave trade, even though some of the staples of legitimate commerce were
already grown in West Africa, and the terms of trade favoured primary produ-
cers in the second quarter of the nineteenth century. With the benefit of hind-
sight, historians have been able to point, justly, to the success of palm produce
and groundnuts. For contemporaries, however, legitimate commerce was a long,
precarious experiment, an era of fluctuating fortunes which held out no guaran-
tees for the future. This explains why European interests, official and private,
thought it necessary to tangle with a series of risky ventures in tropical agricul-
ture. In the 1820s, for example, the French undertook an ambitious agricultural
project in Senegal.28 The main idea behind this scheme was to grow in Africa,
and with African labour, the crops which had been produced on slave plant-
ations in the Americas. A model farm was established, several crops, including
cotton and indigo, were tried out, and new techniques of irrigation and plough-
ing were introduced. The experiment was abandoned in 1831 as a result of mis-
management, lack of capital and ignorance of tropical conditions. In the 1840s
British commercial interests established a model farm at Lokoja on the Niger,
but this, too, was a failure.
The next important wave of experiments occurred just after the middle of the
century and was prompted by a cotton famine in Europe arising out of the
American Civil War. Attempts were made to grow cotton at various points on
the West Coast, such as Senegal, southern Nigeria and the Gold Coast.29 In the
1860s the French still thought that Senegal was destined to become a leading
exporter of cotton. Again, they were disappointed. Many previous errors were
repeated, and American production recovered far more quickly than had been
anticipated. Above all, the Senegalese farmer, envisaging a rather different future
for his country, preferred groundnuts to cotton because they were more profit-
able. A greater degree of success was achieved at Abeokuta in south-west
Nigeria, though there, too, cotton exports dwindled in the 1870s.30 The pro-
moters found that they were unable to compete in international markets, partly,
28 Roger Pasquier, ‘En marge de la guerre de sécession: les essais de culture du coton au Sénégal’,
Annales Africaines, 1955, pp. 185–202.
29 Plantation agriculture on the Gold Coast, where experiments sponsored by the Basel Mission were
of great importance, has been studied by Kwamina B. Dickson, A Historical Geography of Ghana,
Cambridge, 1969, pp. 120–32.
30 J. B. Webster, ‘The Bible and the Plough’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 2, 1963, pp.
418–34.
10°W 0 10°E
20°N
Timbuctu
St. Louis
R.
Se
ne
Dakar ga
l R. L. Chad
R. Ga Ni
Bathurst ge
mb
r
ia
10°N Kano
R. V
OVERSEAS Benin
olta
EXPORTS
Monrovia
Groundnuts
Palm Oil and Kernels Onitsha
Accra Cotonou Old Calabar
Gold Whydah
Gum Grand Bassam Winneba Brass Opobo
Assini Cape Coast Warri Bonny
0 kilometres 500
Axim Elmina
0 statute miles 300
it is interesting to note, because of the high cost of free African labour. The
final phase of experiments came in the 1880s as a result of declining profits in
the palm produce trade. Many proposals were put forward to remedy the prob-
lem, and several of the more feasible were tried out. Arthur Verdier,
a prominent French merchant, began coffee plantations in the Ivory Coast; the
Royal Niger Company started plantations of cocoa, coffee and rubber in the
Niger Valley; and the colonial administration established botanic stations at
Lagos (1887) and on the Gold Coast (1889).
These experiments have implications which extend beyond the local details
given above. As a record of early European endeavours in tropical agriculture,
they are important for geographers and botanists, as well as for historians. They
also represent an interesting stage in the development of economic policy, for
they stand mid-way between the mercantilist concept of colonies serving the
needs of the mother country, and the realisation of this ideal in the different
circumstances of the twentieth century. Furthermore, these nineteenth-century
debates over the means of achieving agricultural progress anticipate the contro-
versy which arose in the colonial period between the protagonists of peasant and
plantation crops. For historians the schemes are especially noteworthy because
they expressed the realisation that the external slave trade would not simply die
of its own accord, and that a positive effort was required to find substitute
exports. Many of those engaged in this search were energetic and commercially
minded Christians, who were intent on converting the soul of Africa as well as
its economy. These men, the militant arm of the abolitionist movement, saw it
as their mission to carry the moral convictions and economic optimism of the
industrial world into the Dark Continent.
The most important and successful experiments, however, were those under-
taken by Africans themselves, without European supervision, indeed frequently
without expatriate officials and traders knowing what was happening. It is not
always realised just how varied the export economy was in some parts of West
Africa during the era of legitimate commerce. At Freetown, for instance, timber
accounted for about 70 per cent of all exports by 1829; by 1860 timber exports
had almost disappeared, and the main items of overseas trade were gold, palm
oil and groundnuts, each of which accounted for about 20 per cent of total
exports; by the 1880s these three products had also declined, and palm kernels
had become the dominant export.31 It was in the 1880s, too, and as a direct
result of the economic problems of the period, that Africans began cocoa farm-
ing in the Gold Coast and southern Nigeria, achieving results which none of
the European ‘experts’ could emulate. These examples illustrate that African
responses to changing returns on their exports were flexible and rapid, given the
31 P. K. Mitchell, ‘Trade Routes of the Early Sierra Leone Protectorate’, Sierra Leone Studies, 16,
1962, pp. 204–17.
The economic basis of imperialism 189
natural resources at their disposal and the technical constraints operating in the
nineteenth century, notably in internal transport.
Palm oil, palm kernels and groundnuts, the main staples of legitimate commerce,
were produced and delivered to the coast entirely through indigenous enterprise.
Yet because of the widespread assumption that the transition to legitimate com-
merce was easy and uneventful, some basic questions about the historical develop-
ment of these crops have still to be asked. For example, few historians have
appreciated that palm oil was not a homogeneous commodity. Some regions, such
as south-west Nigeria, produced a soft-quality oil which fetched a high price;
others, such as the Gold Coast, supplied a harder oil which was less in demand.
These distinctions deserve further consideration, for they are likely to supply much-
needed information about the resource base of the various export regions, about
differences in methods of preparation, and about the motives for developing alterna-
tive exports, such as why the Gold Coast expanded cocoa production at an earlier
date than did Nigeria. Similarly, not enough attention has been paid to the fact that
palm kernels did not simply join palm oil as an additional export but were devel-
oped largely to compensate for the decline of the latter in the second half of the
nineteenth century. Yet some regions exported a much greater proportion of ker-
nels to oil than did others, though both products were in joint supply. This, too, is
a difference which needs exploring further, for it may provide a clue to important
problems, such as the extent of internal trade in palm oil, and the ability of various
parts of the coast to adjust to the decline of staple exports in the late nineteenth
century. Finally, more thought needs to be given to the remarkable ‘do it yourself’
character of staple export production, in which each man became an entrepreneur
in his own right, albeit on a modest scale. Traditional economic frontiers were
broken down through the initiative of African migrants and settlers, who colonised
and developed previously underused land and in doing so brought about changes in
settlement patterns, farming practices, land tenure, and in the role, status and size of
the labour force engaged in export production.32 This is a theme of epic propor-
tions, which still awaits epic treatment.
European demand for vegetable oils had far-reaching economic, social and
political consequences in West Africa, though it is important to stress that these
were not identical in all parts of the region. Ultimately, it should be possible to
define and classify the various areas of West Africa according to the precise type
of adaptive challenge which confronted them, and the nature of their responses
to it. At present it is hard to do more than sketch the outlines of a complex
regional map. The following categories will be suggested here by way of prelim-
inary analysis.
32 On migration see Marion Johnson, ‘Migrants’ Progress’, Bulletin of the Ghana Geographical Associ-
ation, 9, 1964, pp. 4–27, and 10, 1965, pp. 13–40; and R. K. Udo, ‘The Migrant Tenant Farmer of
Eastern Nigeria’, Africa, 34, 1964, pp. 326–39. On land tenure see Akin L. Mabogunje, ‘Some
Comments on Land Tenure in Egba Division, Western Nigeria’, Africa, 31, 1961, pp. 258–69. The
expansion of ‘peasant’ exports in the twentieth century is dealt with in Chapter 6.
190 The economic basis of imperialism
To begin with, there were areas which experienced a decline in the staple
export, slaves, without securing adequate compensation in the form of new
products. This was particularly true of those parts of West Africa which were
either unsuitable for growing palm trees and groundnuts or were too far from
the coast for export production to be remunerative. The Western Sudan, with
its famous trans-Saharan commerce in decline after 1875, was a case in point,
for palm produce and groundnuts were bulky items with a low value to weight
ratio, unlike slaves, which could be traded profitably over long distances. Next,
there were areas which had not been involved in the external slave trade to any
great extent, and which were presented with new openings in the export sector.
This was the case along parts of the coast between Senegal and the Ivory Coast,
which began to export vegetable products in the nineteenth century. Finally,
there were areas in which the change to legitimate commerce meant a shift
from the production of slaves (at least as an export commodity) to the produc-
tion of vegetable oils. This applied to Senegambia and to most of the forest
from the Gold Coast eastwards. There is considerable justification for concen-
trating on the last category, apart from the convenient fact that it happens to be
the best documented. Not only was this extensive region by far the most
important supplier of legitimate exports, despite its close involvement with the
Atlantic slave trade,33 but it was also from points within this area that the Euro-
peans launched their invasion of the interior at the close of the century.34
The general development of this region as an export centre will be outlined
first; the position of export producers will then be investigated with particular
reference to the fortunes of the large entrepreneurs who had dominated produc-
tion during the time of the Atlantic slave trade; the survey will conclude by
examining the situation of the coastal wholesalers, using the Niger Delta as
a case study.
The supply of West African palm produce came from an area which stretched
from Guinea to the Cameroons, though the most important source lay in the
eastern section from the Gold Coast to Old Calabar. The prominence of this
sub-division was the result of the abundance of its oil-palms, which occurred
naturally in a broad belt lying close to the coast,35 and of the network of lagoons
33 In some cases (Old Calabar and Whydah are two obvious examples) it is clear that the overseas
slave trade developed entrepreneurial skills and commercial institutions which greatly assisted the
rise of legitimate trade. However, it would be wrong to infer that the slave trade was in any sense
necessary to the successful expansion of legitimate commerce. Everything that is known about Afri-
can enterprise in internal trade in the pre-colonial period strongly suggests that indigenous societies
would have produced the required number of wholesalers and traders, and in a short space of time,
even if the Atlantic slave trade had never existed.
34 At the same time, it is worthwhile pointing out that areas in the second category also experienced
some of the difficulties of economic transition. See E. A. Ijagbemi, ‘The Freetown Colony and the
Development of “Legitimate” Commerce in the Adjoining Territories’, Journal of the Historical Soci-
ety of Nigeria, 5, 1970, pp. 252–6.
35 Many palm trees were also planted deliberately.
The economic basis of imperialism 191
and inland waterways stretching from Porto Novo to Old Calabar, which made
it possible to transport produce relatively cheaply. In the period immediately
after 1807 the leading centre of production in West Africa was Old Calabar,
which shipped well over half the total palm oil imports entering Great Britain.
In the 1830s Old Calabar was joined, and for a while overtaken, by Bonny, fur-
ther west in the mouth of the Niger Delta. In the 1840s, exports from the Delta
as a whole averaged 15,000–20,000 tons per annum, which was equivalent to
about three-quarters of total oil imports into the United Kingdom. Bonny’s
supremacy lasted until the 1870s, when its suppliers and outlets were captured
by the nearby port of Opobo following a political coup. After the middle of the
century, other centres sprang up and the Niger Delta, though still very import-
ant, no longer completely dominated the West African oil trade. The geograph-
ical and quantitative expansion of legitimate commerce was closely associated
with the decline of the Atlantic slave trade, for until about the 1860s slaves still
competed successfully with palm oil at several points along the coast, especially
at Whydah and Lagos. By the third quarter of the century, palm produce was
the leading overseas export along a broad stretch of the West Coast. During the
last 20 years of the century oil and kernels accounted for over 70 per cent of
the value of total exports from the Gold Coast, over 80 per cent at Lagos and
over 90 per cent in Dahomey and the Niger Delta. A remarkable transformation
of the export economy had been achieved in a comparatively short space of
time.
Groundnuts, an annual crop, were grown for export in a region which
extended from Senegal to Sierra Leone, though as they prefer sandy soils and
a long, reliable dry season, Senegambia became by far the most prominent area
of production. Transport costs made it uneconomic to grow the crop for export
very far inland, so the main areas of production, as in the case of palm oil, lay
near the coast. The small British colony of Gambia was the earliest focal point
of the trade, partly, it is interesting to note, as a result of purchases made by
American traders.36 In the 1820s about 90 per cent of Gambia’s exports con-
sisted of beeswax and hides. Groundnuts were exported for the first time in the
1830s, and by the middle of the century they accounted for two-thirds of all
exports. A proportion of the groundnuts shipped from Gambia were grown in
areas which would have made use of ports in neighbouring French territory,
except for the fact that an export duty was levied on agricultural exports from
Senegal until 1855. With the removal of this duty, exports from Senegal greatly
increased. By the last quarter of the century, the export trade of Senegambia
was as dependent on groundnuts as the forest was on palm produce. The main
areas of production were Casamance, south of Gambia, and Cayor to the north.
(However, further north still, around St Louis, the export trade relied principally
on gum, as it had in the days of Atlantic commerce.) The groundnut trade, like
36 Brooks, Yankee Traders, Old Coasters and African Middlemen, pp. 184–9.
192 The economic basis of imperialism
the palm oil trade, saw the conversion of former slave ports into centres of legit-
imate commerce. Kaolack, for example, became a large centre for the groundnut
trade from the 1860s onwards.37 A great deal of additional historical research
needs to be carried out on most aspects of legitimate commerce, but especially
on the development of groundnut production. Fouquet, Pelissier and others
have made substantial contributions to the study of Senegalese groundnuts in the
modern context, but the economic history of the crop remains to be written.
In some parts of the underdeveloped world the requirements of the industrial
nations were consistent with the maintenance of the established social and political
order. Britain’s demand for Argentinian beef, for example, strengthened the position
of an already existing class of large landowners in that area, since cattle rearing was
most efficient on sizeable units of land.38 Peaceful economic integration was also
associated with a policy of political neutrality in Latin America, though it was not
the only reason for it. In West Africa, by contrast, the accidents of geography and
history which enabled small farmers and traders to participate efficiently in overseas
commerce posed acute problems of adaptation for the traditional warrior entrepre-
neurs who had cooperated so profitably with European slavers during the days of
the Atlantic trade. African rulers experimented with a number of modes of adapta-
tion to their new situation, and these can be classified according to their negative or
positive character. Four of the most important, which were adopted singly or in
conjunction, will be dealt with here.
The first negative response was to continue exporting slaves in defiance of the
ban imposed by the European nations. Little is known at present about the relative
profits of slaving and legitimate commerce, but it seems that few African slave
exporters turned willingly to the new trade, even though the terms of trade were
more favourable in the second quarter of the century than they were to become
later on. This reluctance may be taken as an indication that for established exporters
the costs of legitimate commerce (in terms of diminished political power as well as
of cash income) outweighed the returns. The predicament of Ghezo, the ruler of
Abomey, was duplicated in other parts of the West Coast:
The state which he maintained was great; his army was expensive; the cere-
monies and customs to be observed annually, which had been handed down
to him from his forefathers, entailed upon him a vast outlay of money. These
could not be abolished. The form of his government could not be suddenly
changed, without causing such a revolution as would deprive him of his
throne, and precipitate his kingdom into a state of anarchy.39
37 A. Dessertine, ‘Naissance d’un port: Kaolack, des origines à 1900’, Annales Africaines, 1960, pp.
225–59.
38 H. S. Ferns, ‘Latin America and Industrial Capitalism: The First Phase’, Sociological Review Mono-
graph, 11, 1967, pp. 18–20.
39 Brodie Cruickshank’s report of 1848, quoted in C. W. Newbury, The Western Slave Coast and Its
Rulers, Oxford 1961, p. 51.
The economic basis of imperialism 193
As for the palm oil trade, that was ‘a slow method of making money, and
brought only a very small amount of duties into his coffers’. Ghezo’s support of
the slave trade ceased only with his death in 1858. After the withdrawal of
European nations from the Atlantic trade, the shipment of slaves was handled
mainly by Brazilian merchants, such as Domingo Martinez, who operated in the
Bight of Benin between 1833 and 1864.40 The Brazilians were eventually elim-
inated by the naval squadron, by the closure of foreign slave markets and by
their own inability to procure the necessary European trade goods. By the end
of the 1860s the overseas slave trade had been reduced to a trickle. Responding
to the new trade by trying to perpetuate the old was no longer possible.
Next, African rulers attempted to bolster their fortunes by means which were
familiar to pre-industrial governments throughout the world, namely by employ-
ing armed strength to plunder and to exact tribute from their neighbours. The
kings of Senegambia used this tactic as an outlet for the energies of their hard-
drinking, hard-fighting warrior élite (tyeddo); Ashanti mixed force with diplo-
macy in order to control, or secure access to, the wealth of the coastal peoples;
the kings of Dahomey made annual incursions into Yoruba country; and the
Yoruba states themselves fought a series of wars in which economic goals were
prominent. Military operations and, perhaps more important, the constant threat
of them led to the abandonment of fertile land and to the creation of broad
areas of neutral territory between hostile states. They perpetuated conditions
which were inimical to the growth of the petty capitalism that had been fostered
by legitimate commerce. They dramatised what may be called the crisis of the
aristocracy in nineteenth-century West Africa, a social and political crisis stem-
ming from a contradiction between past and present relations of production.
They were a last resort and, as such, represented the ultimate failure of the
ancien régime to adapt peacefully and efficiently to the demands of the industrial
world.
The first of the two positive modes of adaptation was for former slave sup-
pliers to develop an export trade in legitimate goods. Some of them became
employers rather than exporters of slaves, and they used servile labour to harvest
palm trees, to grow groundnuts and to transport produce to markets. The rise of
legitimate commerce, far from bringing about the abolition of domestic slavery,
increased the demand for cheap labour in Africa itself, and so perpetuated
a service industry (the supply of slaves) which was detrimental to the long-term
development of the natural resources of the region. The result was the growth
of a small group of large export producers in areas which were near enough to
the coast for the transport of bulky goods to be a feasible proposition. In Daho-
mey and some of the Yoruba states, for example, the rulers and important chiefs
established large palm oil estates worked by slave labour. However, ‘big men’
40 David A. Ross, ‘The Career of Domingo Martinez in the Bight of Benin, 1833–64’, Journal of Afri-
can History, 6, 1965, pp. 79–90.
194 The economic basis of imperialism
now had to face competition at their palace gates from a multiplicity of small,
efficient farmers who were only partly committed to the overseas market, but
who supplied the greater part of the produce shipped to Europe in the second
half of the nineteenth century. The large producers found that they were unable
to influence local export prices simply by controlling production, as they had
done previously, yet at the same time they themselves were highly vulnerable to
changes in the prices paid for produce by European merchants on the coast,
since a sizeable part of their total incomes was derived from export earnings.
States which were not situated close to the coast had great difficulty in making
constructive adjustments to legitimate commerce. Ashanti, however, is an interest-
ing example of a partially exceptional case.41 Faced with a severe crisis early in the
nineteenth century, the rulers of Ashanti responded by expanding their export trade
to the north, selling kola nuts and buying cattle and slaves. Demand in the Hausa
states had grown following the jihāds of the early nineteenth century because kola
was an approved stimulant in Muslim communities, which were denied alcohol.
Supplies were increased partly by gathering kola nuts from wild trees, but mainly, it
appears, through the establishment of plantations worked by slave labour.42 Good
fortune, commercial skill and a highly efficient system of government helped Ash-
anti to adjust to the central economic problem which it faced in the nineteenth cen-
tury. Yet some important questions still have to be answered before the response of
Ashanti can be counted as an unqualified success. Not enough is known about the
total value and the rate of profit of the northern trade to say whether its expansion
in the nineteenth century fully compensated for the diminution of exports to the
south. It has to be remembered that the size of the internal market was still severely
limited by transport costs, and that the decline of trans-Saharan trade after 1875
might well have affected purchasing power in the north. Ashanti still depended on
the coast for supplies of munitions, salt and cotton goods, which came through sat-
ellites, such as the Fante states. These states now produced palm oil and kernels for
export, and no longer relied on Ashanti for supplies of slaves for shipment overseas.
Thus, it is likely that there was, from the Ashanti point of view, an unfavourable
shift in the balance of economic power. What is certain is that the attempt to
reassert control over the Fante in the second half of the century brought Ashanti
closer to conflict with the British. Evidently, more research is needed into the
potentially disintegrative elements within the Ashanti state: the implications for her
long-term economic welfare and political stability of the existence of marked
41 Very few historians of Africa can match Ivor Wilks’s achievement in reconstructing the history of
Ashanti. See, for example, ‘Ashanti Government’, in West African Kingdoms in the Nineteenth Cen-
tury, eds. Daryll Forde and P. M. Kaberry, London, 1967, pp. 206–38, and his study of the ‘war’
and ‘peace’ parties in Political Bi-polarity in Nineteenth-Century Asante, Centre of African Studies,
Edinburgh, 1971.
42 Ivor Wilks, ‘Asante Policy Towards the Hausa Trade in the Nineteenth Century’, in The Develop-
ment of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa, ed. Claude Meillassoux, London, 1971, pp.
124–41.
The economic basis of imperialism 195
inequalities of wealth, the growth of the slave labour force, and the frustration of
the merchant class, whose development was deliberately restrained, lest private
enterprise should harm the national interest, as conceived by the king.43
The second positive mode of adaptation was for traditional rulers to recognise
the small producers as a serious new force, and to give them an increased stake
in a reformed political system. For example, Lat Dior, the ruler of Cayor in
Senegal, tried to forge an alliance with the groundnut farmers of his state in the
1870s in an attempt to counterbalance the power of the traditional military
estate. However, support could not always be relied on, and aspirations, once
encouraged, tended to multiply. The small producers used their new wealth to
purchase, among other items, guns, and with these they could threaten the
rulers who sought their cooperation.44 The new generation of export producers
in West Africa had every reason to be wary of encouragement from their super-
iors, for rulers who allowed independent producers to develop did so in the
hope of taxing their wealth. Not surprisingly, this aim became a cause of fric-
tion, particularly in the last quarter of the century, when profits from the export
trade were reduced to a minimum. Furthermore, taxing small producers posed
serious practical problems. Collecting tolls from a convoy of slaves travelling on
an established route was easy enough, but, as the Aro of south-east Nigeria
found, levying duties on palm oil was an entirely different matter, for oil was
produced and traded in small quantities at many diverse points. Thus, the
attempt to accommodate the new capitalist class and secure the incomes of trad-
itional rulers was a difficult operation.
The negative responses may have helped to prevent a sudden decline in
incomes but were ultimately self-defeating. The positive responses achieved
better results but were still not wholly successful. The difficulties of the progres-
sive rulers arose partly from an internal conflict of interest stemming from
a basic change in the structure of export-producing firms, and partly from the
fact that they were unable or unwilling to make the necessary adjustments in the
time allowed by impatient and often unsympathetic foreigners. For a while it
seemed that there was a chance of stabilising the existing frontier between Euro-
peans and Africans on the West Coast, but in the last quarter of the century the
indigenous rulers were called on to make concessions over such matters as rail-
ways, internal tolls and slavery, which they judged, quite rightly, would under-
mine their political independence. At that point, the dialogue over peaceful
coexistence came to an end. Possessing fewer internal assets, and experiencing at
the same time greater external pressures, the modernising aristocracies of West
43 Some important work on these topics is by K. Arhin. See, for example, ‘The Structure of Greater
Ashanti’, Journal of African History, 8, 1967, pp. 65–85, and ‘Aspects of Ashanti Northern Trade in
the Nineteenth Century’, Africa, 40, 1970, pp. 363–73.
44 These developments are discussed by Martin Klein in ‘Slavery, the Slave Trade, and Legitimate
Commerce in Late Nineteenth-Century Africa’, Études d’Histoire Africaine, 2, 1971, pp. 22–4.
196 The economic basis of imperialism
Africa were less able to control their future than were their revolutionary coun-
terparts in Japan after 1868.45
As a general proposition, it can be said that the traditional unit of trade was
less affected by the structural changes brought about by legitimate commerce
than was the traditional unit of production. This was because large wholesalers
were still necessary, whether the commodities to be handled were slaves or palm
oil, whereas large producers were not. Many established entrepôts, such as
Whydah, Lagos, Bonny and Old Calabar, substituted palm oil for slaves and sur-
vived as major ports right down to partition, and in some cases beyond. Their
rulers continued to levy traditional taxes on visiting ships, and their leading mer-
chants received credit and goods on a larger scale than ever before. Even the old
trading premises survived: after abolition, the barracoons (warehouses where
slaves were kept pending shipment) were used to store the new, legitimate
exports. Although the entrepôts were not affected in precisely the same way as
producers in the hinterland, it does not follow that they were not affected at all
by the development of legitimate commerce, or that they found it any easier to
establish a lasting and satisfactory relationship with their European customers.
On the contrary, African rulers had to struggle in the nineteenth century to
control destabilising forces which threatened the cohesion of the entrepôts, and
sometimes their very existence. Some indication of the nature of these forces is
necessary for an understanding of the degrees of solidarity and disunity exhibited
by the middlemen states when faced with increased European pressure towards
the close of the century. The best illustration of their problems is provided by
the history of the area centring on the Niger Delta, which has been the subject
of some important research in recent years.46
Legitimate commerce presented opportunities to a new generation of traders,
as well as producers, because it gave employment to a greater number of inter-
mediaries, who were needed to collect export crops and to distribute manufac-
tured goods. Entry into small-scale trade was easy because there were few
barriers of capital or skill. The result was that existing wholesalers faced more
competition than they had in the past, though this is not to imply that such
rivalry was unimportant during the time of the Atlantic slave trade. The new
traders won their most striking success in the Niger Delta. Virtually all the ‘city
states’, as Dike has called them, experienced serious political unrest between
1850 and 1875, as slaves and ex-slaves challenged the authority of the established
wholesalers and rulers. This movement was personified by Ja Ja, the former slave
who rose to a position of economic importance in Bonny in the 1860s, but
45 A brief survey of this aspect of Japanese history is given in Thomas C. Smith, ‘Japan’s Aristocratic
Revolution’, Yale Review, 5, 1960–1, pp. 370–83.
46 The major studies are K. O. Dike, Trade and Politics in the Niger Delta, 1830–1885, Oxford, 1956;
G. I. Jones, The Trading States of the Oil Rivers, Oxford, 1963; Obaro Ikime, Merchant Prince of the
Niger Delta, London, 1968; and A. J. H. Latham, Old Calabar, 1600–1891: The Economic Impact of
the West upon a Traditional Society, University of Birmingham Ph.D. thesis, 1970.
The economic basis of imperialism 197
whose social origins prevented him from attaining the highest political office. In
1869 Ja Ja founded his own state at nearby Opobo, thus conferring on himself
the political power which he felt his commercial success deserved. The career of
Nana Olomu, the leading figure in Itsekiri trade and politics in the 1880s, pro-
vides another striking example of how advancement was becoming based on
commercial achievement rather than on inherited status, though Nana’s social
origins were less humble than Ja Ja’s, and he was able to further his political
ambitions in his home territory.47 Ability put a man in a strong position; ability
and acceptable family connections made him almost unassailable.
Indigenous commercial institutions in the Delta states were not entirely
immune from change and were affected by the alterations in personnel. At
Bonny and Kalabari, for example, the rise of men whose success was a result of
trading ability rather than of ascribed social position had repercussions on the
traditional canoe ‘house’ (a compact and well organised trading and fighting cor-
poration capable of maintaining a war canoe) because increased social mobility
led to a greater turnover of commercial and political authority. Jones has ana-
lysed the history of these states in the nineteenth century in terms of
a developmental cycle, which started with the expansion of a canoe house,
moved on to a phase of political accretion, in which several houses coalesced,
and culminated in varying degrees of disintegration, as unity broke down.48 For
present purposes it might also be useful to think of the economic aspects of this
cycle in terms of the theory of the firm, whereby a successful company expands,
takes over its rivals and achieves a local monopoly, only to find that its domin-
ance is undermined from within, as managers leave to start their own businesses,
and challenged from outside, as new competitors move in to try and secure
a share of the monopoly profit.
Certain qualifications to the foregoing analysis have to be made, even at the
risk of complicating the story. It should be noted that legitimate commerce
speeded social change in the trading states, but did not initiate it, for social
‘upstarts’ had also found scope for their talents during the days of the Atlantic
slave trade.49 Moreover, some states escaped slave revolts, and in others slave
risings were not always movements of the downtrodden against their masters. In
Kalabari, for example, class conflict was minimised by integrating mechanisms
which helped to assimilate slaves into society.50 In Old Calabar slave risings
were partly demonstrations in support of established, rival political factions, and
so served a functional purpose in reinforcing the status quo. Care must also be
47 On the problems of economic transition among the Itsekiri, see P. C. Lloyd, ‘The Isekiri in the
Nineteenth Century: An Outline Social History’, Journal of African History, 4, 1963, pp. 207–31.
48 Jones, Trading States of the Oil Rivers.
49 See, for example, Kwame Y. Daaku, Trade and Politics on the Gold Coast, 1600–1720, Oxford,
1970, Ch. 5.
50 Robin Horton, ‘From Fishing Village to City State: A Social History of New Calabar’, in Man in
Africa, ed. Mary Douglas and Phyllis M. Kaberry, London, 1969, pp. 37–58.
198 The economic basis of imperialism
taken not to romanticise the careers of the famous Delta traders. Some scholars,
understandably anxious to write African rather than imperial history, have seen
in these men the forerunners of the nationalist movements which developed in
the colonial period. This interpretation bestows on the actors a motive and sense
of purpose which they themselves would have had difficulty in recognising. The
leaders of the Delta states were great traders, and they certainly fought hard to
maintain their independence, but their world view did not extend much beyond
their local commercial interests, their vision of social justice did not include the
emancipation of their own slaves, and they resisted African as well as European
rivals with the true impartiality of homo economicus.
Besides the problem of internally generated instability, the entrepôts faced an
additional complication which did not affect the producers directly, namely the
physical presence of commercial agents from the Western world. In the second
half of the nineteenth century the growth of a bulk trade, combined with the
advent of the steamship, led the European merchants to set up many more shore
bases. With the merchants came missionaries and educated African ex-slaves.
This development was a serious threat to the position of the ruling oligarchy in
the entrepôts. In contrast to the era of the slave trade, when European visitors
tended to be sailors first and traders second, the newcomers were permanent and
competitive wholesalers. Furthermore, the presence of an expatriate community,
however small, had important political consequences. It acted as a magnet for
the disaffected, from slaves seeking freedom to disgruntled members of the local
oligarchy looking for external support for battles which they could not win on
their own. Since the European merchants were the main suppliers of credit,
whatever action they took, whether Machiavellian or innocent in intent, was
bound to have repercussions on the internal political situation, either confirming
the power of the existing rulers or building up the claims of rivals.
Potentially the most serious destabilising influence was the possibility of
a severe trade depression, an event which would have affected the large whole-
salers in much the same way as the large producers because both depended on
foreign trade for their livelihood. Indeed, it could be argued that the middlemen
were even more vulnerable than the producers since some of the entrepôts
relied on local imports for their basic supplies of food, and they nearly all lacked
an alternative means of maintaining their incomes. A crisis in foreign trade
would intensify internal rivalries by fostering disputes over the allocation of
shares in the export trade, over the prices to be asked and given, and over the
distribution of reduced profits. It would also increase external pressures. On the
one hand, European traders would try to pay less for produce and charge more
for manufactured goods; they would become more closely concerned as credit-
ors of faltering and bankrupt African wholesalers; and they would be tempted to
give support to families and houses which appeared more capable of safeguarding
their interests than did the existing rulers. On the other hand, the wholesalers
would run into difficulties with their hinterland customers, as they tried to pass
on the price changes which they themselves had been forced to accept. While
The economic basis of imperialism 199
trade remained prosperous these tendencies, though present, were held in check.
In the last quarter of the century, however, there was a radical change in the
situation.
African producers and wholesalers were not alone in facing problems of adap-
tation in the nineteenth century. Commercial interests on the European side of
the frontier were also profoundly affected by the expansion of overseas trade and
by the change in its character following the rise of legitimate exports. Two
developments helped to bring about a fundamental reorganisation of West Afri-
can trade after 1850, resulting in a greater degree of competition, the final
liquidation of eighteenth-century commercial practices, and the beginnings of
a recognisably modern organisational structure for the expatriate firms. The first
development, in terms of chronology, concerned ocean transport, and
the second involved alterations to the media of exchange used on the West
Coast. Just as there were reactionary, as well as progressive, elements on the
African side of the frontier, so, too, contrary to what might be supposed, there
were those among the European community who did their best to convince
themselves and their customers that the Industrial Revolution had never
occurred.
In the first half of the nineteenth century, the products of legitimate commerce
were carried to Europe by sailing ships, and the leading trading firms all possessed
ocean-going vessels. The Bordeaux firm of Maurel et Prom kept a sizeable fleet of
three-masted ships in service on the route to Senegal between the 1830s and the
1880s, and other large merchants, such as the London firm of F. & A. Swanzy,
which traded to the Gold Coast, followed this practice. However, shortly after the
middle of the century the technical development of the steamship reached a point
where it could begin to compete successfully with sail.51 The African Steam Ship
Company was formed in England in 1851 and began a regular service to the West
Coast in the following year. This firm was joined by another, the British & African
Steam Navigation Company in 1868, first as a rival and then as an associate. The
British lines were the most important serving West Africa, but other European
interests were also represented. In France, a consortium of Bordeaux and Marseilles
firms ran steamships to parts of West Africa in the 1870s before the formation of the
Fabre-Fraissinet line in 1889, and in Germany the merchant house of Woermann
began to run steamers to the West Coast in the 1870s, before the establishment of
the Woermann-Linie in 1886. During the third quarter of the century, the West
African carrying trade was converted to steam, and by the 1870s the sailing ship was
playing a secondary and diminishing role. In 1880 the number of sailing vessels
51 Technical supremacy, however, did not come until the 1880s. See Gerald S. Graham, ‘The
Ascendancy of the Sailing Ship, 1850–85’, Economic History Review, 9, 1956, pp. 74–88. Further
information about the beginnings of steamship services to West Africa can be found in
P. N. Davies, ‘The African Steam Ship Company’, in Liverpool and Merseyside, ed. J. R. Harris,
London, 1969, pp. 212–38, and in a neglected article by Emile Baillet, ‘Le rôle de la marine de
commerce dans l’implantation de la France en A.O.F.’, Revue Maritime, 135, 1957, pp. 832–40.
200 The economic basis of imperialism
entering Lagos harbour, for example, was about a third of the number of steamers
and represented only one sixth of the tonnage of the latter.
The second change centred on the decline of the main transitional currencies,
and on an increase in the circulation of modern money (especially British and
French silver coins) in the key exporting areas.52 In the present state of know-
ledge it is hard to make firm generalisations about this process, but it is certain
that the change was under way before the advent of colonial rule, though the
timing varied at different points along the West Coast. In the second half of the
nineteenth century iron and copper currencies and cowries underwent a serious
depreciation, and by the close of the century had ceased to play an important
part in external trade. Francs were used extensively in the groundnut trade as
early as the 1850s, and florins and shillings became the main media of exchange
for palm produce during the last quarter of the century. It is also the case that
the decline of these currencies was closely associated with a fall in the cost of
supplying them to West Africa. In Europe technical advances made it possible to
manufacture manillas and iron currencies more cheaply, and in Africa new
resources of cowrie shells were discovered on the East Coast around the middle
of the century. Improvements in ocean transport made it possible to deliver all
these currencies at reduced cost. European merchants, competing with each
other for the purchase of produce, began to flood the West African export
market with transitional monies. Over-issue undermined confidence and led to
a fall in exchange rates with other currencies. By the 1880s traders in some
centres needed porters to headload their small change, in much the same way as
workers in Germany needed suitcases to carry home their weekly earnings fol-
lowing the depreciation of the mark in the 1920s. The collapse of transitional
currencies undermined the barter system, which was closely associated with it,
and the mythical ounce and bar trade too, though again little is known at the
moment about this aspect of African monetary history.53
In the long run the advent of the steamship and the introduction of modern
money brought advantages to those engaged in overseas trade, principally
because they assisted the expansion of the market. Without these innovations
West Africa would certainly have become uncompetitive in international trade.
The steamship was cheaper per ton/mile than sail, and this was a vital consider-
ation at a time when the West African export trade had become centred on
bulky vegetable products, which, as noted earlier, were of low value per unit of
52 For further details see A. G. Hopkins, ‘The Currency Revolution in South-West Nigeria in the
Late Nineteenth Century’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1966, pp. 471–83, and a more
comprehensive article by Marion Johnson, ‘The Cowrie Currencies of West Africa’, Journal of Afri-
can History, 11, 1970, pp. 331–53.
53 Further work is also needed to clarify the consequences of the decline of transitional currencies for
African societies, particularly for fixed income groups and those wealthy enough to hold stocks of
money. It would also be interesting to know whether a depreciating exchange rate assisted exports
in the 1860s and 1870s.
The economic basis of imperialism 201
weight compared with slaves. The steamer was also faster than sail; in the
middle of the century sailing ships took about 35 days to reach West Africa, but
by 1900 the steamer had reduced this time by half. The speed of the steamship
made it possible to transport a wider range of perishable goods, and it enabled
traders to complete their transactions more quickly, thus helping them to econo-
mise on capital. In addition, the steamship, being less dependent on natural con-
ditions than was sail, could guarantee regularity of service. Foreknowledge of
the steamer’s arrival enabled traders to purchase and prepare goods for shipment.
Greater readiness reduced the time spent in port, and so lowered running costs.
Modern money helped to increase the number and variety of possible transac-
tions. British and French silver coins were almost perfect substitutes, that is to
say they were acceptable for virtually all goods and services. Africans who were
paid in silver coin for their produce received units of general purchasing power
instead of a packet of goods and transitional currencies. Export earnings could
be diverted more easily to domestic uses or could be spent on imported goods
supplied by a variety of firms. African producers and traders had more freedom
of choice: they were no longer tied to the firm which bought their produce,
and they enjoyed greater independence from rulers who previously had exer-
cised a degree of central control over export sales and over the distribution of
foreign trade earnings. It was no coincidence that francs and shillings spread in
areas where legitimate exports were developing most quickly, and it was no
coincidence either that low denomination coins were in great demand, for they
were an indication of the growing importance of small producers and traders in
the new export economy. These men were not innocents who had a modern
money economy thrust upon them by rapacious expatriate firms; they embraced
the new system willingly because it gave them the means of striking a better
bargain.
In the short run, however, the steamship and modern money had
a profoundly unsettling effect on West African trade. Essentially, they can be
regarded as external economies which made it easier for newcomers to enter
West Coast commerce. The result was a marked increase in competition in
the second half of the nineteenth century. With the arrival of the steamship, the
trader whose resources were very limited could hire a small amount of cargo
space for a short period of time. Merchants trading to West Africa did not need
to buy their own ships, nor did they have to join a consortium to charter one.
Few of the established firms, apart from Woermann, were able to convert to
steam, partly because the initial capital investment needed to build an ocean-
going steamer was much greater than that required for a sailing vessel, and partly
because more working capital was needed to finance the expansion of legitimate
commerce.54 The result was that trading and carrying became separate activities,
54 C. W. Newbury, ‘Credit in Early Nineteenth-Century West African Trade’, Journal of African His-
tory, 13, 1972, pp. 81–95.
202 The economic basis of imperialism
and the established firms were less able to keep control of new entrants than in
the days when they also monopolised shipping space. Moreover, and this is
a feature which is often overlooked, the steamer also concentrated competition
at the ports of call, in contrast to the days of sail, when ships could adapt their
schedules to meet varying market conditions. Evidence of increasing concentra-
tion was to be seen in the expansion of a few favoured centres, such as Dakar,
Freetown and Lagos, and, ultimately, in the decline of well-known trading sta-
tions, such as St Louis, Cape Coast and Opobo.
The commercial effect of the steamship has been commented on by McPhee and
subsequent writers, but the consequences of monetary change have not been fully
appreciated. The steamer brought new traders to the coast, but it could not help
them to trade once they had arrived. As long as barter and transitional currencies
remained firmly entrenched, newcomers were at a severe disadvantage, for they had
to master the complexities of a pre-industrial monetary system, itself a serious barrier
to entry; they had to acquire these strange currencies, in some cases from the estab-
lished firms; and they had to be prepared to engage both in importing and in export-
ing. For example, a new trader hoping to sell cotton goods would have to take
produce in exchange, since transitional currencies were not an acceptable means of
payment in Europe. Cash payments made it possible to separate the two trades, and
enabled firms to specialise in one or other if they wished. This specialisation reduced
the capital required for entering West African trade and encouraged competition. No
wonder the old-established European firms, far from trying to ‘entangle Africans in
the web of a money economy’ strove to maintain the barter system for as long as
possible. In this respect some of the ‘natives’ of Liverpool and Marseilles were far
more conservative than those in the hinterlands of Dakar and Lagos!
Evidence of increasing competition can be seen in the appearance of two new
groups of traders in the second half of the century. First, there were progressive
European merchants who had little or no previous connection with West
Africa, but who established themselves by taking advantage of the steamer and
of cash transactions. For example, Cheri Peyrissac began as a clerk at St Louis
(Senegal) in 1862, and later built up a large independent import and export busi-
ness based on manufactured goods and groundnuts; the Hamburg industrial con-
cern of G. L. Gaiser expanded into West African trade in 1869 in order to
secure supplies of palm produce for its oil mills, and was one of the first firms to
develop a cash trade; the Manchester firm of John Walkden & Company started
to trade with West Africa in 1868 as a mail order business, supplying manufac-
tured goods on commission; and John Holt, a Liverpool merchant, broke into
the Niger Delta trade in the 1870s, and later established branches in other parts
of what was to become Nigeria.55 Many of the older firms tried to adapt to
55 On Gaiser and Holt see Ernst Hieke, G. L. Gaiser: Hamburg–Westafrica, Hamburg, 1949; and
Cherry J. Gertzel, John Holt: A British Merchant in West Africa in the Era of Imperialism, University of
Oxford D. Phil. thesis, 1959.
The economic basis of imperialism 203
legitimate commerce, but very few lasted until the end of the century. They
had every incentive to adjust to the new conditions because they had sunk cap-
ital into African trade, they had spent years building up connections, and many
of them were creditors of African suppliers. Thus, John Tobin, a Liverpool slave
trader, pioneered the palm oil trade in the Niger Delta early in the century.
However, firms of this type were nearly all eliminated by the steamship and by
the collapse of barter. Perhaps the most spectacular rearguard action was that
fought by F. & A. Swanzy, which, with Forster & Smith, dominated the over-
seas trade of the Gold Coast in the early 1850s. Swanzy’s reaction to the advent
of the steamer was not to modernise their business, but to try to establish a local
monopoly of palm oil supplies. Unfortunately for them, the producers retaliated
by successfully boycotting the firm between 1858 and 1866.56 Swanzy’s man-
aged to survive, but the firm declined in importance. The steamer, it could be
said, had taken all the wind out of their sails.
The second new group of merchants were Africans, consisting mainly of lib-
erated slaves and their descendants, men who grew up in settlements such as
Freetown and Libreville, where they were converted to Christianity, took Euro-
pean names and received some education from expatriate missionaries. These
merchants, in sharp contrast to their slave-trading predecessors, were noted for
their Victorian dress, bourgeois values and commitment to legitimate commerce.
It was intended that they should form the nucleus of an African middle class,
which would develop the continent’s economy and uplift its spiritual life.
Although numerically a small group, these liberated Africans had considerable
importance in the second half of the nineteenth century. Many of them returned
to their homelands, and so made their presence felt in most of the main urban
centres on the West Coast. Furthermore, since they became lawyers, civil ser-
vants and missionaries, as well as merchants, their influence spread over a wide
occupational front. Essentially, their role was that of cultural intermediaries, men
who straddled the frontier between Europe and Africa, interpreting, in the
broadest sense of the word, one to the other. Europeans often referred to them,
contemptuously, as ‘trousered Africans’, and Africans criticised them for behav-
ing as Uncle Toms. However, thanks to the painstaking work of Christopher
Fyfe and others, it is now appreciated (or at least it should now be appreciated)
that these were men of genuine dignity and considerable historical
significance.57 They performed an important function in introducing the West-
ern world to Africa, yet they were by no means as alienated from their indigen-
ous culture as has been alleged. They demonstrated to sceptical Europeans that
56 Freda Wolfson, ‘A Price Agreement on the Gold Coast: The Krobo Oil Boycott, 1858–1866’, Eco-
nomic History Review, 6, 1953, pp. 68–77.
57 Christopher Fyfe, A History of Sierra Leone, Oxford, 1962. See also Arthur T. Porter, Creoledom,
Oxford, 1963, and Margaret Priestley, West African Trade and Coast Society, London, 1969.
204 The economic basis of imperialism
Africans were not barbarians, and they were among the first to proclaim that
Africa had a history of its own.
Helped by the steamer and by the transition to cash payments, these mer-
chants mostly became low-cost, import specialists, acting either as independent
wholesalers and retailers, or as agents selling goods on commission for manufac-
turing firms in Europe. Some were involved in the export trade, but the import
business was preferred because it required less capital and also spread investments
over a wider range of goods than the produce trade, which in addition experi-
enced considerable short-run price fluctuations. Before 1900, when trading con-
ditions once again began to favour large firms, a number of African merchants
owned businesses which were as large as some of the European firms, though of
course the latter were much smaller than they were to become in the twentieth
century. Business profits tended to be attracted into property and education, two
assets which continued to appreciate during the nineteenth and twentieth cen-
turies irrespective of political changes.
One of the most outstanding of this new generation of Africans was Richard
Blaize (1845–1904), who left Freetown in 1862 and made his business career in
Lagos.58 Blaize reckoned that he had earned the greater part of his fortune
during the 1860s and 1870s, and was appalled by the narrow profit margins
which ruled towards the end of the century. In the 1880s, he built a new house
and shop, which still stand on the Marina, and he also acquired ‘a landau and
pair of greys with which he drives out occasionally—footman and coachman on
the box’. In 1896 a European official estimated that Blaize was worth about
£150,000, which is a large sum even today, when the value of the pound ster-
ling is far less than it was in the nineteenth century. Blaize’s business, like that
of most of his African contemporaries, died with him. However, the Blaize
Memorial Institute, which was founded soon after his death with money left by
him for that purpose, still flourishes and contributes to what are now regarded as
important functions, namely encouraging local manufacturing activities and pro-
viding Africans with technical training.
These two groups of merchants will be considered in more detail in Chapter
6. The main point to record in the present context is that there were pro-
nounced economic rivalries among firms on the European side of the frontier,
just as there were among African suppliers. Competition between European
firms was characterised by bouts of cooperation and conflict which bore some
resemblance to the accretion-fission cycle experienced by the canoe houses of
the Niger Delta. Typically, a newcomer trying to become established in one of
the West African markets would begin by fixing his prices at levels which were
more attractive than those of the established firms. These firms retaliated and
a price war followed. If this failed to drive out the new entrant, a compromise
58 A. G. Hopkins, ‘Richard Beale Blaize, 1854–1904: Merchant Prince of West Africa’, Tarikh, 1,
1966, pp. 70–9.
The economic basis of imperialism 205
was eventually reached which allowed him to trade in the area on the under-
standing that competition was kept within ‘reasonable’ bounds. However, usu-
ally it was not long before the equilibrium was upset once again, either by the
defection of an existing firm, or by the arrival of another outsider.
The trend was undoubtedly towards greater efficiency. In order to survive,
firms had to adjust to the advent of the steamship, and to the development of
cash transactions, and they also had to make internal improvements, as did John
Holt, by employing better staff and by buying manufactures in bulk where pos-
sible. By the last quarter of the century, evidence from the Gold Coast, Daho-
mey, Lagos, the Niger Delta and Old Calabar indicates that profit margins had
been greatly reduced. The commercial practices of the eighteenth century had
finally disappeared, and the merchants, though not all of them realised it, were,
in terms of business history, on the brink of the twentieth century, when whole-
salers became accustomed to relying on narrower margins and on a much larger
turnover. In 1875, however, the import and export market was still confined to
a few coastal enclaves, and no additional cost-reducing innovations were possible
within the existing political framework.
The adverse movement in the terms of trade in the last quarter of the nine-
teenth century had a serious effect on those engaged in the difficult process of
adapting to legitimate commerce. Normal, non-violent commercial relationships
started to break down, and the ‘moral community’ of traders, already under
some strain, began to dissolve. The trade depression intensified rivalries within
the various interest groups and between African producers on the one hand, and
European firms on the other. Essentially, the dispute was over the distribution
of reduced profits. The decline in the barter terms of trade affected the Euro-
pean firms in West Africa as well as primary producers. Initially, it was these
firms which received lower prices for produce in Europe, and it was up to them
to try and pass on reductions to their African suppliers. The extent to which
they were successful depended on the balance of commercial power in individ-
ual West African markets. Not surprisingly, there was a fierce struggle in the
late nineteenth century as each party sought to control the local market and to
dictate terms to the other.
Evidence from various parts of the West Coast suggests that there were five
main aspects of this struggle. None was entirely new, but each became more
pronounced during the last quarter of the century. First, there were malpractices,
such as diluting palm oil and misrepresenting the quality and length of cloth,
which both sides adopted in an attempt to secure a better bargain than could be
contrived by legitimate means. Second, there were demarcation disputes over
functions and areas of influence. For example, some European firms, such as the
Royal Niger Company, tried to move inland in the hope of buying export
crops more cheaply from the producers than from the coastal wholesalers.59
59 See J. E. Flint’s important study, Sir George Goldie and the Making of Nigeria, London, 1960.
206 The economic basis of imperialism
These moves often provoked retaliation, as when traders from Brass destroyed
the Niger Company’s base at Akassa in 1894. Similarly, some Africans tried to
sell their oil direct to Europe. It was Ja Ja’s threat to bypass the European
middlemen in this way that was largely responsible for his expulsion from
Opobo in 1887. Third, there were serious disputes, common everywhere at
times of depression, and aggravated in the African case by the depreciation in
the value of transitional currencies, about the repayment of the advances which
European firms had made to African suppliers. Fourth, there were deliberate
interruptions to the supply of produce. The Moors withheld supplies of gum in
1885–86, the Yoruba closed their export markets at one time or another during
the 1880s, and the Itsekiri held up palm oil exports in 1886–87. The aim in all
cases was to force European merchants to accept the suppliers’ terms of sale,
a policy which was to be repeated in the 1930s, when West Africa’s foreign
trade underwent its next great crisis. Finally, there were arguments about
escaped slaves, many of whom sought refuge in the European colonies on the
coast. Large-scale African producers and traders resented the loss of their human
capital, especially at a time when trade conditions dictated that slave labour
should be fully exploited.
The outcome was a compromise which affected both parties adversely, and so
satisfied neither. Africans were hit at a time when they were unable to achieve
economies in production and transportation, and Europeans were hit at a time
when their profit margins had already been reduced by increased competition.
In these unprecedented circumstances the merchants, though traditionally suspi-
cious of moves to expand the role of government, which they associated with
increased regulations and additional taxes, began to press for a more active
policy.60 What is more, they also displayed an unaccustomed willingness to
accept higher taxation to pay for action taken on their behalf. In making this
decision, the merchants were undoubtedly influenced by the fact that the cost of
coercion had been greatly reduced in the late nineteenth century by the inven-
tion of two daunting pieces of military equipment, the Gatling gun and the
Maxim gun.
The merchants’ call for action was backed, and indeed, often led, by colonial
administrators.61 Ambitious officials were well aware that posts in West Africa
were rarely springboards to fame even at the best of times, and that a trade
depression was scarcely the ideal setting for a distinguished career. They were
charged with the task of protecting trade, yet when diplomacy failed, as it fre-
quently did, they were unable to influence the policies of the African states
which were the main trading partners of the European colonies. The
60 Information about mercantile pressures can be found in many of the items listed in the Bibliog-
raphy: see especially Aderibigbe, Dike, Dumett, Flint, Hopkins (1968), Latham and Newbury
(1959, 1968, 1969 and 1972).
61 C. W. Newbury and A. S. Kanya-Forstner, ‘French Policy and the Origins of the Scramble for
West Africa’, Journal of African History, 10, 1969, pp. 253–76.
The economic basis of imperialism 207
62 Cherry J. Gertzel, ‘Relations between African and European Traders in the Niger Delta,
1880–1896’, Journal of African History, 3, 1962, pp. 361–6.
208 The economic basis of imperialism
firms, were now prepared to move inland once the government had cleared the
way. A bigger turnover was needed if profits were to grow; firm political boundar-
ies were required to prevent trade from falling into the hands of other European
rivals; and new products had to be found to re-establish the prosperity of the export
trade. France and Britain hoped that there was more than fool’s gold in the interior,
and that some of the fabled wealth of the Western Sudan would rub off on them.
It is now necessary to take a closer look at the policies of the three main Euro-
pean nations with interests in West Africa, because ultimately it was decisions made
by them which led to the partition of the continent. As far as Great Britain was
concerned, her trading success appeared to support the anti-colonial arguments of
Adam Smith and his followers, and it was certainly hard to see what Britain could
gain by creating colonies in West Africa when she already dominated trade without
them. In contrast to a once popular view, Britain’s policy-makers were not itching
to establish colonies throughout the world.63 Britain’s chief aim in West Africa was
to maintain free trade without political involvement, and to persuade France and
Germany to do the same. Free trade, though sometimes presented as a high-minded
principle capable of bringing prosperity with honour to the comity of nations, was
in reality a passport to British supremacy. In conditions of ‘equal’ competition, Brit-
ain was likely to dominate most world markets because she could produce and
transport manufactured goods more cheaply than could any of her rivals. Given this
advantage, it is understandable that Britain was unlikely to initiate a forward policy.
At the same time, it is important to remember that the maintenance of the status
quo in West Africa depended on factors which were largely beyond Britain’s con-
trol. If Britain’s European rivals decided not to cooperate in upholding her suprem-
acy, or if there was a serious threat to trade as a result of developments on the
African side of the frontier, then Britain might be forced to change her traditional
policy, for she had a moral obligation to support her traders in international markets.
The obligation was not binding in all cases, and it had to be judged in relation to
the wider, national interest, but it was a factor to be considered in the formulation
of policy. In 1865 a Parliamentary Committee had recommended withdrawing
from several parts of the West Coast, but by the 1880s it was realised in the metrop-
olis that Britain’s commitments were too large for disengagement to be possible.
Superficially, French policy appeared to have much in common with that of Great
Britain. France, like Britain, wanted to develop a flourishing and peaceful trade with
West Africa, and she was willing to work through indigenous authorities where
possible.64 From the 1830s she began to move towards a liberal tariff regime on the
63 Two of the best studies of British policy towards Africa are Ronald Robinson and John Gallagher
with Alice Denny, Africa and the Victorians, London, 1961, and John D. Hargreaves, Prelude to the
Partition of West Africa, London, 1963. For a global perspective see D. C. M. Platt, Finance, Trade
and Politics in British Foreign Policy, 1815–1914, Oxford, 1968.
64 On French policy see Henri Brunschwig, French Colonialism, 1871–1914: Myths and Realities,
London, 1966, and, for more detail on West Africa, Bernard Schnapper, La politique et le commerce
français dans le Golfe de Guinée de 1838 à 1871, Paris, 1961.
The economic basis of imperialism 209
West Coast, and she also exercised a degree of political restraint which, broadly speak-
ing, kept her in step with Britain. Yet it is now recognised that France took the initia-
tive in the ‘scramble’ for West Africa. Gallagher and Robinson have argued that it was
a political crisis in Egypt in 1882, a rebuff for France, which caused her to adopt
a more aggressive policy in West Africa, but so far this view, stimulating though it is,
has not been confirmed by the research it has helped to inspire.65 Brunschwig has
explained French expansion in terms of a search for national prestige, but this inter-
pretation is not quite as helpful as it seems at first sight, since without close definition
the phrase ‘national prestige’ becomes a vague and all-embracing concept.66 It will be
suggested here that there was an important economic motive in French imperialism,
and that France altered her policy not because her basic aims had changed, but because
she came to realise that different means were required if they were ever going to be
achieved. This conclusion did not come as a sudden flash of insight. It was a gradual
acknowledgement of long-standing facts, namely that with the passage of time the dis-
parity between French and British economic progress and global influence had
increased rather than diminished, and that France was also being overtaken in Europe
by German industrial and military power.
France had long-standing, global commercial ambitions, but few of these had
been realised. Where she laboured, it seemed, Great Britain collected the
rewards. India and Canada were lost to Britain in the eighteenth century, and
France herself was defeated in Europe in 1815 after a series of wars which
played a large part in retarding her economic development in the nineteenth
century.67 Britain, by contrast, emerged from the Napoleonic Wars with her
Industrial Revolution already under way. Since the victors of Waterloo then
pressed the French into declaring the slave trade illegal, it is not surprising that
France viewed abolition as the final move in a British plot to destroy what was
left of her Atlantic commerce. Any illusions that France had recovered her
former power by the middle of the nineteenth century, at least in Europe, were
shattered by the defeat which she suffered at the hands of Germany in 1870.
France was anxious to emulate Britain’s industrial progress, which, according
to some observers, was closely related to the growth of her trading and political
influence overseas. Africa was regarded as a hopeful starting point for a French
recovery because it was reasonably close to Europe, it had long-standing con-
nections with France, and, above all, it was still largely unclaimed—except, of
course, by Africans. Senegal was re-occupied in 1817, and some fortified posts
were established at Assinie, Grand Bassam and Gabon in the 1840s. These
moves, together with the conquest of Algeria in the 1830s, gave some momen-
tum to the notion that France had an imperial destiny in Africa: the idea of link-
ing West and North Africa was current in Paris long before the British began
talking of joining the Cape to Cairo. Yet France gained no spectacular successes.
The fortified posts, as Schnapper has shown, achieved very little, and the expan-
sion of legitimate commerce benefited Britain more than any other European
power.68 Only in Senegal was there some basis for optimism. French commer-
cial interests there had been saved by the fortuitous development of the ground-
nut trade, and by the adoption of measures which limited the entry of foreign
traders. Even in the mid-nineteenth century, France had not allowed herself to
be mesmerised completely by Britain’s advocacy of the free trade cause. During
the last quarter of the nineteenth century she was to move even closer to pro-
tectionist policies, and in doing so was to undermine the basis of Britain’s pos-
ition in West Africa.
France, unlike Britain, had an incentive to upset the status quo in West
Africa. She did not want to provoke Britain by a direct challenge, but she still
had plenty of room for manoeuvre, for it was the weakness as well as the
strength of the British position that her commercial supremacy had not been
accompanied by the large-scale annexation of territory. French imperial policy
in the late nineteenth century was driven by a potent combination of forces: on
the one hand by a fear that British economic expansion, spearheaded by Man-
chester textiles and backed by the world’s strongest navy, would frustrate her
ambitions once again; and on the other hand by an optimism about the wealth
of Africa which had not been equalled since the Moroccans trekked hopefully
across the desert in 1591.
German interests in West Africa will be noted briefly in order to explain their
influence on the policies of the two major powers.69 The German presence
became a factor of some weight in the deliberations of London and Paris during
the last quarter of the century, when, as has been pointed out, Hamburg mer-
chants were rapidly expanding their share of West African trade. German firms
were concentrated at some sensitive points: in Liberia, which was flanked by
British interests in Sierra Leone and French interests in the Ivory Coast; in what
was to become Togoland, a thin wedge of territory between the Gold Coast
and Dahomey, centres of British and French activity respectively; in Dahomey
itself, where they had succeeded in capturing the greater part of the region’s
overseas trade by the 1880s; and in what were to become southern Nigeria and
the Cameroons, which coincided with Britain’s major trading interests in Lagos,
the Niger Delta and Old Calabar. In the 1880s the German government made
an increasing show of protecting its traders on the West Coast, partly as a result
of direct mercantile pressures and partly as an offshoot of a campaign for tariff
protection started by industrialists in response to the onset of the Great
Depression.70 Britain and France regarded the German presence as a serious
threat to their own West African interests, and feared that a forward move by
her might result in the exclusion of their trading firms from the unclaimed mar-
kets of Africa. For France, already worried about British commercial dominance,
this new danger appeared to justify a more decisive, forward policy; for Britain,
slowly waking up to the fact that the era of laissez-faire might not last indefin-
itely, it meant that she had to consider defensive action against two ambitious
rivals, not just one.
The demands made by British and French merchants were very similar, but
rivalry between the European powers meant that they did not coordinate their
policies to produce a joint invasion of Africa, though gentlemen’s agreements
were occasionally made with regard to specific areas. On the contrary, the eco-
nomic crisis between 1875 and 1900 intensified the antagonism between Britain
and France and led to competition for African territory. One feature of the
rivalry was a more aggressive element in the relationship between British and
French firms. The foundation of the Compagnie Française de l’Afrique Équator-
iale in 1880 and the Compagnie du Sénégal in the following year marked a new
phase in French efforts to break into richer and predominantly British markets
in West Africa.71 These firms started trading in the Niger Delta, quickly estab-
lished branches as far as the River Benue, and threatened to expand further still
into what is now northern Nigeria. This enterprising exercise of the rights of
free trade caused Britain some initial embarrassment. However, the French
could not compete for long against the might of the National African Company,
which bought out the French firms in 1884.72 This episode demonstrated that
British supremacy could not be challenged successfully by purely commercial
means, at least by France. The French did not give up their hopes of penetrating
the interior from the Guinea coast, but future efforts were to be launched from
bases in their own colonies of Dahomey and the Ivory Coast and were to be
directed by soldiers rather than by traders.
The other feature of Anglo-French commercial rivalry was growing friction
over areas of customs jurisdiction and levels of tariffs. The economic crisis of the
late nineteenth century intensified the search for revenue and led officials to
extend the boundaries of their colonies, sometimes with, but usually without,
70 Hartmut Pogge von Strandmann, ‘Germany’s Colonial Expansion under Bismarck’, Past & Present,
42, 1969, pp. 140–59; and Hans-Ulrich Wehler, ‘Bismarck’s Imperialism, 1862–1890’, Past & Pre-
sent, 48, 1970, pp. 131–9.
71 C. W. Newbury, ‘The Development of French Policy on the Lower and Upper Niger, 1880–98’,
Journal of Modern History, 31, 1959, pp. 16–26.
72 This firm began life as the United African Company in 1879, became the National African Com-
pany in 1882, and finally turned itself into the Royal Niger Company in 1886.
212 The economic basis of imperialism
instructions from the metropolis. These moves caused serious disputes, as rival
administrations, expanding laterally along the coast, met each other, as they did
for example in the area of Sierra Leone, on the Gold Coast, and at the frontier
between Dahomey and Lagos. At the same time, France began to adopt differ-
ential tariffs in West Africa as a means of increasing revenue and assisting her
trade. The shift to a more protectionist policy was mainly a result of pressure
from French metallurgical, textile and chemical industries, which had difficulty
in competing with British products in world markets.73 Many of the traders in
centres such as Nantes, Bordeaux and Marseilles were opposed to protection to
begin with, but were won over in the 1880s. Differential tariffs were imposed
in Senegal in 1877 and in the Ivory Coast in 1889. Britain, of course, protested
that these actions were contrary to the principles of free trade. The French
replied that tariffs in British colonies already had a differential effect because
they were high on certain goods, such as brandy and wine, which were mainly
French, and low on textiles, which were mainly British. By the 1880s the con-
cept of free trade in West Africa was coming under attack, and the weak spots
in Britain’s empire of informal rule were being revealed.
In Britain, France and Germany, West African affairs were taken up by spe-
cialised organisations, such as chambers of commerce, and by an assortment of
more broadly based imperial movements which were developing rapidly in the
last quarter of the nineteenth century.74 The chambers of commerce in Liver-
pool, Manchester, Bordeaux, Marseilles and Hamburg publicised African prob-
lems in the press, lobbied local members of parliament and made direct contact
with leading figures in the government. Outside the chambers of commerce
African questions were drawn into a variety of campaigns: some dominated by
economic interest groups which, without necessarily having any specific
involvement in Africa, were agitating in France for protectionist measures, and
in Britain for what, more circumspectly, was called ‘fair’ trade;75 others led by
politicians who saw imperialism as a means of saving Europe from socialism; and
others still, headed by geographers, journalists, intellectuals and sundry eccen-
trics, who were beginning to talk in somewhat mystical terms about the rela-
tionship between empire and national greatness. Of course, the imperial
movement was by no means united. Some industrialists wanted colonies in
order to create guaranteed markets for their exports, but others were indifferent
to colonial expansion because in the late nineteenth century, with the terms of
trade moving against primary producers, they were able to buy raw materials
cheaply.
73 C. W. Newbury, ‘The Protectionist Revival in French Colonial Trade: The Case of Senegal’, Eco-
nomic History Review, 21, 1968, pp. 337–48.
74 Bernard Semmel, Imperialism and Social Reform, London, 1960.
75 The best general study is still B. H. Brown, The Tariff Reform Movement in Great Britain, 1881–95,
New York, 1943. For a case study of one area see R. J. Ward, The Tariff Reform Movement in Bir-
mingham, 1877–1906, University of London M.A. thesis, 1971.
The economic basis of imperialism 213
It is clear that further research is needed to identify all the channels of com-
munication which existed between the men on the spot in Africa and those
who formally announced decisions in London and Paris, and to evaluate the
extent to which politicians were susceptible to pressures from pro-imperial inter-
est groups representing what might be called the ‘unofficial mind’ of
imperialism.76 At present it can be said that governments were subjected to con-
siderable and increasing pressures in the later nineteenth century, and that these
pressures were more effective in France than in Britain because French business-
men were less divided by entrenched commitments to free trade, and were
more inclined to put their faith, if not always their investments, in imperial
expansion.
What seems beyond dispute is that those in power in France were more
inclined to take notice of imperial pressure groups than were those in Britain.
Under the Third Republic the political influence of provincial businessmen
increased, and a group of leaders emerged, such as Freycinet, Jauréguiberry and
Rouvier, who were prepared not merely to be influenced by others, but actually
to direct the movement for colonial expansion.77 In Britain, by contrast, policy-
makers in both parties were reluctant to admit that circumstances had altered,
and that attitudes would have to change too. In the 1880s British policy was still
based on two established notions: an unrealistic optimism about the possibility of
equalising tariffs and preserving free trade, an optimism which France was happy to
encourage while her troops advanced inland; and a belief in the value of appease-
ment, that is the distribution of other peoples’ territories in the hope of stabilising
an inherently unstable situation. Since the facts refused to change, no matter how
long British politicians kept their eyes closed, it was the politicians themselves who
eventually had to modify their traditional attitudes towards empire. By the 1890s,
both Liberals and Conservatives were beginning to recognise that a more active
policy was required if any of Britain’s traditional spheres of influence in West Africa
were to be preserved. It would be a mistake to think that Joseph Chamberlain
came, like a bolt from the blue, and created, single-handed, a new attitude towards
imperial affairs. Nevertheless, it was not until he became colonial secretary in 1895
that Britain had a Rouvier of her own.
By the time Britain had decided that a more positive policy was needed, the
partition of West Africa was well under way. In 1879 the French began to
advance across the Western Sudan from Senegal, reaching Bamako (600 miles
inland) in 1883, Timbuctu in 1893, and Lake Chad (2,000 miles from Dakar) in
1900. At the same time, the invasion forces branched south, striking deep into
76 Two interesting local studies are John F. Laffey, ‘The Roots of French Imperialism in the Nine-
teenth Century: The Case of Lyon’, French Historical Studies, 6, 1969, pp. 78–92, and
W. Thompson, Glasgow and Africa: Connexions and Attitudes, 1870–1900, University of Strathclyde
Ph.D. thesis, 1970.
77 C. M. Andrew and A. S. Kanya-Forstner, ‘The French “Colonial Party”: Its Composition, Aims
and Influence, 1885–1914’, The Historical Journal, 14, 1971, pp. 99–128.
15°W 10°W 5°W Timbuctu 0° 5°E from 10°E 15°E
MAURITANIA 1893-4 N.Africa
Agades
R.
St. Louis Se Gao
ne Nioro
ga
1891 NIGER
l
15°N SENEGAL
L. Chad 15°N
R.
Dakar FRENCH SUDAN 1900
N
1889 Kayes Zinder
ig
A
er
Bathurst Segou LT
VO 1899
Ouagadougou Say Sokoto
18
1891 98 6
97 Bamako - 1 90
1884 - 1896
R
Cacheu 1883 Kano
Bissau FOUTA DJALLON
PE
Gando 1903
PORTUGUESE 1898 1902
1887 - 96 1897
UP
GUINEA Zaria
93
18
1897 Nikki
87
18
FRENCH G
10°N Bussa
UI
Bissagos Is. 1889´ - 95
T
Conakry NIGERIA 18
NE
e Yola 94
A
G
nu
190
SIERRA
O
Be
Los Is. LEONE R.
3
R.
Ilorin 1897
18
ASHANTI
Vo
Lokoja
lt
LAND
189
88
French controlled 85
a
1 Ibadan 1888
6 1892
DAHOMEY
18
1906 1894
Kumasi 1885
-9
territory c. 1880 - 1 889
0
90 1896
Lines of French Sherbro Is. LIBERIA 7
IVORY A ST - Lagos
advance after c. Monrovia T D CO
COAS Porto Novo
FRENCH CONGO
the Fouta Djallon (later part of French Guinea), the Ivory Coast and Dahomey,
and meeting the northwards advance of French troops from the Guinea coast.
As a result of this strategy, tight boundaries were drawn around the coastal
settlements of Gambia, Sierra Leone and Liberia. In the mid-1880s, Germany
made two relatively unambitious forward moves, one into Togo (between the
Gold Coast and Dahomey) and one into the Cameroons (on the eastern flank of
the Niger Delta). By the mid-1890s, France had successfully claimed the greater
part of West Africa, and Britain was left with the task of defending her two
most important interests: the Gold Coast and what was to become Nigeria. The
former, as Dumett has shown, was saved for Britain mainly as a result of mer-
cantile pressure.78 Kumasi, the Ashanti capital, was captured in 1896, and expan-
sion further north gave Britain a sizeable colony. In the case of Nigeria, it was
again successful mercantile agitation in the 1890s that kept the French out of
Yorubaland and the Lower Niger.79 Conspicuous in the latter area was the
Royal Niger Company, which, in the classical manner of chartered companies,
used administrative as well as commercial weapons to drive out its competitors,
English as well as French. By 1900 the partition of West Africa was over.
78 R. A. Dumett, British Official Attitudes to Economic Development on the Gold Coast, 1874–1905, Uni-
versity of London, Ph.D. thesis, 1966, pp. 149–80.
79 A. G. Hopkins, ‘Economic Imperialism in West Africa: Lagos, 1880–92’, Economic History Review,
21, 1968, pp. 580–606, and Flint, Sir George Goldie, Chs 10, 11 and 12.
216 The economic basis of imperialism
This chapter has tried to show that the solution to this problem lies in the
economic history of the nineteenth century. Economic motives do not consti-
tute a complete analysis of imperialism, but there is considerable justification for
concentrating on them here because they have been neglected in the past. This
neglect is understandable in view of the current dominance of political and dip-
lomatic interpretations of imperialism, but it has the fundamental disadvantage of
abstracting from West African realities. Trade first brought the Europeans to
Africa in the fifteenth century, and trade remained the basis of their relations
with the continent from then onwards. It is the economic historian’s task to see
whether, and, if so, in what ways, commercial ties were related to the scramble
for Africa.
What happened to Africa was part of a global confrontation between the
developing and the underdeveloped countries in the nineteenth century, though
the nature of the interaction between them, and its outcome, varied in different
parts of the world. The economic expansion of Europe in the nineteenth cen-
tury had a profound and destabilising effect on West Africa because it changed
the structure of export production and involved the region in the trade cycle of
the new, industrial economy. The Afro-European alliance which had made the
external slave trade possible and profitable started to dissolve early in the nine-
teenth century. A new generation of African producers and traders began to
develop outside the limits of the old, foreign trade enclaves, but was unable to
establish a completely satisfactory partnership with merchants on the European
side of the frontier. In some cases, difficulties arose because of obstruction from
traditional rulers, but even where the indigenous authorities were willing to
cooperate, and achieved a measure of success in doing so, there were limits to
the concessions which they were prepared to make. In the event, time was also
against them. During the early, prosperous phase of ‘legitimate’ commerce, each
side could afford to tolerate the economic imperfections (real and alleged) of the
other, and it seemed possible that economic integration could be achieved by
informal means. But the serious decline in the terms of trade in the last quarter
of the nineteenth century upset the precarious balance which maintained the
frontier between Europe and West Africa. Those on the European side of the
frontier had no further scope for improving their efficiency, and they now
feared that West Africa, with its pre-industrial transport system and its numerous
tolls, was in danger of becoming, by international standards, a high-cost produ-
cer. Those on the African side of the frontier decided that if modernisation
meant railways, the end of internal customs duties and the abolition, for what-
ever reasons, of slavery, then it also meant the end of their political independ-
ence. At that point they decided to resist and to defend their sovereignty,
though there were some who, for reasons which have been indicated, were less
than wholehearted in their opposition to European demands.
The economic depression transmitted by the industrial nations caused Eng-
land, France and Germany to come into conflict with each other, as well as
with African states. Their rivalry was partly a reflection of shifts in the balance
The economic basis of imperialism 217
The colonial era has ceased to be regarded as the sole substance of African his-
tory, and there are sound reasons for thinking that colonial rule itself had a less
dramatic and a less pervasive economic impact than was once supposed. Little
more than half a century elapsed between the end of the partition of West
Africa and the beginning of independence. The first 15 years of this period were
devoted to pacifying recalcitrant peoples, the last 15 years were spent trying to
cope with African nationalism, and the intervening years provide plenty of evi-
dence of the superficiality and impermanence of colonial rule, even though this
was the time when the rulers themselves believed that their paternal control
would remain unchallenged for several centuries.
Nevertheless, a good case can still be made out for according the colonial era
separate treatment on economic as well as, more obviously, on political grounds,
quite apart from the organisational necessity of allotting enough space to treat,
with some pretence at adequacy, the vast amount of description, analysis and
polemic which this period had generated. Essentially, and expressed in terms of
the main theme of this study, colonialism marked a new and, broadly speaking,
expansionist phase in the evolution of the modern market economy: its main
achievement was to remove the constraints which had hindered the develop-
ment of the export sector in the nineteenth century. Of course, the colonial
economy also had its limitations in terms of inherent deficiencies and of expect-
ations which it aroused yet seemed incapable of satisfying. As the colonial period
advanced, the limitations appeared, in the eyes of African participants and an
increasing number of sympathetic foreign observers, to outweigh the advantages,
and the expectations began to find political expression. The colonial economy
was not, however, a changeless economy and it started to acquire important
new features (notably a substantial public sector and modern manufacturing
An economic model of colonialism 219
plant) shortly before the coming of independence in the period 1957–60. The
beginning of this novel, and still incomplete, phase in West Africa’s economic
history (and its relation to the process of decolonisation) serves as an appropriate
terminal point for the present study.
The purpose of this chapter is to provide a synoptic view of the evolution of
the colonial economies of West Africa between 1900 and 1960. It will first pre-
sent an economic model of colonialism, which is intended to carry further the
analysis begun in Chapter 4, where the rise of legitimate commerce was con-
sidered in terms of staple theory, and will then outline the statistical basis for
charting the progress of the export economy. The aim of this approach is to
provide analytical and chronological anchorage points for the detailed discussion
which follows in Chapters 6 and 7.1
1 Students requiring an explanatory economics text to accompany this and the following two chapters
are advised to consult H. W. Ord and I. Livingstone, An Introduction to West African Economics,
London, 1969.
2 Dudley Seers, ‘The Stages of Economic Development of a Primary Producer in the Middle of the
Twentieth Century’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 7, 1963, pp. 57–69.
220 An economic model of colonialism
3 It must be emphasised that this paragraph, and the two which follow, present a formal statement of
an ideal type rather than a description of historical reality.
4 Though the degree of instability experienced by the underdeveloped countries should not be exag-
gerated. See Jagdish Bhagwati, The Economics of Underdeveloped Countries, London, 1966, pp. 58–64.
5 The importance of variations on the supply side has been stressed by Alasdair MacBean, Export
Instability and Economic Development, London, 1966.
An economic model of colonialism 221
6 For a specific investigation of this tendency see Rowena Lawson, ‘Engel’s Law and its Application to
Ghana’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 5, 1962, pp. 34–46.
7 Two excellent studies of East Africa, which are invaluable for comparative purposes, are Cyril Ehr-
lich, ‘The Uganda Economy, 1903–1945’, and C. C. Wrigley, ‘Kenya: The Patterns of Economic
Life, 1902–1945’, both in History of East Africa, 2, ed. Vincent Harlow and E. M. Chilver, London,
1965, pp. 395–475 and pp. 209–64 respectively.
8 For an early statement of these differences see H. W. Singer, ‘The Distribution of Gains between
Investing and Borrowing Countries’, American Economic Review, 40, 1950, pp. 473–85. For a broader
and more recent survey see Hla Myint, The Economics of the Developing Countries, London, 1964, Chs
3 and 4.
222 An economic model of colonialism
the motivation and timing of the movement for political independence were
related to the inability of the colonial system to cope with the demands made
upon it. It is important to stress that this failure did not occur simply because
the open economy was immobile and unresponsive, popular though this view
might be. On the contrary, the West African variant of this economy showed
some ability to raise incomes and finance diversification, especially in the period
after the Second World War. The problem was rather that African expectations
were expanding too fast to be contained within a colonial system, whatever its
attributes. Next, the history of West Africa since independence has demonstrated
that the closed economy is not necessarily a means to economic progress. The
closed economy brings new possibilities, but with these come new dangers:
exchange controls may discourage investment; import restrictions combined
with the operation of an independent monetary system may lead to shortages of
consumer goods and to inflation; and political pressures for development may
induce the new rulers to make concessions in the form of wages, jobs and con-
tracts, which in turn may lead to external debts and to internal inefficiencies.10
10 An important case study of these tendencies can be found in Douglas Rimmer, ‘The Crisis in the
Ghana Economy’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 4, 1966, pp. 17–32.
11 The evidence which follows has been derived mainly from Board of Trade, League of Nations and
United Nations publications, details of which are given in the Bibliography.
224 An economic model of colonialism
West Africa’s overseas trade increased about 15 times between 1906–10 and
1955–59. The rate of expansion, though uneven, was certainly rapid, being
about four times as great as in the preceding period of comparable length
between 1850–55 and 1901–05. Imports tended to follow the path taken by
exports for the greater part of the colonial era. Deficits in the visible balance of
trade were possible and were almost the rule in French West Africa after 1925.
Until 1945, these deficits were small and were met by capital transfers from the
metropolis, so that the overall balance of payments was in surplus. After
the Second World War, however, the relationship between visible import and
export values became far more tenuous, and imports began to exceed exports by
a considerable amount,12 a development which was made possible by greater
capital aid from external sources and by the expenditure of reserves built up in
the 1940s and 1950s. The change in the composition of the balance of payments
indicates that the open economy was no longer operating in its purest form.
The volume of overseas trade grew about ten times between 1906–10 and
1955–59.13 Two of the most spectacular increases were Gold Coast cocoa
exports, which rose from a few hundred tons a year in the 1890s to 305,000
tons in 1936/1937, a figure which was not exceeded until 1959/1960, and
groundnut products from Senegal, which averaged around 50,000 tons in the
1890s and reached a peak of 723,000 tons in 1937. Until about 1945 import
and export volumes tended to move together, but after the Second World War
imports were on the whole greater than exports, as Figure 2 illustrates with ref-
erence to French West Africa. This trend was the result of a change in the com-
position of the import trade to include a larger proportion of heavy capital
goods and ancillaries, such as cement and petrol.
Trends in the direction of overseas commerce are not easy to assess precisely,
mainly because of the difficulty of accounting for re-exports. In broad terms,
however, it can be said that the trade of the colonies became increasingly
oriented towards the ruling power in the period following partition, though in
the eyes of the more fervent protectionists and fair traders the immediate results
were not entirely satisfactory.
In 1898 about 40 per cent of the total trade of French West Africa was con-
ducted with France. By 1930, this figure had crept up to about 50 per cent,
chiefly as a result of the expansion of the Senegalese groundnut industry, which
was dominated by French merchants and by French markets. France also
remained the most important trading partner of the tiny, British colony of
Gambia, again because she bought virtually the whole of the groundnut crop.
However, in some of her own colonies, such as Guinea, the Ivory Coast and
Dahomey, France had only a minor share of total trade. It was not until the
12 After 1945 in the case of French West Africa, and after 1955 in the case of the British territories.
13 The expansion of exports from Nigeria, whose products were broadly representative of West
Africa as a whole, is shown in Figure 1.
20° 10° 0° 10°
20° 20°
MAURITANIA
Nouakchott
TOGO
COAST DAHOMEY
SIERRA LEONE IVORY COAST
Lagos
LIBERIA
Monrovia
Accra Porto Novo CAMEROONS
International boundaries Lome
Bingerville
Regional boundaries Abidjan 0 Kilometres 500
20° 10° 0° 0 statute miles 300 10°
200
175
150
125
100
75
50
25
0
1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960
Volume
Price
FIGURE 1 Nigeria: indices of export volume and price, 1911–60 (base 1953 = 100)
(Source: G. K. Helleiner, Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria,
Homewood, 1966, Table IV-A-2, pp. 494–5)
170
160
150
140
130
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955
Exports
Imports
FIGURE 2 French West Africa: indices of the volume of overseas trade, 1925–55 (base
1949 = 100)
(Source: J.-J. Poquin, Les relations économiques extérieures des pays d’Afrique noire de l’union
française, 1925–1955, Paris, 1957, Tables IV and V, p. 24 and 27)
After about, 1900 Britain conducted more trade with her West African colonies
than with other parts of West Africa. This alignment contrasted with the position in
the nineteenth century, though of course it should be remembered that the size of
these colonies had increased as a result of the partition of Africa. Between 1900 and
1930, Britain supplied about 75 per cent of British West Africa’s imports and
received approximately 50 per cent of her colonies’ exports. There was still room
for other trading nations within the British Empire: German firms in particular
made good use of the opportunities presented by the expansion of British rule in
West Africa, especially through their domination of the palm kernel trade. Although
these firms were expelled from the British colonies during the two World Wars,
they showed remarkable resilience in re-establishing themselves thereafter. The
imposition of quotas in the 1930s helped Britain to maintain her share of the import
trade to West Africa, and the Second World War effectively eliminated competitors
in the export trade, with the result that by 1945 Britain, like France, accounted for
about three-quarters of the total overseas commerce of her West African colonies.
Unlike France, however, Britain’s dominance became less marked in the later
1940s, and by 1960 she was responsible for only about half the imports and half the
exports of her possessions in West Africa. It is interesting to note that in the import
trade the main beneficiary of Britain’s decline was Japan, the country whose com-
petitive threat to the Lancashire textile industry had been an important motive for
the introduction of the quota system before the Second World War.
The growth of the export sector was based principally on agricultural and
forest products, most of which were either established staples, such as palm oil,
palm kernels and groundnuts, or had been introduced in an experimental way
before the expansion of European rule, as was the case with cocoa and coffee.
There were a few exceptions, such as mineral exports from Sierra Leone, but
these qualify the generalisation rather than disprove it. Evidence regarding the
composition of exports, it is suggested, supports the argument developed in the
previous chapter that the chief purpose of colonial rule was to speed a process of
economic change which was already under way. Indeed, for some colonies, not-
ably Gambia and Dahomey, there is a sense in which it can be said that the era
of legitimate commerce survived virtually untouched throughout the colonial
period! Even in Liberia, the one independent country in West Africa, the nine-
teenth-century pattern of trade was not disturbed until the 1940s, when rubber
came to dominate the export list. To the extent that there was some diversifica-
tion of exports, then it affected the huge Federation of French West Africa less
profoundly and at a later date than it did the three main British colonies.
In the first half of the colonial period (1900–30) about three-quarters of the
value of all overseas exports from French West Africa were derived from
groundnuts (50–60 per cent), which were farmed in Senegal, and palm products
(15–20 per cent), which came mainly from Dahomey. These two exports
underwent a relative decline in the second half of the period (1930–60) and
especially after the Second World War. In the 1950s groundnuts and groundnut
oil still accounted for about 30 per cent of total exports, but palm products had
228 An economic model of colonialism
fallen away to about 5 per cent. The decline was the result of the expansion of
coffee and cocoa exports from the Ivory Coast. Coffee production was of little
importance before the Second World War, but it developed rapidly after 1946,
and in the 1950s accounted for 25–30 per cent of all exports from the Feder-
ation. Cocoa exports increased more slowly and rose from about 10 per cent to
about 15 per cent of the total during the same period. At the time of independ-
ence in 1960 the two older staples and the two newer ones together accounted
for roughly 75 per cent of all exports. Mineral exports were insignificant during
the colonial period, and in 1955 were responsible for only 4 per cent of total
export values. Nevertheless, by the late 1950s it was clear that minerals, espe-
cially iron ore from Mauritania and bauxite from Guinea, would become
increasingly important in the era of independence.
In British West Africa palm products accounted for about 50 per cent of the
value of total exports at the beginning of the period of colonial rule, dropped to
about 33 per cent by 1930 and fell away to approximately 15 per cent in the
1950s. Before 1930 the decline was almost entirely the result of the rise of the
Gold Coast cocoa industry, which expanded very quickly during the first three
decades of the twentieth century, and by the close of the 1920s was responsible
for 80 per cent of all exports from the colony. Cocoa has remained dominant
ever since, though gold—one of the oldest exports—enjoyed a brief revival in
the 1930s, following a price rise in world markets. Two other important innov-
ations in the 1910s and 1920s were the development of Nigerian cocoa and
groundnut exports, which between them accounted for about a quarter of all
exports from Nigeria in the later 1920s, though palm produce still supplied half
the total. In the second part of the colonial period the two new products con-
tinued to make progress at the expense of the traditional staples, with the result
that by the late 1950s cocoa provided about 20 per cent of all Nigerian exports,
groundnuts and groundnut oil a further 20 per cent, and palm products about
25 per cent. In Sierra Leone there was a more dramatic change in the 1930s.
Palm products, which until then had formed about 70 per cent of total exports,
declined rapidly as a result of the exploitation of diamond and iron-ore deposits.
Mineral exports, negligible in 1930, formed 45 per cent of total exports in 1934
and by the close of the decade had reached over 60 per cent, a figure which,
after some fluctuations, was attained once more in the 1950s.
Minerals were always of greater significance in British than in French West
Africa, even without taking into account the contribution made by Sierra
Leone. In the late 1920s tin represented about 10 per cent of the value of all
Nigerian exports, and gold, diamonds and manganese were each about
5 per cent of Gold Coast exports. All these products had declined slightly by the
end of the colonial period, but the discovery of new resources, notably Nigerian
oil, indicated that minerals were certain to be important in the future develop-
ment plans of the more fortunate countries.
The composition of the import trade presents some interesting continuities
and contrasts with the pre-colonial era, though these cannot be measured with
An economic model of colonialism 229
great precision because the categories by which imports were classified were
altered from time to time and also varied between British and French colonies.14
Manufactured consumer goods were still the chief import, as in the nineteenth
century, and textiles, principally cotton goods, but including an increasing pro-
portion of man-made fibres, such as rayon, remained the leading single item,
accounting for about a third of the value of total imports into French West
Africa and about a quarter of total imports in British West Africa in the period
down to the Second World War. At the same time, two long-established staples
lost their former prominence. Imports of guns and ammunition were curtailed
after the partition of Africa, when the colonial authorities took steps to ensure
that the chief means of coercion were kept in their own hands. Next came the
decline of the liquor trade after the First World War. A combination of reasons
was responsible for this: hostilities cut off Hamburg, the main source of supply,
from West African markets; an increase in the circulation of British and French
currency diminished the demand for liquor as a medium of exchange; the colo-
nial powers, somewhat tardily, introduced measures to limit the trade by raising
customs duties and by imposing higher standards on the quality of imported
spirits; and consumer tastes, influenced by the availability of a wider range of
goods, became more sophisticated.15
Several new items began to appear in the import lists during the early part of
the colonial period. Imports of food, especially rice, fish, sugar, flour and salt,
began to increase in the inter-war years, particularly in Senegal, the Gold Coast,
Nigeria and the Ivory Coast, where some export producers and urban workers
were no longer self-sufficient, and where the development of the overseas
exchange sector had led to a demand for a higher quality and more varied
diet.16 After the Second World War, the rapid expansion in the number of
Europeans in French West Africa (from about 30,000 in 1946 to about 100,000
in 1960) contributed to this trend, for they were the main consumers of
imported foodstuffs. By the end of the colonial period manufactured consumer
goods and foodstuffs between them accounted for about 60 per cent of the
value of all imports into French West Africa, and about 45 per cent in the case
of British West Africa. After the Second World War, however, the import lists
of the wealthier colonies showed an increasing shift to capital goods, such as
machinery and motor vehicles, to semi-finished products and to raw materials.
14 There are also many minor frustrations, which will be familiar to those who have wrestled with the
Blue Books and similar publications. Imports of motor vehicles, for example, though easily counted,
were sometimes listed in terms of their total tonnage only. This formula doubtless served some
obscure purpose of the Customs and Excise Department, but it gives the historian a severe
headache.
15 The liquor trade is a profitable subject of future research, whether it is considered as a commercial
undertaking, as an ideological controversy, or as an issue in international politics.
16 W. B. Morgan, ‘Food Imports of West Africa’, Economic Geography, 39, 1963, pp. 351–62.
230 An economic model of colonialism
This was a significant development because it indicated that in the 1950s, on the
eve of independence, the open economy was showing signs of diversification.
The frontiers of trade were pushed back by this export-led development, so
that by 1960 the area directly involved in production for the overseas market
was very much larger than it had been in the nineteenth century. All the same,
it is important to emphasise that most exports were drawn from a small part of
the total area covered by West Africa, and that the contributions made by vari-
ous regions also remained more or less constant throughout the colonial period.
British West Africa, for example, though only a third of the size of French West
Africa, supplied an average of 72 per cent of the value of total exports from
West Africa as a whole, while the French colonies accounted for only
25 per cent of the total. The remaining territories (Liberia and Portuguese
Guinea) were left with a mere 3 per cent.17 Moreover, there was a considerable
degree of concentration within the British and French territories. Nigeria and
the Gold Coast were responsible for 90–95 per cent of total exports from the
four British possessions, a figure which was equivalent to 37 per cent and
29 per cent respectively of all West African exports. Thus the trade of Nigeria
alone was far more important than that of the whole of French West Africa,
which was roughly on a par with the Gold Coast.18 In French West Africa itself
two colonies, Senegal and the Ivory Coast, were pre-eminent, supplying
between them about 75 per cent of the total exports from the Federation during
the whole of the colonial period. Senegal was the leading centre in the first half
of the twentieth century, but after the Second World War the Ivory Coast’s for-
eign trade expanded rapidly, with the result that by the 1950s the two colonies
were of approximately equal importance.
Many parts of West Africa which lay outside the main export-producing
regions were able to participate in the colonial economy by supplying necessary
inputs into export activities, such as labour. Other areas, however, were scarcely
touched even by indirect economic influences, and some may well have suffered
an absolute fall in living standards as a result of colonial rule. Mauritania, for
example, with its traditional export, gum, in decline, found an imperfect substi-
tute in trading foodstuffs (fish, millet and livestock) to Senegal. The area around
Lake Chad is another instance of a part of West Africa which experienced the
decline of an important traditional activity without at the same time receiving
adequate compensation in the form of new opportunities. The Buduma, who
inhabit the territory south of Lake Chad, originally arrived there without any
knowledge of water transport, but they adopted the techniques of the people
they subjugated, and by selling slaves were able to buy expensive wooden
17 The two German colonies of Togo and Cameroon were occupied by the Allies during the First
World War, and in 1919 they were each split into two parts and placed under British and French
mandate.
18 However, if exports are related to population, then the Gold Coast ranks above all other colonies
in West Africa.
An economic model of colonialism 231
canoes from the distant forest region to the south. This superior means of trans-
port enabled them to dominate much of the Lake Chad region. However, colo-
nial rule brought the internal slave trade to an end. The prosperity of the
Buduma declined and they were forced to adopt cheaper reed skiffs, which are
still in use today. The example of the Buduma, paddling their inferior skiffs and
reflecting nostalgically on prosperous days gone by, serves as a reminder that
market expansion was not a universal phenomenon in twentieth century West
Africa.19
The pre-eminence of four colonies, Nigeria, the Gold Coast, Senegal and the
Ivory Coast, points to a considerable degree of continuity with the past, for all
of them had been centres of legitimate commerce in the nineteenth century,
and the first three had been prominent earlier still in the days of the Atlantic
slave trade. The overwhelming dominance of Nigeria and the Gold Coast is
additional evidence that the British, with luck allied to judgement, were more
determined and at the same time more subtle in the defence of their West Afri-
can interests in the nineteenth century than is often suggested. Certainly, any
assessment of French supremacy based simply on a comparison of the size of the
territories ruled by the two great powers is very misleading. Finally, it is worth
observing that considerable regional inequalities exist in West Africa, though
without there being any marked dualism between the so-called ‘traditional’ and
‘modern’ sectors of the economy. Inequalities were present in the pre-colonial
period, but colonial rule often accentuated and occasionally altered regional dif-
ferences. Local disparities are sometimes ignored in the debate about the ‘widen-
ing gap’ between the living standards of the advanced and the underdeveloped
nations.20
A historical survey of the terms of trade of West African export producers
comes as near as is possible to providing a film of the performance of the open
economy, though, since some of the reels are missing, the result is necessarily
jerky and incomplete. The net barter terms of trade, that is the ratio between
the indices of average export and import prices, measure changes in the quantity
of imports which can be derived from a given unit of exports. The income
terms of trade, that is the barter terms of trade multiplied by an index of the
volume of exports, provide information about the total import-purchasing
power of the country concerned.21 In evaluating trends in the terms of trade the
19 The Buduma’s loss was others’ gain: for a discussion of the ending of internal slavery see Chapter 6,
section 2.
20 The emphasis given here to differences within regions and countries (in addition to the obvious
comparison between national and colonial units) is paralleled by recent studies of English and
American history at critical points of economic development. See, for example, E. A. Wrigley,
Industrial Growth and Population Change, Cambridge, 1961, and Douglass C. North, ‘Agriculture
and Regional Economic Growth’, Journal of Farm Economics, 41, 1959, pp. 943–51.
21 For a fuller explanation of these terms see Ord and Livingstone, An Introduction to West African Eco-
nomics, pp. 363–7, and, more generally, Gerald M. Meier, The International Economics of Development,
New York and London, 1968, pp. 41–65.
232 An economic model of colonialism
following points have to be borne in mind: the indices measure changes in rela-
tion to one base year rather than absolute gains and losses; they do not take
account of alterations in the quality of imports and exports; because the indices
are derived from averages they tend to disguise the behaviour of individual com-
modities. In the 1930s, for example, the export trade of Sierra Leone changed
its character, but the indices at present available for West Africa do not take this
particular shift fully into account.
The three main sources are Helleiner’s data on Nigeria, which are presented
in Figure 3, Hymer’s figures for the Gold Coast (Figure 4) and Poquin’s import-
ant, yet virtually unused, work on French West Africa (Figure 5). Since the trade
of Nigeria, the Gold Coast and French West Africa included all the main items of
West Africa’s external commerce, there is reason to think that composite indices
relating to these areas are broadly representative of the region as a whole. In the
analysis which follows, the three main sources have been supplemented by evi-
dence relating to the period 1900–11, by Cox-George’s work on Sierra Leone
between 1914 and 1945, by Bauer’s material dealing with the Gold Coast
between 1935 and 1951, and by Berg’s survey of real income trends in West
Africa from 1939 to 1960.22
Taking the period 1900–60 as a whole, it is clear that economic progress in
the underdeveloped world was largely dependent on circumstances affecting the
major industrial powers. Particularly outstanding in this connection was the
impact of what, in terms of the theory of international trade, must be called for-
tuitous events, notably the two World Wars. More orthodox movements, such
as the transmitted effects of Juglar cycles of under nine years, are harder to dis-
cern. With regard to the controversy about the long-term prospects of primary
producers in the underdeveloped world, the evidence available does not lend
decisive support to either optimists or pessimists.23 The barter terms of trade
fluctuated around a falling trend from 1913–45, but then recovered between
1945 and 1960. The income terms of trade, though clearly affected by changes
in the barter terms, tended to move upwards, reflecting the general expansion of
export volumes during the twentieth century. By the close of the colonial
period, West Africa’s total import-purchasing power was about four times as
great as it had been at the beginning of the century. Allowing for the fact that
the population had roughly doubled during the same period, it can be said that
average per capita importing capacity was twice as high in 1960 as in 1900. Not
all export earnings went straight to the producers, and the distribution of bene-
fits was also uneven geographically and socially. On this criterion, which of
22 N. A. Cox-George, Finance and Development in West Africa, London, 1961; P. T. Bauer, West African
Trade, Cambridge, 1954, pp. 410–21, and Elliot J. Berg, ‘Real Income Trends in West Africa,
1939–1960’, in Economic Transition in Africa, ed. Melville J. Herskovits and Mitchell Harwitz,
London, 1964, pp. 199–238.
23 These prospects depend, of course, on the development of new exports, as well as on price move-
ments affecting existing exports.
An economic model of colonialism 233
200
175
150
125
100
75
50
25
0
1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960
250
225
200
175
150
125
100
75
50
25
0
1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960
course excludes wider welfare considerations, it would seem that Africans gained
from participating in international trade.
A more detailed historical analysis of the terms of trade can be made by divid-
ing the period 1900–60 into the following five sections: 1900–13, 1914–21,
1922–29, 1930–44 and 1945–60. It will be argued here that there is a significant
relationship between these five phases and the general economic and political
history of the region, though no simple, mechanistic interpretation is intended.
It is hoped that the connections briefly noted in the ensuing analysis will be
234 An economic model of colonialism
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955
Net Barter Terms of Trade
Income Terms of Trade
FIGURE 5 French West Africa: terms of trade, 1925–55 (base 1938 = 100)
(Source: J.-J. Poquin, Les relations économiques extérieures des pays d’Afrique noire de l’union
française, 1925–1955, Paris, 1957, p. 135)
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
31
29
32
38
28
33
34
30
35
36
37
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
FIGURE 6 French West Africa (including Togo): bank notes in circulation, 1928–38
(in millions of francs)
(Source: Huguette Durand, Essai sur la conjoncture de l’ Afrique noire, Paris, 1957, graph
XXII, p. 119)
of the new administrations much easier than it would otherwise have been. It
made possible the financing of development projects, notably railways, which
were necessary if the economy was to expand beyond the limits set by nine-
teenth-century conditions of export production. Finally, it induced more
Africans to enter the export market, and so led to a further growth in the
volume of exports, and to plantings of tree crops which were to bear fruit in
the 1920s and 1930s. Developments between 1900 and 1913 were not quite
as smooth and uneventful as the foregoing summary may suggest. The parti-
tion of West Africa ended in an atmosphere of bonanza, as traders and produ-
cers hoped for a lucky strike to compensate for the lean years they had
endured. At the turn of the century, there was a minor gold rush in the
Gold Coast, and, more prosaically, a rubber boom, which resulted from the
discovery of wild rubber trees in parts of the forest zone from Guinea to
Nigeria. When the gold rush came to an end, which it did very quickly,
when most of the rubber trees ceased to be worth tapping, and when the
first geological surveys dispelled some of the more fanciful hopes of those
whose judgement had been seriously affected by a consuming desire to get
rich quickly, then the great majority of West African export producers settled
down soberly to a slower, harder grind towards prosperity.
These favourable trends were interrupted by the First World War. The barter
terms of trade declined as a result of the shortage and consequently the high
price of imported goods. Export expansion was checked by the closure of some
European, especially German, markets, and by a lack of shipping space. The
outcome was a fall in the income terms as well. In 1919 West Africa participated
briefly in the post-war boom, but then suffered severely in the slump of
1920–21, which was signalled by a dramatic collapse of export prices. These
years saw the elimination of many smaller import and export firms, European as
well as African, and the consolidation of the position of a few large concerns.
The fluctuations of the period revealed to a new generation of Africans the
extent to which their fortunes depended on external forces. They in turn dem-
onstrated their disenchantment with colonial rule by organising protests in the
main centres of trade. The First World War had serious consequences for West
Africa: it was an unpleasant foretaste of the greater conflict of 1939–45, which
was to have an even bigger impact on the tropical colonies.24
In 1922 there began a recovery which lasted until 1929. The barter terms of
trade improved, though they were not as favourable as in the pre-war years, and
the income terms also revived as a result of a rise in the volume of exports. The
exact degree of recovery is hard to judge. Helleiner’s estimates indicate that the
real incomes of producers of palm oil and kernels, which accounted for about
24 Some of the effects of the First World War have been explored in a valuable article by Michael
Crowder, ‘West Africa and the 1914–1918 War’, Bulletin de l’ IFAN, B, 30, 1968, pp. 227–45. See
also Cox-George, Finance and Development in West Africa, Ch. 8.
236 An economic model of colonialism
half the value of Nigeria’s exports, were lower in the 1920s than they were in
the period before the First World War, whereas incomes of producers of cocoa
and groundnuts increased.25 In the absence of technical advances in agriculture,
the capacity to import was maintained only by increased inputs of labour and
land. Existing export producers had to work harder, and new producers had to
be attracted into the export sector. The latter development was made possible
by the arrival of the motor lorry, which enabled new areas of export production
to be opened up. All that can be said at present, pending further, more detailed
investigation, is that the recovery of 1922–29 was a limited one, and that most
export producers were unlikely to have experienced any marked improvement
in their living standards.
From 1930–44, the barter terms of trade declined once more, apart from
a brief recovery in 1935–37, and during the Second World War reached their
lowest point of the century. More remarkable still, the income terms also
showed a downward trend (though again there was a limited recovery in the
mid-1930s) in spite of the fact that there was some expansion in the volume of
exports.26 The Second World War had a much more serious effect on West
Africa than did the world slump of the 1930s because of an acute shortage of
consumer imports and because of the abrupt closure of many export markets in
Europe. French West Africa, having declared for the Vichy government in
1940, found itself blockaded by the Allies and so was particularly badly affected.
By the end of the war, West Africa’s total importing capacity was lower than at
any time since 1900 (with the possible exception of 1921), though population
and public debts had both increased greatly since the beginning of the century.
The adverse trends of the period 1930–44 had important consequences. Invest-
ment was curtailed and ambitious projects postponed. Retrenchment was the
theme, safety first the motto and indirect rule the philosophy cut to suit the
narrow cloth of the time. The main exceptions to this generalisation arose, per-
versely, during the Second World War, when a few schemes, such as the devel-
opment of a harbour at Monrovia, were undertaken to aid the Allied war effort.
The long period of economic hardship led to the rise of a movement which was
eventually to bring colonial rule to an end. This movement had its beginnings
in the economic crisis of the 1930s, and, as a result of the Second World War,
it became more widespread, more articulate and ultimately irresistible.
After 1945 there was a rapid and unexpected improvement in the barter
terms of trade brought about by a revival in demand for tropical products,
which were required to assist the post-war recovery of Europe, and later to
meet the need for raw materials during the Korean war. The upward trend
25 Helleiner, Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria, pp. 5–7, Tables 11 B to
11 B 6.
26 An interesting illustration of the depressive effects of this trend can be seen in Figure 6, which plots
the fall in currency circulation in French West Africa, and also demonstrates the extent of seasonal
variations in the size of the money economy.
An economic model of colonialism 237
levelled off in the second half of the 1950s, but the barter terms still remained more
favourable than at any point since the period before the First World War. The
volume of exports grew at the same time, slowly at first, but then more swiftly in
the 1950s, with the result that the total importing capacity of West Africa achieved
record levels. Several important developments were closely associated with this
final, and generally prosperous, phase of colonial rule. There was a rapid, and seem-
ingly irreversible, expansion of the public sector. At the same time, there was
a revival of confidence and a renewed inflow of investment, just as there had been
in the period 1900–13, which also followed a an economic slump and a political
crisis. Although the growth in the volume of exports was achieved mainly by estab-
lished means, it also resulted from an increase in agricultural productivity brought
about by the adoption of insecticides, fertilisers and better quality seeds. In the
1950s, too, the expansion of the market reached the point where large-scale manu-
facturing could begin. This phase saw the end of colonial rule. On the one hand,
the colonial powers felt a need to placate and reward colonial subjects who had
endured the hardships of the war effort; on the other hand, Africans were more
organised and better financed than they had been and could make sure that the
required concessions were forthcoming.
The analysis of the colonial period which follows is divided into two chapters,
each corresponding to a stage in the history of the open economy. Chapter 6 will
examine the construction of the open economy. Accordingly, the main focus will
be on the first half of the colonial period (1900–30), but subsequent events will be
dealt with if they contributed to the maintenance of the open economy in its classic
form. In contrast, Chapter 7 will concentrate on the difficulties experienced by the
open economy and on the alterations which were made to it in the second half of
the colonial period (1930–60). Accordingly, the chief emphasis will be on dysfunc-
tional developments, that is those which tended to modify the open economy.
Most historical accounts of the colonial period have followed the political divisions
established by the major powers, and have dealt, in turn, with British and with
French West Africa. This procedure is not suitable for the thematic, economic ana-
lysis proposed here. Chapters 6 and 7 will treat the economies of French, British,
German and Portuguese West Africa as a whole, on the grounds that the similarities
between them in terms of structure and evolution were more marked than the dif-
ferences, though these will be noted wherever they were important. This approach
has two secondary advantages: it includes Liberia, a country which, though politic-
ally independent since 1847, developed a typical open, export economy in the
twentieth century; and it may also help to break down the insularity which academ-
ics have inherited from their colonial past.27
27 The adverse effects of this insularity continue to be felt. For example, French scholars write about
the Senegalese groundnut industry, but rarely mention northern Nigeria, and British scholars dis-
cuss the monetary system of British West Africa without making any reference to the system oper-
ating in the neighbouring French colonies.
6
COMPLETING THE OPEN ECONOMY
This chapter is devoted to an analysis of the open economy during the first half
of the colonial era. The evidence is organised around two themes which are
central to the economic history of the period. The first theme is the introduc-
tion of the economic and political institutions which were needed to complete
the structure of the open economy. The second theme concerns the way in
which the component parts of the open economy combined to activate domes-
tic resources and to expand West Africa’s overseas trade.
Two opposed views are commonly expressed about the development of
export economies during the early part of the colonial period, though other, less
prominent, interpretations can easily be found. An established argument holds
the colonial government primarily responsible for introducing and managing
economic change. One branch of this position suggests that Africans were
tutored, in the event swiftly and efficiently, by a benign, though necessarily
paternal, regime. McPhee, for example, told the story of The Economic Revolution
in British West Africa (1926) very much from this official standpoint.1 Another
also emphasises the role of the administration, but disputes the idea that colonial
rule was beneficial to Africans and criticises official policy for disrupting and
exploiting allegedly stable and prosperous traditional societies. This approach can
be found in Suret-Canale’s Afrique noire occidentale et centrale: l’ère coloniale,
1900–1945 (1964).2 A more recent view has been advanced in different con-
texts by a number of development economists, and is concerned primarily with
the mobilisation of land and labour resources in the indigenous economy. This
approach is very different from that of McPhee and Suret-Canale: it bypasses the
1 See also Alan Pim, The Financial and Economic History of the African Tropical Territories, Oxford, 1940.
2 Now in translation under the title French Colonialism in Tropical Africa, 1900–1945, London, 1971.
Completing the open economy 239
historical problem of the costs and benefits of colonial rule, and it seeks chiefly
to analyse the contribution made by Africans to the process of export expansion.
Both views have their merits, but neither is acceptable without some modifi-
cation. The first, though it has the advantage of paying attention to detail and
chronology, is particularly suspect because it underplays the role of Africans
themselves, while the conclusions it reaches about the welfare consequences of
colonial rule over-generalise a limited amount of frequently ambiguous evi-
dence. The second view is more sophisticated and reflects recent trends in
development economics, but it tends to exaggerate the ease and simplify the
process of growth by suggesting that colonial development was essentially
a matter of taking up the slack in existing, underutilised resources—in much the
same way as a prefabricated building can be erected by persuading enough hands
to pull on a rope. What is required for present purposes is an approach which
combines the historical depth of the first view with the analytical strength of
the second.
The central problem is to identify and evaluate the main formative influences
on the open economy. The difficulty lies in striking a balance between causes,
when the nature of the evidence is such that these cannot be measured with
great precision. For example, any book which claims to be based on recent
research is bound to stress the contribution made by indigenous producers and
traders. At the same time, however, care must be taken not to dismiss the his-
tory of European enterprise in West Africa as the unfashionable preoccupation
of those who have failed to keep up with the somewhat exhausting pace of
change in African studies.3 A preliminary classification suggests that the chief
formative influences can be divided into two broad categories: imported and
indigenous. The former were significant in economic policy, transport, the dis-
tributive system and money and banking. The latter can be analysed in terms of
land and labour inputs. In brief, it will be argued that imported, colonial influ-
ences were in varying degrees necessary to the completion of the open econ-
omy, but were not a sufficient cause of it, and that it was indigenous
entrepreneurs, by accepting and creating market opportunities, who ensured that
export production did in fact expand.
These two categories will be dealt with in turn, though it will become evi-
dent that there was considerable interaction between them. The organisation of
the chapter will have to take account of this overlap: for instance, while dealing
with externally induced changes in the distributive system it will be convenient
to examine the position of Africans as well as of Europeans; similarly, in discussing
3 Non-specialists may be under the impression that European activities have been fully investigated.
This is not the case. For example, no one has written an economic history of the railway systems in
West Africa, and there have been hardly any studies of expatriate trading, mining and plantation
enterprises, or of official economic policy. These are important subjects, and it would be unfortunate
if research students avoided them for fear of being thought old-fashioned in their approach to Afri-
can history.
240 Completing the open economy
held, would be to the advantage of all parties. Of course, the main purpose of
having colonies in West Africa was to secure a profitable trade for the mother
country, and in some cases tariff regulations were devised to see that this
happened.5 All the same, it was necessary to make sure that some of the gains
from international trade accrued to Africa because, in the last resort, if Africans
remained poor they could not afford to buy manufactured goods. The belief that
colonial rule should be based on cooperation and mutual interest rather than on
crude exploitation found comprehensive expression in Lord Lugard’s book The
Dual Mandate in British Tropical Africa (1922). The concept of the dual mandate,
which admirably combined philosophical largesse with financial economy,
became acceptable rather later in France (according to British writers anyway)
than it did in England, though with the publication of Albert Sarraut’s influential
work La mise en valeur des colonies françaises in 1923 it can be said to have found
a small niche in the official mind of French colonialism.
A few attempts were made to swim against the still powerful tide of laissez-
faire thinking, but they were never wholly successful. At the turn of the century
Joseph Chamberlain talked boldly about developing the tropical estates of the
British Empire, but his schemes for financial aid were either blocked or whittled
away by the Treasury.6 The world which Gladstone had so recently departed
was to continue to feel his influence in the field of public finance until well into
the twentieth century. Two more plans of development were put forward
immediately after the First World War. These were reflections of recent experi-
ence, both of the increased role which governments had been forced to assume
during the war, and of the hastily awakened appreciation of the economic
importance of the colonies at a time when the metropolis was under siege. Gov-
ernor Guggisberg formulated a ten-year plan for the Gold Coast covering the
period 1919–28, and involving the expenditure of about £25 million, mainly on
improving the transport system.7 This plan, which was to be financed out of the
colony’s own resources, and therefore caused no alarm among Treasury officials
in London, was cut back as a result of the years of indifferent trade in the early
1920s. However, there were some important achievements, notably the comple-
tion of the Accra to Kumasi railway line in 1923, the building of a deep-water
harbour at Takoradi, which was finished in 1928, and the construction of about
3,000 miles of motor roads. In France, Albert Sarraut, a former governor-
general of Indo-China and minister of colonies, put forward a similar, though
more extensive, scheme of public works in 1921.8 His plan, which was designed
to exploit the resources of the Empire more fully, also had to be severely
modified as a result of the post-war slump and the failure of Germany to pay
reparations. Nevertheless, some projects were advanced: the Thiès–Kayes section
of the Senegal railway was completed in 1923, improvements were made to
Dakar harbour and a start was made on a plan to irrigate the middle Niger. All
these schemes were designed to complete the structure of the open economy.
Their aim was to expand the export economy, in contrast to later development
plans, which were concerned mainly with growth in other sectors of the
economy.
The prevailing view of the role of government in the economy found charac-
teristic expression in the principles underlying colonial finance. The basic aim
was self-sufficiency. As far as the British colonies were concerned, Earl Grey’s
famous dictum, enunciated in 1852, still held true: ‘the surest test for the sound-
ness of measures for the improvement of an uncivilised people is that they
should be self-supporting’. In France budgetary reforms were adopted in 1900
which gave the colonies a greater degree of fiscal autonomy, but which also
required them to pay their own way. From 1904 to 1957 the colonies were
linked in a Federation (with its capital at Dakar) which controlled the collection
and distribution of nearly all indirect taxes.9 The main aim of the Federation
was to ensure that the rich colonies (Senegal and the Ivory Coast) paid for their
poor relations, thus preventing the latter from becoming a drain on the metrop-
olis. The four British colonies in West Africa remained financially independent
of each other, and the two smaller territories (Sierra Leone and Gambia) had to
receive support from Britain when they ran into financial difficulty.
To achieve financial self-sufficiency, both British and French colonies relied
mainly on revenue from customs duties, which accounted for more than half of
total revenue for the greater part of the colonial period.10 The proportion was
even higher before the First World War, but it declined as a result of the expan-
sion of direct taxes, such as head tax and income tax, and the growth of revenue
from public investments. Nearly half the revenue was spent on the salaries and
pensions of expatriate officials, a fact which helps to explain the introspective
nature of official attitudes in the critical period between the two World Wars; at
a time when discontent was brewing in Africa, government records seem to be
dominated by information about promotions and pensions. Another large slice
of public income went to repay the capital and interest on loans raised for devel-
opment purposes. In the case of Nigeria, this item rose from 14 per cent of total
revenue in 1926 to 33 per cent in 1934. The amount left for the economic
departments, such as agriculture and forestry, was minute. Furthermore, the offi-
cial budget was subject to large and unpredictable variations of the kind which
9 C. W. Newbury, ‘The Formation of the Government General of French West Africa’, Journal of
African History, 1, 1960, pp. 111–28.
10 For a detailed case study see Sir Alan Pim, ‘Public Finance’, in Mining, Commerce, and Finance in
Nigeria, ed. Margery Perham, London, 1948, pp. 225–79.
Completing the open economy 243
were typical of open economies. Revenue was most likely to grow during
a trade boom, which meant that spending from current income could expand
only fitfully. In the event of a slump, however, expenditure could not be
reduced very easily because of the high proportion of fixed outgoings on salaries
and debt repayments. The result was that the fiscal burden grew more onerous
when trade was depressed, and was particularly heavy during the period
1930–45.
There were two additional sources of public finance: grants-in-aid and
loans. Grants-in-aid did not amount to large sums, and they were of no gen-
eral importance in colonial development programmes. They were used select-
ively to help out colonies such as Gambia and Sierra Leone, which
occasionally ran deficits, and to assist in emergencies, such as the need to
increase defence expenditure during the First World War. Public loans,
floated on the stock markets of London and Paris, were much more import-
ant. All the same, Frankel’s pioneering study has shown that investment in
tropical Africa in the period before the Second World War was very limited
compared with what was required, what was to come in the future and what
was already being invested in other parts of the world.11 Gross public and
private foreign investment in West Africa amounted to about £147 million in
the period 1870–1936. Approximately 50 per cent of this sum was public
investment, which was mostly spent developing the transport system, notably
railways. Regional disparities were marked: only about one-fifth of total
investment in West Africa (roughly £30 million) was placed in French terri-
tories; the rest went to the smaller, though more populous, British colonies.
The ability to raise loans depended entirely on the resources of the colonies
themselves, which helps to explain why the differences between rich and
poor colonies increased rather than diminished with the passage of time. The
borrowing capacity of the colonies, like the size of their current revenues,
fluctuated with the trade cycle. The result was that down to 1945 investment
tended to follow rather than cause growth, and capital flows magnified the
effects of booms and slumps instead of reducing them.
Given the economic philosophy and financial stringency of the early colonial
period, there was little scope for basing development policy on anything other
than the well-tried Victorian principle of self-help. The validity of this conclu-
sion is illustrated by government policy towards the important questions of com-
merce, land and labour. These three subjects will be examined in detail later and
are mentioned briefly at this stage simply to indicate the orientation of official
thinking. With regard to commerce, the administrations created free trade areas
within each colony and then allowed market forces to operate more or less
without restraint. An indulgent attitude towards the expatriate trading firms is
11 S. H. Frankel, Capital Investment in Africa, London, 1938, and Suret-Canale’s comments on his fig-
ures in Afrique noire, pp. 205–14.
244 Completing the open economy
understandable when it is remembered that these firms had been in the forefront
of the clamour for government intervention in West Africa at the close of
the nineteenth century. As to land, British and French policy confirmed Afri-
can rights and encouraged the development of an indigenous class of inde-
pendent export producers. In the case of the labour force, colonial policy
aimed at permitting and sometimes directly enforcing mobility, so that key
areas could secure an adequate supply of workers. Only in the field of trans-
port, as will now be shown, was official enterprise dominant. For the rest,
lack of techniques and personnel, lack of money and lack of commitment to
the idea of active government involvement in economic affairs meant that
the colonial authorities played a less prominent part in creating the open
economy than is sometimes thought.
According to Lord Lugard, ‘the material development of Africa may be
summed up in one word—Transport’.12 One-word summaries of complex
problems cannot be expected to achieve a high degree of accuracy. Never-
theless, it remains true that economists invariably assign modern transport
facilities an important place in bringing about economic growth.
W. W. Rostow, for example, has claimed that railways were the most
important single cause of industrial ‘take-off’ in North America, Germany
and Russia, and that they were very influential elsewhere, notably in
England.13 It is not hard to see why this should have been the case.
Modern transport has the effect of discounting space, that is to say it moves
goods and people over longer distances faster and more cheaply than was
possible previously. This innovation has had profound consequences. It has
released capital and labour tied up in traditional transport operations for
more productive employment elsewhere; it has led to the rise of new
resources, such as coal and iron, which are basic to industrial development;
and it has stimulated the export sector, which in turn has generated capital
for internal investment. In view of the real and alleged significance of
modern transport in the development of West Africa, it is surprising that
economic historians have conducted so little research into the subject.14
The survey that follows will concentrate on internal innovations, namely
railways, harbours, motor transport and waterways. Improvements in ocean
transport, principally the change from sail to steam, have been outlined
already in Chapter 4.
R.N
i
ge
Nguru
r
Bamako Ouagadougou Kano
Zaria Maiduguri
Kaduna
10°N Bobo Dioulasso Paraku Jos
Kankan e
Conakry Jebba nu
. Be
Freetown Blitta Baro R
Pendembu
Kumasi Ibadan Makurdi
Monrovia Lagos Enugu
Buchanan Lome Porto
Abidjan Tema Novo
Accra Cotonu Yaounde
Douala
Takoradi Port Harcourt
Railways
Rivers
0 kilometres 600
0 statute miles 375 10°E
10°W 0°
Plans for the construction of railways in West Africa had been canvassed by
private promoters since at least the middle of the nineteenth century.15 Spacious
in conception, obscure in purpose and all too clearly astronomical in cost, these
schemes required, and failed to obtain, government support. However, with the
advent of a serious economic crisis in the last quarter of the nineteenth century,
commercial interests and government officials became convinced that railways
were needed to maintain West Africa’s competitiveness in international markets.
The construction of railways began in the 1880s and concluded in the 1920s at
the end of the first phase of colonial rule. The ideas of private sponsors quickly
became government property. The French aimed to drive east from Senegal and
capture the Western Sudan, which could then be linked with lines from North
Africa and from the southern coast of West Africa, thus enabling France to con-
trol the greater part of Africa west of Egypt and the Congo. British policy was
on the whole less ambitious, being based on the maintenance of existing spheres
of influence, though the possibility of a line which would run from southern
Nigeria up to Lake Chad and beyond to Egypt was considered at the turn of
the century during a mood of temporary euphoria.
The present railway map of West Africa clearly reflects these half-realised
projects. The three main developments were in Senegal, the Gold Coast and
Nigeria. The Senegal railway was begun in 1881, and after several changes of
plan and many delays Dakar was finally joined to Bamako (a distance of 720
miles) in 1923.16 On the Gold Coast a line from Sekondi to Kumasi was fin-
ished in 1903, another from Accra to Kumasi was ready in 1923, and a third
completed the triangle by joining the two coastal ports in 1927. In Nigeria
the principal line was begun at Lagos in 1896 and reached Kano (a total of
711 miles) in 1911. A second line, joining Port Harcourt in eastern Nigeria to
Kaduna via Enugu and Jos, was completed in 1926. There were shorter rail-
ways running from Freetown to Pendembu (completed in 1906); Lome to
Atakpame (1913); Conakry to Kankan (1914); Cotonu to Parakou (1936); and
Abidjan to Bobo Dioulasso (1936). By 1940 West Africa had a total of 5,200
miles of railway line, which was divided roughly equally between the British
and French colonies.
Although the French experimented at an early stage with railway construction
by private contract (and the British were nearly persuaded to do the same), in
the event virtually the whole of the West African railway system was built by
the colonial governments and with public capital.17 There seem to have been
three main reasons for this exceptional degree of official entrepreneurship. First,
15 Olufemi Omosini, ‘Railway Projects and British Attitudes Towards the Development of West
Africa, 1872–1903’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 5, 1971, pp. 491–507.
16 The construction of this line over a period of 50 years is an epic which certainly merits a study of
its own.
17 For a comparative study (of Dahomey, Togo and south-west Nigeria), see C. W. Newbury, The
Western Slave Coast and Its Rulers, Oxford, 1961, pp. 141–7.
Completing the open economy 247
building railways in territories which had been acquired not only recently, but
by force, raised a number of potentially explosive issues regarding land rights,
labour supplies and, ultimately, political control. French and British governments
felt that all these matters were best kept in official hands. Second, from the
outset the railways had a military and administrative function as well as an eco-
nomic one. Colonial governments had a close interest in the direction of railway
routes and in the timing of construction because they wanted to be able to
move soldiers and officials to key points as quickly as possible. Finally, private
contractors and investors did not rush to build railways in West Africa. Those
who did come forward wanted subsidies or other concessions, and frequently
proved to be inefficient. Capital requirements were high because the railways
had to serve a wide and sparsely populated area. Furthermore, some lines had to
be built in anticipation of demand and not simply in response to it. Their ultim-
ate profitability was not guaranteed and in any case was certain to be a distant
event. Where private capital was wary, government enterprise became necessary.
Harbour improvements were closely related to programmes of railway
construction.18 The steamship had already begun to expose the limitations of
West African ports, many of which could not cope with vessels larger than trad-
itional sailing ships. The steamer, however, did not have a marked effect on
export production, whereas the railway did. By 1900 it was clear that existing
harbours were unable to handle the volume of produce that the railway was
capable of delivering. As a result, substantial alterations were made to the major
ports beginning around 1900 and continuing throughout the colonial era. In
some places, established centres, such as Dakar, Lagos and Freetown, were
improved. Elsewhere, entirely new ports, such as Port Harcourt and Takoradi,
were developed. The result was the decline of smaller centres, such as Badagri,
St Louis and Old Calabar, and the increasing concentration of the export trade
on a few large ports served by railways. In the 1930s, no less than 65 per cent of
the total tonnage of French West Africa’s overseas trade passed through Dakar.
Takoradi on the Gold Coast and Lagos in Nigeria were equally dominant. The
leading European ports for West African trade remained, as in the nineteenth
century, Liverpool, Bordeaux, Marseilles and Hamburg.
Once the early, superficial talk about ‘tapping the wealth of the interior’ had
vanished into the hot tropical air, it became apparent that the influence of the
railway was restricted to a small area on either side of the track. Large numbers
of widely dispersed producers had not been brought into the export economy
because the cost of taking their crops to the railway station would still have
been too high in relation to the price obtainable. Before 1918 there were very
few all-weather roads in West Africa outside the towns. The reason for this was
simple: the motor car was a novelty, and the type produced at that time was
18 A collection of case studies of the development of West African ports can be found in B. S. Hoyle
and D. Hilling, eds., Seaports and Development in Tropical Africa, London, 1970.
248 Completing the open economy
slow, expensive and so heavy that it tended to devour the roads it travelled on.
Contrary to what might be assumed, at that time few officials or expatriate firms
saw any future for the motor car in the underdeveloped world. In 1907, for
example, the British Cotton Growing Association recorded its opinion that with
regard to West Africa ‘metal roads and motor transport are, as far as one can
judge, a mistake’.19 In the 1910s the pioneers of commercial passenger and
freight services were Africans, the most prominent of whom was a Nigerian
named W. A. Dawodu.
Prevailing attitudes were rendered as obsolete as the early vehicles themselves
by the introduction of faster, cheaper and lighter Ford models, which reached
West Africa in 1918. In 1923 the first motor car crossed the Sahara from Algeria
to Timbuctu, an epic journey, though it was soon to become a commonplace
one. By 1930 commercial haulage firms were operating in and around the main
centres of economic activity in West Africa and the Sahara. By 1940 French
West Africa had about 10,000 vehicles compared to a mere 16 in 1913. The
expansion of motor transport in British West Africa was even faster: in the
1920s the vehicles imported by the Gold Coast and Nigeria were double the
number and twice the tonnage of those entering the French colonies.20 The
importation and operation of motor transport were in the hands of private firms,
both African and European. Road building, however, was undertaken mainly by
the colonial governments, which on the whole planned routes to feed the rail-
ways rather than to compete with them, though in West Africa, as in other
parts of the world, there was a growing rivalry between the two systems of
transport after the Second World War. It is important to note that Africans,
whose needs were not met by the official road-building programme and who
could command the necessary resources, also contributed to the new infrastruc-
ture. The cocoa farmers of Nigeria and the Gold Coast, for example, built their
own roads and bridges in the 1910s and 1920s and ran fleets of motor lorries to
speed the evacuation of their crop. The framework of the present West African
road system, without which the expansion of motor transport could not have
taken place, was erected in the 1920s and 1930s. For some officials and local
communities, the construction of a road to join the outside world was the out-
standing event of their time, a historical and personal drama that has been cap-
tured by Joyce Cary’s evocative novel, Mister Johnson (1939).
The development of inland waterways was on a modest scale, principally
because the Europeans found, as Africans had found before them, that river
transport was severely hampered by rapids and by marked seasonal variations in
the water level. However, relatively simple improvements, such as the clearing
19 C.O. 520/55, British Cotton Growing Association to Colonial Office, 8 August 1907, Public
Record Office.
20 For a case study, see A. M. Hay, ‘The Development of Road Transport in Nigeria, 1900–1940’,
Journal of Transport History, n.s., 1, 1971, pp. 95–107.
Completing the open economy 249
of existing waterways, stimulated the local economy in some areas, as, for example,
in parts of southern Nigeria. Not surprisingly, the main innovation, the use of
paddle steamers, occurred on stretches of water such as the Niger, the Benue and
the Senegal, which Africans had already made into well-known highways. Although
steamers were owned mainly by private firms, some attempt was made to coordin-
ate river and rail transport. The Senegal railway, for example, though it ended at
Bamako, linked up there with the middle Niger, thus connecting Dakar with Tim-
buctu and Gao. At the same time, however, traditional canoe transport occasionally
provided serious and unforeseen rivalry for the railways, as in the case of the Lagos
line, which had difficulty attracting traffic during its first ten years of operation
because of competition from canoes on the river Ogun.
West Africa, along with other parts of the world, benefited from modern trans-
port in many of the ways predicted by the classical economists. Freight rates were
greatly reduced. In 1909 the cost of headloading ranged from 3s 1d to 5s per ton/
mile on the Gold Coast, depending on the commodities carried. Hand carts and
cask rolling cost from 1s 2½d to 1s 11d. The charge by rail averaged 11¼d in 1903
but dropped to between 4d and 7½d in the 1920s, while the motor lorry cost as
little as 3d per ton/mile in 1930. These dramatic reductions had far-reaching conse-
quences. In substituting machinery for human power, modern transport encouraged
a more efficient combination of factors of production by releasing scarce labour
resources for other employment, by increasing mobility and by spreading informa-
tion about market opportunities. Europeans moved into the interior; Africans trav-
elled to cocoa and groundnut farms, and to the towns. Additionally, the fall in the
cost of transport was an external economy which accelerated the expansion of the
export sector by making production profitable over a wider area and for a larger
number of farmers and permitted the development of new resources, such as the
coal deposits found near Udi in eastern Nigeria in 1909. Railways and roads pushed
back and reshaped the traditional frontiers of trade. The arrival of the Lagos railway
at Kano in 1911, for example, was an event of great significance in African com-
mercial history. It marked the final decline of the old, north-facing, trans-Saharan
trade, the reorientation of the markets of the interior towards the coastal ports, and
the coalescence of two centres of exchange which, in previous centuries, had been
in only sporadic contact with each other.
The foregoing assessment of the impact of modern transport requires qualifi-
cation, both to avoid the sweeping character of traditional interpretations, which
have tended to follow the spirit of Lord Lugard’s pronouncement on this sub-
ject, and to take account of recent research, such as Fogel’s study of North
America, which has shown that the importance of railways in economic devel-
opment can easily be exaggerated.21 Generalisations about the effects of modern
transport often refer, at least by implication, to the area as a whole. Yet Liberia
21 Robert W. Fogel, Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History, Baltimore,
1964.
250 Completing the open economy
had no harbour or motor roads until the 1940s and no railway until the 1950s.
Large parts of the interior of former French West Africa are still without
modern transport today. The benefits of modern transport were felt most
strongly in a few territories, notably the Gold Coast, Nigeria and Senegal,
whose resources were large enough for them to invest in a modem infrastruc-
ture. Once again the point emerges that the regional effects of colonial eco-
nomic development were very varied. It is also a mistake to think of modern
transport as creating an export economy out of nothing. Most of the leading
exports were being shipped abroad before the introduction of railways and motor
transport. Indeed, it can be said that modern transport was attracted primarily to
regions which, though still full of uncertainties, had already begun to demon-
strate their economic potential.22 Moreover, the provision of modern transport
did not guarantee an automatic and dramatic expansion of exports. In Dahomey
railways had relatively little impact, while in Nigeria long stretches of track were
unsuccessful, either because they passed through barren land, or because freight
rates on certain products were too high. Finally, it should be remembered that
communications were designed mainly to evacuate exports. There were few lat-
eral or inter-colonial links, and little attempt was made to use railways and roads
as a stimulus to internal exchange.
The distributive system associated with overseas trade changed considerably
during the first phase of colonial rule. Discussion of these changes has to pro-
ceed cautiously, however, for they have long been the subject of a political and
economic controversy concerning the role of the expatriate firms. This debate
owes much of its longevity to a lack of hard evidence, for conjecture thrives
where refutation is impossible, and assertions, if repeated often enough, eventu-
ally assume the dignity and title of facts.23 The analysis presented here aims to
outline the main changes affecting the expatriate commercial houses, to explain
why they occurred and to consider their effects on African firms.
The most striking changes involved innovations in geographical location and
commercial structure. The expatriate firms, which had been situated on the
coast ever since overseas trade with West Africa began, started to move inland
in numbers in the 1890s. They were carried into the interior by the railway,
and they travelled in the wake of the administration, having become the willing
camp-followers of those they had roused to action. By the 1920s the leading
firms had branches in the main centres of trade throughout West Africa.24
22 In this respect the West African case was similar to that of Colombia, where economic growth
began before the appearance of modern transport facilities. See Everett E. Hagen, On the Theory of
Social Change: How Economic Growth Begins, Homewood, 1962, p. 363.
23 Two exceptional, pioneering studies must be mentioned, as they have both tried to disentangle fact
and fiction: J. Mars, ‘Extra-Territorial Enterprises’ in Mining, Commerce, and Finance in Nigeria,
ed. M. Perham, London, 1948, pp. 43–136, and P. T. Bauer, West African Trade, Cambridge, 1954.
24 For a contemporary guide to the expatriate firms, see A. Macmillan, The Red Book of West Africa,
London, 1920.
Completing the open economy 251
Structural changes increased the size and reach of the expatriate firms. From being
relatively small concerns dominated by one man or by a partnership, they began to
form limited liability companies. A few of many possible examples will suffice to illus-
trate this development, which began at the close of the nineteenth century: John Holt
& Co. became a limited company in 1897; Cheri Peyrissac in 1908; R. & W. King,
founded at the close of the seventeenth century, followed suit in 1911; and Maurel et
Prom in 1919. There was also a move towards concentration. Many small businesses
were eliminated and the survivors amalgamated to produce a handful of very large
firms. This trend was already apparent in the 1880s, and it developed still further
during the first phase of colonial rule, until by 1930 there were three outstanding
firms (the United Africa Company (U.A.C.), the Compagnie Française de l’Afrique
Occidentale and the Société Commerciale de l’Ouest Africain). Between them these
giants handled roughly two-thirds to three-quarters of West Africa’s overseas trade,
and their commercial network may be compared in size and importance with the
administrative system operated by the colonial powers. Indeed, sometimes the ‘district
officer’ of U.A.C. had more local influence (and was certainly better paid) than the
‘branch manager’ of His Majesty’s Government.
The most prominent of the three firms was the U.A.C., which alone handled
nearly half of West Africa’s overseas trade in the 1930s. U.A.C. dominated British
West Africa, and its subsidiaries bought and shipped about a quarter of the principal
exports of French West Africa. U.A.C. was the weighty offspring of two sizeable par-
ents: the Royal Niger Company, which was formed in 1886, and the African Associ-
ation, which was established three years later. Although the Niger Company lost its
royal charter in 1900, it continued to trade on a large scale, and in 1920 was bought
by W. H. Lever, the soap magnate, for £8 million. The African Association survived
until 1919, when it merged with Miller Bros and F. & A. Swanzy to form the African
& Eastern Trade Corporation Ltd. In 1920 Lever just failed in a bid to buy this com-
pany too, but in 1929 the African & Eastern came to an agreement with Lever Bros.
and the result was the formation of a gigantic combine known as U.A.C. The next
most important firm was the Compagnie Française de l’Afrique Occidentale (C.F.A.
O.), which was established in 1887. C.F.A.O. also had a long West African ancestry,
being descended from the Compagnie du Sénégal (1881), which was itself heir to the
Marseilles house of C. A. Verminck, whose West African interests dated back to the
1840s. The third large firm, the Société Commerciale de l’Ouest Africain (S.C.O.A),
was created in 1907 by a Swiss and French consortium out of another established
West African concern, Ryff, Roth et Cie. S.C.O.A. had less than half the capital and
far fewer branches than C.F.A.O. when it started, but overtook its rival after
the Second World War. Good business histories of these three firms, which are
still the leading expatriate trading concerns in West Africa today, would help
to resolve the controversy which has long surrounded their activities. 25
25 A certain amount of information on U.A.C. can be found in Charles Wilson’s The History of Uni-
lever, 2 vols, London, 1954, and Unilever, 1945–1965, London, 1968. A descriptive account of the
252 Completing the open economy
The chief survivors among the smaller firms were John Holt, Paterson
Zochonis, Maurel et Prom and Peyrissac. Of the few newcomers to West Afri-
can trade, the most significant (apart from specialist firms like Cadbury Bros and
the mining companies) were those customarily referred to as Levantines, a term
which covers nationals from a large number of countries bordering the eastern
Mediterranean. Levantine migrants, especially Lebanese, began settling in West
Africa at the close of the nineteenth century. Most of them had originally
planned to go to America, but for various reasons they failed to progress further
west than the African coast. By 1929 there were just over 3,000 Levantines in
French West Africa and a slightly smaller number in the British colonies. These
immigrants began trading in a small way, but because they were enterprising,
low-cost operators they quickly achieved success in certain fields. They first
made their mark in Guinea, where they started a boom in rubber exports in
1898. By paying in cash, they put an end to barter and forced a number of
European firms out of business. Subsequently, they bought other export crops,
such as groundnuts and cocoa, and sold cotton goods. In the 1920s and 1930s
they spread into motor transport, and also ran hotels and restaurants. Their num-
bers continued to increase and they remained important throughout the colonial
period.26 The Levantines, though not beyond criticism, have often been treated
with unjustified hostility by Europeans and Africans. Theirs is a misfortune com-
monly experienced by aliens who lack political influence.
A high degree of concentration was also apparent in banking and shipping.
Unlike the commercial firms, however, banking and shipping interests were
never very numerous. The leading companies owed their positions less to suc-
cessful take-overs and more to government support, at least at the outset. The
steamship companies received subsidies, and the banks were given monopolistic
rights over currency issues. The result was that a few, privileged firms were able
to achieve an almost unassailable ascendancy. In 1890 the British shipping com-
panies serving the West Coast were brought fully under the control of
A. L. Jones’s firm, Elder, Dempster & Co. Ltd.27 Jones’s fleets increased from 35
vessels totalling 53,000 tons in 1884 to 101 vessels totalling 301,000 tons in
1909, the year of his death. French shipping became concentrated on two Mar-
seilles companies, Chargeurs Réunis and its smaller associate, Fabre et Fraissinet,
both of which had financial and managerial links with C.F.A.O. In 1895, Elder,
Dempster and the leading German firm, Woermann Linie, reached an agree-
ment which limited competition between them and established a joint policy
operations of the French firms is given in Jean and René Charbonneau, Marchés et marchands d’Afri-
que noire, Paris, 1961.
26 For further information, see Fuad I. Khuri, ‘Kinship, Emigration, and Trade Partnership among the
Lebanese of West Africa’, Africa, 35, 1965, pp. 385–95, and William R. Stanley, ‘The Lebanese in
Sierra Leone: Entrepreneurs Extraordinary’, African Urban Notes, 5, 1970, pp. 159–74.
27 P. N. Davies, ‘The African Steam Ship Company’, in Liverpool and Merseyside, ed. J. R. Harris,
London, 1969, pp. 212–38.
Completing the open economy 253
towards newcomers. The French firms were not associated with this agreement
because they did not compete on the same routes as the larger English and
German companies. The shipping ‘conference’ (as such arrangements are called)
enabled the two major firms to control the bulk of the West African shipping
trade. Their principal weapon was the deferred rebate system, by which shippers
who agreed to use only conference vessels received a refund on a proportion of
their freight payments. The rebate was paid retrospectively to prevent those of
wavering loyalty from switching to another line. The conference was suspended
during the First World War, but it was reconstituted in 1924 and was not chal-
lenged with any measure of success until the 1930s, when U.A.C. began to run
ocean-going vessels of its own.28
Commercial banking was dominated in the British territories by the Bank of
British West Africa (B.B.W.A.) (1894), and in the French colonies by the
Banque de l’Afrique Occidentale (1901). Not until the arrival of Barclays Bank
(Dominion, Colonial & Overseas) in 1926 was there a serious threat to the pos-
ition of B.B.W.A. Even so, rivalry between the two banks was limited by
mutual understandings of the kind which habitually restrain members of the pro-
fessions from competing too fiercely with each other.
The foregoing developments are best explained as a response to changes in
the commercial environment between 1880 and 1930. Essentially, the conver-
sion to limited liability and the emergence of a few large firms were results of
the need both to conserve and to augment commercial capital. Between 1870
and 1936 nearly £50 million was invested in West Africa by private foreign
interests. Most of this money was contributed by trading firms, and, understand-
ably, virtually all of it went into commerce. The need to safeguard existing
investments by eliminating competition was an important motive for amalgam-
ation during times of unsatisfactory trade, as in the 1880s and 1920s. These
periods were also characterised by temporary ‘ceasefire’ arrangements. The
export firms, for example, would often agree to share total purchases on the
basis of their past performance. Pooling agreements of this kind nearly always
broke down when trading conditions improved, and when member firms
decided that they could do better on their own. The need to increase capital
came with the geographical advance of the expatriate firms, which was itself
a product of the adverse conditions of the late nineteenth century. At a time
when profit margins on traditional staples had been greatly reduced, expansion
inland was necessary to secure a larger turnover and to capture a share in any
new, and more profitable, trade that might be developed. However, expansion
could not be achieved without mobilising more funds than the average expatri-
ate firm in West Africa had at its disposal. Hence the trend towards company
28 For further details, see Charlotte Leubuscher, The West African Shipping Trade, 1909–1959, Leyden,
1963, Chs 3 and 4.
254 Completing the open economy
economies of scale which they were able to achieve, and from the regularity
and continuity of service which they could offer. All the same, it is undeniable
that oligopoly was closer to monopoly than it was to perfect competition, and
it is also true that the large firms regarded concentration as being primarily in
their own interests. John Mars, in a detailed study of the operations of expatri-
ate enterprises in the 1930s, has shown that in certain areas and on specific
commodities the large firms were occasionally able to make profits which
were excessive in relation to what would have been obtained had there been
greater competition.29 On the rare occasions when competition was fully
effective, as when Saul Raccah broke into the Nigerian groundnut trade in
the 1930s, the farmer received a higher price for his produce.30 Whether this
example can be generalised for the trade as a whole, and over a longer period
of time, is an interesting counter-factual proposition, though not one that
would be easy to test.
In assessing the role of the expatriate firms, it is important to distinguish
between two different questions: what the economic situation of West Africa
would have been without these companies; and how their performance com-
pares with the optimum contribution which might have been made. With
regard to the first question, the chief functions of the expatriate firms were to
provide and display the consumer goods which were the main incentive for
export production, and to ensure that exports were marketed in the industrial
countries. In carrying out these activities they incurred risks in holding stocks
and promising future deliveries, and they also financed the operations of many
African traders. Without the expatriate firms there would have been less invest-
ment in commerce, less expertise in international markets and a much smaller
foreign trade sector. As to the second question, it is clear that the record of the
expatriate concerns fell short of what was theoretically possible. Once estab-
lished, the large firms became conservative in outlook. They were concerned
more to defend their existing positions than to open new fields of enterprise.
For example, down to the 1950s they showed little interest in developing local
industries, partly because this was, in any case, a difficult task, and partly because
they did not want to tackle unfamiliar projects.31 The large firms also did little
to encourage training in modern business management. Africans had to acquire
the necessary skills on their own and, in the event, slowly. Furthermore, it is at
least an arguable probability that greater competition would have given Africans
a rather better deal in terms of the prices they received for produce and paid for
consumer goods. Finally, there is no doubt that a large proportion of trading
29 ‘Extra-Territorial Enterprises’, in Mining, Commerce, and Finance in Nigeria, ed. M. Perham, 1948,
pp. 76–87.
30 For an outline of Raccah’s career see Hancock, Survey of British Commonwealth Affairs, II, Part 2,
pp. 216–17.
31 This question is considered in greater detail in Chapter 7.
256 Completing the open economy
profits, surplus funds and expatriate salaries were transferred abroad instead of
being invested in Africa.
The position of African businessmen under colonialism was not quite as
simple as it has often been made to appear. The main trends in the fortunes of
indigenous import and export firms were as follows. African merchants were
able to flourish during the period 1850–80 because trading conditions at that
time gave no overwhelming advantage to large firms. The restricted size of the
market, the introduction of cash payments and the advent of the steamer were
circumstances which enabled small firms to achieve a considerable degree of suc-
cess. From the 1880s onwards the commercial environment began to favour
large firms, and many smaller concerns, European as well as African, found that
they lacked the capital and skills to survive. African merchants did not give up
easily, however, and by the 1920s they, too, were experimenting with company
formation in an attempt to mobilise more capital. But by then the large expatri-
ate concerns had established almost total dominance, and thereafter small firms,
whatever their nationality, found the barriers to entry almost insurmountable.
The two successful attempts which are often quoted were made by Levantines,
not by Africans: Saul Raccah won a sizeable share of the Nigerian groundnut
trade in the 1930s, and A. G. Leventis broke into the Gold Coast import and
export trade during the Second World War.32 These men found a space for
themselves at the point where the economies of scale enjoyed by the large firms
were outweighed by the diseconomies which resulted from the comprehensive
and relatively unspecialised nature of their business. That is to say, the new-
comers began by exploiting particular markets and specific lines of goods; they
were in a position to make decisions on the spot instead of having to refer mat-
ters to a head office in Europe; and they were able to match pioneer aggression
against an established, bureaucratic outlook. However, these exceptions, being
so few, prove the rule, for Raccah and Leventis were particularly skilled, highly
motivated and adventurous businessmen.
The conclusions which can be derived from this survey of changing business
fortunes need to be stated carefully. In the first place, it is likely that African
import and export firms suffered a decline in the proportion of overseas trade
which they handled, at least as far as the established staples were concerned.
However, the extent of this decline should not be exaggerated, for the European
firms already dominated the trade of the main ports in the period 1850–80—a
fact that is not always emphasised. In terms of value, however, the external trade
in African hands was probably greater in the 1920s than it had been in the mid-
nineteenth century. What happened was that all groups gained from the expan-
sion of trade during the first phase of colonial rule, but that the expatriate firms
gained relatively more than the indigenous firms. Secondly, it is misleading to
point to the decline of Africans in the traditional import and export trades
without at the same time recognising their enterprise in other branches of com-
merce. Many Africans were astute enough to realise that their best course lay in
developing new types of trade rather than in trying to compete with the large
two-way firms. In Nigeria, for example, Africans were the first to import and
operate commercial motor vehicles, to market sewing machines, to build cin-
emas and to establish a bread-making industry. Thirdly, it is important to
remember that externally induced changes in the economic environment were
only partly responsible for the shift in the relative positions of expatriate and
indigenous firms. Internal structural weaknesses, such as the existence of inherit-
ance laws which made it hard to keep an African business together after the
death of its founder, were also very significant.
Considerable disagreement also exists over the fortunes of the African middle-
men, the intermediaries who linked producers and consumers to the import and
export firms. Some sources claim that the middlemen were swept away at the
close of the nineteenth century; others give prominence to the attacks made on
them by expatriate firms in the 1930s! The first claim has arisen mainly because
undue attention has been paid to the downfall of a few prominent individuals,
such as Ja Ja and Nana Olomu, who ran big trading monopolies in the nine-
teenth century, while the activities of an expanding number of smaller traders in
the twentieth century have been largely ignored. Studies by Gertzel and Ikime
have made it clear that, in southern Nigeria anyway, many expatriate firms were
quick to realise that they could not afford to disrupt the indigenous distributive
system completely.33 The expansion of the market in the period 1900–30 was
made possible not only by the movement inland of the expatriate firms, but also
by an increase in the number of African intermediaries. In 1908 the manager of
Lagos Stores Ltd, which had several branches in the interior of Nigeria, esti-
mated that less than 1 per cent of his firm’s total trade was transacted with the
final consumer.34 The census figures for the large towns in West Africa confirm
that trade was an expanding occupation, not a declining one.
The life of Omu Okwei (1872–1943), a prominent woman trader in Onitsha,
provides an interesting example of indigenous enterprise during this less-
publicised phase of African commercial history in the period following the
decline of the great middlemen of the nineteenth century.35 Omu Okwei’s trad-
ing career was greatly helped by the inland advance of the expatriate firms after
1900. She developed close commercial relations with the Niger Company, sell-
ing palm produce to the company and retailing imported goods. By 1910, her
business had grown to the point where she was allowed credit of £400 a month.
33 Cherry J. Gertzel, ‘Relations between African and European Traders in the Niger Delta,
1880–1896’, Journal of African History, 3, 1962, pp. 361–6; Obaro Ikime, Merchant Prince of the Niger
Delta, London, 1968, pp. 187–8.
34 C.O. 520/68, Egerton to Crewe, 16 December, 1908, Public Record Office.
35 For further details see Felicia Ekejiuba, ‘Omu Okwei, the Merchant Queen of Ossomari:
A Biographical Sketch’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1967, pp. 633–46.
258 Completing the open economy
By the 1920s, she was diversifying her interests, putting money into property,
investing in lorries and canoes and making cash advances to other traders. At her
death she left a small fortune, which included 24 houses in Onitsha and about
£5,000 in the bank. Omu Okwei’s career serves as a reminder of the presence
and influence of women traders in West Africa, and as a particular illustration of
the proposition that colonialism, having destroyed some of the great figures of
the nineteenth century, helped to create new opportunities for at least some sec-
tions of the indigenous population.
In short, the middlemen lost the political power which formerly they had
used to support their market demands, and they also had to adapt to new devel-
opments, such as the coming of the railway, but as a group they survived. How-
ever, contrary to the allegations of expatriate officials and merchants, the
continued presence of a multiplicity of indigenous traders was not a wasteful
allocation of human resources. As Bauer has made clear, the so-called middle-
men were highly competitive and generally efficient channels of collection and
distribution.36 The idea of direct trade with the producers, though appealing at
a time when expatriate firms were trying to cut their costs, was an economic
fantasy. In a situation where producers and consumers were both numerous and
scattered, abolishing the middlemen would have meant reducing the size of the
market.
The last of the external influences to require examination is the colonial mon-
etary system. As noted in Chapter 4, the decline of transitional currencies and
the spread of British and French coins date from about the middle of the nine-
teenth century. Thus, the introduction of the colonial monetary system was not
a sudden event. Once again, the role of the colonial authorities was to speed
a process which was already under way. The administrations encouraged the
adoption of modern money in three ways: by demonetising transitional curren-
cies; by paying its expanding labour force in European coin; and by insisting on
receiving taxes in cash rather than in kind. Some of the expatriate firms were
also keen to see a cash trade develop, but others clung to barter for as long as
possible. The Niger Company, for example, did not conduct a cash trade until
after about 1905. The most potent agents of change were Africans themselves,
especially the new generation of small export producers who realised that cash
transactions would enable them to strike a better bargain. By about 1910, Euro-
pean currencies were widespread in West Africa. In the period 1906–10, exports
of sterling silver to British West Africa averaged £666,190 per annum, which
was almost as much as was issued for the United Kingdom itself. Naturally,
there were some areas which continued to use transitional currencies for local
transactions during the greater part of the colonial period. Perhaps the best
example was eastern Nigeria, where the government’s decision to ban further
36 Bauer, West African Trade, pp. 22–34. The general point remains, even though Bauer may well
have over-emphasised the extent of competition among African traders.
Completing the open economy 259
imports of manillas in 1902 inadvertently had the effect of stabilising their value.
In 1948–49, when manillas were finally called in, no less than 30 million were
collected.37
The increasing circulation of European currencies led to the introduction of
modern banking institutions. The first successful bank in West Africa was the
Banque du Sénégal, which was established at St Louis in 1854. This bank was
founded primarily to assist the development of legitimate commerce, and specif-
ically to handle compensation payments to former slave owners following the
abolition of slavery in the French empire in 1848. In 1901 the Banque du Séné-
gal was replaced by the Banque de l’Afrique Occidentale (B.A.O.). B.A.O.,
which was designed to serve the wider area that had just been brought under
French rule, was the most important bank in French West Africa during the
colonial period. Towards the close of the nineteenth century several attempts
were made to set up banks in the British possessions, notably in Sierra Leone
and the southern part of Nigeria, but none was successful until 1894, when
a group of businessmen headed by A. L. Jones, the shipping magnate, founded
the Bank of British West Africa (B.B.W.A.), which expanded rapidly. By 1910,
it had established branches in most of the leading commercial centres in the
British colonies, as well as in Monrovia, the capital of Liberia. The bank’s paid
up capital, a mere £12,000 in 1894, had grown to £200,000; the number of its
employees had increased from six to 114; its depositors from a few dozen to
4,410; its deposits from about £30,000 to just over £1 million. B.B.W.A.,
though joined by a second large and successful expatriate bank, Barclays (D.C.
& O.), in 1926, remained the leading bank in British West Africa throughout
the colonial period.
The largely unplanned infiltration of an underdeveloped region by an
advanced monetary system was a global phenomenon in the nineteenth century.
The expansion of international trade and the adoption of the gold standard
among the industrial powers had repercussions in India, Ceylon, Australia, Indo-
China, Puerto Rico, Mexico and the Philippines—to list just some of the lead-
ing examples. It was also a process that gave rise to a number of problems. In
West Africa these included the provision of satisfactory controls over the supply
and repatriation of currency; the equitable division of seignorage (the difference
between the bullion value and the face value of the coinage) between the
metropolis and the colonies; and the maintenance of adequate reserves for cur-
rencies circulating in the colonies.38
The French dealt with these problems by utilising an existing private institu-
tion, the Banque de l’Afrique Occidentale and subjecting it to an increasing
37 United Africa Company, ‘The Manilla Problem’, Statistical and Economic Review, 3, 1949, pp.
44–56.
38 These questions are discussed further in A. G. Hopkins, ‘The Creation of a Colonial Monetary
System: The Origins of the West African Currency Board’, African Historical Studies, 3, 1970, pp.
101–32.
260 Completing the open economy
39 There is no satisfactory study of the colonial monetary system in French West Africa. A certain
amount of historical information can be found in M. Leduc, Les institutions monétaires africaines: pays
francophones, Paris, 1965.
40 In practice, there was no problem of convertibility until after 1945.
Completing the open economy 261
money from local circulation. This reduction in the local money supply lowered
incomes in the colony. The result was that imports declined to the point where
they were equated with exports once more, though at a lower equilibrium level.
In short, money was regarded mainly as a medium of external exchange.
Judged by nineteenth-century principles of sound money, the colonial monet-
ary system had certain points in its favour. The operation of the system pre-
vented the colonies from accumulating deficits. Its self-regulating qualities,
combined with the colonial tradition of balancing the budget, virtually elimin-
ated the risk of inflation and the danger of a balance of payments crisis. Because
the colonial system had close connections with the metropolis, currencies circu-
lating in the dependencies enjoyed an international reputation and a degree of
stability, though the latter advantage was more pronounced in the case of ster-
ling than in the case of the franc. Finally, the profits derived from seignorage
and from investing the currency reserves gave the colonies some additional rev-
enue which had not been available previously.
The system had also had its limitations.41 The chief disadvantage was that the
growth of the internal exchange economy tended to be inhibited by monetary
tightness, except when there was an export surplus. This favourable situation
was often short lived, and always unpredictable. Theoretically, there was nothing
in the monetary system to prevent the commercial banks from expanding the
money supply through lending operations, but in practice banking policy was
passive and remained so, as Killick has shown with reference to the Gold Coast,
down to the time of independence.42 The banks usually invested their money in
the metropolis, in the same way as the W.A.C.B. and B.A.O. invested the cur-
rency reserves outside the West African colonies. The underdeveloped colonies
found themselves loaning money to the advanced countries, principally because
of a lack of acceptable local investment opportunities. Bank lending policy gen-
erally followed the trade cycle by expanding credit during a boom and reducing
it at a time of slump. This practice tended to magnify rather than diminish the
fluctuations in trade experienced by primary export producers in the colonies.
Moreover, bank loans were confined mainly to the large expatriate firms, thus
reinforcing their dominant position in commerce. The banks were willing to
accept deposits from Africans, and as early as 1910 £263,000 (about a quarter of
B.B.W.A.’s total deposits) belonged to African customers. When it came to bor-
rowing, however, Africans ran into difficulties. They found it hard to present
themselves as being personally trustworthy in the eyes of expatriates, and they
41 For a full discussion see two pioneering studies: J. Mars, ‘The Monetary and Banking System and
the Loan Market of Nigeria’, in Mining, Commerce, and Finance in Nigeria, ed. M. Perham, 1948, pp.
177–224; and W. T. Newlyn and D. C. Rowan, Money and Banking in British Colonial Africa,
Oxford, 1954.
42 Tony Killick, ‘The Monetary and Financial System’, in A Study of Contemporary Ghana, 1, The
Economy of Ghana, eds. Walter Birmingham, I. Neustadt, and E. N. Omaboe, London, 1966, pp.
294–331.
262 Completing the open economy
also faced problems of supplying the kind of security thought normal in Europe,
chiefly because indigenous customs regarding the ownership of property often
meant that individuals were not free to negotiate mortgages.
The foregoing discussion of government policy, transport, the distributive
system and money and banking has attempted to clarify what might be called
the external contribution to the development of the open economy. The main
conclusion to emerge, whatever judgements are made about the beneficial or
deleterious effects of colonialism, is that the expatriate role was less dynamic and
more circumscribed than is often supposed. Within the limits indicated, external
influences were important and in some cases crucial, but it would be mistaken
to think that they were sufficient to guarantee an automatic expansion of the
export sector. Indeed, it is possible to find instances where the efforts of expatri-
ates (especially when coercion was used) led to meagre or even counterproduct-
ive results. The fact that, with certain regional qualifications, the results were
substantial implies that other factors, especially those relating to the responsive-
ness of African societies, were of critical significance. The remaining task is to
assess the nature and extent of the indigenous contribution by focusing on the
utilisation of land and labour resources.
1920s, and at least two colonial secretaries, Harcourt and Ormsby-Gore, were
prepared to consider the case with more than formal interest. Their concern was
not simply a response to Lever’s pressure but arose out of a fear that the greater
technical efficiency achieved by plantation developments in other parts of the
world would make it impossible for indigenous producers in West Africa to
compete in international markets. Their attitude shows that British policy at
least was not clearly laid down right at the start of the colonial era.
Nevertheless, the planters’ frontier made little headway in West Africa. In the
French territories concessions were limited shortly after the turn of the century, and
some were cancelled altogether. The only plantations worth noting were those in
the southern part of the Ivory Coast.44 These expanded briefly in the 1920s but
declined rapidly after the Second World War. By 1955 little more than 200 French
planters remained, and they produced only a very small proportion of total exports.
In German West Africa the initial rate of expansion was not maintained, and planta-
tion development was brought to a halt by the First World War.45 In British West
Africa the oil mills which Lever had been allowed to start in Sierra Leone proved
unsuccessful, his more ambitious plans for palm oil plantations were frustrated, and
he was forced to transfer his interest to the Congo, where the Belgian government
adopted a more generous approach to the distribution of African land. Lever ful-
minated against the backwardness of indigenous methods of extracting palm oil, but
these methods, though technically inferior, had overall advantages which expatriates
found hard to match.46 Ironically, the one area where expatriate plantations did
become important was Liberia, the only politically independent state in West
Africa. The Liberian economy had limped along from crisis to crisis since
the second half of the nineteenth century, unable to find a permanently successful
export and accumulating a number of external debts. By the 1920s, it was evident
that a substantial injection of foreign capital was needed to retrieve the situation,
and in 1926 the government leased 1 million acres to a large American firm, the
Firestone Rubber Company, for a term of 99 years.47 Rubber exports began to
expand in the late 1930s, and by 1950 accounted for about 90 per cent of the value
of all Liberia’s exports.
44 H. Frechou, ‘Les plantations européennes en Côte d’Ivoire’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 8, 1955, pp.
56–83. A small number of banana plantations were established in French Guinea in the 1930s.
45 After the First World War the plantations were run by Britain under the mandate of the League of
Nations. They reverted to Germany in the 1920s but were taken over again by Britain after
the Second World War. See S. H. Bederman, ‘Plantation Agriculture in Victoria Division, West
Cameroons: An Historical Introduction’, Geography, 51, 1966, pp. 349–60, and, for a study of the
operation of these plantations, E. Ardener, S. Ardener, and W. A. Warmington, Plantation and Vil-
lage in the Cameroons, London, 1960.
46 Peter Kilby, Industrialization in an Open Economy: Nigeria 1945–1966, Cambridge, 1969, pp.
146–68.
47 Firestone’s, of course, had its own reasons for entering Liberia. For further information see the
items by Brown, McLaughlin and Taylor listed in the bibliography.
Completing the open economy 265
The reasons why the colonial powers decided to limit foreign concessions in
West Africa are more complex than is usually thought. To start with, it is necessary
to dispose of traditional explanations which have long camouflaged more important
influences. It is often said that plantations failed to become established in West
Africa because the climate was unsuitable for white settlers. There is no force in this
argument. The alleged unhealthiness of the tropics did not prevent the establish-
ment of European plantations in the Belgian Congo, French Equatorial Africa or
Malaya, and it did not discourage serious applicants in West Africa either. Further-
more, the control of malaria and other tropical diseases was becoming more effect-
ive by the start of the twentieth century, and the so-called White Man’s Grave was
beginning to lose some of its unsavoury reputation.48 In the case of the British col-
onies, it has been argued that the government was committed by its policy of
trusteeship to maintaining the land in African hands. This is an unsatisfactory
explanation because trusteeship was an eclectic concept, at least as far as means were
concerned. The Dutch, for example, had a policy of trusteeship which was used to
justify the introduction of plantations into Indonesia; Britain, too, was prepared to
permit plantation developments in certain parts of the empire; and substantial con-
cessions were granted in French Equatorial Africa.49 The problem cannot be solved
simply by a general reference to the notion of the dual mandate: the question that
has to be answered is why trusteeship took the particular form it did in West Africa.
There were four main reasons why Europeans failed to play a dominant part in the
production of West African exports. The first reason relates specifically to minerals;
the remaining three concern agricultural production. In the case of mineral resources
considerable weight must be given to a fortuitous geological fact, namely that known
and commercially exploitable deposits were not distributed profusely throughout West
Africa. Had the gold mining boom of 1899–1902 lasted beyond the Boer War, and
had many other mineral resources been found about the same time, then the eco-
nomic history of West Africa might well have taken a very different course. It is con-
ceivable that trusteeship would have been interpreted in a way which was more
favourable to expatriate interests, for it would have been hard to resist the argument
that European capital and skill were needed to benefit Africans as well as Europeans.
The discovery of iron and diamonds in Sierra Leone in the 1930s, and their exploit-
ation by expatriate firms, is an exceptional case which supports this hypothesis.
Of the three reasons why expatriate plantations were of little significance in West
Africa, two have been almost entirely ignored and the third needs to be given
greater emphasis than it has in the past. To begin with, it is important to appreciate
that the planters’ frontier was held back partly by strong opposition from established
trading interests. Many of those who pressed for agricultural concessions, men such
as Verdier and Lever, were also engaged in buying, shipping and selling produce.
48 Raymond E. Dumett, ‘The Campaign against Malaria and the Expansion of Scientific, Medical and
Sanitary Services in British West Africa, 1898–1910’, African Historical Studies, 1, 1968, pp. 153–97.
49 S. Amin and C. Coquéry-Vidrovitch, Histoire économique du Congo, 1880–1968, Dakar, 1970, Part 1.
266 Completing the open economy
Other expatriate traders who lacked either the capital or the inclination to enter
production feared that their more adventurous rivals would be in a position to
undercut them by a considerable margin and to establish a monopoly over the
supply of export crops. This anxiety explains why German traders opposed conces-
sions in Togo, why C.F.A.O. was hostile to plantations in French West Africa, and
why Manchester and Liverpool traders mounted a powerful campaign in opposition
to Lever’s demands between 1906 and 1920. In the latter year, Lever bought up the
Niger Company and with it much of the opposition to his schemes. Nevertheless,
the profound split among expatriate business interests in West Africa undoubtedly
did much to weaken the case put forward by those who wished to see extensive
European plantations established in that part of the continent.
The second and equally neglected reason is that the few European plantations
which were established in colonial West Africa nearly all failed. They started with
two serious drawbacks, a considerable ignorance of tropical conditions and
a notable lack of capital, which had also characterised previous experiments during
the era of legitimate commerce. These handicaps often proved fatal at the outset.
Even if they were overcome, two more problems arose almost immediately. One
was a shortage of labour, which also meant that wages had to be relatively high.
The other problem was that plantations, being highly specialised, were particularly
susceptible to shifts in world supply. Many of the early expatriate planters in West
Africa committed themselves heavily to coffee production and were eliminated by
competition from South America soon after the turn of the century. Both problems
are illustrated by the history of French plantations on the Ivory Coast, which sur-
vived in the second half of the colonial period only because they received large sub-
sidies in the form of forced labour and tariff preferences. The record of expatriate
plantations in the West African colonies was scarcely one to encourage either a very
widespread demand for concessions, or wholehearted government support for
European adventures in African agriculture.
The third reason is perhaps more obvious, but still needs to be stressed. It is
that by the time controversy over concessions was at its height, Africans had
already succeeded in generating an export economy by their own efforts.
Exports of palm products recovered from the difficulties of the 1880s and 1890s
and expanded after the turn of the century; the Gold Coast cocoa industry had
become the largest in the world by 1910; groundnuts, long established as the
main export staple in Senegambia, and in any case not suited to plantation pro-
duction, had become very important in northern Nigeria by 1914. Peasant pro-
duction had proved itself; plantations had not. Furthermore, plantations were
bound to interfere with traditional land rights and to lead to disputes over labour
recruitment. Both matters were guaranteed to arouse widespread protests from Afri-
cans. Their hostility could easily find political expression, and so threaten the colo-
nial authorities and colonial rule itself. This evidence, and its implications, proved
decisive. The French gave their backing to indigenous farmers in West Africa spe-
cifically to avoid the complications which expatriate enterprise had brought in
Algeria and Indo-China, and the majority of British officials, led by Clifford, the
Completing the open economy 267
influential governor of the Gold Coast (1912–19) and Nigeria (1919–25), agreed to
a similar course of action. In Chapter 4 it was argued that the nineteenth century
saw the rise of a new generation of export producers, and that the partition of West
Africa was motivated partly by the need to create an economic environment which
would allow them to flourish. In restricting the planters’ frontier in West Africa,
and in supporting African producers, the colonial powers were carrying nineteenth-
century policy to a fruitful conclusion.
The foregoing argument can be summarised as follows. Official policy towards
concessions was not settled by 1900, but evolved gradually during the initial phase
of colonial rule. The controversy was not simply between enlightened, liberal civil
servants on the one hand, and the ‘soap boilers of the world’, as Hancock called
them, on the other, but between combinations of various interests with officials
and businessmen represented on both sides. To understand why expatriate plant-
ations were unimportant in West Africa it is necessary to focus not on climatic or
vaguely humanitarian explanations, but on the failure rate among those plantations
which were established, on the ability of the indigenous society to produce the
required exports, and on the relative strengths of expatriate traders and expatriate
planters. The hypothesis advanced here is that expatriate plantations were more
likely to become established in parts of the tropics where opposition from traders
was non-existent or ineffective, and where peasant exports were slow to respond
to external demands.
To these statements may be added a final comment about the wisdom of the policy
adopted by the colonial powers. Some writers have argued that by preventing the
development of a free market in land the authorities deprived the community of the
benefits which would have arisen from a more efficient utilisation of resources.50 This
criticism is open to question. It fails to appreciate that policy was fluid enough at the
start of the colonial period to allow some plantations to be started, and that these
experiments were unable to survive without official aid. Furthermore, there was no
guarantee that the benefits of plantation development would have accrued mainly to
the producing country. Plantations have often formed enclaves which have failed to
transmit growth to the domestic economy. The oft-predicted downfall of West Afri-
can palm produce exports has not occurred. Plantations of palm trees can supply better
quality produce, but the achievement may involve higher production costs. Where
plantations have succeeded in reducing production costs, their advantage has some-
times been cancelled by political instability, as in the cases of Indonesia and the
Congo.51 The moral is an important one: decisions on agricultural policy should also
consider the wider social and political implications of changes in the means of working
the land.
50 For example, F. J. Pedler, Economic Geography of West Africa, London, 1955, pp. 38–9.
51 Peasant exports have also been affected by political instability in the post-colonial era, as the
example of eastern Nigeria makes clear.
NOUAKCHOTT
Inland Niger
R. Se Delta Project Timbuctu
nega
l Gao
St. Louis Louga
R.
L. Debo 16°N
DAKAR
Nig
Kayes Sansanding Mopti
er
Thies
Kita Niamey Zinder
Nguru
OUAGADOUGOU
BAMAKO
BATHURST Koudougou
Sikasso Kano
BISSAU Bobo Dioulasso Zaria Maiduguri
KADUNA
CONAKRY Kankan Parakou Bauchi
Korhogo
Pepel Minna
Bouake Ilorin R.Benue
FREETOWN
Moyamba
Kumasi Ibadan Makurdi
MONROVIA Benin
ENUGU
Palm oil and Kernels LOME
Cocoa Sassandra ACCRA LAGOS
Groundnuts ABIDJAN Port Harcourt 4°N
PORTO NOVO
Coffee
Bananas
Rubber
Cotton
0 kilometres 600
Ten years ago, an historical analysis of the African contribution to the development
of the export economy would have had to rely heavily on a mixture of untested tra-
ditions and speculation. Today, as a result of some painstaking empirical research, reli-
able information is available for certain areas and products, though more work still
needs to be undertaken.52 Two contrasting regions and exports will be considered
here; the Gold Coast cocoa industry, which has been examined in a series of import-
ant studies by Polly Hill,53 and the origins of the northern Nigerian groundnut trade,
which has been reconstructed, most valuably, by Jan Hogendorn.54 Both examples
will be supplemented by evidence relating to French West Africa.
In less than 20 years (1892–1911) shipments of cocoa from the Gold Coast grew
from nothing to around 40,000 tons, making the colony the largest cocoa exporter
in the world. This position has been maintained ever since. In the 1960s, the cocoa
belt covered about 4 million acres, the industry provided employment for
several million people, and in 1964 exports reached a peak of 538,000 tons. The
rapid expansion of the early days is all the more remarkable when it is remembered
that the cocoa tree is not indigenous to West Africa, that it takes several years
before it begins to yield, and that it does not reach maturity until it is about 15 years
old. Cocoa-farming was a thoroughly capitalist enterprise from the outset: it
involved taking risks with an unfamiliar product; substantial investments of time and
money; the ability to plan ahead; and a willingness to defer present consumption for
the sake of future returns. This major innovation used to be explained by stressing
the role of government sponsorship and supervision, and by underplaying the con-
tribution made by Africans. In particular, it was thought that cocoa was simply
added piecemeal to the traditional activities of small-scale, settled farmers, and so
made few demands on the indigenous economic and social structure.
The reality was very different. Although the government played some part in
making seeds and plants available, it is now clear that neither colonial officials
nor expatriate firms had much idea of what was happening in the interior until
after the cocoa industry was firmly established. Polly Hill’s fieldwork has revealed
that the innovators were not settled ‘peasants’ but migrant farmers in the south-
east part of the Gold Coast, who began to move in the 1890s from the Akwa-
pim ridge to virgin land in nearby Akim Abuakwa.55 The migrants were pulled
52 The chief gaps are as follows: groundnuts in Senegambia; palm products in Sierra Leone and
Nigeria; cocoa on the Ivory Coast and in Ashanti on the Gold Coast. These topics have been con-
sidered to some extent by geographers, anthropologists and economists, but not by economic his-
torians. The Nigerian cocoa industry has been investigated by Dr Sara Berry and by the present
writer.
53 See especially The Migrant Cocoa-Farmers of Southern Ghana, Cambridge, 1963.
54 J. S. Hogendorn, The Origins of the Groundnut Trade in Northern Nigeria, University of London, Ph.
D. thesis, 1966.
55 Dr Hill is careful to point out that in dispelling one myth she is anxious not to create another. The
migrant farmers studied by her are only part of the story; the subsequent development of cocoa
farming in the large Ashanti region in the 1920s and 1930s has yet to be examined in a work of
comparable scope or depth.
270 Completing the open economy
into this adventure mainly by a desire to find a replacement for the flagging
staples of legitimate commerce, in which they were involved as producers or
traders. They may also have been pushed into colonising new land by population
pressure in their home areas. These farmers did not merely add cocoa to their trad-
itional activities; they migrated specifically to grow cash crops for export, and food
production had to be fitted into this primary objective. Indeed, specialisation in
cocoa production by some farmers soon led others to concentrate on growing food-
stuffs for sale. Finally, it is important to realise that generalisations about the scale of
agricultural operations in West Africa can be very misleading. While it is apparent
that the majority of cocoa farmers operated on a small scale in comparison with the
plantations (of several hundred acres) which dominated production in other parts of
the world, it is equally true that the size (and shape) of farms on the Gold Coast
varied greatly, and that individual farmers might own one plot or several plots.
Diversity was both a sensitive adaptation to local geography and an indication of the
varied skills, ambitions and fortunes of export producers.
The so-called ‘traditional’ social structure proved to be an asset rather than
a liability.56 Established forms of cooperative enterprise were harnessed or adapted to
finance the migration itself, and to purchase land in new areas. Two types of group
organisation were especially prominent: first the ‘company’, which was an association
of non-kinsmen similar to the traditional huza system of the Krobo people, and was
common among migrants from patrilineal societies; and second, a system of purchasing
family lands, which was adopted by groups of kinsmen from matrilineal societies, such
as the Aburi and Akropong. Both arrangements gave individuals group support, yet
neither inhibited them from exercising their initiative or from profiting by it. For
example, migrants from matrilineal societies allowed their kinsmen usufructuary rights
on part of the land they had purchased, but they also retained large tracts for them-
selves. Furthermore, the migrants did not find themselves fettered by communal obli-
gations when it came to managing their farms. On the contrary, they usually found it
advantageous to employ cheap family labour, at least at the outset, and to continue to
cooperate with kinsmen and friends in tasks which were beyond the reach of individ-
uals, such as the construction of roads and bridges. Hired labour became significant
only after the turn of the century, when some established farmers found that they
could afford to supplement their family labour force by employing outsiders, and so
could expand their farming activities. Migration was a continuous process and is still
going on today. As nearby lands were taken up, and as motor transport became avail-
able in the 1920s, the migrants began to move further afield, though they never lost
contact with their homelands. Thus, the cocoa belt has changed its size and shape over
the years as new lands have been developed through the reinvestment of past profits,
and as old farms have gradually fallen into disuse.
56 The brief discussion in this paragraph should be related to the extended analysis of the ‘traditional’
economy presented in Chapter 2.
Completing the open economy 271
The development of cocoa in the Ivory Coast presents some interesting parallels
with the Gold Coast. There, too, migrants were first in initiating and then in expand-
ing cocoa farming.57 The earliest migrants were Dioula from north of the forest, who
travelled south to take up land in the 1910s. Many Dioula financed their agricultural
ventures with funds they had accumulated in pre-colonial trading activities. Some
were rich enough to buy land outright, and also to hire labourers from the outset.
A second group of migrants, the Baoulé, came from a poor farming area in the
savanna, and so started with few resources. They often had to begin as abusa labourers,
that is men who harvested the crop in return for a one third share of it. Dioula and
Baoulé farmers used family labour as well, especially migrants who came south to
work for their relatives on a seasonal basis. The host communities were sufficiently
adaptable to meet these new demands, and local farmers also took up cocoa farming
successfully, as Köbben’s studies of the Agni and Beté have demonstrated.58 Strangers
were welcomed not only because of the rents they paid, but because they added to the
manpower, and hence to the political importance, of the local community. Indeed, in
some villages immigrant farmers came to outnumber their hosts. Although land was
occasionally sold, the indigenous authorities preferred to alienate the use of land rather
than land itself. This arrangement preserved the interests of the local community, and
at the same time allowed scope for individual enterprise. Usufructuary rights gave the
immigrant farmer sufficient incentive and security, for he acquired absolute rights over
property created by his own efforts, such as cocoa trees and food crops.
The main contrast between cocoa production on the Gold Coast and on the Ivory
Coast is that the French colony developed later and also more slowly. The explanation
of this distinction must remain tentative, at least until a full comparative analysis has
been undertaken. The main reason, however, appears to lie in the nature of the exter-
nal authority rather than in a sharp contrast in the geographical endowment or in the
receptivity of indigenous societies in the two colonies. The effect of French policy
was to retard the development of cash crops in the Ivory Coast. In 1908 Governor
Angoulvant tried to revive the colony’s flagging export trade and public revenue by
making cocoa farming compulsory. The timing of this effort was scarcely propitious,
for the governor, beneath whose iron exterior there beat a heart of steel, was also
engaged in vigorous military operations in the forest zone in an attempt to complete
the pacification of the country. Without adequate monetary incentives, the local
inhabitants showed no enthusiasm for growing export crops. Later on, in the 1920s
and 1930s French officials favoured expatriate cocoa and coffee planters rather than
indigenous farmers, notably by supplying the expatriates with forced labour. Not sur-
prisingly, the local inhabitants reacted sharply against the government’s measures:
many Africans spent a great deal of unproductive time hiding from the administration,
while the administration occupied itself, equally unproductively, in trying to find
57 Marguerite Dupire, ‘Planteurs autochtones et étrangers en basse Côte d’Ivoire orientale’, Études
Éburnéennes, 8, 1960, pp. 7–237.
58 A. J, F. Köbben, ‘Le planteur noir’, Études Éburnéennes, 5, 1956, pp. 7–185.
272 Completing the open economy
them. Forced labour was abolished in 1946, and Africans were then able to enter
export production in conditions that were much closer to those which had long per-
tained on the Gold Coast. The results were dramatic. Within a few years the expatriate
planters had almost been eliminated by African competitors; there was a massive
increase in the volume of exports; the Ivory Coast joined Senegal as France’s richest
West African colony.
The production of groundnuts differs from cocoa in several obvious respects.
Groundnuts are found mainly in the savanna; they are an annual crop, yielding
a return in the season in which they are planted; and some varieties are indigen-
ous to West Africa, where they have long been grown as foodstuffs. Yet the
rapid expansion of groundnut exports, no less than the story of cocoa farming, is
worth studying because it, too, raises questions of why and how African farmers
decided to commit themselves to production for an overseas market, and so illu-
minates the process of growth from an indigenous base.
Exports of groundnuts from northern Nigeria were negligible before the First
World War, yet within a few years had become one of Nigeria’s most important
sources of foreign earnings. In 1913, 19,300 tons valued at £175,000 were exported,
and in 1920, after some war-time fluctuations, shipments reached 45,000 tons worth
£1,120,000. By the 1950s Nigeria and Senegal produced between them, and in
roughly equal proportions, over three-quarters of the world’s exports of groundnuts.
An additional amount, equivalent to about half the volume of exports, was produced
for home consumption. In the early 1960s, according to Helleiner’s estimate, as many
as 9 million people were involved in groundnut production in northern Nigeria.59
The initial expansion in northern Nigeria was made possible by the completion of the
Lagos railway, which reached Kano in 1911. Once again, however, it is important to
emphasise that changes within the agricultural sector itself owed little or nothing to
external influences. Indeed, the British spent their time trying to promote cotton
rather than groundnuts. These cotton-growing experiments ran true to West African
form: they failed. In any case, farmers near Kano had already taken up groundnut
farming for export, and for the best of reasons. They found that groundnuts gave
a better return than cotton, which required more labour, took more out of the soil,
and, in the last resort, could not be eaten.
The innovators were a readily identifiable group, not migrant farmers in this
case, but Hausa traders. The Hausa had been involved in long-distance trade
throughout West Africa for several centuries before the advent of colonial
rule.60 They had commercial skill, organisation and capital. They also had an
incentive to develop new activities, for their traditional trades were no longer as
secure or as profitable as they had been: to the north, trans-Saharan commerce
was in decline; in the south the traditional kola routes were shifting to the coast.
59 Gerald K. Helleiner, Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria, Homewood,
1966, p. 107.
60 See above, pp. 103–10.
Completing the open economy 273
A small group of Hausa traders perceived that groundnuts offered a new, and
potentially lucrative, commercial opportunity. They contacted their established
agents and suppliers in the villages around Kano, persuaded farmers to grow
more groundnuts, or to grow them for the first time, offered financial assistance
and gave guarantees regarding the purchase of the harvest. The fact that local
farmers were prepared to trust the Hausa traders and to treat them as opinion
leaders was vital to the success of the enterprise. European advisers, whose
record was in any case rather poor, made far less of an impression. The Hausa
buyers sold the crop to the expatriate firms, which purchased it somewhat reluc-
tantly at first, and then rather more eagerly when it was found that shipments
fetched good prices. It was the sudden rise of the groundnut trade which finally
forced the Niger Company to complete the modernisation of its business—a
very different story from the conventional notion of expatriate firms dragging
Africans into the commercial world of the twentieth century!
The Kano area had long produced grain and cotton for the market, so agri-
culture was far from being stuck in a subsistence groove. Farmers were keen to
develop a profitable export crop in order to pay taxes, to finance their trading
activities in the dry season and generally to expand their purchasing power.
Agriculture in the Kano region was a subtle mixture of shifting and permanent
cultivation, the latter being associated with manuring, water and soil conserva-
tion, and, wherever possible, irrigation. Traditional rules governing the tenure
and use of land did not present an obstacle to capitalist enterprise. Household
farming was organised on an individual as well as on a communal basis, and
measures were taken to ensure that, as far as possible, the products of labour
went to the person concerned and that usufructuary rights could be inherited.
The massive increase in groundnut production was achieved partly by reducing
the amount of land under other foodstuffs and cotton, but mainly by introdu-
cing minor, though highly effective, changes in technique, which made more
efficient use of existing land and labour resources. These changes involved
shorter fallow periods, increased manuring and a greater degree of interplanting.
It was only in the 1920s and 1930s, with the advent of the motor car and better
roads, that expansion took the form of increasing the amount of land and the
number of labourers employed in the industry. Between 1911 and 1937 about
1 million acres around Kano were brought under groundnut cultivation, and
many thousands of migrants from other parts of northern Nigeria came in to
swell the numbers engaged in groundnut production. Despite the simplicity of
the techniques used and the intensity with which the whole area is now farmed,
in the 1960s yields per acre were still among the best in the world.
The case of northern Nigeria is paralleled in certain important respects by the
example of Senegal.61 The main historical difference, as noted in Chapter 4, is that
61 See studies by Fouquet, Jarrett, Pehaut, Pélissier and Pitot noted on pp. 371–74. The role of head
taxes needs further study in this context: future research may reveal contrasts as well as similarities.
274 Completing the open economy
groundnut exports from Senegambia date from the era of legitimate commerce.
The rise of the industry again resulted from the initiative of African farmers at
a time when European interests in the region were centred on other products.
From the 1880s onwards groundnuts expanded on the extensive margin following
the progress of the Senegal railway. By 1908, before exports from Nigeria had even
begun, Senegal was already the world’s leading supplier. In due course, societies
such as the Wolof, the Fulani and the Serer, which had different institutions and
economies, all became involved in groundnut farming. Each adapted successfully by
releasing individual skills and energies, by developing cooperative organisations, and
by modifying traditional agricultural practices, as the Serer, for example, substituted
groundnuts for millet, while at the same time keeping their cattle economy intact.
These societies made use of family labour, but they also showed a willingness to
accept outsiders and adjust to their presence. Immigrant labourers (known as navé-
tanes in Senegal and as ‘strange’ farmers in Gambia) were an important feature of
export production right from the start of the groundnut trade. Sometimes they
simply rented land and farmed it; often they agreed to work for two or three days
a week on their landlord’s farm in return for food, lodging and enough time to
grow groundnuts on their own account.
The new economy even found a new ideology. The Mourides, a Muslim sect
founded in 1886, began to win converts in the groundnut areas of Senegal from the
1890s, notably among the Wolof. An important doctrine of this sect was the belief
that hard physical work in this world was a passport to salvation in the next.62 This
tenet was turned to practical advantage through the establishment of groundnut
farms managed by lay instructors and worked by initiates. When these novices had
demonstrated their mastery of Mouride doctrine, and had also shown themselves to
be proficient farmers, they spread out, set up farms of their own and attracted a new
set of followers. The Mourides, whose adherents numbered about 700,000 in the
1960s, became prominent groundnut producers during the colonial period, and
they also acquired considerable political influence. They provide a good example of
how pre-colonial, Islamic frontiers came into contact with influences from the
Western world, were modified by them, but survived to exert a strong and con-
structive economic influence under colonialism.63 A parallel may be drawn with the
onward march of the Christian frontier in the cocoa regions of the forest zone,
where the religion of the West was also adapted to give effective support to new
economic activities.64
The preceding survey of agricultural developments shows that societies in dif-
ferent parts of West Africa were willing and able to supply innovators, to
62 Abdoulaye Wade, ‘La doctrine économique du, mouridisme’, Annales Africaines, 1967, pp.
175–206.
63 It should be added that in many respects the Mourides have now become a conservative force. For
a recent account see Donal B. Cruise O’Brien, The Mourides of Senegal, Oxford, 1970.
64 J. B. Webster, ‘Agege: Plantations and the African Church, 1901–1920’, Nigerian Institute of Social
and Economic Research, Conference Proceedings, London, 1962, pp. 124–30.
Completing the open economy 275
65 The examples cited should be sufficient to establish these conclusions. For two further, supporting
case studies see Sara S. Berry, ‘Christianity and the Rise of Cocoa Growing in Ibadan and Ondo’,
Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 4, 1968, pp. 439–51, and Raymond Dumett, ‘The Rubber
Trade of the Gold Coast and Asante in the Nineteenth Century: African Innovation and Respon-
siveness’, Journal of African History, 12, 1971, pp. 79–102.
MALI
R.
16°N MAURITANIA 16°N
Se
n
eg
R.
al
Dakar NIGER
N
Mopti
ige
GAMBIA
r
SE Lake Chad
NE
GA Niamey
L
Bamako UPPER
Sokoto
PORT. VOLTA
GUINEA. Ouagadougou Kano
GUINEA
GHANA
Conakry
N Kaduna
ake
IG
E
Freetown Jos
IVORY
RI
Bou
A
TOGO
SIERR LEONE COAST
e
nu
Volt
DAHOMEY
Be
a
LI
BE R .
RI
Monrovia A Kumasi Enugu
Abidjan Co
to
CAMEROUN
go
Accra
n
s
ATLANTIC OCEAN
4°N
La ou
4°N
0 kilometres 400
workers a year between 1905 and 1918, while in the Nigerian tin fields between
1918 and 1939 the labour force ranged from 15,000 men a year to a peak of
40,000. Finally, labour was required by the colonial governments in connection
with various public works, and, to a lesser extent, by the expatriate commercial
firms, principally for handling stocks. Much of this demand was urban based, but
labourers also followed official enterprise outside the towns, notably to build rail-
ways and roads and to carry equipment in the pre-lorry age.
The supply of labour can be considered under four headings, though these by
no means exhaust the subject: population growth; geographical mobility; social
change; and official policy.
In 1910 West Africa’s population was about 36 million. This figure is rather
greater than others which are sometimes quoted, as there are grounds for think-
ing that early estimates were the result of substantial undercounting.66 By 1965
the population had reached roughly 88 million. It seems safe to say that on
a conservative estimate the total population has doubled in about 50 years. In
general terms this rapid increase was the result of a high birth rate coupled with
a falling death rate. However, it is important to note that the rate of increase
was much slower during the early phase of colonial rule than it was in the
period after 1945, because it was only after the Second World War that medical
and sanitary services underwent major improvements, and so began to have
a marked effect on the death rate. Indeed, before 1945 it is likely that the
increase in the mobility of West African peoples may have assisted the spread of
fatal and incapacitating diseases. The conclusion which can be drawn from this
information is that while the growth of population is necessary to an under-
standing of the process of economic change during the colonial period as
a whole, it is far less relevant to an explanation of the early expansion of, for
example, cocoa farming on the Gold Coast or groundnut exports from Nigeria,
for both occurred in a relatively short space of time, and long before the popu-
lation ‘explosion’ had begun.
Much more important in the present context was the increased geographical
mobility of the population. As has been stressed on several occasions already, the
mobility of the labour force was a long-established feature of the West African
economy; it ante-dated the Atlantic slave trade, and its importance grew during
the era of legitimate commerce. In the pre-colonial period there had been
a sizeable movement of manpower northwards as far as the desert oases. In the
twentieth century, by contrast, it is the inhabitants of the Western Sudan who
travel to the coast, and as wage-earners rather than as slaves. Greater mobility
was achieved by the imposition of head taxes (especially in French West Africa),
by the introduction of modern transport, and by the emergence of a free (wage)
labour force. These innovations have sometimes led to the movement of whole
settlements, which have abandoned defensive and often crowded hilltop sites,
and ventured down into the plains.67 They have also brought about an expan-
sion in the number of what might be termed ‘shuttle migrants’, that is men who
leave their homes for a short period to work in agriculture or in the mines,
often travelling great distances to do so.
Migrant labour has frequently been condemned by commentators who have
seen little difference between a shifting and a shiftless labour force. However,
thanks largely to Elliot Berg’s pioneering work, it is now realised that migrant
labour (except, of course, when coerced) can make sense in West African
conditions.68 Demand for labour in agriculture is highly seasonal and is best met
by a temporary increase in the work force. Moreover, the increase can usually
be achieved without disrupting the domestic economy of the migrants.69 For
example, many of the workers on Nigerian cocoa farms come from the north,
where the peak demand for labour occurs at a different time of the year. In sec-
tors such as mining, where migrant labour persists, even though there are no
marked seasonal demands, it is indicative not of backwardness on the part of
Africans in committing themselves fully to wage employment, but of backward-
ness on the part of expatriates in persisting with a low-wage policy. The reasons
for this policy will be considered later on.
The improvement in geographical mobility was closely associated with an
important social change in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries,
namely the decline of internal slavery and the rise of a free (wage) labour force.
This event, which is certain to become one of the central themes in the labour
history of Africa, deserves a great deal more attention from historians than it has
received so far. In the context of the argument advanced in Chapter 4 on
imperialism, the ending of slavery is to be seen as a major feature of the social
revolution which originated early in the nineteenth century, when the new
export economy began to offer wider opportunities to ordinary Africans, free as
well as unfree. Not surprisingly, the unfree were among the last to be allowed
to participate independently in activities which would enable them to assert
themselves against their masters. With regard to the utilisation of labour
resources under colonialism, the significance of the collapse of slavery is not that
the traditional slave labour force was markedly inefficient in performing the
duties allotted to it, but that many of the numerically preponderant farm slaves
67 This movement has been investigated with reference to Nigeria, Togo and Dahomey
by M. B. Gleave in ‘Hill Settlements and their Abandonment in Tropical Africa’, Transactions of the
Institute of British Geographers, 40, 1966, pp. 39–49.
68 See especially ‘The Economics of the Migrant Labour System’, in Urbanisation and Migration in West
Africa, ed. Hilda Kuper, Berkeley, 1965, pp. 160–81. Mention should also be made of Walter
Elkan’s Migrants and Proletarians, London, 1960, a model of careful scholarship which deals princi-
pally with Uganda.
69 For a recent survey of the literature on this question, see Marvin P. Miracle and Sara S. Berry,
‘Migrant Labour and Economic Development’, Oxford Economic Papers, 22, 1970, pp. 86–108.
Completing the open economy 279
were employed outside the expanding export sectors, and were also highly
immobile—for reasons which are obvious enough.
French and British attitudes towards internal slavery are classic illustrations of
the struggle between the normative and the pragmatic that characterised imperial
policy in so many fields. The formal position was quite clear: France and Britain
had made opposition to slavery part of official policy and were committed to its
abolition in all their territories. At the same time, however, both governments
sought for practical reasons to control the pace of emancipation. They did not
wish to risk disrupting export production by provoking sudden social upheaval.
Furthermore, they needed the cooperation of at least some of the indigenous
rulers, and could scarcely demolish one of the bases of their power. They also
faced some very real problems of defining slavery, of identifying slaves and of
enforcing anti-slavery legislation. There was an additional awkward fact: the
colonial powers themselves made use of forced labour in the twentieth century.
Faced with a shortage of unskilled labour, they, like African rulers before them,
had recourse to compulsion. Forced labour was never very widespread in West
Africa as a whole, though it survived in French West Africa until 1946, and it
had some local importance, as, for example, in the European plantations on the
Ivory Coast and in the construction of the Dakar–Bamako railway. Despite
these qualifications, it remains true that the colonial powers regarded slavery as
obstructing their long-term economic interests. Their presence in West Africa
undoubtedly encouraged emancipation, though the practical difficulties which
they encountered meant that slavery was not abolished overnight but tended
instead to wither away.
The main stages of emancipation in West Africa can be outlined quite briefly.
A start was made early in the nineteenth century, but at that time official action
was confined to a few coastal colonies, and consequently did not have any
direct effect on the interior. Freed slaves were enrolled in various apprenticeship
schemes, they were recruited into the armed forces, and the French even experi-
mented with a dubious plan for ‘free’ emigration to North America. The Act of
1833, abolishing slavery throughout the British Empire, did not have much
effect on West Africa. However, when the French parliament passed a similar
measure in 1848, some further steps were taken, especially at Gorée and St
Louis in Senegal, where several thousand slaves were freed and their masters
compensated.70 Nevertheless, no serious attack on internal slavery was made
until the 1880s, and then it came as a by-product of the partition of Africa.
When the Europeans advanced inland, they quickly realised that they had
underestimated the size of the problem of slavery. According to an estimate
made in 1905, there were about 2 million slaves in French West Africa, and it
70 M’baye Guèye, ‘La fin de l’esclavage à Saint Louis et à Gorée en 1848’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 28,
1966, pp. 637–56, and Roger Pasquier, ‘A propos de l’émancipation des esclaves au Sénégal en
1848’, Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 54, 1967, pp. 188–208.
280 Completing the open economy
was reckoned that in the heart of the large Muslim states between a quarter and
a half of the total population was in a state of enslavement. In these circum-
stances hasty and enforced emancipation might have had unwelcome conse-
quences. Indeed, by the start of the twentieth century the exodus of slaves had
deprived the desert oases of the cheap labour they needed to maintain their
complex systems of irrigated agriculture, and so had accelerated the decline of
the already waning trans-Saharan trade.71 Beginning in 1887, the French
attempted to stabilise the situation by establishing a series of villages de liberté,
which had the declared aim of resettling homeless slaves and achieving gradual
emancipation. The reality was rather different.72 The villages, far from develop-
ing into the Freetowns and Librevilles of the interior, acted as disincentives to
emancipation, for their luckless inhabitants became the captifs du commandant, the
unfree labourers and porters of the local administration. The limitations of the
villages were eventually acknowledged by the French government and most of
them were closed between 1907 and 1910. The problem of rootless ex-slaves
was less serious for the British than it was for the French, though after the turn
of the century Lugard did establish a few settlements for freed slaves in northern
Nigeria, including in Bornu one memorial to Victorian principles called Liberty
Village.
Emancipation progressed more quickly after 1900. In 1905, following an inci-
dent in which a well-connected French official in Senegal was shot by an
equally well-connected African who had been accused of slave trading, a decree
was issued authorising stronger action against internal slavery.73 In the period
1905–07 about 300,000 slaves were freed in French West Africa, and substantial
numbers continued to be released in the years which followed.74 The liberators,
judging all slave-holders to be bad, but regarding some as more dangerous than
others, concentrated on areas where unfree labour was thought to underpin the
opposition of indigenous rulers to the French presence. In 1911, to take one
example, about 1,500 slaves were given their freedom after the collapse of the
Fulani revolt in Guinea. The British also tightened up their legislation against
slavery during this period, though without becoming involved in such extensive
military activities. From the 1920s the process of liberation was greatly helped
by the spread of motor vehicles, which released labour previously tied up in the
costly business of moving goods by headloading. By about 1930 emancipation
was well advanced, though instances of slavery and slave trading are still occa-
sionally reported today.
71 J. Aymo, ‘Notes de sociologie et de linguistique sur Ghadames’, Bulletin de Liaison Saharienne, 10,
1959, pp. 129–57.
72 Denise Bouche, Les villages de liberté en Afrique noire, Paris, 1968.
73 M’baye Guèye, ‘L’Affaire Chautemps (avril 1904) et la suppression de l’esclavage de case au Séné-
gal’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 27, 1965, pp. 543–59.
74 J.-L. Boutillier, ‘Les captifs en A.O.F. (1903–1905)’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 30, 1968, pp. 513–35.
Completing the open economy 281
On the whole, the transition from slave to free labour was achieved without
widespread economic and social dislocation. The quiescence of the change has
undoubtedly contributed to the neglect of what was nevertheless an event of
fundamental importance in West African history. To some extent the relative
ease of transition was the product of the delaying tactics adopted by the major
powers. The British, whose policy of indirect rule gave support to indigenous
authorities in certain areas, were more successful in this than the French, whose
military vigour led to the elimination of a number of important African rulers,
and to greater problems of resettlement. To some extent, too, the ease of transi-
tion reflected the fact that many so-called slaves were virtually indistinguishable
from free men and were not interested in supporting sudden social revolution.
Yet neither of these explanations is wholly satisfactory: colonial policy was
unable fully to control events, and slavery, in the sense of well-defined eco-
nomic and social deprivation, was a reality for numerous Africans in many areas.
The explanation advanced here is that the smoothness of the transition was
largely a function of the availability of acceptable alternative opportunities.75
Land suitable for export cultivation was at hand and could be taken up at little
cost save the labour involved in clearing it. By good fortune, much of the crit-
ical period of emancipation coincided with a trading boom after the turn of the
century, which made export production attractive. Moreover, social change, in
this context at least, did not involve widespread occupational mobility. That is
to say, most slaves were farmers, or, if not, they knew how to farm, and they
either remained in or entered the agricultural sector, the main difference being
that now they worked for themselves instead of for an overlord. Problems of
resettlement, it is suggested, arose chiefly in areas where these opportunities did
not exist. This was especially the case in the far-flung and poor French colonies.
As Verdier pointed out in 1964, there are former slaves in Niger who still con-
stitute a servile labour force largely because they have great difficulty in becom-
ing anything else.76 In short, most slaves stayed in agriculture and assisted the
expansion of the colonial economy. Unlike nineteenth-century England, men
were not pushed off the land to make way for a new type of agriculture and to
provide labour for a growing industrial sector. In West Africa there was no land-
less proletariat shifting, as it were, from parish to parish. A permanent urban
labour force was slow to develop, but migrant labour was purposeful and
anchored to the land. No extensive retraining was needed because traditional
techniques and implements remained dominant. There were no machine break-
ers because there were few machines to break.
75 For a similar conclusion in a different context see Benedicte Hjejle, ‘Slavery and Agricultural Bond-
age in South India in the Nineteenth Century’, Scandinavian Economic History Review, 15, 1967, pp.
71–126.
76 R. Verdier, ‘Problèmes fonciers nigeriens’, Penant, 74, 1964, pp. 587–93.
282 Completing the open economy
a great change arose as over 400 of this chief’s slaves, whose average value
at that time was £10 to £12, ran away and never returned. He thus lost at
least £4,000 and is in consequence a poor man now. This speaks for itself
and I think explains the dread with which rich natives in the Interior
view our advance into the country.77
Nevertheless, it would be naive to conclude that all former slave owners were
completely eliminated. Some managed to adapt by becoming rentiers, collecting
dues from ex-slaves in exchange for granting rights of cultivation. Others
acquired the skills needed for survival by going into trade or agriculture, or by
selling their political expertise—if they had any—to the colonial rulers. As
Toupet has shown with reference to Mauritania, the Littama, formerly a tribe of
warriors and slave owners, moved south and became settled cultivators, whereas
the Haratin, a group of freed slaves, did not adapt so well.78 For them, the aban-
donment of the nomadic way of life led to poverty and to the forced sale of
their only asset, their cattle. Assessing the rise and fall of social classes is acknow-
ledged to be one of the most subtle of historical problems; further research will
doubtless show that this is as true of Africa as it is of Europe.
Although the African labour force managed to adapt itself in the ways indi-
cated, there was still a shortage of unskilled labour in the period 1890–1930,
especially in the expatriate sectors. Some perplexed officials advocated importing
‘the industrious Chinaman’ to fill the gap; others preferred Indian labour; while
the real enthusiasts wanted Indian elephants as well! The reasons originally given
by colonial observers for the shortage of labour have led to a number of miscon-
ceptions which, regrettably, can still be found today in some textbook general-
isations about development problems.
Traditional explanations stress factors such as the tenacity of pre-industrial
social systems, the lack of psychological preparedness for modern employment
and the limited wants of the potential labour force. The latter notion has given
rise to the concept of the target worker, that is someone who enters wage
employment with a specific aim in mind—the stock example is to buy a bicycle
—and then leaves for home again. However, despite his desire to own a bicycle,
77 Quoted in A. G. Hopkins, ‘The Lagos Strike of 1897: An Exploration in Nigerian Labour History’,
The Past and Present Society, Corpus Christi College, Oxford. The extract from this article is
reprinted with the permission of the Society from Past and Present, A Journal of Historical Studies, 35,
1966, p. 141.
78 ‘Quelques aspects de la sédentarisation des nomades en Mauritanie sahélienne’, Annales de Géogra-
phie, 73, 1964, pp. 738–45.
Completing the open economy 283
the African labourer, so it has been alleged, was characterised by inefficiency and
by a high rate of absenteeism. This interpretation of the motivation and per-
formance of African workers has had far-reaching practical implications. For
example, it was largely responsible for the persistence of a low wage-rate during
the early phase of colonial rule. According to conventional supply and demand
analysis, employers should have responded to a shortage of labour by raising
wages. But the belief that Africans were target workers was used to justify the
payment of low wages in order to prevent employees from reaching their targets
too quickly. High wages, it was argued, would have diminished the volume of
labour in employment by making targets attainable in a short time. On these
assumptions, the predominance of migrant labour was held to prove that Afri-
cans had cultural and psychological blockages which prevented them from com-
mitting themselves fully to wage employment. Migrant labour was also thought
to be responsible for the low productivity of wage-earners, and so contributed
to the low wages which were paid. Forced labour and the imposition of head
taxes were justified, though never too loudly, on the grounds that by helping to
overcome these blockages they had an educative effect on primitive peoples.
The evidence now available makes it clear that the conventional view,
though it may be relevant in certain cases, can no longer remain the central
explanation of the general shortage of wage labour in West Africa during the
first phase of colonial rule. The point made by Adam Smith with reference to
eighteenth-century England is equally applicable to the African labour force
during the colonial period: ‘Some workmen indeed, when they can earn in four
days what will maintain them through the week will be idle the other three.
This however is by no means the case with the greater part’.79 With regard to
the so-called tenacity of traditional social systems, this book has attempted to
show that to categorise pre-industrial societies in this way is to lose contact with
reality, and that in any case West African peoples were reorganising to meet the
new demands of the Western world in the period of legitimate commerce—
before the advent of colonial rule. The related notions of psychological unpre-
paredness and limited wants founder on the import and export figures, which
show that Africans were eager to expand their purchases of consumer goods,
and that to do so they created a series of export economies in ways which have
already been indicated. Wage-earners responded positively to monetary incen-
tives; the aggregate supply curve of labour did not become regressive at an early
point; and the concept of West Africans as target workers needs to be seriously
modified.80 As to the alleged inefficiency of African labour, this, too, is a subject
where prejudice has long survived unquestioned. By looking at the facts of this
particular matter Peter Kilby has made an unusual and most welcome contribution
79 Quoted in Phyllis Deane, The First Industrial Revolution, Cambridge, 1965, p. 141.
80 Elliot J. Berg, ‘Backward-Sloping Labor Supply Functions in Dual Economies: The Africa Case’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75, 1961, pp. 468–92.
284 Completing the open economy
with constant walking for a twelve month averaging 400 miles a month,
the work this year having been rather harder than usual, a large number of
carriers have been incapacitated from sore feet, the metalling of new roads
making matters worse. In one gang … the majority had their soles almost
completely worn through, to say nothing of cracks.
However, the official mind, though not quite equal to the problem, did not
lack inspiration:
The experiment was then tried of tarring the carriers’ feet. Coal tar is
most suitable. It fills the cracks and is good antiseptic, besides affording
some protection if applied thick. The results have proved quite good and
many carriers are now able to keep to the road who would otherwise
have to lie up.
Fortunately, the introduction of the motor car and the spread of an even older
Western product—boots—quickly consigned this experiment to the locker of
discarded colonial remedies, and so forestalled the rise of a new breed of heavy-
footed porters throughout the tropical colonies.
The second reason for the shortage of labour was simply that the pay offered
was not high enough to tempt the labour force of an underpopulated area into
taking disagreeable jobs, when there were more rewarding alternatives available,
81 ‘African Labour Productivity Reconsidered’, Economic Journal, 71, 1961, pp. 273–91.
82 Quoted in D. K. Greenstreet, ‘The Transport Department: The First Two Decades’, Economic Bul-
letin of Ghana, 10, 1966, p. 42.
Completing the open economy 285
83 H. Myint, The Economics of the Developing Countries, London, 1964; R. Szereszewski, Structural
Changes in the Economy of Ghana, 1891–1911, London, 1965; and Gerald K. Helleiner, Peasant Agri-
culture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria, Homewood, 1966. Myint’s book, which com-
bines brevity, lucidity and originality, must rank as one of the very best of the numerous attempts
which have been made to comprehend the process of economic growth. Szereszewski’s study is full
of bold and stimulating ideas, though it is handicapped somewhat by a theoretical framework
which is too sophisticated for the evidence. Helleiner’s work has set a high standard in relating data
and theory and is indispensable for serious students of African development problems.
286 Completing the open economy
rise in output resulted mainly from increased inputs of land and labour, and
therefore that both factors had been to some extent underemployed previously.
The economics of labour utilisation in this situation require careful consideration.
It is particularly important to distinguish between overpopulated parts of the world,
where underemployment may arise because insufficient land is available to provide
full employment for all members of the household, and underpopulated regions, such
as West Africa, where the agricultural labour force may be underemployed because of
a lack of effective demand for its potential output.84 A certain number of man-hours
was spent unproductively, not through choice, and not as a result of a culturally deter-
mined rejection of profitable opportunities, but because the only alternative was to
produce goods for which there was no market. The increased demand for West Afri-
can exports in the early colonial period altered the traditional relationship between
goods and leisure. In terms of forgone opportunities, leisure became more expensive
because Africans could now choose to improve their material incomes by earning the
cash to buy imported goods. This option was taken up; existing export producers
decided to work harder, and newcomers were attracted to the export sector. The
allocation of labour inputs between various alternatives was determined by the relative
efficiency of these alternatives in purchasing consumer goods, as witness the swing
away from traditional staples in the 1880s, the rubber boom at the turn of the century,
and the preference which farmers in the savanna showed for groundnuts instead of for
cotton. Thus, West Africa had a built-in capacity to increase its production of export-
able commodities, and the main function of expatriate influences was to create the
conditions which gave Africans a better vent for their latent, surplus resources.
Myint has stressed the value of this theory for understanding the speed and rela-
tive ease of ‘peasant’ export development in underpopulated regions such as West
Africa. Four main points emerge from his analysis. First, the expansion of output
was achieved without an agricultural revolution. Productivity per man increased,
but productivity per man hour or per acre remained unchanged. Second, export
production was self-financing in the sense that farmers employed family labour,
used traditional tools and had access to land that was virtually costless. Third, the
risks involved in entering export production were minimised because Africans did
not have to reduce their output of foodstuffs at the same time. This favourable
situation contrasts with certain overpopulated parts of the world, where the
export sector has been slow to develop partly because farmers have had to choose
between these two types of activity and have been understandably reluctant to
place their supply of essential foodstuffs at risk. Fourth, Myint has suggested that
the pattern of export development in underpopulated regions falls into two stages:
the first occurs when farmers take up export production in an unspecialised way
as an adjunct to subsistence farming; the second arises later on, when a certain
84 For a useful summary of the literature on this subject see Charles H. C. Kao, Kurt R. Anschel and
Carl K. Eicher, ‘Disguised Unemployment in Agriculture: A Survey’, in Agriculture in Economic
Development, eds. Carl K. Eicher and Lawrence W. Witt, New York, 1964, pp. 129–44.
Completing the open economy 287
was the reallocation of labour between the sexes, as men gave up their military func-
tions and became more involved in farming, an occupation which traditionally had
been dominated by women in many areas.87 Finally, greater output was sometimes
the result of improved techniques arising out of a reorganisation of farming practices,
as was the case at the start of the Nigerian groundnut industry, when relatively minor
changes produced a substantial increase in productivity.
Modifying the assumptions on which the theory is based also has implications
for its capacity to explain the speed and alleged ease of West African export
growth. It may well be true that most Africans did not have to grapple with the
problems of an agricultural revolution in the conventional sense, but the case of
northern Nigeria shows that there was at least one exception to this rule, and
since research into the agricultural history of West Africa is only just beginning, it
would be unwise at this stage to assume that this particular example is of limited
importance. It is also true that agricultural development was self-financing in the
sense of not requiring expatriate capital, but it is inaccurate to suggest that each
household was capable of entering export production without additional help
from indigenous sources. The examples of cocoa and groundnut farming have
shown that, in the initial stages, group cooperation and financial reserves accumu-
lated from previous economic activities were essential to the success of these ven-
tures. Next, the idea that risks were minimised because of the unspecialised nature
of early exporting activities presupposes a greater degree of homogeneity in the
structure of agricultural production than was actually the case, and it fails to do
justice to the considerable entrepreneurial abilities of the innovators. Those who
started the cocoa industries of the Gold Coast and Nigeria, and the groundnut
industry of northern Nigeria, were heavily committed to export production right
from the outset. For them, novelty and risk were two of the most prominent fea-
tures of these ventures. Finally, Myint’s concept of two stages of peasant export
expansion, though not invalidated, is too schematic, for there were specialised and
unspecialised producers in both phases of development. In the case of West
Africa, it may be more realistic to think in terms of three overlapping stages: the
first in which small groups of innovating entrepreneurs experimented in a fairly
specialised way with a variety of export crops; the second in which their total or
partial success led to widespread imitation by small scale, semi-specialised farmers;
and the third in which rural differentiation encouraged the appearance of a new
and much larger group of specialists.88
Colonial rule did not create modernity out of backwardness by suddenly disrupting
a traditional state of low-level equilibrium. On the contrary, the nature and pace of
economic development in the early colonial period can be understood only when it
is realised that the main function of the new rulers was to give impetus to a process
87 An important general survey of this subject is the study by Ester Boserup, Woman’s Role in Economic
Development, London, 1970.
88 This third stage is considered in Chapter 7, Section 1.
Completing the open economy 289
which was already under way. An economic structure based on ‘peasant’ export pro-
duction and offering the prospect of a mass market had begun to emerge early in
the nineteenth century. Towards the close of the century, however, it became
apparent that this economy could not attain its full potential simply by relying on
the working of the natural laws in which mid-nineteenth century liberals had
placed such faith. Foreign intervention took place to remove constraints which
threatened to make West Africa uncompetitive in world markets, which retarded
the development of expatriate commercial interests, and which inhibited the
growth of indigenous capitalist enterprise. These problems led first to partition, and
then to the colonial solution described in the preceding pages. By creating the con-
ditions which gave Europeans and Africans both the means and the incentive to
expand and diversify legitimate commerce, colonial rule completed the integration
of West Africa into the economy of the industrial world and marked a further stage
in the growth of the market. Important though it was, the expatriate role did not
extend much beyond this general function of connecting West Africa to inter-
national markets. It was Africans who grasped the new opportunities, made the key
entrepreneurial decisions and introduced fundamental changes in the vital agricul-
tural sector. They did so by utilising established and allegedly antiquated economic
and social institutions.
The export economy which had emerged by 1930 came as close to the ideal-type
open economy as West Africa was to reach. Since the foregoing pages have concen-
trated on human agency, especially African agency, in creating this economy, it is
appropriate at this point to recall that the influence of rulers and ruled alike was con-
strained, above all, by the resource base of the region. Factor endowments can
change, but the change is rarely accomplished quickly. West Africa’s comparative
advantage lay in supplying the world market with tropical produce. It was this activity
which offered the region the best prospect of expanding its domestic, as well as its
overseas, market. Colonial rulers did not need to legislate against industrialisation89
because there were already weighty reasons—such as low incomes, poor infrastruc-
ture and lack of capital and skills—why modern manufacturing plant was not estab-
lished in West Africa during the first half of the colonial era. However, the open
economy was not a frozen economy, and after 1930 it underwent important modifi-
cations, as will now be shown.
89 The claim that the pacte colonial operated to prevent industrialisation needs to be reconsidered in the
light of Mark Karp’s article, ‘The Legacy of French Economic Policy in Africa’, in French-Speaking
Africa, ed. William H. Lewis, 1965, pp. 145–53.
7
THE OPEN ECONOMY UNDER
STRAIN
During the inter-war period, the colonial economy was considered as much part
of the natural order as was the House of Lords or the Third Republic. None of
the respected commentators on imperial affairs envisaged or desired any radical
alternative, and it was generally agreed that the colonial export economies
would continue to function in such a way as to bring about prosperity and pro-
gress for all concerned. Similarly, orthodox wisdom held that colonial rule
would endure to a point so remote in time as to defy precise calculation. Inde-
pendence was an event which was an arguable possibility, like the agnostic’s
view of the Day of Judgement, but not one to be prepared for seriously. In
the second half of the colonial period these assumptions about normality were
challenged with a speed and insistence that made even British empiricism seem
a doctrine of inflexibility. During the 1940s and 1950s the open economies of
West Africa underwent important modifications, with the result that by about
1960 few operated in their original, classical form. Moreover, between 1957 and
1965 the whole of colonial West Africa (with one exception) achieved political
independence. The exception was Portuguese Guinea, a tiny possession that
continues, so it is claimed, to move slowly (indeed, virtually imperceptibly)
towards the realisation of the assimilationist ideals which are advertised as the
chief motive for the continued presence of West Africa’s first colonial power.
The purpose of this chapter is to describe and account for the modifications
which were made to the open economies of West Africa during the years
1930–60. More has been written about this phase of African history than about
any preceding period of comparable length. The problem is no longer to secure
enough historical information, as was the case in Chapter 2, but rather to com-
press, without too much distortion, the important specialised work which has
been carried out in recent years, notably by economists and political scientists.
The open economy under strain 291
There is the further complication that some of the major developments of this era
were not peculiar to West Africa, or even to Africa as a whole, but had global
significance. The Second World War, for example, was as important for the
ending of colonialism throughout the world as were the American and French
Revolutions in encouraging the rise of liberal nationalism in Europe during the
nineteenth century. Consequently, any explanation of economic and political
change which focuses solely on relations between Africans and their rulers is
bound to be incomplete. An attempt will be made to take account of extra-
African influences, though restrictions of space will prevent them from being trea-
ted on a scale appropriate to their importance. In spite of these difficulties there is
still room, even within the compass of one brief chapter, for a degree of novelty
both in presentation and in argument, if only for the reason that no general inter-
pretation of this concluding phase of colonial rule has been advanced by an eco-
nomic historian with respect to French and British West Africa.
In essence, it will be argued that modifications were introduced as
a consequence of severe strains experienced by the open economy in
the second half of the colonial era. These strains were of two contrasting
kinds. One was imposed by a long period of hardship between 1930 and
1945, when export expansion was checked and the frontiers of the market
economy contracted. It was at this time that Africans began to demonstrate
their dissatisfaction with the open economy and with the alien rulers who
presided over it. Initially, the response of the colonial powers was slow and
inadequate, but by 1945 Britain and France had acknowledged the need for
changes in official policy. The other was imposed by the expansion of the
open economy after the Second World War, when there was a vigorous
revival of exports and renewed growth in the domestic market. This period
saw not only the implementation of changes made necessary by the pressures
built up between 1930 and 1945, but also a novel development in the cap-
acity of the open economy to generate structural change (albeit on a modest
scale) through the establishment of modern manufacturing activities. African
opposition to colonialism was not dissolved by this economic recovery. On
the contrary, aspirations multiplied and prosperity helped to finance the rise
of political organisations which were to lead eventually to independence.
The simplest way of presenting this argument would be to proceed immedi-
ately to an examination of the two periods of strain noted above. To begin
with, however, it is necessary to give further consideration to occupational roles
in the export sector, and to degrees of specialisation within these roles, to
understand the differential effects of fluctuations in the performance of the open
economy. It is also important to explore developments in domestic exchange
activity, since the West African variant of the open economy grew out of the
indigenous economy and continued to interact with it. These subjects have
been neglected in the past, yet both should be central to the study of African
economic and social history in the twentieth century.
292 The open economy under strain
1 S. Rhodie, ‘The Gold Coast Cocoa Hold-up of 1930–31’, Transactions of the Historical Society of
Ghana, 9, 1968, pp. 105–18.
2 Daryll Forde, ‘The Rural Economies’, in The Native Economies of Nigeria, eds. Daryll Forde and
R. Scott, London, 1946, pp. 86–7.
3 R. Galletti, K. D. S. Baldwin, and I. O. Dina, Nigerian Cocoa Farmers, Oxford, 1956, pp. 149–52.
4 Polly Hill, ‘The Myth of the Amorphous Peasantry: A Northern Nigerian Case Study’, Nigerian Jour-
nal of Economic and Social Studies, 10, 1968, pp. 239–60.
The open economy under strain 293
5 I should like to thank Chief T. A. Doherty for helping me reconstruct the history of his family.
294 The open economy under strain
as a clerk in an African firm in Lagos, and began trading on his own in 1891
with £47 capital. The expansion of colonial rule did not inhibit the growth of
his business, for during the three years 1899–1901 Doherty’s average net receipts
from sales amounted to nearly £50,000 per annum. By 1904 Doherty had estab-
lished branches in Lagos and in the interior, and by 1911 he was referred to as
‘the leading native trader in Lagos in imported textiles’.6 The firm’s growth was
checked in the 1920s, but at his death Doherty was still a very wealthy man.
His son modernised the business by forming a limited liability company in 1930,
and by introducing the structure and style of a department store after
the Second World War. Some of the trading profits were reinvested in the com-
pany: the remainder went, in sizeable sums, into property, education and, inev-
itably, politics. When Chief Doherty’s Rolls-Royce sweeps by, the yellow
dusters wave in acknowledgement of an indigenous commercial success.
Developments affecting the wage labour force are also relevant to the argu-
ment advanced in this chapter. To begin with, the number of Africans in paid
employment underwent a marked increase during the second half of the colonial
period, and especially following the expansion of the economy and administra-
tion after 1945. Occasionally, the growth of employment opportunities occurred
in an almost dramatic way, as in the case of Guinea, where the discovery and
rapid exploitation of minerals in the 1950s created a paid labour force where
previously almost none had existed. By 1960 the wage labour force in West
Africa was estimated, conservatively, to be roughly 2 million strong, though this
was still only about 6 per cent of the total labour force of 33 million.7 In add-
ition, a reserve army of unemployed arose in the towns during and after the
1930s, by which time the acute shortage of unskilled labour had been
overcome.
Various explanations have been advanced to account for this persistent search
for employment in the second half of the colonial period.8 What might be
called, loosely, an anthropological argument suggests that the expedition to
secure work is a modern version of traditional initiation rites, after which the
returning migrant, having overcome a series of hazards, can present himself to
his elders as a fully fledged adult. This view, though not without value, has been
exaggerated in the past, mainly, it seems, because for some time after it became
established no one thought of an alternative. What might be termed, even more
loosely, a psychological explanation holds that Africans continue to be lured to
centres of employment by the promise of bright lights and excitement. Again,
there may be some truth in this interpretation, but as it stands it rests on a naive
assumption regarding the motivation of African migrants. A more recent view,
which has achieved popularity among a number of economists, suggests that the
increase in the number of Africans presenting themselves for paid employment
in the towns was the result of a differential between urban wages and rural
incomes. Belief in the significance of this differential has led some commentators
to refer to African urban employees as an ‘aristocracy’ of labour. It is true that
some highly qualified Africans held well-paid and attractive jobs, but the major-
ity of urban employees were unskilled men who earned relatively low wages.
By the time their higher outgoings (urban rents, food and the maintenance of
incoming relatives) have been taken into account, the net differential, if it
existed, was scarcely sufficient to maintain seigneurial standards of consumption.
An alternative explanation of the growth in the volume of labour on offer
should be based on the following considerations, which are extensions of the
approach adopted in the last chapter.9 Knowledge of employment opportunities
was more widespread after 1930 than before. With the spread of motor vehicles,
the means of reaching the centres of demand were more readily available and
were also cheaper. Improved conditions of work, reflected in a fall in accident
and mortality rates, increased the attractions of certain kinds of employment.10
Family connections and ethnic organisations had been developed to assist new-
comers, and these eliminated some of the problems which had faced the early,
pioneer migrants.11 Finally, the assessment individuals made of their employment
prospects was more optimistic than was warranted by a detached appraisal of the
total employment situation.12 Towns were regarded as places where advance-
ment was possible, and African immigrants were no more deterred by the exist-
ence of widespread unemployment than was that famous English migrant, Dick
Whittington, when he set out to make his fortune in London in the fourteenth
century.13 The ‘aristocratic’ urban employee was important as an ideal rather
than as a reality.
Certain features of this enlarged wage labour force need emphasising. To
begin with, an increasing proportion of wage-earners took permanent jobs in
the second half of the colonial period. Next, a substantial part of the wage
labour force outside agriculture shared a common and readily identifiable
employer, namely the colonial government, while most of the remainder
worked for expatriate commercial and mining firms. Furthermore, employees
in the ‘modern’ sector tended to be located in concentrated settlements.
Indeed, immigration was largely responsible for a remarkable expansion in the
size of West African towns in the second half of the colonial era. Increases of
between three and ten times over a period of 20 to 40 years were common,
as the following examples show: the population of Dakar rose from 94,000 in
1939 to nearly 400,000 in 1960; that of Abidjan from 18,000 to 180,000
during the same period; Freetown grew from 44,000 in 1921 to 128,000 in
1963; and Lagos from 99,000 in 1936 to 675,000 by 1962. Finally, institu-
tions were introduced to help employees cope with their new environmental
and work situations. Africans adapted indigenous associations to deal with
these urban problems, just as they did in agriculture and trade, so there was
no sudden destruction of that once popular textbook figure—tribal man. As
some of the migrants became proletarians, they also adopted modern organisa-
tions, notably trade unions. Modern trade unions existed in West Africa even
before the First World War but were confined to a very small minority of
skilled workers, such as civil servants. During and after the Second World
War, however, came the growth of ‘new unionism’, which began to embrace
the unskilled wage-earners. These unions were urban based; they relied heav-
ily on permanent wage-earners for their membership; and they were particu-
larly strong in the public sector. The part they played during the periods of
strain experienced by the open economy will be considered later in this
chapter.
The foregoing survey of three major occupations is intended in general to
contribute to the writing of indigenous history, and in particular to correct
the conventional portrayal of the role of Africans in the export sector. The
analysis has questioned the belief that Africans (or Chinese for that matter)
can be referred to in aggregate, as if their daily lives approximated closely to
a notional idea of unremarkable and uniform simplicity. In this instance, the
economist’s formal assumption that each factor of production is homogeneous
is seriously at variance with reality. A more complex view, it is suggested, is
more accurate and is of greater value in understanding the final phase of colo-
nial rule. There has been a tendency, for example, to exaggerate the so-called
‘buffer capacity’ of African producers. It is often said that Africans can absorb
the effects of a slump in the export sector because the typical cocoa or
groundnut farmer grows his own foodstuffs as well, the typical trader is also
a farmer and the typical labourer is a migrant who can easily return to the
land. This argument ignores the existence of specialised groups in each cat-
egory, men who could revert to self-sufficiency only by restructuring their
economic activities and by taking a substantial cut in their living standards.
The large farmers, the leading traders and the permanent wage earners stood
to gain most from the expansion of the open economy but were also most at
risk when it entered a stagnant phase. These men, though numerically a small
proportion of the total population, were highly significant in economic and
political terms. Knowledge of the composition of the independence move-
ments, it is suggested, helps to explain the nature of their demands, their rela-
tions with the colonial powers and the character of the new governments
which were established in West Africa after 1957.
The open economy under strain 297
14 A. R. Prest and I. G. Stewart, The National Income of Nigeria, 1950–51, London, 1953, and
P. T Bauer, West African Trade, Cambridge, 1954, Ch. 27.
15 See, for example, Bernard Vinay, L’Afrique commerce avec l’Afrique, Paris, 1968; Alan M. Hay and
Robert H. T. Smith, Interregional Trade and Money Flows in Nigeria, Ibadan, 1970; and Paul Bohan-
nan and George Dalton, eds., Markets in Africa, Evanston, 1962.
298 The open economy under strain
16 Marcel Capet, Traité d’économie tropicale, Paris, 1958, pp. 276–7. This neglected work contains
a great deal of useful information about French West Africa during the period 1945–54.
The open economy under strain 299
increased during the 1950s. This was a special case, brought about partly by the
presence of expatriates and partly by the diversification of tastes among wealthier
Africans, and did not reflect a failure in indigenous production of basic foods.
Novel features of the trade in foodstuffs during the twentieth century are
worth noting for purposes of comparison with the pre-colonial period.
Improved crop storage facilities have tended to reduce seasonal variations in the
market availability of food. This innovation has been influential not only in
enlarging the business of food traders, but also in making possible the mainten-
ance of a permanent labour force outside agriculture. Transport developments,
especially the introduction of motor vehicles, have blurred the distinction drawn
in Chapter 2 between local and long-distance trade. For the first time it has
become profitable to trade staple food crops outside the area of production, as
the case of Accra illustrates.17 In 1957–58 Accra imported 144,000 tons of food-
stuffs (mainly plantains, processed manioc and root manioc) from the interior.
A proportion of this total was supplied by local market gardens, but 55 per cent
was brought from between 50 and 100 miles away, and no less than 30 per cent
came from distances of more than 100 miles, stretching as far as the Northern
Territories. Moreover, since the food trade is highly competitive, each region in
the hinterland has been encouraged to specialise in the production of
a particular type of food for the Accra market. A similar extension of the food
trade can be seen in other parts of West Africa: in the Ivory Coast, for instance,
where the cocoa and coffee farmers in the south imported about 12,000 tons of
rice a year from northern parts of the country in the 1950s; and in Nigeria,
where rice, cowpeas and guinea corn are sent several hundred miles to southern
destinations, and palm oil travels from the forest to the savanna.
The main items of long-distance trade also survived colonial rule, and at least
some grew in volume. As was shown in the last chapter, the movement of
labour increased in the twentieth century following the decline of slavery and
the rise of wage employment opportunities. It is highly probable that the trad-
itional fish trade also expanded. The specialised communities which paid their
taxes in fish on the middle Niger during the sixteenth century now supply
urban centres hundreds of miles away: in 1954, for example, Mopti and Segou
sent 10,000–12,000 tons of dried fish to the Ivory Coast alone.18 Similarly, local
salt from Bilma in Niger continues to have a wide sale in northern Nigeria,
where it is exchanged against grain.19 Certain other minerals, notably gold and
17 H. P. White, ‘Internal Exchange of Staple Foods in the Gold Coast’, Economic Geography, 32, 1956,
pp. 115–25, and Thomas T. Poleman, ‘The Food Economies of Urban Middle Africa: The Case of
Ghana’, Food Research Institute Studies, 2, 1961, pp. 121–74.
18 Jean Tricart, ‘Les échanges entre la zone forestière de Côte d’Ivoire et les savanes soudaniennes’,
Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 9, 1956, p. 219.
19 Capitaine Grandin, ‘Notes sur l’industrie et le commerce du sel au Kawar et en Agram’, Bulletin de
l’IFAN, B, 13, 1951, pp. 488–533; Maurice Fievet, ‘Salt Caravan’, Nigeria Magazine, 41, 1953, pp.
4–20.
300 The open economy under strain
iron, are still produced by traditional means and traded over long distances,
though information about quantities is insufficient to permit comparisons
with the pre-colonial period. There is enough evidence, however, to demon-
strate the impressive development of two of the greatest traditional trades:
kola and livestock.
The western part of the savanna continues to receive its supplies of kola nuts
from the Ivory Coast and, to a lesser extent, from Sierra Leone, as in the pre-
colonial period.20 Exports by land and sea from the Ivory Coast grew from
2,000 or 3,000 tons a year at the beginning of the present century to
28,000–30,000 tons in 1954, by which time kola had become the colony’s most
valuable export after coffee and cocoa. About one-third of this total was des-
tined for consumption in Senegal, where the expansion of groundnut exports
had raised domestic purchasing power. This increased trade, however, no longer
passes along the ancient caravan routes. Most exports now move north by lorry
to Bamako, the capital of Mali, and are then taken by rail to Senegal, while the
remainder are sent by steamer to Dakar. The eastern part of the savanna is sup-
plied by Ghana (formerly the Gold Coast) and by Nigeria.21 Northern Nigeria,
long established as the major market, became even more important during the
colonial period as a result of the development of the groundnut trade. Trad-
itionally, the main channel of distribution for this region was an overland route
from the Gold Coast, which delivered about 500 tons of kola nuts a year in the
late nineteenth century. Two innovations have brought about a fundamental
reorientation of this pre-colonial marketing arrangement. First, in the 1880s
a group of Hausa merchants began to use the regular steamship service to trans-
port kola to Lagos from Accra and Cape Coast. The modernisation of the kola
trade was completed in 1911, when the railway reached Kano; from then on it
was no longer necessary to use porters and pack animals to carry the nuts north
from Lagos. The trade expanded, and in 1924 almost 10,000 tons of kola were
imported into Nigeria by way of the new sea route. Second, during the 1920s
kola trees of the type found in the Gold Coast began to be grown in Nigeria
itself, with the result that domestic production eventually supplanted imports. In
1964 no less than 54,000 tons of kola were sent to northern Nigeria from the
south. However, this Nigerian initiative did not lead to the demise of the Gold
Coast kola industry. Traders in that colony reacted, in characteristic fashion, by
seeking out new markets, and with the aid of the motor lorry they succeeded
in establishing themselves elsewhere, notably in Upper Volta and parts of Mali
and Niger.
20 Jean-Loup Amselle, ‘Les réseaux marchands Kooroko’, African Urban Notes, 5, 1970, pp. 143–58.
21 A. G. Hopkins, An Economic History of Lagos, 1880–1914, University of London Ph.D. thesis,
1964, pp. 407–13, and Paul E. Lovejoy, ‘The Wholesale Kola Trade of Kano’, African Urban Notes,
5, 1970, pp. 129–42.
10°W 0° 10°E
Timbuctu
Podor
St. Louis Nioro Sarafere Gao
Matam Bakel Hombori
Mopti Bandiagara
Kayes Dori
Segou Niamey Katsina Zinder
Kita Djenpe Ouahigouya
Sokoto
San
Bathurst Yako Say
Bamako Jega Maiduguri Dikwa
Kouri Fada Kano
Siguiri Sikasso Ouagadougou N´gouma
Labe Tenkodogo Gaya Potiskum
Boke Kouroussa Bougouni
Navrongo Zaria
Bobo Leo Bussa Bauchi
Mamou Kankan Gambaga Kontagora
Tengrela Dioulasso
10°N Wa
Conakry Kissidougou Djougou Kaiama
Kong Yendi Yola
Beyla Bole N Bida
Touba Kani
Sakhala Kintampo Salaga
Freetown N N Wukari
Bondoukou Abeokuta Lokoja
Abomey Ibadan N
Seguela Kumasi N
Lagos
Cotonou
Porto Novo
Sekondi
N Isolated Occurrences of Cola Nitida
22 For an account of one branch of this trade see Polly Hill, Studies in Rural Capitalism in West Africa,
Cambridge, 1970, pp. 80–140.
23 See Chapter 2, section 2.
24 Albert Feuerwerker, ‘Handicraft and Manufactured Cotton Textiles in China, 1871–1910’, Journal
of Economic History, 30, 1970, pp. 338–78.
Oudeika
Aleg
Mentes Agades
Podor Timbuctu
Nema In-Gall Termit
16°N St. Louis Goundam Gao 16°N
Niatounke Tahoua
Dakar Nioro Mopti Filingue
Nara Nguigmi
Kayes
Dori Goure L. Chad
San Niamey
Kano Nguru
Mali Ouagadougou Sokoto
Ziguinchor Bamako Maiduguri
Bougouni Sikasso Fort
Labe Tenkodogo Nafada
Zaria Lamy
Mamou Bobo Dioulasso Kontagora
Kankan Tengrela Jos
Conakry Bauchi
Jebba
Ferkessedougou Salaga
Freetown Ilorin
Bondoukou Ibadan
Kintampo Lokoja Makurdi
Bouake Abeokuta
Kumasi Lagos Enugu
Railways Monrovia Datoa Porto
Lome Novo
Main Livestock Trade Routes
Accra Cotonou Calabar
Abidjan
0 800 Kilometres Sassandra Takoradi
Port Harcourt 4°N
0 500 statute miles
0 12°E
half of the nineteenth century onwards: by 1962 only about 8 per cent of tex-
tiles intended for consumption in Nigeria were produced by traditional hand-
weavers. However, a substantial proportionate decline is still consistent with an
absolute rise in the volume of traditional production because the market under-
went a massive expansion during the same period. Indeed, the evidence suggests
that some African crafts, having resisted the initial impact of imports delivered to
the interior by rail, received a new lease of life during the latter half of the colo-
nial era.
It is quite clear, for example, that the manufacture and sale of leather goods
increased with the growth of the livestock trade. It is equally certain that the
production of clay pots also survived. One local study has shown that the pot-
tery industry of the Shai people in the southern part of the Gold Coast
expanded during the colonial period, and in the 1960s had an output of about
500,000 pots a year.25 Thus, part of the demand for palm wine and water con-
tainers is still met by domestic products, even though the Gold Coast has long
been one of the greatest importers of European manufactures in West Africa.
Another specialised piece of research has drawn attention to the continuing
dynamism of the traditional cloth industry in Iseyin in western Nigeria.26 It is
known, too, that the production of expensive and weighty Kente cloth still
flourishes in Ghana, for in 1962 output was estimated to be about 2 million
square yards, or almost 900 tons.27 These two cases are not isolated exceptions.
Even as late as 1964, when modern textile factories had been established in
West Africa, traditional hand-weavers using hand-spun yarn produced about
9,000 tons of textiles, which was roughly a third of total domestic output. The
main areas of production in that year were Nigeria, Mali, Upper Volta, Ghana,
the Ivory Coast and Senegal. Again, it is striking that the regions where trad-
itional manufactures continue to thrive include countries which are also the lar-
gest importers of consumer goods. Finally, it is worth noting that the growth
and diversification of the open economy have encouraged the rise of new types
of ‘cottage’ industry, such as bicycle repairing, which have helped to offset losses
suffered by those crafts that were affected by European competition.
The reasons for the survival of traditional manufactures in the twentieth cen-
tury can be summarised as follows. Certain products are protected by proximity
to the market and by low overheads at the manufacturing stage. This is particu-
larly true of hollow-ware, such as pots, which are costly to transport over long
distances and are produced in West Africa mainly by cheap family labour. Some
products continue to sell, even though they compete directly with cheaper
25 A. K. Quarcoo and Marion Johnson, ‘Shai Pots’, Baessler-Archiv, 16, 1968, pp. 47–88.
26 Jennifer M. Bray, ‘The Craft Structure of a Traditional Yoruba Town’, Transactions of the Institute of
British Geographers, 46, 1969, pp. 179–93, and ‘The Economics of Traditional Cloth Production in
Iseyin, Nigeria’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 17, 1969, pp. 540–51.
27 United Nations, ‘The Textile Industry in the West African Sub-region’, Economic Bulletin for Africa,
7, 1968, pp. 103–25.
The open economy under strain 305
European imports, because they are highly regarded by consumers. Local salt
remains in demand because its taste is preferred and because it is thought to
enhance virility. Similarly, local ironware is held to be stronger and more dur-
able than imported substitutes. It is easy to deride these beliefs as examples of
the ‘primitive’ nature of consumer behaviour in the underdeveloped world.
However, it is as well to remember that the agents of what is, technically, the
modern world also sell their products—from beer to cars—by appealing to
human ambitions and weaknesses. It would be fairer to say that modern adver-
tising has failed to dissolve established brand loyalties. Traditional crafts also sur-
vived because they were able to secure a niche as special lines in a differentiated
product market. Consumers bought imported and domestic textiles because
there were hundreds of varieties of cloth, and not all served the same purpose or
suited the same tastes. Indeed, as the colonial period advanced, traditional tex-
tiles became increasingly fashionable as an index of status and as a symbol of
identification with African culture and with the nationalist movement.28 Some
crafts survived by employing new techniques. Thus, the use of sewing machines
enabled tailors to cut production costs and increase their output.
By far the greater part of domestic trade remained in the hands of Africans
themselves. The success of local traders in expanding and redirecting internal
trade in the twentieth century is a feat which has not been fully acknowledged,
yet one which merits comparison with the more publicised achievements of
Africans in export production. Just as indigenous, and allegedly antiquated, insti-
tutions proved their dynamism in agriculture, so too the pre-colonial distributive
system fostered the growth of trade in the twentieth century. All the main fea-
tures of commercial organisation discussed in Chapter 2, such as rotating mar-
kets, landlords, brokers, credit and the family firm, survived. It was the attributes
of the family firm, particularly its flexible size, low overheads, familiarity with
local conditions, reserves of skill, goodwill and capital, and wide geographical
coverage, that made expansion possible. On the whole, the economic unity of
areas which had been linked by market transactions in the pre-colonial period
was not severed by European rule. Under the French and British, as in the time
of Mansa Musa, long-distance trade continued to span political divisions. Ironic-
ally, it was the achievement of political independence which led to the erection
of barriers to the internal flow of goods and services, the claims of territorial
sovereignty proving in this instance more than a match for the ideals of pan-
Africanism.
Continuity with the past is exemplified by the way in which the Hausa and
Dioula, the great long-distance traders of the pre-colonial period, managed to
perpetuate their dominance in the twentieth century. Admittedly, their success
28 In England the traditional crafts of saddlers and thatchers have experienced a revival since
the Second World War as a result of the increasing affluence and changing aspirations of new social
classes.
306 The open economy under strain
36 On this lagged response, see Robert M. Stern, ‘The Determinants of Cocoa Supply in West
Africa’, in African Primary Products and International Trade, eds. I. G. Stewart and H. W. Ord, Edin-
burgh, 1965, pp. 65–82.
The open economy under strain 309
high produce prices) but was squeezed out of the economy by an adverse move-
ment in the terms of trade.
At particularly critical times farmers demonstrated their dissatisfaction with the
state of the economy in more militant ways, principally by withholding supplies
in the hope of forcing buyers to offer increased prices. This was a well-
established technique, and one which had given expression to African resent-
ment, frustration and despair during periods of unsatisfactory trade in the nine-
teenth century. A number of protests of this kind took place in the years
between the two World Wars, the best known being the three main cocoa
hold-ups on the Gold Coast. The first was in 1921, when the post-war boom in
cocoa prices suddenly came to an end;37 the second occurred in 1930–31 fol-
lowing the onset of the world slump;38 the third, which also involved Nigeria,
took place in 1937 and was a reaction to a further downturn in the terms of
trade and to a market-sharing agreement made by the European buying firms.39
These rural ‘strikes’ were led by substantial, specialised farmers, men whose
‘buffer capacity’ was limited and who strove to persuade the small farmers (who
had less to lose) to present a united front against the buying firms. The hold-ups
failed, but in failing worsened Afro-European relations, and in particular
increased the hostility of the larger farmers towards the expatriate firms and
towards the expatriate government, which was regarded as supporting the exist-
ing marketing system.
The decline in the producers’ terms of trade also affected traders. Business
became less profitable, but few traders were able to introduce compensating
reductions in operating costs because their overheads were already very low.
They, too, expressed their opposition by demonstrations against measures which
weighed on them particularly heavily, such as increased taxation and the issue of
trading licences during the Second World War. Usually, however, their protests
were small scale, spontaneous and of short duration. With the possible exception
of the women’s riots in eastern Nigeria in 1929, in which commercial interests
played a prominent part, none of the traders’ demonstrations had the impact of
the hold-ups organised by the farmers. Nevertheless, a group of merchants in
Nigeria and the Gold Coast did initiate one important and constructive move,
and this is worth mentioning as evidence of the reactions of ‘Westernised’ Afri-
can businessmen to the problems of the inter-war period.
At the beginning of the twentieth century the common assumption among
the educated, and the predominantly Christian, merchants in the large coastal
entrepôts was that the implementation of colonial notions of partnership and
assimilation would present them with more opportunities for advancement than
37 David Kimble, A Political History of Ghana, 1850–1928, Oxford, 1963, pp. 49–51.
38 S. Rhodie, ‘The Gold Coast Cocoa Hold-up of 1930–31’, Transactions of the Historical Society of
Ghana, 9, 1968, pp. 105–18.
39 Josephine Milburn, ‘The 1938 Gold Coast Cocoa Crisis: British Business and the Colonial Office’,
African Historical Studies, 3, 1970, pp. 57–74.
310 The open economy under strain
they had enjoyed previously. The reality was rather different. By about the time
of the post-war slump of 1921, it was clear that African import and export mer-
chants had suffered a serious decline relative to their European rivals. Some Afri-
cans dropped out of the direct import and export business. Those who remained
recognised that it was necessary to adopt Western business institutions if they
were to remain in what they termed ‘the commercial race’. In the 1920s and
1930s African merchants tried to establish limited liability companies and
modern banking institutions of their own in an attempt to find ways of compet-
ing with the massive expatriate combines, which were themselves products of the
new and more competitive commercial environment of the twentieth century. Per-
haps the best examples of the commercial ambitions of the time were the spectacu-
lar ventures mounted by the Gold Coast businessman, Tete-Ansa, who became
known, momentarily, as the ‘Napoleon’ of West African commerce.40 Between
1925 and 1935, Tete-Ansa founded producers’ cooperatives in Nigeria and the
Gold Coast in an attempt to strengthen the bargaining position of farmers and
lower their costs; he formed the Industrial and Commercial Bank in Nigeria, which
was intended to finance African participation in external trade; he set up an agency
in New York to sell produce and to buy imports for shipment to West Africa. The
scheme was a radical one, but the aims behind it were moderate enough. Tete-Ansa
and his backers were seeking a better place for Africans (especially educated Afri-
cans) within the colonial system, but they were not asking for total African control
of the economy, still less for political independence. Tete-Ansa’s plans were unsuc-
cessful, but the Waterloo of this Napoleon had its significance. The liquidation of
Tete-Ansa’s companies and his own self-imposed exile in Canada symbolised the
failure of his brand of moderate leadership and reformist proposals. By the late
1930s Africans were beginning to undertake a more fundamental re-appraisal of
their predicament.
As members of the coastal elite, African merchants suffered social humiliation as
well as economic defeat. Educated, Christian Africans found themselves treated
with less consideration after the expansion of colonial rule than they had been in
the nineteenth century. Since their aspirations and life-styles were linked more
closely to those of the European community than was the case with most African
colonial subjects, they were especially sensitive to social rebuffs stemming from
racial prejudice. They were excluded from a number of commercial organisations
and social clubs, some of which had begun on a multiracial basis. Even cricket, that
most imperial of games, failed to act as an integrative force. As early as 1898, one
British governor on the West Coast ordered two cricket pitches to be laid, ‘one for
the Europeans the other for the natives’.41 Matches played between the two teams
became tests of the capacity of the races, a practical application of Carlyle’s bizarre
40 A. G. Hopkins, ‘Economic Aspects of Political Movements in Nigeria and in the Gold Coast,
1918–1939’, Journal of African History, 7, 1966, pp. 133–52.
41 C.O. 147/116, McCallum to Chamberlain, 31 August 1897, Public Record Office.
The open economy under strain 311
theories, though when the African side hit a winning streak the series was discon-
tinued! The French, lacking cricket, but possessing an alternative and more explicit
instrument in their policy of assimilation, were equally unsuccessful. In practice
very few Africans became ‘Frenchmen’. Fewer still wished to do so after 1940,
when the attractions of becoming citizens of a defeated nation and a declining
imperial power were scarcely compelling. By contrast, a number of Frenchmen
‘went native’, took African wives and settled in Africa. This was assimilation in
reverse, and it was severely frowned on because it was regarded as diluting the phys-
ical and moral strength of the ‘superior’ race. Thus, the period 1930–45 saw the
further alienation of an elite of articulate and influential Africans, men who had
hoped for a partnership under colonial rule, but who discovered that there was no
way of ‘playing the white man’ and winning.
Evidence concerning the fortunes of African wage-earners relates mainly to
employees in the so-called modern sector, and even that is incomplete at present.
Nevertheless, it seems certain that urban employees suffered a serious fall in their
living standards during the period 1930–45.42 Some wage-earners were thrown
out of work as expatriate firms and government departments reduced the size of
their labour force. Others experienced a cut in their rates of pay: the average
weekly wage of unskilled workers in the Nigerian tin mines, for example, fell
from between 6s and 7s a week in 1928 to 3s 6d in 1937. However, most wage-
earners remained in employment and were affected not by a downward pressure
on money wages but by un upward movement of costs as imported goods, urban
rents and some foodstuffs became more expensive, especially during the Second
World War. The money wages of the majority of urban employees remained sta-
tionary for a period of about 50 years: from the 1890s down to about 1940 the
ruling rate for unskilled workers in the main urban centres of British West Africa
was between 9d and 1s a day. During the Second World War this stability was
broken, and some wage increases were granted. However, the increments tended
to lag behind the rise in prices, and in any case were inadequate to compensate for
them. Consequently, real incomes fell.
Africans reacted forcefully to this erosion of their living standards. Urban pro-
tests, ranging from organised strikes to spontaneous demonstrations and riots,
became increasingly frequent. Public employees, especially railway workers,
were the pacesetters in forming unions and promoting militant action. The his-
tory of strike action in West Africa goes back to the nineteenth century, but
widespread labour protests in the region as a whole date from the First World
War. Thereafter strikes became a fairly common way of expressing grievances
and reached a peak (in terms of frequency and lost working days) during
the Second World War. The following are among the most prominent examples
of urban protests between 1918 and 1945, though only a few of these have
42 Elliot J. Berg, ‘Real Income Trends in West Africa, 1939–1960’, in Economic Transition in Africa,
eds. Melville J. Herskovits and Mitchell Harwitz, London, 1964, pp. 199–238.
312 The open economy under strain
been studied in detail. In French West Africa there was a strike of dock workers
at Conakry in 1919; serious riots in Porto Novo in 1923;43 a strike of railway
workers on the Dakar–Niger line in 1925; disturbances at Lome in 1933;
another railway workers’ strike (at Thiès) in 1938, resulting in military interven-
tion, six deaths and a further 30 men wounded; and a series of protests against
the use and abuse of compulsory labour in Senegal and the Ivory Coast during
the Second World War. In British West Africa there were serious strikes and
demonstrations in all four colonies. In the Gambia there were strikes in 1921
and 1929.44 In Sierra Leone the railway workers came out in 1919, 1920 and
1926; the miners struck in 1935 and 1937; a wide range of employees in the
public and private sectors stopped work in 1938–39; and a peak of 13 serious
stoppages was recorded in 1942.45 The Gold Coast experienced a strike of
public employees in 1919 and 1921; strikes in the gold mines in 1924 and 1930;
a series of stoppages among railway workers, miners and Public Works Depart-
ment employees in the late 1930s, of which the most important was the railway-
men’s strike of 1939; and ten major strikes in 1942. Nigeria had a strike of
railway workers in 1920; disturbances in Benin in 1937–39;46 mass protests by
the railway workers, led by Michael Imoudu, in 1941–42; and a successful gen-
eral strike in 1945, which involved 17 unions representing about 30,000
employees, and lasted for 37 days.
It is appropriate at this point to consider expatriate economic policy during
the period 1930–45. It will be contended that the nature of the problems
demanding attention and the limitations on the range of possible solutions were
determined by the adverse economic circumstances of the period rather than by
any grand, independent conception of the imperial mission in the tropics.
A complementary argument will show that the policies adopted by private
enterprise and by the public authorities not only failed to make any impression
on the economic problems facing West Africa, but also heightened the tension
existing between colonial subjects and their rulers.
The main aim of the expatriate firms during this period was self-preservation.
Mining and trading companies in Africa did not achieve immunity from the
world slump or from the conflict of 1939–45 merely because they happened to
be foreign. The white man’s business magic (double-entry bookkeeping and the
limited liability company) proved insufficient to ward off the effects of these
43 John A. Ballard, ‘The Porto Novo Incidents of 1923: Politics in the Colonial Era’, Odu, 2, 1965,
pp. 52–75.
44 Christopher Allen, ‘African Trade Unionism in Microcosm: The Gambia Labour Movement,
1939–67’, in African Perspectives, eds. C. H. Allen and R. S. Johnson, Cambridge, 1970, PP.
393–426.
45 H. E. Conway, ‘Labour Protest Activity in Sierra Leone During the Early Part of the Twentieth
Century’, Labour History, 15, 1968, pp. 49–63.
46 Philip A. Igbafe, ‘The Benin Water Rate Agitation, 1937–39: An Example of Social Conflict’, Jour-
nal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 4, 1968, pp. 355–75.
The open economy under strain 313
two great crises, and many firms went into liquidation. Mars calculated that 197
expatriate commercial companies existed in Nigeria at one time or another
between 1921 and 1936, but that only 14 of these enjoyed an unbroken exist-
ence as independent firms.47 The majority of the remainder either went out of
business or were taken over by more substantial rivals, thus completing a process
of amalgamation begun in similar circumstances at the close of the nineteenth
century. The most spectacular failure occurred in 1931, with the collapse of
Lord Kylsant’s shipping empire, which included the main British steamship com-
panies serving West Africa.48 Almost as serious were the insolvencies of the
Banque Commerciale Africaine and the Banque Française de l’Afrique in the
same year. The former concern was rescued by the Banque de l’Afrique Occi-
dentale, but the latter went into liquidation. Clearly, it was not only African
banks and mercantile firms that ran into difficulties at this time.
The surviving firms adopted two main defensive tactics. To begin with, they
decided to close many of their retail outlets and up-country branches in order to
economise on overheads. In 1929, for example, the newly formed United Africa
Company possessed about 80 out-stations in the Kano area alone; by the close
of the 1930s the number had been reduced to 25. A similar policy of retrench-
ment was pursued by Peyrissac in Senegal and by the Société Commerciale de
l’Ouest Africain throughout French West Africa. Next, the large firms divided
the import and export trade on an agreed basis with the aim of restraining com-
petition and limiting risks. During the First World War a few substantial, mainly
British, companies formed the Association of West African Merchants (A.W.
A.M.), which was designed to represent their interests in official quarters and to
coordinate policy in the private sector. The import trade was divided among the
leading companies by the Staple Lines Agreement (1934) and by a more com-
prehensive Merchandise Agreement, which replaced it in 1937 and survived
until shortly after the end of the Second World War. Market-sharing arrange-
ments were made in the produce trade, too, through the formation of ‘pools’, in
which member firms aggregated their individual purchases and then divided
them according to previously agreed proportions. Some mining interests oper-
ated much the same system on an international scale: Nigerian tin output, for
instance, was controlled by the terms of the International Tin Agreement
between 1931 and 1946. Measures to restrain competition reached their high
point during the Second World War, when the large expatriate firms became
the main agents of the official Marketing Boards and also received preferential
treatment in the issue of import licences and shipping quotas.
47 J. Mars, ‘Extra-Territorial Enterprises’, in Mining, Commerce and Finance in Nigeria, ed. Margery
Perham, London, 1948, p. 52.
48 P. N. Davies, ‘The African Steam Ship Company’, in Liverpool and Merseyside, ed. J. R. Harris,
London, 1969, pp. 231–4.
314 The open economy under strain
The policy of ‘safety first’ enabled most of the leading expatriate firms to
keep afloat. However, survival was bought at a price. In pursuing what they
regarded as their legitimate business interests, the expatriate companies helped to
foster African discontent. By failing to diversify, and by reducing their existing
commitments, the main agents of capitalist enterprise in the colonies acknow-
ledged their inability to initiate a move from slump to boom conditions. Dis-
investment, though understandable, simply depressed the economy further and
was regarded by Africans as an indictment of foreign private enterprise in the
empire. Moreover, widespread and hostile publicity, which appeared whenever
‘secret’ trade agreements were concluded, ensured that African dissatisfaction
was directed firmly towards the expatriate firms concerned. The standing of the
authorities also suffered: it was hard to see how the doctrine of trusteeship was
being applied impartially when governments gave protection to those most
fitted to stand on their own feet, while allowing African businessmen, such as
Tete-Ansa, to remain exposed to the full rigour of market forces.
A study of government policy between 1930 and 1945 reveals that the colonial
authorities, far from imposing themselves on events, as the Annual Reports contrived
to suggest, were engaged in the less-majestic task of coping with developments
which they had not initiated, which they understood imperfectly, and which threat-
ened to undermine their position in Africa. Although the colonial powers made
some attempt to influence the performance of the export sector, the colonial econ-
omies remained dependent on export crops and prices set externally. Nevertheless,
by applying tariffs to limit the scope of the open economy and adopting other inter-
ventionist measures, government policy unwittingly pointed towards a future that
was to materialise after the Second World War. The official record during this
period can be considered under four headings: capital investment and economic
planning; agriculture; manufacturing; and overseas trade.
The depressed state of trade affected the colonial governments directly because
of the close connection between public revenue and customs receipts. In French
West Africa the Federation’s income from customs duties dropped by
47 per cent between 1930 and 1931. Elsewhere the fall, though not so dramatic,
was still serious. The case of Sierra Leone, where customs receipts declined by
about a third between 1928 and 1934, was typical of the British colonies.49 At
the same time, fixed outgoings (chiefly salaries, pensions and repayments on
loans) were very much greater than they had been earlier in the century. Conse-
quently, the colonies entered a phase of budgetary crisis. The authorities reacted
to this unwelcome situation in three ways. First, they increased customs duties
in a bid to maintain total revenue at its customary level. This tactic was unsuc-
cessful, and its main result was to increase the prices Africans paid for imported
goods. Second, they pursued a policy of retrenchment, the orthodox response of
49 One of the few detailed studies of public finance during this period is to be found in N. A. Cox-
George, Finance and Development in West Africa: The Sierra Leone Experience, London, 1961, Ch. 13.
The open economy under strain 315
the time, and one which was also adopted in Europe. Retrenchment involved
drastic reductions in expenditure on public works together with staffing econ-
omies, such as early retirement in the case of European officials and loss of work
in the case of unskilled African labourers. Expenditure on new public works in
both French and British colonies did not regain the levels of the 1920s until the
close of the 1930s, by which time military considerations were beginning to
influence the direction as well as the size of additional investment. Third, public
money in the form of grants and loans was made available by the metropolitan
governments to help the colonies through their financial difficulties. This policy
marked a further departure, albeit an enforced one, from the prevailing doctrine
of colonial self-sufficiency; it implied acceptance of a more active government
role in the economy; more specifically, it represented an advance from the
endeavours of Chamberlain, Guggisberg and Sarraut in the direction of eco-
nomic planning. Yet these were tentative beginnings. There was no sharp break
with the past; loans remained more important than grants; the sums advanced
were relatively modest; and the results were far from dramatic, as the following
examples show.
In France, the Great Colonial Loan was authorised in 1931, and its expend-
iture tied initially to the Maginot Plan, which was promulgated in the
same year. The greatness of this loan owed more to the interest rates charged
than to the generosity of the sums advanced, for by 1939 only about £7 million
(less than half the amount authorised) had been spent in French West Africa.
This sum, which was roughly the same as was expended in public works from
the Federation’s own resources in the 1920s, was invested mainly in transport
improvements and in the ill-fated Niger agricultural scheme. The Maginot Plan
itself was as ineffective in developing the Empire as was that unfortunate minis-
ter’s more notorious Line in repelling German troops in 1940. A further eco-
nomic plan for the colonies, drawn up by the Popular Front government in
1936, was buried as speedily as was its sponsor. Britain’s approach to the finan-
cial problems of the colonies was symbolised by the Colonial Development Act
of 1929. The Act was designed as much to reduce unemployment in the United
Kingdom (by stimulating exports) as to help the colonies.50 About £6,500,000
was advanced under the terms of the Act down to 1939. A substantial propor-
tion of this total was in the form of grants to assist insolvent colonies balance
their budgets; the remainder took the form of loans, on which interest was pay-
able. A great deal of the expenditure went on projects such as the provision of
mining equipment, which mainly benefited industrialists in the United King-
dom, at least in the initial stages. British West Africa’s share of funds amounted
to only £500,000, and the largest single sum (about £250,000) went to support
the activities of the Sierra Leone Development Company (D.E.L.C.O.), an
50 George C. Abbott, ‘A Re-examination of the 1929 Colonial Development Act’, Economic History
Review, 24, 1971, pp. 68–81.
316 The open economy under strain
expatriate firm formed in 1930 to exploit the iron ore resources of the colony.
The investment proved successful, and from the 1930s Sierra Leone’s economy
of ‘legitimate’ commerce, inherited from the nineteenth century, at last began to
change. The shortcomings of the 1929 Act were recognised in the Colonial
Development and Welfare Act of 1940, which aimed at giving the colonies
more comprehensive and more generous assistance. However, this Act achieved
few immediate results because war-time needs caused a diversion of funds and
led to a shortage of skilled administrators.
The limited influence of the colonial governments is further illustrated by
their endeavours in the huge agricultural sector. This is not to deny that
a measure of success was attained by a number of dedicated officials, men who
really did ‘serve’ in the Empire. One of the most notable achievements was the
elimination of rinderpest, which spread into Africa in the 1890s and decimated
herds in many parts of the continent before being brought under control in the
1920s and 1930s. On the whole, however, the efforts of officials were seriously
hampered by shortage of money, lack of knowledge of tropical agriculture and
by the long-term nature of research in this field, which meant that many of the
experiments undertaken in the 1930s did not begin to yield results until after
the Second World War.51 At a time when Africans were looking for cost-
reducing innovations and alternative exports, government policy was memorable
chiefly for its failures, some of which were spectacular.
Between 1930 and 1934 the French established Sociétés Indigènes de Prévoy-
ance (S.I.P.) throughout their West African colonies. These organisations, which
originated in Senegal in 1909, were supposed to improve agricultural methods,
organise the storage of food crops and provide credit for farmers. In practice the
S.I.P. became officially sponsored tax-gathering agencies and were also used as
a means of political control. Compulsory cooperatives were a contradiction, and
it is not surprising that they won little local support.52 The next failure was the
attempt to create, in Governor Carde’s phrase, ‘an island of prosperity’ in the
interior of French West Africa. The original plan, put forward in 1919 and
backed by French textile manufacturers, was to use the Niger to irrigate land for
the production of cotton in Soudan. Preliminary work started in 1924, and in
1931 the scheme was incorporated in the Maginot Plan, which made provision
for the cultivation of rice as well as of cotton. The Office du Niger was created
in the following year to carry out the project. The officials of this new institu-
tion certainly did not lack imagination. Their aim was to irrigate nearly
51 W. K. Hancock, Survey of British Commonwealth Affairs, 1918–1939, II, part 2, London, 1942, pp.
326–69; R. H. Green and S. H. Hymer, ‘Cocoa in the Gold Coast: A Study in the Relations
Between African Farmers and Agricultural Experts’, Journal of Economic History, 26, 1966, pp.
299–319; A. Pitot, ‘L’homme et les sols dans les steppes et savannes de l’A.O.F.’, Cahiers d’Outre-
Mer, 5, 1952, pp. 215–40.
52 J. Suret-Canale, Afrique noire occidentale et centrale: L’ère coloniale 1900–1943, Paris, 1964, pp.
299–310.
The open economy under strain 317
2 million acres and to settle 1.5 million African colonists in the area. Unfortu-
nately, the technical expertise of the administrators did not match their breadth
of vision. By 1937, the Niger scheme had cost over £1 million; by 1940 there
were about 12,000 settlers on three sites which were more like refugee camps
than model villages; and by 1953 only about 62,000 acres had been irrigated. In
1929 the British administration also began to introduce cooperatives. These
were planned on a more modest scale than in French West Africa, but the
results were equally disappointing.53 The failure to invest sufficient money in
agricultural research was exposed in a dramatic way by the outbreak of a disease
known as swollen shoot, which began to attack cocoa trees on the Gold Coast
in the late 1930s. The only remedy that could be devised was the drastic one of
cutting down infected trees. This solution, however necessary, was scarcely cal-
culated to improve relations between farmers and officials, especially at a time
when the export trade was seriously depressed.
The subject of industrialisation is introduced at this point solely with reference
to the present argument, and will be accorded more general treatment in the
next section of this chapter.54 The history of modern manufacturing in West
Africa dates from the First World War, though down to 1945 progress was very
slow and was confined to a few centres and to a narrow range of products.
Constraints on industrial development were not determined simply by colonial
policy, as is sometimes suggested. Nevertheless, the conservatism of the expatri-
ate firms, combined with the indifference of the colonial authorities, meant that
opportunities which did exist were not exploited fully. It seems fair to suggest
that before 1945 industrial enterprise in West Africa sprang neither from official
plans to develop the colonies, nor from market growth in the region itself, but
from a need to support the Allied cause during two World Wars.
During these periods of emergency, the colonial powers were concerned to
secure tropical raw materials while at the same time economising on scarce ship-
ping space. Hence the main form of industrial activity, and one which usually
involved government participation or encouragement, was export processing.
Perhaps the best example is the groundnut crushing industry of Senegal.55 The
industry began during the First World War, but afterwards experienced some
difficulty in making progress, and in the 1920s most of its output was consumed
locally. However, in 1933 vegetable oils from the French colonies were given
preference in the metropolitan market, and in 1936 groundnut oil began to be
shipped from Senegal. Small though the industry was, it ran into opposition
from processing firms in Marseilles, and a limit was placed on the volume of
refined oil shipped to France from West Africa. With the outbreak of
53 J. C. de Graft-Johnson, African Experiment: Co-operative Agriculture and Banking in British West Africa,
London, 1958, Chs 4–7.
54 It is hoped that the comments in this and the following paragraph will stimulate further research
into the early phase of industrialisation in West Africa.
55 J. Suret-Canale, ‘L’industrie des oléagineux en A.O.F.’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 3, 1950, pp. 280–8.
318 The open economy under strain
the Second World War the needs of France became more pressing than those of
Marseilles; additional mills were set up in Soudan, Upper Volta and Niger in
1941–42, and exports of groundnut oil increased from less than 6,000 tons
a year to a peak of 31,000 tons in 1945. Other export-processing industries
which expanded in West Africa as a result of war-time needs were saw-milling,
palm-oil bulking, cotton-ginning and fishcanning. The conditions of siege
which prevailed during the two World Wars also stimulated the development of
import-substituting industries. These were attempts to achieve self-sufficiency in
essential items, such as cement and other building materials, and to maintain the
flow of exports by supplying scarce consumer manufactures, such as household
goods, cigarettes and processed foodstuffs, notably sugar. When these local
industries proved unable to compensate for war-time deficiencies, the Allies
made use of forced labour in export production. The establishment of modern
industries failed to mitigate the hardship suffered by indigenous interest groups
between 1930 and 1945, but it did demonstrate that manufacturing plant could
operate in tropical Africa. This was a lesson which African leaders were to use
against their mentors after 1945.
Discussions of government intervention in overseas trade between 1930 and
1945 usually concentrate on the Marketing Boards established in British West
Africa during the Second World War. There are grounds for thinking that this
bias has led to the neglect of issues which are relevant not only to an appreci-
ation of the historical context in which the Boards were conceived and estab-
lished, but also to an understanding of changes in the role of government in the
economy during this period. It will be suggested here that the Marketing Boards
were just one feature of a search for security which was the prime concern of
the two major colonial powers in the years between the onset of the world
slump and the end of the Second World War. It will be shown that the Boards
were part of a package of measures, including tariff changes, which were
designed to influence the performance of the economy after 1930; that plans for
Marketing Boards ante-date the Nowell Commission, whose report in 1938 is
customarily regarded as inspiring their foundation; and that the French experi-
mented with broadly similar arrangements at an earlier date than did the British,
a point which is not mentioned in the standard works on Marketing Boards in
the British territories. French commercial strategy will be considered first in the
hope that the analysis, though necessarily brief, will by its prominence encourage
historians and economists to treat the comparative aspects of official policy more
seriously than they have done in the past.
French commitment to free trade had long been half-hearted. As early as
1892 a limited range of measures aimed at protecting French exporters had been
applied to certain West African colonies and would probably have been
extended had not Britain succeeded in 1898 in negotiating an agreement which
guaranteed equal treatment for her traders and goods in the Ivory Coast and
Dahomey. Disappointment with the results of this modified system of free trade,
combined with a desire to ensure that the colonies assisted the reconstruction of
The open economy under strain 319
France after the First World War, led to renewed clamour for the introduction
of protectionist measures. In 1928 the Federation (with the exception of the
Ivory Coast and Dahomey) was brought under the preferential tariff regime
already operated by France with respect to various other parts of her empire.56
Steps were taken to reinforce this legislation as a result of the world slump.
Durand has estimated that no fewer than 50 measures regulating the overseas
trade of French West Africa were introduced between 1931 and 1941.57 The
most important of these were the imposition in 1934 of quotas on foreign goods
imported into parts of the Federation not covered by the Anglo-French conven-
tion of 1898, and the ending of the convention itself in 1936, with the result
that the Ivory Coast and Dahomey were included in the tariff arrangements
introduced in the rest of French West Africa eight years earlier.
The system of imperial preference was supported by two new institutions. As
far as exports from West Africa were concerned, caisses de compensation were
formed for rubber and coffee (1931), bananas (1932) and vegetable products
(1933–34). These compensation funds were built up by levying a surcharge on
foreign imports of these products at the ports of entry in France and were then
paid out to support producer prices in the colonies at times when these fell
below a certain minimum level. The aim, price stabilisation, was clearly an
anticipation of measures which were adopted by Britain and France during
the Second World War, though at this stage there was no attempt to establish
a government monopoly of exports. On the import side, comités de surveillance
were created in 1936 to keep a check on the prices of goods shipped to the
colonies. A price freeze was imposed in 1937 and again in 1939, though it is
hard to see how practical effect could have been given to this intention.
Between 1939 and 1941 the metropolitan government took over the functions
of the various funds and boards, and assumed complete control of overseas trade,
though still employing the expatriate firms to act as its agents.
In Britain, as in France, the First World War helped revive interest in tariff
reform, though in the event only slight changes were made to existing customs
regulations. In 1919 duties were imposed on palm kernels and tin leaving West
Africa, and a rebate allowed on imports of these commodities entering the
United Kingdom. The rebate on palm kernels failed to divert trade to Britain
and was withdrawn in 1922, but the duty on tin remained until 1938. The
world slump caused a more widespread conversion to protectionism, and the
Ottawa Conference of 1932 had an important effect on the tariff regime of the
West African colonies. Sierra Leone and the Gambia were brought into the new
system of imperial preference immediately. Nigeria and the Gold Coast could
not be assimilated fully because of treaty obligations to other powers. Neverthe-
less, from 1932 the exports of all four colonies were allowed free entry into the
United Kingdom, whereas those from outside the Empire had to pay duties, and
from 1934 quotas were applied to goods sent to British West Africa from coun-
tries such as Japan, which had no formal rights guaranteeing equal treatment.
The days when Britain’s commercial policy was based on maintaining an open
door in all parts of the world had ended.58
The slump (and the cocoa hold-up of 1930–31) also led to a number of pro-
posals in favour of official intervention in the export market. The most promin-
ent of the schemes put forward in the early 1930s was the Bartholomew Plan of
1931, which was designed to use government power to influence the world
cocoa market and to stabilise prices on the Gold Coast.59 This plan was rejected
by the Gold Coast government, which argued against official intervention in
1931 on much the same grounds as Professor Bauer was to use in 1954 in his
more comprehensive attack on the marketing monopolies which the authorities
did eventually establish.60 The persistence of the depression in overseas trade,
together with the hold-up of 1937, caused the government to modify its pos-
ition to the extent of appointing a commission to investigate the arrangements
for marketing cocoa. The Nowell Commission’s Report, which appeared in
1938, recommended the creation of collective marketing agencies, but no action
had been taken by the time of the outbreak of war, and in the event it was the
emergency caused by hostilities which led to official control of overseas trade.
The Ministry of Food took over the purchase of the cocoa crop in 1939; the
West African Cocoa Control Board was set up in 1940; and the West African
Produce Control Board, which handled all the main export crops, was estab-
lished in 1942. Under the new arrangements, private firms still purchased
exports in Africa, but they sold to one buyer, the official Board, which also
fixed the prices to be paid.
Official intervention in overseas trade failed to solve West Africa’s problems,
and was of little help to France and Britain either. In the case of the French
colonies, imperial preference strengthened bilateral trading links and gave both
parties a measure of certainty with respect to markets for their products. How-
ever, French West Africa had to pay for this security by becoming integrated in
a high-cost, high-price trading system, which, among other disadvantages, meant
that the colonies had to buy relatively expensive French consumer goods.
Imperial preference was worth even less to British West Africa. Britain’s attempt
to shelter tropical exports was unsuccessful, partly because she consumed only
a small proportion of the Empire’s total output of the main staples, and partly
because the new tariff system did nothing to diminish competition among pro-
ducers within the Empire. At the same time, the colonies failed to derive any
58 The open economies of British West Africa still remained open, of course, with respect to Britain.
59 West Africa, 19 September 1931, pp. 1146–7.
60 West Africa, 17 October 1931, p. 1262, and a further comment by Bartholomew in ibid, 25 Febru-
ary 1933, p. 177.
The open economy under strain 321
advantages from the privileges accorded to imports from Britain. The imposition
of quotas, for example, prevented Africans from buying cheaper Japanese textiles
and footwear. African producers also failed to benefit from the various Funds
and Boards which were set up to stabilise prices and incomes. Indeed, the low
buying prices fixed by the Marketing Boards in British West Africa amounted,
in effect, to a forced loan in aid of the war effort. The main beneficiaries of the
statutory monopolies were the large expatriate firms. Official patronage con-
firmed and extended the private ‘pooling’ arrangements which they had oper-
ated previously. These firms not only supported state intervention, they even
helped to plan it.61
The stress experienced by the open economy between 1930 and 1945 had
a profound influence on the course of West African history. The favourable
terms of trade, the swelling public revenues and the optimism of the early twen-
tieth century had first made possible, and then sustained, a policy of cooperation
between colonial rulers and key interest groups among their African subjects.
The unfavourable terms of trade, the declining revenues and the pessimism of
the period 1930–45 were reflected in the discontent expressed by African farm-
ers, traders and wage-earners, and led to mounting criticism of the colonial
regime.
Expatriate reactions failed either to improve the performance of the open
economy or to dissolve African hostility. Officials and firms retrenched and
waited for a boom that did not come until the end of the Second World War.
After 1930 there was some pretence, but little reality, about developing the
estates of the Empire. Many of the poorer parts of West Africa, though they still
found a place in the speeches of politicians and on the maps of Empire, were in
effect abandoned by the colonial rulers. To the extent that the colonial govern-
ments and commercial firms did take effective action, it was in support of
expatriate rather than African interests. It was possible to discern the beginnings
of a change in government attitudes early in the 1930s, and more explicit recog-
nition of the need for reform was made during the Second World War, but
there was no New Deal for the colonies before 1945. This was a time when the
white man’s burden consisted of the politicians of Europe rather than the subject
peoples of Africa.
The depressed state of trade and the bankruptcy of colonial policy had
a fundamental influence on the nature and organisation of African opposition to
foreign rule. By the close of the 1930s, the gradualist approach of moderate
Africans, such as Macaulay, Diagne and Tete-Ansa, had been discredited, and
new, more radical leaders, such as Azikiwe, Danquah, Wallace-Johnson and
Lamine Guèye, had begun to emerge. Instead of calling for a re-interpretation
of the dual mandate within the imperial context, some of these spokesmen, in
61 P. T. Bauer, ‘Origins of the Statutory Export Monopolies of British West Africa’, Business History
Review, 28, 1954, pp. 204–7.
322 The open economy under strain
their different ways, pressed for political independence and for a re-structuring
of the colonial economy. ‘It is not enough’, proclaimed Danquah, ‘to live in the
old agricultural economy. We must manufacture and buy our own goods. We
must industrialise our country’.62 Whereas the following of the moderate leader-
ship had been confined to the elite of a few large urban centres, the new leaders
began to mobilise mass support by incorporating farmers, traders and wage-
earners into modern political organisations. Thus, the period 1930–45 is to be
treated as an integral part of an explanation of the rise of nationalism in West
Africa, and not merely as a ‘background’ to the more-publicised events of the
years which followed the end of the Second World War.
Africans and Europeans towards colonial rule. Third, African agitation for eco-
nomic and political reforms, though generated before 1945, increased greatly
after the war. Fourth, modifications were brought about partly through the self-
interest of the colonial powers. Ideally, these four themes should be treated sim-
ultaneously in order to emphasise the interaction among them; unfortunately,
the medium of the printed word does not allow this freedom. The compromise
adopted here is to deal in turn with the history of African pressures and Euro-
pean policy, and to relate the remaining themes (the performance of the open
economy and the changing climate of international relations) to them.
Although economic expansion began in 1945, prosperity did not return to West
Africa immediately the war ended. The barter and income terms of trade started to
recover, but it was not until the close of the 1940s that the losses suffered during
the war years were made good, and it was only in the 1950s that living standards
rose clearly above the levels of the 1930s. There were two main reasons for this
delay: on the import side, consumer goods were in short supply during the immedi-
ate post-war years, and so were expensive—in Europe as well as in Africa; on the
export side, part of the earnings of producers continued to be withheld by official
marketing agencies, which fixed prices at levels lower than those ruling in world
markets. Farmers and traders were not worse off than they had been during the
war, but their living standards did not improve as fast as they had expected. The
same was true of employees in the public sector, whose wage rates, though begin-
ning to move upwards, still lagged behind increases in the cost of living. In under-
standing African reactions to this situation, it is important to appreciate that what
mattered was not so much the relationship between the standard of living and an
objectively defined poverty line, as the failure of slowly rising living standards to
catch up with rapidly rising expectations. In attempting to retain the loyalty of their
subjects during the war years, the colonial powers had not only used the stick of
compulsory labour but had also dangled some carrots. Statements on colonial policy
held out the promise of a ‘New Deal’ once the struggle to safeguard democracy and
freedom had been won. Around the comer were better times and homes fit, as it
were, for African heroes to live in. When, inevitably, reforms took longer to imple-
ment than had been anticipated, African disappointment was the more acute.
The outcome of this set of circumstances was predictable: some of the most
widely supported demonstrations of discontent in the whole colonial period
occurred between 1945 and 1950, when governments in Africa were subjected to
greater pressures than they had ever experienced. African discontent continued to
find expression in ways which had become familiar during the period 1930–45.
The best-known examples of these protests are the Nigerian national strike of 1945
(noted in the previous section of this chapter), the strike on the Dakar railway in
1947–48,64 the riots on the Gold Coast in 1948, involving a boycott of European
64 A semi-fictional, and most readable, account of this strike has been given by Sembene Ousmane,
Les bouts de bois de Dieu, Paris, 1960.
324 The open economy under strain
firms and mass demonstrations by African ex-servicemen,65 and the highly publi-
cised shooting incident at the Enugu coal mines in 1949, in which 21 miners lost
their lives.66 One, admittedly imperfect, index of militancy among wage-earners is
provided by the record of man-days lost through strike action. A recent study of
Nigerian labour history during the period 1940–60 has shown that the greatest
number of withdrawals occurred between 1945 and 1950, when over 100,000
man-days were lost every year.67
African protest movements acquired one additional, highly distinctive feature
in the post-war era: they assumed a more organised and a more overt political
form. This development began, as has been shown, in the 1930s, but during
the Second World War political expression in the colonies was restricted for
security reasons. After 1945, however, continuing discontent in Africa supplied
the incentive to mobilise and coordinate sectional interests, and to provide them
with a political forum. The years between 1945 and 1950 saw an upsurge of
militant, anti-colonial activities in the West African territories—in the press, in
mass demonstrations and in confrontations between African leaders and colonial
officials. At the same time, it was becoming hard for the victors of a war fought
to preserve free speech to justify restraining political expression among their
colonial subjects. The creation of the United Nations in 1945 provided an inter-
national platform for the declamation of anti-colonial sentiments, while at the
national level the rise to power of the Labour Party in Britain and the promin-
ence of the Communist Party in France brought about a more sympathetic atti-
tude towards colonial grievances. Consequently, colonial officials were inhibited
from adopting extreme punitive measures. In West Africa political leaders were
‘agitators’; they were never forced to become ‘terrorists’.
It is not the purpose of this book to provide a detailed account of the political
mobilisation that occurred after the Second World War.68 Nevertheless, some of
65 Colonial Office, Report of the Commission of Enquiry into Disturbances in the Gold Coast, London,
1948.
66 Agwu Akpala, ‘The Background of the Enugu Colliery Shooting Incident in 1949’, Journal of the
Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1965, pp. 335–64.
67 Robin Cohen, The Role of Organised Labour in the Nigerian Political Process, University of Birming-
ham Ph.D. thesis, 1971, p. 248.
68 See Thomas Hodgkin, African Political Parties, Harmondsworth, 1961. Only a few of the many stud-
ies of West African politics can be mentioned here. Three valuable books which deal with the
region as a whole are Thomas Hodgkin, Nationalism in Colonial Africa, London, 1956; Ken Post,
The New States of West Africa, Harmondsworth, 1964; and Aristide R. Zolberg, Creating Political
Order, Chicago, 1966. Important studies of specific territorial units are Dennis Austin, Politics in
Ghana, 1946–60, Oxford, 1964; James S. Coleman, Nigeria: Background to Nationalism, Berkeley
and Los Angeles, 1958; Richard L. Sklar, Nigerian Political Parties, Princeton, 1963; Martin
L. Kilson, ‘Nationalism and Social Classes in British West Africa’, Journal of Politics, 20, 1958, pp.
368–87; and the same author’s Political Change in a West African State: A Study of the Modernization
Process in Sierra Leone, Cambridge, 1966; John R. Cartwright, Politics in Sierra Leone, 1947–1967,
Toronto, 1970; Ruth Schachter Morgenthau, Political Parties in French-Speaking West Africa, Oxford,
1964; and Aristide R. Zolberg, One-Party Government in the Ivory Coast, Princeton, 1964.
The open economy under strain 325
Sierra Leone People’s Party (S.L.P.P.), formed in 1951, derived much of its ini-
tial inspiration and funds from provincial Mende commercial interests.
It is hard to discern any detailed, constructive economic proposals in the pro-
grammes of these political organisations, though economic grievances, and gen-
eralised solutions to them, clearly occupied a prominent place.69 The main
emphasis, understandably enough, was on attacking colonialism, and there was
a tendency to assume that the end of colonial rule would itself be sufficient to
solve basic economic problems. Once African leaders controlled the ‘command-
ing heights’ of the economy, sizeable gains, so it was said, would accrue to their
supporters. A reorganisation of the Marketing Boards, combined with controls
on the exporting firms, would give farmers a better price for their produce;
restrictions on the activities of the expatriate commercial firms would provide
more opportunities for African traders; industrialisation would lead to improved
living standards for wage-earners, and would also benefit the economy as
a whole. Indeed, there was a tendency to regard industrialisation as a cure-all:
Durand has commented on the mystique which surrounded the concept in the
French territories,70 and the same phenomenon was found in British West
Africa. The Commission of Enquiry appointed to investigate the riots on the
Gold Coast in 1948 reported that ‘at every turn we were pressed with the cry
of industrialisation. We doubt very much if the authors of this cry really under-
stood more than their vague desire for something that promised wealth and
higher standards of life’.71 It was a sign of the times that the Commission
(which itself knew little about industrialisation) went on to recommend the
introduction of certain types of secondary industry.
The character of African opposition to colonialism underwent a change after
1950, as the bitterness and militancy which had characterised the immediate
post-war years were replaced by a more conciliatory and cooperative mood.
There were two main reasons for this change: West Africans were beginning to
receive some of the benefits of economic expansion, and the colonial powers
had started to make substantial concessions to African demands by promoting
a greater degree of self-government, and (as will be shown later) by introducing
a number of economic reforms. Two events symbolised this transition: in 1950
Houphouët-Boigny agreed to sever his links with the French Communist Party
in return for the introduction of a more progressive regime on the Ivory Coast;
in 1951 Nkrumah was released from prison and appointed leader of government
business on the Gold Coast. In political terms the 1950s are best regarded as
a period of dyarchy, in which power was increasingly shared between the colo-
nial rulers and the wealthier, more articulate and more influential of their
69 There is an interesting study to be made of the origins and evolution of African economic thought
between 1930 and 1960.
70 Durand, Essai sur la conjoncture, p. 144.
71 Colonial Office, Report of the Commission of Enquiry into the Disturbances in the Gold Coast, London,
1948, p. 54.
The open economy under strain 327
subjects. Neither prosperity nor access to political power served to retard the
movement towards independence. On the contrary, once Africans perceived
that their aspirations were attainable, progress was made at an even faster pace.
As Tocqueville remarked about an earlier revolutionary process, ‘evils which are
patiently endured when they seem inevitable become intolerable when once the
idea of escape from them is suggested’.72
The new spirit of cooperation is illustrated by the improvement in the for-
tunes of the three groups of specialists which supported the principal political
parties. The marked recovery in the barter terms of trade in the 1950s presented
producers with incentives and opportunities which had not arisen since the end
of the First World War, and then only briefly. Farmers found it profitable to
increase the volume of foodstuffs to meet the growing needs of the domestic
market and to expand export production, which reached record levels in the
1950s, despite the fact that in the British territories the Marketing Boards still
retained a large slice of export proceeds.
The growth of agricultural output was achieved mainly by traditional means,
that is by applying underused labour to underused land. This further develop-
ment on the extensive margin was made possible by the expansion of motor
transport and by the increased use of bicycles, which helped farmers commute
between plots. However, there were also signs, which were important for the
future of West African agriculture, of a rise in productivity (an increase in
output per man and per acre) through the application of chemical fertilisers,
higher yielding seeds and pest controls. These innovations affected both estab-
lished export staples and products destined for domestic consumption. In the
case of exports, the addition of potassium fertilisers increased the yield from oil
palms, pesticides eliminated some of the diseases afflicting the cocoa tree, and
new varieties of groundnut helped conserve nutrients in the soil. With regard to
the domestic economy, improved types of grass provided better pasture, live-
stock selection and breeding schemes raised the quality of cattle, and plans to
expand the output of swamp rice, vegetables, poultry and dairy produce were
implemented.73
The motives underlying agricultural improvements were of two kinds. Ori-
ginally, the colonial rulers wanted to ensure that West Africa was self-sufficient
during the war years and could also produce the quantity of exports needed to
aid the war effort and to speed Europe’s recovery after 1945. Then, from the
1950s, concern was expressed about the future of West African agriculture,
which, it was feared, would run into the problem of diminishing returns if, in
the absence of scientific and managerial improvements, labour continued to be
applied in increasing quantities to a fixed amount of land. Fortunately, West
72 Aléxis de Tocqueville, The Old Regime and the French Revolution, New York, 1856, p. 214.
73 For further details see W. B. Morgan and J. C. Pugh, West Africa, London, 1969, Ch. 10.
328 The open economy under strain
Africa still has time to avert this danger. Although population is growing rapidly,
farming land is still available in most parts of the region.
Indigenous businessmen were equally quick to take advantage of the openings
presented in the 1950s by the growth and diversification of the economy, and
by the shift in political power—which put public funds into African hands.
Besides expanding domestic commerce in ways outlined earlier in this chapter,
Africans also increased their share of the direct import and export trade, which
had long been dominated by expatriate firms. Their success was especially
marked in the wealthier colonies, where the exchange economy was expanding
rapidly. In Nigeria, for example, the African share of the import trade rose from
5 per cent in 1949 to 20 per cent in 1963. Furthermore, as will be shown
shortly, aspiring businessmen gained substantially from the policy of Africanisa-
tion introduced by the large expatriate firms during the 1950s. More signifi-
cantly, Africans were among the first to perceive and exploit entirely new
opportunities: the growth of towns meant the development of a construction
industry;74 rising urban incomes led to a demand for better-quality foodstuffs;
increasing literacy created a market for books and Western entertainment; and
the spread of motor vehicles brought about a need for ancillary services, such as
garages. Some of the most prominent Nigerian entrepreneurs of the post-war
era have made their fortunes by providing for these needs: Ayo Otaru as the
manufacturer of ‘Lion’ bread in Ibadan; Chief T. A. Odutola as a supplier of
tyres and spare parts for motor vehicles; Sir Mobolaji Bank-Anthony in con-
struction, road haulage, cinemas and bookshops; and Alhaji S. L. Edu as
a government food contractor. Many other, less well-known, figures have
engaged in similar activities on a smaller scale.75 One of the most important
consequences of the diversification of the open economy is that Africans have
begun to acquire the technical skills which they have lacked in the past.
Wage-earners benefited from the recovery which took place during the 1950s
in two ways. The expansion of the economy in general, and the growth of the
public sector in particular, brought new opportunities for wage employment.
The decade also saw a rise in real wages, though the exact extent of the gains
varied, being rather greater in the French territories than in British West
Africa.76 The improvement should not be exaggerated. The rise in real wages
was from a low level and it was not continuous, there being a check, for
74 Practically every book on West Africa provides some information about the growth of towns in the
twentieth century; as yet, little attention has been paid to the interesting question of how they were
built.
75 See, for example, the local study by R. A. Akinola, ‘The Industrial Structure of Ibadan’, Nigerian
Geographical Journal, 7, 1964, pp. 116–20.
76 Elliot J. Berg, ‘Real Income Trends in West Africa, 1939–1960’, in Economic Transition in Africa,
eds. Melville J. Herskovits and Mitchell Harwitz, 1964, pp. 199–238, and John F. Weeks, ‘Further
Comment on the Kilby/Weeks Debate: An Empirical Rejoinder’, Journal of Developing Areas, 5,
1971, p. 171.
The open economy under strain 329
example, at the close of the 1950s. The broad, upward trend, while it did not
retard the growth of trade unions or eliminate strike action,77 did remove much
of the violence from labour protest in the colonies. The emphasis of the organ-
ised labour movement was on negotiation rather than on revolution, though
strong words were often spoken on the way to the conference room.
The causes of this rise in real wages are a matter of controversy, stemming on
the one hand from the economist’s concern with the problem of the relationship
between wage rates and the development prospects of African countries, and on
the other from the historian’s interest, imported from Europe, in the role of
trade unions as a force for economic and political change. Berg and Butler, sup-
ported by Weeks, have taken the view that African trade unions had relatively
little power.78 They have pointed out that wage-employment affected only
a small proportion of the total labour force, and that many wage-earners, being
migrants, had no interest in union activities. Consequently, trade unions had
few members; they lacked solidarity; their financial resources were limited; and
their leadership tended to be of poor calibre. The conclusion derived from this
analysis is that the decision to raise money-wages in the 1940s and 1950s was
made by employers, not as a result of union pressure, but in recognition of the
increased cost of living and of the need to maintain a stable labour force. Against
this view it has been argued by Warren and Kilby, with support from Cohen,
that unions had strengths as well as weaknesses.79 They were located in strategic-
ally sensitive places, such as capital cities; their members were well represented
in key jobs, notably in public service; their activities attracted publicity, both in
Africa and in sympathetic newspapers in England and France; and at times when
discontent was widespread they were able to mobilise non-union support, espe-
cially from the urban unemployed, and to mount demonstrations which were
impressive in size and threatening in appearance. The conclusion drawn from
this evidence is that unions were influential in extracting concessions from
77 There were major strikes in the Gold Coast, Nigeria and Sierra Leone in 1955–56.
78 Elliot J. Berg and Jeffrey Butler, ‘Trade Unions’, in Political Parties and National Integration n Tropical
Africa, eds. James S. Coleman and Carl G. Rosberg, Berkeley, 1964, pp. 340–81; John F. Weeks,
‘A Comment on Peter Kilby: Industrial Relations and Wage Determination’, Journal of Developing
Areas, 3, 1968, pp. 7–17; Elliot J. Berg, ‘Urban Real Wages and the Nigerian Trade Union Move-
ment, 1939–60: A Comment’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 17, 1969, pp. 604–17;
and John F. Weeks, ‘Further Comment on the Kilby/Weeks Debate: an Empirical Rejoinder’,
Journal of Developing Areas, 5, 1971, pp. 165–74.
79 W. M. Warren, ‘Urban Real Wages and the Nigerian Trade Union Movement, 1939–60’, Eco-
nomic Development and Cultural Change, 15, 1966, pp. 21–36; Peter Kilby, ‘Industrial Relations and
Wage Determination: Failure of the Anglo-Saxon Model’, Journal of Developing Areas, 1, 1967, pp.
489–520; the same author’s ‘A Reply to John F. Weeks’ Comment’, Journal of Developing Areas, 3,
1968, pp. 19–26; W. M. Warren, ‘Urban Real Wages and the Nigerian Trade Union Movement,
1939–60: Rejoinder’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 17, 1969, pp. 618–33; Robin
Cohen, ‘Further Comment on the Kilby/Weeks Debate’, Journal of Developing Areas, 5, 1971, pp.
155–64; and Kilby’s ‘Final Observations’, Journal of Developing Areas, 5, 1971, pp. 175–6.
330 The open economy under strain
employers during the 1940s and 1950s, even though results fell some way short
of expectations.
The friction generated by this debate arises not merely because both sides
believe themselves to be correct, but because they probably are. Berg and Butler
are right to draw attention to weaknesses in African trade unions. It would be
a mistake to regard the unions as a compelling, or even as a dominant, force in
the economic and political history of West Africa between 1945 and 1960. This
is one reason why the analysis presented in this chapter has concentrated on
three major African interest groups, and why the third group, the labour force,
has not been treated as if its history were synonymous with that of trade unions.
At the same time, it is equally clear that the authorities could not afford to
ignore the presence of organised labour. Unions were much stronger after 1945
than they had been beforehand, and they had a special significance in certain
colonies, such as Guinea. Governments may have been prepared to grant wage
increases simply in response to a rise in the cost of living, and in the absence of
any organised pressure to do so, but the fact that pressure existed is likely to
have influenced both the timing and the nature of the settlement. Generalisa-
tions, if stretched too far, lose their explanatory power. The question of the
effectiveness of unions in raising wages is one which needs to be decided with
reference to particular colonies and to particular points in time.
The foregoing survey completes the analysis of the evolution of African inter-
ests between 1945 and 1960. It remains to view this same period from the
standpoint of the colonial powers.
A ruling power (or class) can meet demands for radical reform in one or
more of three ways. It can do nothing at all, in the hope that the problem will
solve itself; it can adopt a policy of repression; and it can try conciliation. West
Africa has experienced all three approaches. A policy of ‘wait and see’ prevailed
during the period 1930–45, and, as has been shown, proved unsuccessful.
A policy of repression was used occasionally during the Second World War and
in the immediate post-war years. Until about 1950 Britain and France were still
unsure of the strength of African opposition, and they had not appreciated the
extent to which their own power had declined. Consequently, coercion was
used at times in an attempt to control the growth of anti-colonial organisations.
In 1949–50, large numbers of Africans were killed, wounded or imprisoned in
an aggressive campaign against the P.D.C.I. and Houphouët-Boigny, while on
the Gold Coast strong action was taken against the C.P.P. and Nkrumah, who
was jailed in 1950. These measures were partly a reflection of the belief, popular
among defenders of the ‘free’ world at the time of the Cold War, that foreign
nationalists were really communists in disguise.80 The Colonial Office, though
well stocked with historians, seems momentarily to have forgotten the
80 Colonial Office, Report of the Commission of Enquiry into Disturbances in the Gold Coast, London,
1948, p. 91, where the governor’s views on ‘communist’ methods are recorded.
The open economy under strain 331
81 Benjamin Franklin, ‘Rules for Reducing a Great Empire to a Small One’, Works, 3, 1806, p. 343.
82 Sierra Leone is a case in point. See Ralph Gerald Saylor, The Economic System of Sierra Leone,
Durham, 1967, pp. 95, 147–57.
83 Much of the foregoing interpretation, and virtually the whole of the exposition which follows, is
derived from the work of four scholars, all of whom arrived, quite independently, at complemen-
tary conclusions. Elements of the basic argument were first advanced by Marcel Capet in his neg-
lected study of the period 1945–54 entitled Traité d’économie tropicale: les économies d’A.O.F., Paris,
1958, pp. 123–32, 163–72. Ten years later two studies of changes in the mercantile functions of the
expatriate firms appeared: Atsé-Léon Bonnefonds, ‘La transformation du commerce de traite en
Côte d’Ivoire depuis la dernière guerre mondiale et l’indépendance’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 21, 1968,
332 The open economy under strain
pp. 395–413, and Charles Wilson, Unilever, 1945–1965, London, 1968, pp. 213–26. Then, in the
following year, came Peter Kilby’s comprehensive and indispensable volume, Industrialization in an
Open Economy: Nigeria, 1945–66, Cambridge, 1969.
84 United Africa Company, Statistical and Economic Review, 20, 1957, pp. 39–45; Statistical and Economic
Review, 30, 1965, p. 57. It is planned to increase the proportion to 80 per cent by 1980. Critics of
the expatriate commercial firms have argued, with some justification, that these changes amounted
to little more than ‘window dressing’. This criticism does not invalidate the point made here that
there was a gain in status and pay for a small, but important, indigenous interest group.
85 At least one firm was also affected by a type of unplanned Africanisation. The monopoly of the
Sierra Leone Selection Trust, granted in 1935, was undermined after the Second World War by
The open economy under strain 333
Africans were much cheaper to employ than Europeans; they knew the country
and its languages better; their local connections were frequently helpful in open-
ing new markets and holding on to established ones; and they were often out-
standingly successful businessmen. The decision to make room for aspiring
Africans was also an astute political move. By the close of the 1940s it was
apparent that the long-term interests of the expatriate firms lay in securing
a stake for themselves in an Africa ruled by Africans rather than by Europeans.
By providing more opportunities for indigenous traders, the expatriate firms
advanced their own interests and also improved their image in the eyes of their
most vociferous critics.
The more radical innovation was the introduction of modern industry. It is
widely, but incorrectly, assumed that the expatriate companies were firmly
opposed to industrialisation in Africa throughout the colonial period. That they
showed little or no interest in modern manufacturing before 1945 is undoubt-
edly true. Their skills were those of general merchants, and, as merchants, they
presided comfortably over commercial empires in which market-sharing agree-
ments had blunted aggressive entrepreneurial drives. Moreover, industrialisation
meant complications and risks. The establishment of local industries might have
offended metropolitan manufacturers and aroused the displeasure of the shipping
companies which dominated the West African carrying trade. Above all, there
was no clear indication that the local market was large enough to justify experi-
ments of this kind, especially in the depressed economic climate which existed
between 1930 and 1945.
After the Second World War, a departure from traditional attitudes became
less risky and more compelling. By the 1950s, the effective demand for manu-
factures had reached the point in some parts of West Africa where it could sus-
tain at least a few firms of the size needed to produce the goods most
commonly required, and for those firms to operate at sufficient capacity to keep
their costs down and the prices of their products competitive with imports from
Europe.86 Furthermore, the expansion of the market, by introducing a greater
degree of competition, had reduced profit margins on many staple imports. The
traditional firms not only countered this challenge by specialising, as has been
shown, but also by becoming manufacturers, in the hope that they could achieve
sufficient savings in production and transport costs to undersell their new rivals.
It was no coincidence that the leading manufacturers in West Africa during the
1950s were established commercial firms, such as U.A.C., C.F.A.O., S.C.O.A.,
the illicit activities of African diggers and Levantine traders. This development received formal rec-
ognition in 1956, when African miners were granted licences. Saylor, The Economic System of Sierra
Leone, Ch. 4, provides a summary view. For a comprehensive account of the industry as a whole
see H. L. van der Laan, The Sierra Leone Diamonds, London, 1965.
86 These remarks barely hint at a complex problem. For a discussion of the importance of economies
of scale in different types of import-substituting industries, and of variations in factor proportions
among firms within particular industries see Kilby, Industrialization in an Open Economy, Ch. 11.
334 The open economy under strain
John Holt and Maurel et Prom, all of which had to undertake considerable
internal reorganisation and acquire staff with the necessary technical skills. By
starting modern industries, as by specialising in trade, these firms also helped to
further Afro-European cooperation during the final phase of colonial rule.
The production of goods for domestic consumption, such as processed food,
drink, clothing and construction materials, accounted for the largest share of
modern manufacturing output in West Africa during the 1950s and 1960s. This
emphasis is understandable, given the relatively low level of purchasing power,
the need to manufacture for a mass market and the motives of the first industri-
alists. However, it was not feasible to produce a complete range of these items
locally. The advantage lay with industries which could achieve the greatest
saving in costs by being located near their final market. Factories using a high
proportion of local materials, especially items which were expensive to transport,
such as timber, lime, clay and water, were particularly favoured, as were
industries in which freight charges on finished articles were higher than on
the constituent raw materials, as was the case with hollow-ware.87 Typical
import-substituting industries established in the 1950s were those producing
cigarettes, beer, cement, footwear, textiles, furniture and utensils, and the
principal concentrations of modern manufacturing were in the four wealthiest
colonies, the leading centres being Lagos and Dakar. Export processing also
underwent further development in the 1950s, chiefly as a result of the intro-
duction of power-driven machinery. Once again, the main economy was the
saving made in freight charges by processing heavy raw materials, such as
timber and minerals, at source. Finally, it should be noted that the expatriate
firms invested in service industries, especially those requiring technical skills.
This involvement became necessary to meet demands derived from the satis-
faction of prior wants; the spread of motor vehicles, for example, made it
essential to set up service stations.
Changes in the economic role of colonial governments after 1945 were as
striking as those affecting the expatriate firms and have certainly attracted more
scholarly attention. Innovations in the public sector were partly the result of
African pressures, and were partly conceived in self-interest, but they were also
influenced by shifts in the global balance of power after the Second World War.
Britain and France emerged from the war as victors, but with their economies
run down and their international position irretrievably weakened. Large parts of
their empires had been overrun by enemy forces, and France herself had been
occupied by German troops. After 1945, both powers began to lose their grip
on political developments in their overseas territories. By the time nationalist
movements were gathering momentum in West Africa, important concessions
had already been made elsewhere. After much heart-searching, Britain granted
87 As pointed out in Chapter 2, these principles also influenced the location of manufacturing activity
in the pre-colonial period.
The open economy under strain 335
independence to India in 1947, and France was forced to relinquish her posses-
sions in Indo-China between 1950 and 1955. Other commitments remained,
and both countries found themselves engaged in some painful rear-guard actions,
particularly in areas where the issue of self-government was complicated by the
presence of white settlers, as in the cases of Algeria and Kenya. Nevertheless,
even colonial powers learn lessons in the end, and by the early 1950s, if not
before, it was clear that Britain and France had decided not to try to retain
West Africa by force.
Alterations to government policy after 1945 centred on one outstanding
development: the expansion of the public sector. This innovation involved
changes in the level of public investment, the introduction of economic plan-
ning and the exercise of controls over the marketing of export crops. These fea-
tures of official policy will be considered in turn.
Assessing the volume of capital flows to underdeveloped countries is not an
easy task, partly because of the empirical difficulty of locating all the sources of
supply, and partly because of the conceptual problem of deciding what consti-
tutes investment. However, in the case of West Africa the main trend is not in
dispute: there was a marked increase in foreign investment after the Second
World War. Between 1947 and the end of 1956, French public investment in
her West African territories amounted to 106 billion 1956 C.F.A. francs, com-
pared to 46 billion 1956 C.F.A. francs for the period 1903–46. Thus the
volume of investment was more than twice as great in the ten years between
1947 and 1956 as in the whole of the previous 43 years.88 Overseas public
investment in British West Africa, though running at less than half the level of
French aid, was also greater between 1946 and 1960 than in the period between
1900 and 1945.89 These figures do not tell the entire story. A substantial per-
centage of public investment after 1945 took the form of grants rather than
loans, which meant that the recipients carried proportionately lighter burdens of
repayment than in the pre-war era. Furthermore, fragmentary though the avail-
able statistics are, it is clear that private investment also rose following the revival
of the export market after the Second World War. Finally, it should not be for-
gotten that the colonies had access to funds derived from local sources, especially
customs duties and (in the case of British West Africa) revenues supplied by the
Marketing Boards. A study of these sources reveals an important contrast. In the
case of French West Africa, domestic funds accounted for 25 to 30 per cent of
88 Elliot J. Berg, ‘The Economic Basis of Political Choice in French West Africa’, American Political
Science Review, 54, 1960, pp. 394–5. Capet’s estimate (Traité d’économie tropicale, p. 293) suggests an
even greater contrast between pre-war and post-war levels of investment. As there is no obvious
means of choosing between the two sources, I have used Berg’s more conservative figures.
89 There is no work on British Africa to compare with Teresa Hayter’s French Aid, London, 1966. For
a general survey see Leonard Rist, ‘Capital and Capital Supply in Relation to the Development of
Africa’, in Economic Development for Africa South of the Sahara, ed. E. A. G. Robinson, London, 1964,
pp. 444–74.
336 The open economy under strain
official development expenditure between 1946 and 1958, whereas in the four
British territories the proportion was almost reversed: only about 25 per cent of
the total came from overseas public agencies in the period 1945–59.90
The increase in the resources at the disposal of public authorities made it pos-
sible to undertake measures to expand exports and to assist new projects outside
the export sector. The rise in the volume of overseas aid, together with the
funds accumulated by the marketing boards, weakened the relationship between
overseas earnings and domestic demand, and enabled the economy to grow to
some extent independently of the performance of the export sector. After 1945,
imports into French West Africa began to expand faster than exports. Ten years
later, the same trend appeared in the British territories. The economy remained
open, but it no longer operated in its pure form. Two, more specific, comments
should be added to this general observation. In the first place, modifications to
the open economy were most pronounced in Nigeria, the Gold Coast, Senegal
and the Ivory Coast, for it was these richer colonies which attracted most of the
foreign capital (public and private) invested in West Africa and were in
a position to tap substantial domestic funds as well. Consequently, post-war eco-
nomic development further accentuated already established regional inequalities.
Secondly, though the sources of foreign capital proliferated after the Second
World War, Britain and France remained the chief suppliers.91 Of the two,
French investment was greater in absolute terms, and it formed a higher propor-
tion of total public funds available in the colonies. Bilateral aid played a part in
modifying the open economy, but it also helped to maintain, and in the case of
France to strengthen, ties between the metropolis and the dependencies.
The considerable rise in public investment brought into being a new service
industry of economists and administrators. Indeed, the period after 1945 has
some claims to being termed the Age of the Planners. On this occasion there
was no bonfire of controls, as there had been at the end of the First World
War.92 The victors began to talk of ‘winning’ the peace, of a ‘strategy’ for
growth and of a ‘big push’ towards development. The rise to power of left wing
parties in Britain and France ensured that these ideas were translated into plans
and given high priority. Just as the Marshall Plan (1948) was designed to aid the
reconstruction of Europe, so the colonial powers initiated programmes for
speeding economic recovery in their empires.
This was the time, again following a precedent set during the war, when
a whole new language, a kind of Esperanto for planners, was created from initials.
As far as French West Africa was concerned, the main agency was F.I.D.E.S.
90 Ona B. Forrest ‘The Financing of the Present Development Plans of West Africa’, in International
Finance and Development Planning in West Africa, eds. Sune Carlson and O. Olakanpo, Lund, 1964,
pp. 55–6.
91 The United States was the leading foreign investor in Liberia.
92 R. H. Tawney, ‘The Abolition of Economic Controls, 1918–1921’, Economic History Review, 13,
1943, pp. 1–30.
The open economy under strain 337
lines to serve mines in Mauritania, Guinea, Sierra Leone and Liberia, and exten-
sions from Jos to Maiduguri (in Nigeria) and from Bobo Dioulasso to Ouaga-
dougou (in Upper Volta). Measuring the expansion of road transport in terms of
the number of miles of road built is an exercise which may well be a cure for
insomnia, but as an index of economic change it can easily be misleading. Apart
from the fact that many West African roads disappear during the rainy season,
there is also the basic problem, which is sometimes ignored, of deciding what
constitutes a road in an underdeveloped economy. There seems little point in
providing detailed lists of ‘relevant’ figures, though this could be done without
difficulty. All that will be said here is that on a conservative estimate the
number of miles of tarred roads increased about ten times (admittedly from
a very low base) between 1945 and 1960. In the case of Nigeria, which has
been studied in some detail, there were about 8,000 miles of tarred roads in
1963, compared with just over 500 miles in 1945. A more certain indication of
road improvements is provided by the number of motor vehicles, which also
grew about ten-fold in the period 1945–60. In 1959, there were just over
180,000 motor vehicles in West Africa, of which total 94,000 were in the Brit-
ish territories and 86,000 in the French colonies.
The rapid expansion of the road transport industry galvanised activity on sev-
eral fronts. It assisted the expansion of export crops; it stimulated internal trade;
it helped manufacturers, both by reducing the cost of delivering raw materials to
the factory and by distributing finished products to a wider market. Although
motor vehicles were first envisaged as feeding the railway, they managed to cap-
ture a substantial share of the import and export traffic after the Second World
War. Road transport benefited from cost-reducing innovations, such as the
diesel engine, but it was no cheaper than the railway, except on certain short-
haul journeys. Its competitive advantage stemmed from its geographical mobility,
its speed and its organisational flexibility, which meant that it could vary rates
quickly, adjust schedules to deal with particularly profitable (or unprofitable)
items, and provide a door-to-door service.
The 1950s saw the beginnings of consistent and widespread success in apply-
ing scientific knowledge to tropical agriculture. The best results, as noted earlier,
were achieved by introducing new types of plants, seeds, fertilisers and pesticides
to existing agricultural systems. The failures, which received much more publi-
city, were all in the established West African tradition of undertaking grandiose
projects that departed radically from long-standing practices. An extraordinary
plan for producing eggs in the Gambia, started in 1948 under the direction,
appropriately enough, of Dr Fowler, was wound up in 1951 at a cost of about
£1 million,96 and an ambitious scheme to mechanise agriculture in Nigeria,
launched in 1949, sank, weighed down by its own rusty tractors, in 1953.97
A more cautious approach has prevailed since the early 1960s.98 Mechanisation
is no longer regarded as a way of producing an instant agricultural revolution in
the tropics, and officials have ceased to assume that large farms can be equated
automatically with high productivity. A salutary side-effect of scientific research
has been to give Western experts more respect for the methods employed by
African farmers.
Official enterprise has been important throughout West Africa in encouraging
industrial development since the 1950s. Government involvement of an indirect
kind has been most evident in measures to assist private manufacturers establish
import-substituting and export-processing industries. These measures included
protective import duties and quotas, grants and cheap loans, guaranteed pur-
chases of certain products, and tax relief for infant industries.99 In French West
Africa, part of what was termed ‘industrial’ investment was also spent developing
mineral resources, particularly bauxite deposits in Guinea and iron ore in Mauri-
tania. Direct public enterprise has concentrated mainly on expanding public util-
ities, notably electricity. The most striking plan of this kind was the Volta River
Project, which was a comprehensive and costly scheme for generating hydro-
electric power, producing aluminium from local bauxite and irrigating farms in
the south-east part of the Gold Coast.100 Since electricity is virtually the only
form in which power for modern industry is stored in West Africa (and produc-
tion can be measured accurately), it provides a useful indication of the level of
industrial development in the region. In 1962 total electricity production for all
West Africa was 1,745 million kilowatt-hours. By international standards this
total was very low, being less than one fifth of production in the United King-
dom, which had additional sources of power and a much smaller population.
The unevenness of development within West Africa is demonstrated by the fact
that four countries accounted for 86 per cent of total production, and Nigeria
alone for 45 per cent.101
No satisfactory comparison of French and British policy towards the overseas
trade of their West African possessions has been undertaken. Most research has
centred on the operation of the Marketing Boards in British West Africa; neither
the French marketing system nor tariff policy has been studied in depth. Much
of the discussion which follows must be regarded, inevitably, as tentative.102 It
will be suggested that the policies of the two principal colonial powers were
98 Although Ghana and Nigeria can provide some exceptions to this generalisation.
99 For two case studies see Helleiner, Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria,
pp. 310–20, and Saylor, The Economic System of Sierra Leone, pp. 147–57.
100 Plans for this project were drawn up during the 1950s, but not implemented until the following
decade.
101 The leading producers in 1962 were Nigeria (786 million kilowatt-hours), Ghana (431 million),
Senegal (172 million) and the Ivory Coast (120 million).
102 And is partly designed to stimulate further research into the neglected aspects of these subjects.
Anyone who undertakes a full study of the marketing systems operating in French West Africa
after 1945 will be making a useful contribution to the recent economic history of the region.
340 The open economy under strain
103 In 1955 an Institut d’Émission was set up for French West Africa, and in 1959 this body became
the Banque Centrale des États de l’Afrique de l’Ouest.
104 The principal difference was that the C.F.A. franc did not follow the several devaluations of the
metropolitan franc after the war, and therefore had a higher value, whereas currencies in the ster-
ling area continued to exchange at par.
The open economy under strain 341
powers. Marketing policy, as reshaped after the Second World War, was adver-
tised as being in the interests of Africans, and can be regarded as an attempt to
modify the operation of the open economy by eliminating fluctuations in pro-
duce prices and in producer incomes.
In the immediate post-war years French governments were uncertain both
about the need for stabilisation, given the high prices ruling in the world and
within the preferential system, and about the means by which it might be
achieved. However, support funds (caisses de soutien) guaranteeing minimum pro-
duce prices were formed for most export crops between 1946 and 1949. In the
Ivory Coast, for example, funds for coffee and cocoa were established by means
of export levies imposed at the ports of exit.105 This arrangement proved
unpopular with the farmers who were supposed to benefit from it, and in 1950
a proposal to raise the levies was met by a number of protests in the true Gallic
tradition of direct peasant action. The farmers objected because a proportion of
the levy went to the Federation and was used to support groundnut prices in
Senegal, and because the caisse had ceased to act as a stabilising body and had
become simply a tax-gathering agency. In the period 1949–50, the powers of
the various caisses were reduced and the marketing system became, in the words
of Ramboz, ‘incoherent and ineffectual’. Between 1954 and 1956, a series of
new stabilisation funds (caisses de stabilisation) were created for the principal
French West African exports. This development was prompted by the initiation
of a more liberal tariff regime, which threatened, ultimately, to expose French
Africa to the lower prices which prevailed outside the preferential system, and
by the fall in world produce prices at the end of the Korean war. The stabilisa-
tion funds aimed at fixing producer prices and guaranteeing minimum incomes,
and were financed by levies on exporters, by export duties and by a central fund
in Paris (Fonds National de Régularisation des Cours des Produits d’Outre-Mer).
With some modifications, the reformed caisses survived down to, and in many
cases after, independence.
An accurate assessment of the effectiveness of the French marketing system
cannot be made until the necessary research has been completed. On present
evidence it is highly unlikely that any notable achievements were recorded
before 1954. After the reforms of 1954–56 there seems to have been
a considerable degree of success in fixing producer prices, but there is little
information about the more crucial issue of the stabilisation of incomes. Produ-
cer prices were set well above world prices, but consumer imports were, on
average, equally highly priced. However, it is worth mentioning that the caisses,
unlike the Marketing Boards in British West Africa, made serious efforts to
influence incomes by trying to control the volume of produce placed on the
105 A rare and neglected case study of the French marketing system is Yvonne-Claude Ramboz, ‘La
politique caféière de Côte d’Ivoire et la réforme de la caisse de stabilisation des prix du café et du
cacao’, Revue Juridique et Politique, 19, 1965, pp. 194–218.
342 The open economy under strain
market, and they also used their reserves to support prices when the market
weakened, as it did in the second half of the 1950s.
The British government had few doubts about the desirability of stabilising
the prices paid to producers, mainly because exports from the British colonies
were more exposed to the world market than was the case with French West
Africa. Officials were also confident that the marketing system established during
the war was capable of achieving this aim. Some institutional reorganisation was
carried out between 1947 and 1949, when the West African Produce Control
Board was replaced by separate commodity boards in each of the four colonies.
Subsequently, the only alteration of importance took place in 1954, when the
Nigerian Marketing Boards were reconstituted to operate on a regional basis.
The Marketing Boards, while still employing the expatriate firms as buying
agents, used their monopoly powers to fix the prices paid to producers. Their
declared policy was to set this price below the world price during times of pros-
perity, and to use the difference to form a reserve, which would then be paid
out to support producer prices when the world market became depressed. In
practice, the policy pursued by the Boards took a rather different course. In the
decade after the war, when world prices were buoyant, substantial reserves were
accumulated, as was intended. However, when the demand for tropical raw
materials slackened, as it did from the mid-1950s, the boards still fixed prices
slightly below the levels ruling in international markets, and so continued to
acquire funds, albeit on a much reduced scale. It has been calculated that export
producers in the Gold Coast lost as much as 41 per cent of their potential gross
incomes as a result of deductions made by the Marketing Boards between 1947
and 1961, and that Nigerian farmers lost an average of 27 per cent.106 The
reserves were certainly spent in the late 1950s and early 1960s, but they were
used, in the main, to finance government development projects, and not, as ori-
ginally planned, to compensate export-producers.
The initial policy of stabilisation, and the subsequent deviation from it, have
provoked a major controversy among economists concerned with African devel-
opment. The claim that the Boards had stabilised prices was first attacked by
Professor Bauer in a now famous study of the marketing system in British West
Africa.107 Bauer pointed out that the imperial government never defined what it
meant by stabilisation. He showed that to stabilise producer prices was not
necessarily to stabilise incomes because the farmers’ total receipts depended on
the volume of sales as well as on their unit price. Volume could be neither con-
trolled nor, of greater practical relevance, predicted. Bauer’s analysis of the his-
torical record led him to conclude that while the Boards had virtually eliminated
intra-seasonal price fluctuations, they had achieved little success in stabilising
106 The figure for Nigeria is an unweighted average of the losses from cocoa, groundnuts and palm
produce.
107 P. T. Bauer, West African Trade, Cambridge, 1954.
The open economy under strain 343
prices from season to season and had totally failed to stabilise incomes. Indeed,
Bauer contended that incomes were more unstable under the Marketing Board
system than they would have been in its absence. He went on to suggest that
the Boards had had a generally depressive effect on the economy by damping
down demand and possibly by blunting the incentive to invest in productive
enterprises within and outside agriculture. Bauer’s critique did not pass unchal-
lenged at the time, but later research has substantiated his main arguments.
Bauer’s study was published in 1954, at a time when the Marketing Boards were
still accumulating funds and pursuing their stated aim of price stabilisation. Hellei-
ner, writing in 1966, was in a position to assess their subsequent performance.108
His analysis confirmed that the Boards had failed to stabilise incomes, and also
showed that they had virtually abandoned any attempt to do so. Helleiner then
went on to argue that the role of the Boards had changed in the second half of the
1950s, and that they were to be judged primarily as agencies promoting economic
development. His detailed survey of Nigerian experience led him to conclude that
while some of the reserves had been misspent, most of the funds accumulated by
the Boards had been invested usefully in various government-sponsored projects,
notably agricultural research, road construction and local industries. Helleiner con-
tended that the Boards had proved to be effective in mobilising savings for invest-
ment which otherwise would not have been made; if the reserves had been paid
out direct to the farmers, the greater part of the additional income would have been
spent on imported consumer goods, thus perpetuating the open economy rather
than assisting diversification. The strength of Helleiner’s case lies in his ability to
point to factual achievements. To suggest that the reserves would have been spent
more wisely if they had been returned to the farmers is to pose a question about an
event that did not take place. Nevertheless, the evidence presented in this chapter
makes it possible to add one, possibly interesting, speculation. Since diversification
was taking place in the 1950s as a result of market growth, and not solely through
government initiative, there would seem to be a case for supposing that had the
funds accumulated by the Boards been left in the hands of the farmers, the market
would have grown faster and expenditure on consumer goods would have given
further impetus to import-substituting industries.109 Merely to raise the possibility is
to draw attention to the fact that the controversy over the Marketing Boards is also
a debate about wider issues, which are not always stated explicitly: about private
versus public enterprise; about the emphasis to be given to consumption as opposed
to investment; and about the meaning of ‘desirable’ expenditure in an era in which
‘development’ is sometimes a euphemism for redistribution.
108 Gerald K. Helleiner, Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria, Homewood,
1966.
109 An argument on these lines is developed further by Cyril Ehrlich, ‘Marketing Boards in Retro-
spect: Myth and Reality’, in African Public Sector Economics, Centre of African Studies, Edinburgh,
1970, pp. 121–45.
344 The open economy under strain
110 Wontack Hong, ‘Industrialisation and Trade in Manufactures: The East Asian Experience’, in The
Open Economy, eds. Peter B. Kenen and Roger Lawrence, New York, 1968, pp. 213–39.
111 Celso Furtado, Economic Development of Latin America, Cambridge, 1970, pp. 75–81.
The open economy under strain 345
recognition has been given to the extent to which changes introduced after
the Second World War had their origins in pressures built up and remedies can-
vassed during the period 1930–45. By about 1950, the major colonial powers were
clearly moving with the new tide, trying on the one hand to placate their African
subjects, and on the other to safeguard the future of the expatriate business interests
which had played such an important part in installing them in the continent in the
first place. Judged by these criteria, decolonisation in West Africa was one of colo-
nialism’s greatest triumphs.
Finally, an examination of the role of the government in modifying the open
economy reveals a marked contrast between French and British West Africa.
The French colonies were on the whole poorer, and they relied heavily on
French capital, markets and personnel.112 The British colonies, besides being
wealthier, were also less dependent on imperial aid and markets. The modifica-
tions made to the economies of French West Africa after 1945 had the effect of
integrating the Federation more closely with the metropolis, whereas in British
West Africa economic innovation sprang mainly from the expansion of the
open economy itself, and so was self-financing to a much greater extent. This
distinction had far-reaching political implications: it helps to explain why the
Gold Coast and Nigeria took the lead in demanding and achieving independ-
ence, and why the French colonies, when offered independence in 1958, chose,
with the exception of Guinea, to remain temporarily within the French
Community.113
This chapter has offered an economic interpretation of the rise of African national-
ism that also runs counter to some well-known, if simplistic, beliefs. In the first place,
it should be clear that independence was not a result of the enlightened policy of
rulers who managed to steer their subject peoples towards self-government in accord-
ance with a grand plan laid down at the outset of the colonial period. Only hindsight
suggests that granting independence was anything other than a belated recognition of
the unforeseen. Secondly, it is equally certain that African nationalism was not simply
a spontaneous, mass movement of the downtrodden, directed against sun-helmeted,
exploiting masters and led by men whose readiness for self-sacrifice was matched only
by their determination to survive long enough to improve the living standards of
their fellow countrymen.
Opposition to colonialism was based on an imperfect alliance of three major
interest groups of farmers, traders and wage-earners, all of whom shared a degree of
commitment to the exchange economy which distinguished them from the bulk of
the population. Political leaders were drawn from the higher, more-affluent
112 This distinction has been drawn out by Elliot J. Berg in a typically incisive article, ‘The Economic
Basis of Political Choice in French West Africa’, American Political Science Review, 54, 1960, pp.
391–405.
113 The timing of independence was as follows: The Gold Coast (Ghana), 1957; Guinea, 1958;
Nigeria, 1960; the constituent states of the Federation of French West Africa (apart from Guinea),
1960; Togo, 1960; Sierra Leone, 1961; and Gambia, 1965.
A
16°W 8°W 0° 8°E 16°E
HAR
LIBYA
SA
ALGERIA
H
IS
AN
SP
20°N 20°N
MAURITANIA
NIGER
MALI
CHAD
SENEGAL
GAMBIA
UPPER VOLTA
PORTUGUESE 10°N
GUINEA
GUINEA
FEDERATION OF NIGERIA
114 This task was helped (and made necessary) by extensions to the franchise and by the introduction
of local elections after 1945.
115 James C. Davies, ‘Toward a Theory of Revolution’, American Sociological Review, 27, 1962, pp.
5–19.
116 Lewis A. Coser, ‘The Termination of Conflict’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 11, 1958, pp.
170–83.
117 French West Africa was split up at independence largely because the wealthy colonies, especially
the Ivory Coast, did not want to continue subsidising the poorer parts of the Federation.
8
THE ECONOMY IN RETROSPECT
The strategy adopted in this book has been to state the argument at the outset,
and then to develop it, step by step, in successive chapters. Consequently, no
revelations have been saved for these final pages, which will recall, briefly, the
main points of interpretation.
The central theme of this study has been the interaction of the various internal
and external factors which have determined the structure and performance of the
market economy. Older views of the development of the West African economy
stressed the importance of external influences, principally colonial rule, and focused
on a comparatively short and recent time span. The colonial rulers were thought to
have started with a static, subsistence economy, and to have brought about
a transformation which was almost as impressive as that once achieved with the
loaves and fishes. The present work has noted the inaccuracies of the myth of
Primitive Africa, has emphasised the role of the indigenous population and has
covered a long period of time. However, this study has also shown that what has
become known as ‘the African point of view’ is to some extent a misnomer, which
stems from the myth of Merrie Africa and from an exaggerated belief in the com-
munal solidarity of pre-industrial societies. In reality, there are various African
points of view, each of which needs to be analysed before a satisfactory account of
indigenous economic history can be constructed.
The interpretation put forward here has explained stability and change in the
market economy by making use of concepts which will also be familiar to his-
torians and economists specialising in other parts of the underdeveloped world.
The analysis presented in Chapter 2 was principally a commentary on the stereo-
type of the ‘traditional’ society. It was argued that this concept is of questionable
value because it greatly exaggerates differences between the aims of pre-
industrial and of industrial societies, and because the institutional characteristics it
The economy in retrospect 349
describes have little foundation in fact. Ideal types are not designed to represent real-
ity, but they are supposed to illuminate it. When they fail to do this, they serve only
to direct research along false trails. Like Platonic Ideas, they need keeping in their
heavenly place. The pre-colonial economy was complex, efficient and adaptable,
and it had reached a relatively advanced stage of commercial capitalism long before
the impact of the Western world was felt in Africa. It was not the will to achieve
that was lacking,1 but the means of achieving which were limited. The expansion
of the domestic market was retarded not by institutional rigidities determined by
anti-capitalist values, but by identifiable economic obstacles, especially by
a deficiency of effective demand, which was related, in turn, to the land–labour
ratio and to high distribution costs. This conclusion, it is suggested, is important for
an understanding of the West African past (and present), and is also in agreement
with recent research on other parts of the underdeveloped world.2
Chapter 3 considered the possibility that these internal obstacles might have been
overcome by means of international trade. The concept of dualism was used to
explain why the external commercial relations which existed before the nineteenth
century failed to establish strong, beneficial linkages with the domestic economy.
This approach involved a consideration of the economics of slave-producing, as
well as, more conventionally, of the role of Africans in slave-trading. It was
concluded that Saharan and Atlantic commerce was privately profitable, but that
its social benefits were at best limited and in some cases were non-existent.
Chapter 4 argued that the early nineteenth century saw the start of the
modern economic history of West Africa, in the sense that the economic struc-
ture which began to take shape at that time was essentially that which existed at
the close of the colonial era. The history of the nineteenth century was analysed
in terms of staple theory,3 which was used to show how the growth in exports
of vegetable oils mobilised factors within the domestic economy, and led to the
integration, for the first time, of internal and external exchange sectors. This
development created tensions within Africa by shifting economic power from
a few, large exporters to numerous, small-scale farmers, and also involved produ-
cers in the cyclical fluctuations generated by industrial Europe. It was contended
that the initial structural changes and the subsequent performance of the new,
‘legitimate’ exports were central to an understanding of the motives for, and the
timing of, the scramble for West Africa in the late nineteenth century.
1 David C. McClelland’s stimulating theory, presented in The Achieving Society, Princeton, 1961, has
little relevance for West Africa.
2 See Morris D. Morris, ‘Towards a Reinterpretation of Nineteenth-Century Indian Economic His-
tory’, Journal of Economic History, 23, 1963, pp. 606–18; T. Scarlett Epstein, Capitalism, Primitive and
Modern: Some Aspects of Tolai Economic Growth, Canberra, 1968; and David Pitt, Tradition and Economic
Progress in Samoa, Oxford, 1970.
3 For a discussion of the historical role of foreign trade in promoting development, see K. Berrill,
‘International Trade and the Rate of Economic Growth’, Economic History Review, 12, 1960, pp.
351–9.
350 The economy in retrospect
A formal model of this developing, export economy was outlined in Chapter 5 and
applied to the period of colonial rule. The model made use of the concepts of ‘open’
and ‘closed’ economies and refined them to fit West African circumstances and to suit
the purposes of history rather than of economic policy. The performance of the West
African economies during the colonial era was charted by means of the terms of trade,
which were used to identify periods of market contraction and growth. It was sug-
gested that the multiplier effects of staple exports were weaker in open economies
based on indigenous, ‘peasant’ producers than in countries of recent settlement, such
as Canada and Australia, where there were considerable advantages of capital and skills,
and where economic policy enjoyed a greater degree of independence. At the same
time, it was contended that open economies which relied on ‘peasant’ exports estab-
lished stronger linkages than those associated with mining and plantation enclaves,
where there was little connection between ‘modern’ and domestic sectors, and where
the tendency for foreign trade earnings to be leaked abroad was more pronounced.
Chapter 6 focused on export growth during the first half of the colonial
period (1900–30) and evaluated expatriate and indigenous contributions to the
completion of the open economy. The expatriate role, though necessary to the expan-
sion which was achieved, was seen as encouraging a process which was under way
before the partition of Africa. Innovations in the key agricultural sector were made by
African farmers themselves. Indigenous producers of all ethnic groups, whether in the
forest or savanna, whether growing annuals or perennials, whether Muslim or Chris-
tian (or neither), proved that they were responsive to monetary incentives, that they
were prepared to travel to distant places, that they were willing to experiment with
new crops and with novel techniques of farm management, and that they were ready,
on occasion, to provide their own social overhead capital (in the shape of roads and
bridges) in advance of government action. The so-called ‘traditional’ society was not
eliminated: export expansion involved a certain amount of social change, as the
example of the decline of slavery made clear, but in general pre-colonial economic
and social institutions survived and proved functional to the development of the open
economy. The mobilisation of domestic factors of production was considered in terms
of the vent-for-surplus theory of international trade, which was modified to take
account of historical evidence relating to the role of African producers.
Chapter 7 identified the dysfunctional elements which caused the open econ-
omy to be modified during the second half of the colonial period (1930–60).
To begin with, attention was paid to differentiation within the export sector
and to developments in the domestic economy in order to stress the importance
of the quantitative size of the market, its geographical extent and the social com-
position of those involved in exchange activities.4 This analysis was then related
4 In West Africa the ‘traditional’ sector survived and expanded because of export growth. In some
other parts of the world it survived because it remained isolated from the foreign trade sector. See
Chi-Ming Hou, ‘Economic Dualism: The Case of China, 1840–1937’, Journal of Economic History,
23, 1963, pp. 277–97.
The economy in retrospect 351
to changes in the barter and income terms of trade in an attempt to explain why
the open economy experienced severe strains after 1930. This period of stress, it
was argued, was causally linked to the rise of the nationalist movement and to
the beginnings of industrialisation. After 1945, governments started to intervene
in the ‘natural’ working of the open economy. At the same time, growth within
the existing export sectors began to lead, at least in some countries, to develop-
ment, that is to structural change involving the introduction of modern manu-
facturing industries. The appearance of these novel features at the close of the
colonial period makes the achievement of independence a suitable terminal
point for this study.
There is a moralist in every historian. The moral of this book is mainly didac-
tic, though it has prescriptive implications. The history presented here has
sought to direct attention away from the adventures and triumphs of great lead-
ers, past and present, and towards the activities of the overwhelming majority of
Africans, those who have never ranked among the élite. This shift of emphasis
may have beneficial academic consequences if it encourages researchers to leave
the air-conditioned corridors of power and venture into the farms and markets.
It may also have some practical use if it reminds those who formulate policy and
exercise authority that the skills and energies of ordinary Africans are probably
the continent’s greatest assets. This is one lesson which the present can, and
should, learn from the past.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Bibliographies are the basis of all academic study. They are particularly important in
enabling new subjects to be pursued independently and outside a small group of special-
ists. The principles underlying the compilation and organisation of the present bibliog-
raphy are as follows:
1. The entries consist of books and articles published since 1945, though a few, earlier
works of outstanding importance have been included.
2. The bibliography contains most of the secondary works which can be defined as
economic history, but includes only a small selection of the contributions of political
historians, geographers, economists and anthropologists, which are also relevant to
the study of economic history.
3. The entries have been arranged under the chapter headings of this book. The alloca-
tion reflects, though none too precisely, the use made of the various items here, but
it does not mean that the works concerned have no value in other contexts. A few
studies appear under more than one chapter heading. No entries have been made
for Chapters 1 and 8 because these chapters contain only brief introductory and con-
cluding comments.
4. Books are referred to by listing author, title, place of publication and date of publi-
cation. Articles are referred to by listing author, title, name of the journal, volume
number (where available), year of publication and page numbers. Where authors
have published the same piece on more than one occasion, only the most recent
reference has been included.
Chapter 2
The domestic economy: structure and function
Agboola, S. A., ‘The Introduction and Spread of Cassava in Western Nigeria’, Nigerian Journal
of Economic and Social Studies, 3, 1968, pp. 369–386.
Ames, David W., ‘The Economic Basis of Wolof Polygyny’, Southwestern Journal of Anthropol-
ogy, 11, 1955a, pp. 391–403.
Bibliography 353
Ames, David W., ‘The Use of a Transitional Cloth-money Token Among the Wolof’,
American Anthropologist, 57, 1955b, pp. 1016–1023.
Anyane, S. La, Ghana Agriculture, London, 1963.
Arhin, K., ‘Status Differentiation in Ashanti in the Nineteenth Century: A Preliminary Study’,
Research Review, 4, Institute of African Studies, University of Ghana, 1968, pp. 34–52.
Arhin, K., ‘Aspects of Ashanti Northern Trade in the Nineteenth Century’, Africa, 40,
1970, pp. 363–373.
Arnold, R., ‘Separation of Trade and Market: Great Market of Whydah’, in Trade and
Market in the Early Empires, eds. K. Polanyi et al., Glencoe, 1957, pp. 177–187.
Aymo, G., ‘Notes de sociologie et de linguistique sur Ghadamès’, Bulletin de Liaison Sahari-
enne, 10, 1959, pp. 129–157.
Baker, H. G., ‘Comments on the Thesis that there Was a Major Centre of Plant Domesti-
cation Near the Headwaters of the River Niger’, Journal of African History, 3, 1962, pp.
229–233.
Barbour, K. M., and Prothero R. M., eds., Essays on African Population, London, 1961.
Bascom, William R., ‘The Esusu: A Credit Institution of the Yoruba’, Journal of the Royal
Anthropological Institute, 82, 1952, pp. 63–69.
Bascom, William R., ‘Urbanization Among the Yoruba’, American Journal of Sociology, 60,
1955, pp. 46–54.
Bascom, William R., ‘Les premiers fondemonts historiques de l’urbanisme Yoruba’, Présence
Africaine, 23, 1958–9, pp. 22–40.
Bascom, William R., ‘Urbanism as a Traditional African Pattern’, Sociological Review, 7,
1959, pp. 29–43.
Biebuyck, D., ed., African Agrarian Systems, London, 1963.
Bohannan, P., ‘Some Principles of Exchange and Investment among the Tiv’, American
Anthropologist, 57, 1955, pp. 60–70.
Bohannan, P., and Bohannan, L., Tiv Economy, London, 1968.
Bohannan, P., and Dalton, G., eds., Markets in Africa, Evanston, 1962.
Bray, J. M., ‘The Organization of Traditional Weaving in Iseyin, Nigeria’, Africa, 38, 1968,
pp. 270–280.
Buchanan, K. M., and Pugh, J. C., Land and People in Nigeria, London, 1955.
Callaway, A., ‘From Traditional Crafts to Modern Industries’, Odu, 2, 1965, pp. 28–51.
Capot-Rey, R., and Damade, W., ‘Irrigation et structure agraire à Tamentit’, Travaux de
l’Institut de Recherches Sahariennes, 21, 1962, pp. 99–119.
Carter, G. F., ‘Archaeological Maize in West Africa: A Discussion of Stanton and Willett’,
Man, 64, 1964, pp. 85–86.
Cauneille, J., and Dubief, J., ‘Les Reguibat Legouacem: chronologie et nomadisme’, Bul-
letin de l’IFAN, B, 17, 1955, pp. 528–550.
Centre of African Studies, Markets and Marketing in West Africa, Edinburgh, 1966 (mimeo.).
Childe, V. G., What Happened in History, Harmondsworth, 1942.
Chilver, E. M., ‘Nineteenth-Century Trade in the Bamenda Grassfields, Southern
Cameroons’, Afrika und Übersee, 45, 1961, pp. 233–258.
Cissoko, S. M., ‘Famines et épidémies à Tombouctou et dans la boucle du Niger du XVIe
au XVIIIe siècle’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 30, 1968, pp. 806–821.
Clark, J. D., ‘The Spread of Food Production in Sub-Saharan Africa’, Journal of African His-
tory, 3, 1962, pp. 211–228.
Clark, J. Desmond, The Prehistory of Africa, London, 1970.
Cohen, Abner, ‘The Social Organization of Credit in a West African Cattle Market’, Africa,
35, 1965a, pp. 8–20.
354 Bibliography
Gery, R., ‘Une industrie autochtone nigérienne: les sauniers du Manga’, Bulletin de l’IFAN,
B, 14, 1952, pp. 309–320.
Glanville, R. R., ‘Salt and the Salt Industry of the Northern Province’, Sierra Leone Studies,
16, 1930, pp. 52–56.
Goody, Jack, Technology, Tradition, and the State in Africa, London, 1971.
Goody, Jack, and Mustapha, T. M., ‘The Caravan Route from Kano to Salaga’, Journal of
the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1967, pp. 611–616.
Grandin, Capitaine, ‘Notes sur l’industrie et le commerce du sel au Kawar et en Agram’,
Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 13, 1951, pp. 488–533.
Green, M. M., Igbo Village Affairs, London, 1947.
Guèye, Youssouf, ‘Essai sur les causes et les conséquences de la micropropriété au Fouta-
Toro’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 19, 1957, pp. 28–42.
Halpern, Jan, ‘Traditional Economy in West Africa’, Africana Bulletin, 7, 1967, pp. 91–112.
Harris, Jack S., ‘Some Aspects of Slavery in South-Eastern Nigeria’, Journal of Negro History,
27, 1942, pp. 37–54.
Harris, Rosemary, ‘The Influence of Ecological Factors and External Relations on the
Mbembe Tribes of South-East Nigeria’, Africa, 32, 1962, pp. 38–52.
Havinden, M. A., ‘The History of Crop Cultivation in West Africa: A Bibliographical
Guide’, Economic History Review, 23, 1970, pp. 532–555.
Helleiner, Gerald K., ‘Typology in Development Theory: The Land Surplus Economy
(Nigeria)’, Food Research Institute Studies, 6, 1966, pp. 181–194.
Hill, Polly, ‘Some Characteristics of Indigenous West African Economic Enterprise’, Eco-
nomic Bulletin of Ghana, 6, 1962, pp. 3–14.
Hill, Polly, ‘Notes on Traditional Market Authority and Market Periodicity in West
Africa’, Journal of African History, 7, 1966a, pp. 295–311.
Hill, Polly, ‘Landlords and Brokers: A West African Trading System’, Cahiers d’Études Afri-
caines, 6, 1966b, pp. 349–366.
Hill, Polly, Studies in Rural Capitalism in West Africa, Cambridge, 1970.
Hiskett, E. M., ‘City of History: The Story of Kano’, West African Review, 28, 1957, pp.
849–856.
Hiskett, E. M., ‘Materials Relating to the Cowry Currency of the Western Sudan’, Bulletin
Of the School of Oriental and African Studies, 29, 1966, pp. 122–142; 339–366.
Hodder, B. W., ‘Some Comments on the Origins of Traditional Markets in Africa
South of the Sahara’, Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 36, 1965, pp.
97–105.
Hodder, B. W., ‘Some Comments on Markets and Market Periodicity’, in Markets and Mar-
keting in West Africa, Centre of African Studies, University of Edinburgh, Edinburgh,
1966 (mimeo.), pp. 97–106.
Hodder, B. W., and Ukwu, U. I., Markets in West Africa, Ibadan, 1969.
Holas, B., ‘Les peuplements de la Côte d’Ivoire’, Cahiers Charles de Foucauld, 35, 1954, pp.
49–69.
Holas, B., ‘Les poids à peser l’or’, Notes Africaines, 104, 1964, pp. 113–116.
Hopen, Edward C., The Pastoral Fulbe Family in Gwandu, London, 1958.
Hopkins, A. G., ‘Underdevelopment in the Empires of the Western Sudan’, Past & Present,
37, 1967, pp. 149–156
Horton, Robin, ‘The Ohu System of Slavery in a Northern Ibo Village-Group’, Africa, 24,
1954, pp. 311–336.
Horton, Robin, ‘African Traditional Thought and Western Science’, Africa, 37, 1967, pp.
50–71 and 155–187.
356 Bibliography
Lo, Capitaine, ‘Les foggaras du Tidikelt’, Travaux de l’Institut des Recherches Sahariennes, 10,
1953, pp. 139–179; 11, 1954, pp. 49–77.
Lombard, Jacques, ‘Aperçu sur la technologie et l’artisanat Bariba’, Études Dahoméennes, 18,
1957, pp. 5–60.
Lombard, Jacques, Structures de type ‘féodal’ en Afrique noire, Paris, 1965.
Lovejoy, Paul E., ‘Long-Distance Trade and Islam: The Case of the Nineteenth-Century
Hausa Kola Trade’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 5, 1971, pp. 537–547.
Mabogunje, Akin L., ‘Some Comments on Land Tenure in Egba Division, Western
Nigeria’, Africa, 31, 1961, pp. 258–269.
Malowist, M., ‘The Social and Economic Stability of the Western Sudan in the Middle
Ages’, Past & Present, 33, 1966, pp. 3–15.
Malowist, M., ‘Rejoiner’, Past & Present, 37, 1967, pp. 157–162.
Maquet, Jacques J., ‘A Research Definition of African Feudality’, Journal of African History,
3, 1962, pp. 307–310.
Mauny, Raymond, ‘Essai sur l’histoire des métaux en Afrique occidentale’, Bulletin de
l’IFAN, B, 14, 1952, pp. 543–595.
Mauny, Raymond, ‘La monnaie marginelloide de l’ouest africain’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B,
19, 1957, pp. 659–669.
Mauny, Raymond, ‘Anciens ateliers monétaires ouest-africains’, Notes Africaines, 78, 1958,
pp. 34–35.
Mauny, Raymond, Tableau géographique de l’ouest africain au moyen âge, Dakar, 1961.
McLoughlin, Peter F. M., ed., African Food Production Systems, Baltimore, 1970.
Meillassoux, Claude, ‘Essai d’interprétation du phénomène économique dans les sociétés
traditionnelles d’autosubsistence’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 4, 1960, pp. 38–67.
Meillassoux, Claude, ‘L’économie des échanges précoloniaux en pays Gouro’, Cahiers
d’Études Africaines, 3, 1963, pp. 551–576.
Meillassoux, Claude, Anthropologie économique des Gouro de Côte d’Ivoire, Paris, 1964.
Meillassoux, Claude, ed., The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa,
London, 1971.
Menzel, Brigitte, Goldweights from Ghana, Berlin, 1968.
Mercier, Paul, ‘Travail et service public dans l’ancien Dahomey’, Présence Africaine, 13,
1952, pp. 84–91.
Miège, J., ‘Les cultures vivrières en Afrique occidentale’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 7, 1954, pp.
25–50.
Miner, Horace M., The Primitive City of Timbuctoo, Princeton, 1953.
Miracle, Marvin P., ‘Interpretation of Evidence on the Introduction of Maize into West
Africa’, Africa, 33, 1963, pp. 132–135.
Miracle, Marvin P., ‘The Introduction and Spread of Maize in Africa’, Journal of African His-
tory, 6, 1965, pp. 39–55.
Morgan, W. B., ‘Agriculture in Southern Nigeria (Excluding the Cameroons)’, Economic
Geography, 35, 1959, pp. 138–150.
Morgan, W. B., ‘Peasant Agriculture in Tropical Africa’, in Environment and Land Use in
Africa, eds. M. F. Thomas and G. W. Whittington, London, 1969, pp. 241–271.
Morgan, W. B., and Pugh, J. C., West Africa, London, 1969.
Murdock, George Peter, Africa: Its Peoples and their Culture History, New York, 1959.
Nadel, S. F., A Black Byzantium, Oxford, 1942.
Netting, Robert McC., ‘Household Organisation and Intensive Agriculture: The Kofyar
Case’, Africa, 35, 1965a, pp. 422–428.
358 Bibliography
Netting, Robert McC., ‘A Trial Model of Cultural Ecology’, Anthropological Quarterly, 38,
1965b, pp. 81–96.
Netting, Robert McC., Hill Farmers of Nigeria, Seattle, 1968.
Niane, D. J., ‘Recherches sur l’empire du Mali au moyen âge’, Recherches Africaines, 1,
1959, pp. 35–46; 5, 1960, pp. 17–36; 9, 1961, pp. 31–51.
Niane, D. J., ‘Mise en place des populations de la Haut-Guinée’, Recherches Africaines, 5,
1960, pp. 40–53.
Niangoran-Bouah, Georges, ‘Poids à peser l’or’, Présence Africaine, 46, 1963, pp. 202–20.
Nicolaisen, Johannes, ‘Ecological and Historical Factors: A Case Study from the Ahaggar
Tuareg’, Folk, 6, 1964, pp. 75–81.
Nicolas, François-J., ‘Le bouracan ou bougran, tissu soudanais du moyen âge’, Anthropos,
53, 1958, pp. 265–268.
Nicolas, G., ‘Circulation des biens et échanges monétaires au nord Niger’, Cahiers de l’Insti-
tut de Science Économique Appliquée, Supplement 129, 5, 1962, pp. 49–62.
Oroge, E. A., The Institution of Slavery in Yorubaland with Particular Reference to the Nineteenth
Century, University of Birmingham, Ph.D. thesis, 1971.
Ott, A., ‘Historical Significance of Akan Gold Weights’, Transactions of the Historical Society
of Ghana, 9, 1968, pp. 17–42.
Pageard, R., ‘Note sur le peuplement de l’est du pays du Ségou’, Journal de la Société des
Africanistes, 31, 1961, pp. 83-90.
Palausi, G., ‘Un projet d’hydraulique fluviale soudanaise au XVe siècle: le canal de Soni-Ali’,
Notes Africaines, 78, 1958, pp. 47–9.
Perie, J., and Sellier, M., ‘Histoire des populations du cercle de Dosso’, Bulletin de l’IFAN,
B, 12, 1950, pp. 1015–1074.
Portères, Roland, ‘Vieilles agricultures de l’Afrique intertropicale’, Agronomie Tropicale, 5,
1950, pp. 489–507.
Portères, Roland, ‘L’introduction du maïs en Afrique’, Journal d’Agriculture Tropicale et de
Botanique Appliquée, 2, 1955, pp. 221–231.
Portères, Roland, ‘La monnaie de fer dans l’ouest-africain au XXe siècle’, Recherches Afri-
caines, 5, 1960, pp. 3–13.
Portères, Roland, ‘Berceaux agricoles primaires sur le continent africain’, Journal of African
History, 3, 1962, pp. 195–210.
Reyburn, William D., ‘Polygamy, Economy and Christianity in the Eastern Cameroun’,
Practical Anthropology, 6, 1959, pp. 1–19.
Riad, Mohammed, ‘The Jukun: An Example of African Migrations in the Sixteenth
Century’, Bulletin De l’IFAN, B, 22, 1960, pp. 476–485.
Richard-Molard, J., ‘Les densités de population au Fouta-Djallon’, Présence Africaine, 15,
1952, pp. 95–106.
Rougerie, Gabriel, ‘Lagunaires et terriens de la Côte d’Ivoire’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 3,
1950, pp. 370–377.
Schneider, Harold K., ‘A Model of African Indigenous Economy and Society’, Comparative
Studies in Society and History, 7, 1964, pp. 37–55.
Sellnow, Irmgard, ‘Die Stelling der Sklaven in der Hausa-Gesellschaft’, Mitteilungen des Insti-
tuts für Orientforschung, 10, 1964, pp. 85–102.
Skinner, Elliott P., The Mossi of the Upper Volta, Stanford, 1964a.
Skinner, Elliott P., ‘West African Economic Systems’, in Economic Transition in Africa, eds.
Melville J. Herskovits and Mitchell Harwitz, London, 1964b, pp. 77–97.
Smith, Michael G., ‘A Study of Hausa Domestic Economy in Northern Zaria’, Africa, 22,
1952, pp. 333–347.
Bibliography 359
Smith, Robert, ‘The Canoe in West African History’, Journal of African History, 11, 1970,
pp. 515–533.
Stanton, W. R., ‘The Analysis of the Present Distribution of Varietal Variation in Maize,
Sorghum and Cowpea in Nigeria as an Aid to the Study of Tribal Movement’, Journal of
African History, 3, 1962, pp. 251–262.
Stanton, W. R., and Willett, Frank, ‘Archaeological Evidence for Changes in Maize Type
in West Africa’, Man, 63, 1963, pp. 117–123.
Stenning, J., ‘Transhumance, Migratory Drift, Migration: Patterns of Pastoral Fulani
Nomadism’, Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, 87, 1957, pp. 57–73.
Stenning, J., Savannah Nomads, London, 1959.
Sundström, Lars, The Trade of Guinea, Lund, 1965.
Suret-Canale, Jean, ‘Les sociétés traditionnelles en Afrique tropicale et le concept de mode
de production asiatique’, La Pensée, 117, 1964, pp. 21–42.
Toupet, C., ‘La vallée de la Tamourt en Naaj: problèmes d’aménagement’, Bulletin de
l’IFAN, B, 20, 1958, pp. 68–110.
Tymowski, Michal, ‘Le Niger, voie de communication des grands états du Soudan occi-
dentale jusqu’à la fin du XVIe siècle’, Africana Bulletin, 6, 1967, pp. 73–95.
Tymowski, Michal, ‘La pêche à l’époque du moyen âge dans la boucle du Niger’, Africana
Bulletin, 12, 1970, pp. 7–26.
Ukwu, U. I., ‘The Development of Trade and Marketing in Iboland’, Journal of the Historical
Society of Nigeria, 3, 1967, pp. 647–662.
Verdier, Raymond, ‘Féodalités et collectivismes africains’, Présence Africaine, 39, 1961, pp.
79–101.
Wilks, Ivor, ‘A Medieval Trade-Route from the Niger to the Gulf of Guinea’, Journal of
African History, 3, 1962a, pp. 337–341.
Wilks, Ivor, The Northern Factor in Ashanti History, Legon, 1962b.
Willett, Frank, ‘The Introduction of Maize into West Africa: An Assessment of Recent
Evidence’, Africa, 32, 1962, pp. 1–13.
Wills, J. B., ed., Agriculture and Land Use in Ghana, Oxford, 1962.
Wrigley, Christopher, ‘Speculations on the Economic Pre-history of Africa’, Journal of Afri-
can History, 1, 1960, pp. 189–203.
Chapter 3
External trade: the Sahara and the Atlantic
Adu, Boahen A., Britain, the Sahara, and the Western Sudan, 1788–1861, 1964, Oxford.
Aguirre-Beltran, G., ‘Tribal Origins of Slaves in Mexico’, Journal of Negro History, 31, 1946,
pp. 269–352.
Akinjogbin, I. A., Dahomey and its Neighbours, 1708–1818, London, 1967.
Alagoa, E. J., ‘Long-distance Trade and States in the Niger Delta’, Journal of African History,
11, 1970, pp. 319–329.
Alagoa, E. J., ‘The Development of Institutions in the States of the Eastern Niger Delta’,
Journal of African History, 12, 1971, pp. 269–278.
Anstey, Roger T., ‘Capitalism and Slavery: A Critique’, Economic History Review, 21, 1968,
pp. 307–320.
Ardener, Edwin, ‘Documentary and Linguistic Evidence for the Rise of the Trading Pol-
ities between Rio Del Rey and Cameroons, 1500–1650’, in History and Social Anthropol-
ogy, ed. I. M. Lewis, London, 1968, pp. 81–126.
360 Bibliography
Arhin, K., ‘The Financing of Ashanti Expansion, 1700–1820’, Africa, 37, 1967, pp.
283–291.
Arnold, Rosemary, ‘A Port of Trade: Whydah on the Guinea Coast’, in Trade and Market in the
Early Empires, eds. K. Polanyi, C. M. Arensberg, and H. Pearson, Glencoe, 1957, pp. 154–
176.
Arnold, Rosemary, ‘Separation of Trade and Market: Great Market of Whydah’, in Trade
and Market in the Early Empires, eds. K. Polanyi, C. M. Arensberg, and H. Pearson, Glen-
coe, 1957, pp. 177–187.
Bénard, J. Cl., ‘L’armement honfleurais et le commerce des esclaves à la fin du XVIIIe
siècle’, Annales de Normandie, 10, 1960, pp. 249–264.
Bennett, Norman Robert, ‘Christian and Negro Slavery in Eighteenth-Century North
Africa’, Journal of African History, 1, 1960, pp. 65–82
Berbain, Simone, Le comptoir français de Juda (Ouidah) au XVIIIe siècle, Paris, 1942.
Bethel, Leslie, ‘The Mixed Commissions for the Suppression of the Transatlantic Slave
Trade in the Nineteenth Century’, Journal of African History, 7, 1966, pp. 79–93.
Blake, J. W., European Beginnings in West Africa, 1454–1578, London, 1937.
Bolt, Christine, The Anti-Slavery Movement and Reconstruction, Oxford, 1969.
Booth, Alan R., ‘The United States African Squadron, 1843–1861’, Boston University Papers
in African History, 1, 1964, pp. 79–117.
Bovill, E. W., The Golden Trade of the Moors, 2nd ed., London, 1968.
Brown, George W., ‘The Origins of Abolition in Santo Domingo’, Journal of Negro History,
7, 1922, pp. 365–376.
Brunschwig, Henri, ‘La troque et la traite’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 2, 1962, pp. 339–346.
Centre of African Studies, The Transatlantic Slave Trade from West Africa, Edinburgh, 1965
(mimeo.).
Checkland, S. G., ‘American Versus West Indian Traders in Liverpool, 1793–1815’, Journal
of Economic History, 18, 1958, pp. 141–160.
Checkland, S. G., ‘Finance for the West Indies, 1780–1815’, Economic History Review, 10,
1958, pp. 461–469.
Chiché, Marie-Claire, Hygiène et santé à bord des navires négriers au XVIIIe siècle, Paris, 1957.
Chilver, E. M., and Kaberry, P. M., ‘Sources of the Nineteenth-Century Slave Trade:
Two Comments’, Journal of African History, 6, 1965, pp. 117–120.
Coupland, R., The British Anti-Slavery Movement, London, 1933.
Curtin, Philip D., Africa Remembered: Narratives by West Africans from the Era of the Slave
Trade, Madison, 1967.
Curtin, Philip D., ‘Epidemiology and the Slave Trade’, Political Science Quarterly, 83, 1968,
pp. 190–216.
Curtin, Philip D., The Atlantic Slave Trade: A Census, Madison, 1969.
Curtin, Philip D., and Vansina, Jan, ‘Sources of the Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Slave
Trade’, Journal of African History, 5, 1964, pp. 185–208.
Daaku, K. Y., Trade and Politics on the Gold Coast, 1600–1720, Oxford, 1970.
Daget, Serge, ‘L’abolition de la traite des noirs en France de 1814 à 1831’, Cahiers d’Études
Africaines, 11, 1971, pp. 14–58.
Davidson, Basil, Black Mother: The Years of the African Slave Trade, London, 1961.
Davies, K. G., The Royal African Company, London, 1957.
Davis, David B., ‘James Cropper and the British Anti-Slavery Movement, 1821–1823’,
Journal of Negro History, 45, 1960, pp. 241–258.
Davis, David B., ‘James Cropper and the British Anti-Slavery Movement, 1823–1833’,
Journal of Negro History, 46, 1961, pp. 154–173.
Bibliography 361
Hyde, F. E., Parkinson, B. B., and Marriner, S., ‘The Nature and Profitability of the Liver-
pool Slave Trade’, Economic History Review, 5, 1953, pp. 368–377.
Jobson, R., The Golden Trade or the Discovery of the River Gambra, London, 1968.
Johnson, Marion, ‘The Ounce in Eighteenth-Century West African Trade’, Journal of Afri-
can History, 7, 1966, pp. 197–214.
Johnson, Vera M., ‘Sidelights on the Liverpool Slave Trade, 1789–1807’, Mariner’s Mirror,
38, 1952, pp. 276–293.
Jones, G. I., ‘Native and Trade Currencies in Southern Nigeria during the Eighteenth and
Nineteenth Centuries’, Africa, 28, 1958, pp. 43–54.
Jore, Léonce, ‘Les établissements français sur la côte occidentale d’Afrique de 1758 à 1803’,
Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 51, 1964, pp. 7–477.
Karpinski, R., ‘Considérations sur les échanges de caractère local et extérieure de la Séné-
gambie dans la deuxième moitié du XVe et au début du XVIe siècle’, Africana Bulletin,
8, 1968, pp. 65–83.
Kleist, Alice M., ‘The English African Trade under the Tudors’, Transactions of the Historical
Society of Ghana, 3, 1957, pp. 137–150.
Klingberg, Frank J., The Anti-Slavery Movement in England, New Haven, 1926.
Kup, A. P., ‘Early Portuguese Trade in the Sierra Leone and Great Searcies Rivers’, Boletim
Cultural da Guiné Portuguesa, 18, 1963, pp. 107–124.
Lacroix, Louis, Les Derniers Négriers, Paris, 1952.
Latham, A. J. H., Old Calabar, 1600–1891: The Economic Impact of the West upon
a Traditional Society, University of Birmingham, Ph.D. thesis, 1970.
Laufry, J., ‘Chronique de ghadames’, Ibla, 32, 1945, pp. 367–385; 33, 1946, pp. 343–371.
Law, R. C. C., ‘The Garamantes and Trans-Saharan Enterprise in Classical Times’, Journal
of African History, 8, 1967, pp. 181–200.
Levy, Claude, ‘Slavery and the Emancipation Movement in Barbados, 1650–1833’, Journal
of Negro History, 55, 1970, pp. 1–14.
Lewicki, Tadeusz, ‘L’état nord-africain de Tahert et ses relations avec le Soudan occi-
dentale à la fin de VIIIe et au IXe siècle’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 2, 1962, pp.
513–535.
Lewicki, Tadeusz, ‘Traits d’histoire du commerce trans-saharien’, Etnograia Polska, 3, 1964,
pp. 291–311.
Lewicki, Tadeusz, ‘Arab Trade in Negro Slaves up to the End of the XVIth Century’, Afri-
cana Bulletin, 6, 1967, pp. 109–111.
Lhote, H., ‘Note sur l’origine des lames d’épées des Touaregs’, Notes Africaines de l’Institut
Français d’Afrique Noire, 61, 1954, pp. 9–12.
Lloyd, Christopher, The Navy and the Slave Trade, London, 1949.
Ly, Abdoulaye, La compagnie du Sénégal, Paris, 1958.
Malowist, Marian, ‘Le commerce d’or et d’esclaves au Soudan occidentale’, Africana Bul-
letin, 4, 1966, pp. 49–72.
Malowist, Marian, ‘Les fondemonts de l’expansion européenne en Afrique au XVe
siècle; Europe, Maghreb et Soudan occidentale’, Acta Poloniae Historica, 18, 1968, pp.
156–179.
Malowist, Marian, ‘Les débuts du système de plantations dans la période des Grandes
Découvertes’, Africana Bulletin, 10, 1969, pp. 9–130.
Manning, Patrick, ‘Slaves, Palm Oil and Political Power on the West African Coast’, African
Historical Studies, 2, 1969, pp. 279–288.
Mannix, Daniel P., and Cowley, Malcolm, Black Cargoes, London, 1962.
Marshall, Peter, The Anti-Slave Trade Movement in Bristol, Bristol, 1968.
Bibliography 363
Martin, Gaston, Nantes au XVIIIe siècle: lère des négriers (1714–44), Paris, 1931.
Martin, Gaston, Histoire de l’esclavage dans les colonies françaises, Paris, 1948.
Mason, Michael, ‘Population Density and “Save Raiding”: The Case of the Middle Belt of
Nigeria’, Journal of African History, 10, 1969, pp. 551–564.
Mason, Michael, ‘Reply’, Journal of African History, 12, 1971, pp. 324–327.
Mathieson, W. L., Great Britain and the Slave Trade, 1839–1865, London, 1929.
Maugat, M. E., ‘La traite clandestine à Nantes au XIXe siècle’, Bulletin de la Société Archéolo-
gique et Historique de Nantes et de la Loire-Inférieure, 93, 1954, pp. 162–9.
Mauny, Raymond, Les navigations médiévals sur les côtes sahariennes antérieures à la découverte
portugaise (1434), Lisbon, 1960.
Mauny, Raymond, Tableau géographique de l’ouest africain au moyen âge, Dakar, 1961.
Merritt, J. E., The Liverpool Slave Trade from 1789 to 1791, University of Nottingham, M.
A. thesis, 1959.
Merritt, J. E., ‘The Triangular Trade’, Business History, 3, 1960, pp. 1–7.
Meyer, J., ‘Le commerce négrier nantais (1774–1792)’, Annales, 15, 1960, pp. 120–129.
Meyer, J., ‘Du nouveau sur le commerce négrier nantais du XVIIIe siècle’, Annales de Bre-
tagne, 2, 1966, pp. 229–239.
Minchinton, W. E., ‘The Voyage of the Snow Africa’, Mariner’s Mirror, 37, 1951, pp.
187–196.
Monod, T., ‘Le Rev. John Newton: matelot, négrier et pasteur’, Notes Africaines, 89, 1961,
pp. 18–23.
Morton-Williams, Peter, ‘The Oyo Yoruba and the Atlantic Trade, 1690–1830’, Journal of
the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1964, pp. 25–45.
Morton-Williams, Peter, ‘The Influence of Habitat and Trade on the Politics of Oyo and
Ashanti’, in Man in Africa, eds. Mary Douglas and Phyllis M. Kaberry, London, 1969,
pp. 79–98.
Mousnier, J., ed., Journal de la traite des noirs, Paris, 1957.
Pearsall, A. W. H., ‘Sierra Leone and the Suppression of the Slave Trade’, Sierra Leone Stud-
ies, 12, 1959, pp. 211–229.
Polanyi, Karl, ‘Sortings and “Ounce Trade” in the West African Slave Trade’, Journal of
African History, 5, 1964, pp. 381–393.
Polanyi, Karl, Dahomey and the Slave Trade, Seattle and London, 1966.
Porter, Dale H., The Abolition of the Slave Trade in England, 1784–1807, Hampden, 1970.
Porter, R., ‘The Crispe Family and the African Trade in the Seventeenth Century’, Journal
of African History, 9, 1968, pp. 57–77.
Porter, R., ‘English Chief Factors in the Gold Coast, 1632–1753’, African Historical Studies,
1, 1968, pp. 199–209.
Priestley, Margaret, West African Trade and Coast Society, Oxford, 1969.
Richardson, P. D., The Bristol Slave Trade in the Eighteenth Century, University of
Manchester, M.A. thesis, 1969.
Rinchon, Père D., ‘Les armements négriers au XVIIIe siècle’, Académie Royale des Sciences
Coloniales Mémoires, 7, 1956, pp. 1–178.
Rinchon, Père D., Pierre-Ignace-Liévin van Alstein, capitaine négrier, Dakar, 1964.
Rodney, Walter, ‘Portuguese Attempts at Monopoly on the Upper Guinea Coast,
1580–1650’, Journal of African History, 6, 1965, pp. 307–322.
Rodney, Walter, ‘African Slavery and Other Forms of Social Oppression on the Upper
Guinea Coast, in the Context of the Atlantic Slave Trade’, Journal of African History, 7,
1966, pp. 431–443.
364 Bibliography
Rodney, Walter, West Africa and the Atlantic Slave Trade, Historical Association of Tanzania,
Dar es Salaam, 1967.
Rodney, Walter, ‘Gold and Slaves on the Gold Coast’, Transactions of the Historical Society of
Ghana, 10, 1969, pp. 13–28.
Rodney, Walter, ‘Upper Guinea and the Significance of the Origins of Africans Enslaved
in the New World’, Journal of Negro History, 54, 1969, pp. 327–345.
Rodney, Walter, A History of the Upper Guinea Coast, 1545–1800, Oxford, 1970.
Ronen, Dov, ‘On the African Role in the Trans-Atlantic Slave Trade in Dahomey’, Cahiers
d’Études Africaines, 11, 1971, pp. 5–13.
Ryder, A. F. C., ‘The Re-establishment of Portuguese Factories on the Costa Da Mina to the
Mid-Eighteenth Century’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 1, 1958, pp. 157–181.
Ryder, A. F. C., ‘An Early Portuguese Trading Voyage to the Forcados River’, Journal of
the Historical Society of Nigeria, 1, 1959, pp. 294–321.
Ryder, A. F. C., ‘Dutch Trade on the Nigerian Coast during the Seventeenth Century’,
Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1965, pp. 195–210.
Ryder, A. F. C., Benin and the Europeans, 1485–1897, London, 1969.
Seeber, Edward D., Anti-Slavery Opinion in France during the Second Half of the Eighteenth
Century, Baltimore, 1937.
Sheridan, R. B., ‘The Commercial and Financial Organization of the British Slave Trade,
1750–1807’, Economic History Review, 11, 1958, 249–263.
Sheridan, R. B., ‘The Plantation Revolution and the Industrial Revolution, 1625–1775’,
Caribbean Studies, 9, 1969, pp. 5–25.
Suret-Canale, Jean, ‘Contente et conséquences sociales de la traite africaine’, Présence Afri-
caine, 50, 1964, pp. 127–150.
Thornton, A. P., ‘The Organization of the Slave Trade in the English West Indies,
1660–1685’, William and Mary Quarterly, 12, 1955, pp. 399–409.
Trepp, Jean, ‘The Liverpool Movement for the Abolition of the English Slave Trade’, Jour-
nal of Negro History, 13, 1928, pp. 265–285.
Valensi, L., ‘Esclaves chrétiens et esclaves noirs à Tunis au XVIIIe siècle’, Annales, 22, 1967,
pp. 1267–1288.
Verger, Pierre, Bahia and the West Coast Trade (1549–1851), Ibadan, 1964.
Verger, Pierre, ‘Rôle joué par le tabac de Bahia dans la traite des esclaves au Golfe de
Bénin’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 4, 1964, pp. 349–369.
Verger, Pierre, ‘Mouvements de navires entre Bahia et le golfe de Bénin (XVIIIe– XIXe
siècles)’, Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 55, 1968, pp. 5–36.
Verger, Pierre, Flux et reflux de la traite des nègres entre le golfe de Bénin et Bahia de Todos os
Santos du 17e et au 19e siècle, Paris and the Hague, 1968.
Vidalenc, Jean, ‘La traite des nègres en France au début de la Révolution (1789–1793)’,
Annales Historiques de la Révolution Française, 29, 1957, pp. 56–69.
Ward, W. E. F., The Royal Navy and the Slavers, New York, 1969.
Williams, Eric, Capitalism and Slavery, 2nd ed., London, 1964.
Wrigley, C. C., ‘Historicism in Africa: Slavery and State Formation’, African Affairs, 70,
1971, pp. 115–123.
Wurie, A., ‘The Bundukas of Sierra Leone’, Sierra Leone Studies, 1, 1953, pp. 14–25.
Wyndham, H. A., The Atlantic and Slavery, London, 1935.
Wyndham, H. A., The Atlantic and Emancipation, London, 1937.
Zerbo, G. K., ‘L’économie de traite en Afrique noire ou le pillage organisé (XVe–XXe siè-
cles)’, Présence Africaine, 11, 1956–57, pp. 7–31.
Bibliography 365
Chapter 4
The economic basis of imperialism
Aderibigbe, A. B., ‘Trade and British Expansion in the Lagos Area in the Second Half of the
Nineteenth Century’, Nigerian Journal of Economic and Social Studies, 4, 1962, pp. 188–195.
Ajayi, J. F. A., ‘The British Occupation of Lagos, 1851–61: A Critical Review’, Nigeria
Magazine, 69, 1961, pp. 96–105.
Akintoye, S. A., ‘The Economic Background of the Ekitiparapo, 1878–1893’, Odu, 4,
1968, pp. 30–52.
Amenumery, D. E. K., ‘The Extension of British Rule to Anlo (South-east Ghana),
1850–1890’, Journal of African History, 9, 1968, pp. 99–117.
Amenumery, D. E. K., ‘Gerado de Lima: A Reappraisal’, Transactions of the Historical Society
of Ghana, 9, 1968, pp. 65–78.
Andrew, C. M., and Kanya-Forstner, A. S., ‘The French “Colonial Party”: Its Compos-
ition, Aims and Influence, 1885–1914’, The Historical Journal, 14, 1971, pp. 99–128.
Anjorin, A. O., ‘European Attempts to Develop Cotton Cultivation in West Africa,
1850–1910’, Odu, 3, 1966, pp. 3–15.
Arhin, K., ‘The Structure of Greater Ashanti’, Journal of African History, 8, 1967, pp. 65–85.
Atger, Paul, La France en Côte d’Ivoire de 1843 à 1893, Dakar, 1962.
Austen, Ralph A., ‘The Abolition of the Overseas Slave Trade: A Distorted Theme in
West African History’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 5, 1970, pp. 257–274.
Awe, B., ‘The Ajele System: A Study of Ibadan Imperialism in the 19th Century’, Journal of
the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1964, pp. 43–60.
Baillet, Emile, ‘La rôle de la marine de commerce dans l’implantation de la France en A.O.
F.’, Revue Maritime, 135, 1957, pp. 832–840.
Bennett, Norman R., and Brooks, George E., eds., New England Merchants in Africa:
A History through Documents, 1802 to 1865, Boston, 1965.
Bevin, H. J., ‘The Gold Coast Economy about 1880’, Transactions of the Gold Coast and
Togoland Historical Society, 2, 1956, pp. 73–86.
Bevin, H. J., ‘M. J. Bonnat: Trader and Mining Promoter’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 4,
1960, pp. 1–12.
Brooks, George E., ‘American Trade as a Factor in West African History in the Early
Nineteenth Century: Senegal and the Gambia, 1815–1835’, in Western African History,
eds., Daniel F. McCall, Norman R. Bennett, and Jeffrey Butler, New York, 1969, pp.
132–152.
Brooks, George E., Yankee Traders, Old Coasters and African Middlemen: A History of American
Legitimate Trade with West Africa in the Nineteenth Century, Boston, 1970.
Brunschwig, Henri, French Colonialism, 1871–1914: Myths and Realities, London, 1966.
Centre of African Studies, The Theory of Imperialism and the European Partition of Africa, Edin-
burgh, 1967 (mimeo.).
Chamberlain, M. E., ‘Lord Aberdare and the Royal Niger Company’, Welsh History
Review, 3, 1966, pp. 45–62.
Charpy, Jacques, La fondation de Dakar, Paris, 1958.
Clinton, J. V., ‘King Eyo Honesty II of Creek Town’, Nigeria Magazine, 69, 1961, pp.
182–188.
Coquery-Vidrovitch, Catherine, ‘Le blocus de Whydah (1876–1877) et la rivalité franco-
anglaise au Dahomey’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 2, 1962, pp. 373–419.
Davies, P. N., ‘The African Steam Ship Company’, in Liverpool and Merseyside, ed.
J. R. Harris, London, 1969, pp. 212–238.
366 Bibliography
Désiré-Vuillemin, Geneviève, ‘Un commerce qui meurt: la traite de la gomme dans les
escales du Sénégal’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 5, 1952, pp. 90–94.
Dessertine, A., ‘Naissance d’un port: Kaolack, des origines à 1900’, Annales Africaines, 7,
1960, pp. 225–259.
Dickson, K. B., ‘Evolution of Seaports in Ghana: 1800–1928’, Annals of the Association of
American Geographers, 55, 1965, pp. 98–111.
Dike, K. O., Trade and Politics in the Niger Delta, 1830–1885, Oxford, 1956.
Dumett, R. A., British Official Attitudes to Economic Development on the Gold Coast,
1874–1905, University of London, Ph.D. thesis, 1966.
Fage, J. D., A History of West Africa: An Introduction, Cambridge, 1969
Flint, J. E., Sir George Goldie and the Making of Nigeria, London, 1960.
Foster, C. J., ‘The Colonization of Free Negroes in Liberia, 1816–35’, Journal of Negro His-
tory, 38, 1953, pp. 41–67.
Fyfe, Christopher H., ‘The Life and Times of John Ezzidio’, Sierra Leone Studies, 4, 1955,
pp. 213–223.
Fyfe, Christopher H., ‘Four Sierra Leone Recaptives’, Journal of African History, 2, 1961, pp.
77–85.
Fyfe, Christopher H., A History of Sierra Leone, Oxford, 1962.
Ganier, G., ‘Lat Dyor et le chemin de fer de l’arachide (1876–1886)’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B,
27, 1965, pp. 223–281.
Gertzel, Cherry J., John Holt: A British Merchant in West Africa in the Era of Imperialism, Uni-
versity of Oxford, D. Phil. thesis, 1959.
Gertzel, Cherry J., ‘Relations between African and European Traders in the Niger Delta,
1880–1896’, Journal of African History, 3, 1962, pp. 361–366.
Gertzel, Cherry J., ‘Commercial Organisation on the Niger Coast, 1852–1891’, in Histor-
ians in Tropical Africa, ed. E. T. Stokes, Salisbury, Rhodesia, 1962, pp. 289–304.
Gifford, Prosser, and Louis, William R., Britain and Germany in Africa: Imperial, Rivalry and
Colonial Rule, New Haven, 1967.
Hargreaves, J. D., ‘Towards a History of the Partition of Africa’, Journal of African History, 1,
1960, pp. 97–109.
Hargreaves, J. D., Prelude to the Partition of West Africa, London, 1963.
Hargreaves, J. D., ‘African Colonization in the Nineteenth Century: Liberia and Sierra
Leone’, Boston University Papers in African History, 1, 1964, pp. 57–76.
Hargreaves, J. D., ‘West African States and the European Conquest’, in Colonialism in
Africa, 1870–1960, eds. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan, Vol. 1, The History and Politics
of Colonialism, 1870–1914, Cambridge, 1969, pp. 199–219.
Hieke, E., G.L. Gaiser: Hamburg—Westfrika, Hamburg, 1949.
Hopkins, A. G., ‘Richard Beale Blaize, 1854–1904: Merchant Prince of West Africa’,
Tarikh, 1, 1966, pp. 70–79.
Hopkins, A. G., ‘The Currency Revolution in South-West Nigeria in the Late Nineteenth
Century’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1966, pp. 471–483.
Hopkins, A. G., ‘Economic Imperialism in West Africa: Lagos, 1880–92’, Economic History
Review, 21, 1968, pp. 580–606.
Horton, Robin, ‘From Fishing Village to City State: A Social History of New Calabar’, in
Man in Africa, eds. Mary Douglas and Phyllis M. Kaberry, London, 1969, pp. 37–58.
Howard, Allen, ‘The Role of Freetown in the Commercial Life of Sierra Leone’, in Freetown:
A Symposium, eds. Christopher Fyfe and Eldred Jones, Freetown, 1968, pp. 38–64.
Hoyt, Joseph B., ‘Salem’s West Africa Trade, 1835–1863, and Captain Victor Francis
Debaker’, Essex Institute Historical Collections, 102, 1966, pp. 37–73.
Bibliography 367
Igbafe, Philip A., ‘The Fall of Benin: A Reassessment’, Journal of African History, 11, 1970,
pp. 385–400.
Ijagbemi, E. A., ‘The Freetown Colony and the Development of “Legitimate” Com-
merce in the Adjoining Territories’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 5, 1970,
pp. 243–256.
Ikime, Obaro, Merchant Prince of the Niger Delta, London, 1968.
Johnson, Marion, ‘Migrants’ Progress’, Bulletin of the Ghana Geographical Association, 9,
1964, 4–27 and 10, 1965, pp. 13–40.
Johnson, Marion, ‘The Cowrie Currencies of West Africa’, Journal of African History, 11,
1970, pp. 331–353.
Jones, G. I., The Trading States of the Oil Rivers, Oxford, 1963.
Kanya-Forstner, A. S., The Conquest of the Western Sudan: A Study in French Military Imperial-
ism, Cambridge, 1969.
Klein, Martin A., Islam and Imperialism in Senegal, Edinburgh, 1968.
Klein, Martin A., ‘Slavery, the Slave Trade, and Legitimate Commerce in Late
Nineteenth-Century Africa’, Études d’Histoire Africaine, 2, 1971, pp. 5–28.
Kopytoff, Jean Herskovits., A Preface to Modern Nigeria: The Sierra Leoneans in Yoruba,
1830–1890, Madison, 1965.
Laffey, John F., ‘The Roots of French Imperialism in the Nineteenth Century: The Case
of Lyon’, French Historical Studies, 6, 1969, pp. 78–92.
Latham, A. J. H., Old Calabar, 1600–1891: The Economic Impact of the West upon
a Traditional Society, University of Birmingham, Ph.D. thesis, 1970.
Limberg, L., ‘The Economy Of The Fanti Confederation’, Transactions of the Historical Soci-
ety of Ghana, 11, 1970, pp. 83–103.
Lloyd, P. C., ‘The Isekiri in the Nineteenth Century: An Outline Social History’, Journal of
African History, 4, 1963, pp. 207–231.
Mabogunje, Akin L., ‘Some Comments on Land Tenure in Egba Division, Western
Nigeria’, Africa, 31, 1961, pp. 258–269.
Mahoney, F., ‘Notes on Mulattoes of the Gambia before the Mid-19th Century’, Transac-
tions of the Historical Society of Ghana, 8, 1965, pp. 120–129.
Manning, Patrick, ‘Some Export Statistics for Nigeria, 1880–1905’, Nigerian Journal of Eco-
nomic and Social Studies, 9, 1967, 229–234.
Manning, Patrick, An Economic History of Southern Dahomey, 1880–1914, University of Wis-
consin, Ph.D. thesis, 1969.
McIntyre, W. D., The Imperial Frontier in the Tropics, 1863–1873, London, 1967.
McPhee, Allan, The Economic Revolution in British West Africa, London, 1926.
Mitchell, P. K., ‘Trade Routes of the Early Sierra Leone Protectorate’, Sierra Leone Studies,
16, 1962, pp. 204–217.
Newbury, C. W., ‘The Development of French Policy on the Lower and Upper Niger,
1880–98’, Journal of Modern History, 31, 1959, pp. 16–26.
Newbury, C. W., The Western Slave Coast and Its Rulers, Oxford, 1961.
Newbury, C. W., ‘North African and Western Sudan Trade in the Nineteenth Century: A
Re-evaluation’, Journal of African History, 7, 1966, pp. 233–246.
Newbury, C. W., ‘The Protectionist Revival in French Colonial Trade: The Case of
Senegal’, Economic History Review, 21, 1968, pp. 337–348.
Newbury, C. W., ‘Trade and Authority in West Africa from 1850 to 1880’, in Colonialism
in Africa, 1870–1960, eds. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan, Vol. 1, The History and Politics
of Colonialism, 1870–1914, Cambridge, 1969, pp. 66–99.
368 Bibliography
Newbury, C. W., ‘The Tariff Factor in Anglo-French West African Partition’, in France
and Britain in Africa: Imperial Rivalry and Colonial Rule, eds. Prosser Gifford and William
R. Louis, New Haven, 1971, pp. 221–259.
Newbury, C. W., ‘Credit in Early Nineteenth-Century West African Trade’, Journal of Afri-
can History, 13, 1972, pp. 81–95.
Newbury, C. W., and Kanya-Forstner, A. S., ‘French Policy and the Origins of the Scram-
ble for West Africa’, Journal of African History, 10, 1969, pp. 253–276.
Pasquier, Roger, ‘En marge de la guerre de sécession: les essais de culture du coton au
Sénégal’, Annales Africaines, 2, 1955, pp. 185–202.
Pasquier, Roger, ‘En marge du centenaire de Dakar; Bordeaux et les débuts de la navigation
à vapeur vers le Brésil’, Revue Historique de Bordeaux et du Département de la Gironde, 4,
1957, pp. 219–237.
Pasquier, Roger, ‘Villes du Sénégal au XIXe siècle’, Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer,
47, 1960, pp. 387–426.
Pasquier, Roger, ‘A propos de l’émancipation des esclaves au Sénégal en 1848’, Revue Fran-
çaise d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 54, 1967, pp. 188–208.
Pearson, Scott R., ‘The Economie Imperialism of the Royal Niger Company’, Food
Research Institute Studies, 10, 1971, pp. 69–88.
Person, Yves, ‘Samori et la Sierra Leone’, Cahiers d’Etudes Africaines, 7, 1967, pp. 5–26.
Robinson, Ronald, and Gallagher, John, with Alice Denny, Africa and the Victorians,
London, 1961.
Ross, David A., ‘The Career of Domingo Martinez in the Bight of Benin, 1833–64’, Journal
of African History, 6, 1965, pp. 79–90.
Schnapper, Bernard, ‘La fin du régime de l’exclusif, le commerce étranger dans les
possessions françaises d’Afrique tropicale (1817–1870)’, Annales Africaines, 6, 1959,
pp. 149–200.
Schnapper, Bernard, La politique et le commerce français dans le Golfe de Guinée de 1838 à 1871,
Paris, 1961.
Stilliard, N. H., The Rise and Development of Legitimate Trade in Palm Oil with West Africa,
University of Birmingham, M.A. thesis, 1938.
Swanzy, Henry, ‘A Trading Family in the Nineteenth-Century Gold Coast’, Transactions of
the Gold Coast and Togoland Historical Society, 2, 1956, pp. 87–120.
Thompson, William, Glasgow and Africa: Connexions and Attitudes, 1870–1900, University
of Strathclyde, Ph.D. thesis, 1970.
Vignes, K., ‘Étude sur la rivalité d’influence entre les puissances européennes en Afrique
équatoriale et occidentale depuis l’acte général de Berlin jusqu’au seuil du XXe siècle’,
Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 48, 1961, pp. 5–95.
von Strandmann, Hartmut Pogge, ‘Germany’s Colonial Expansion under Bismarck’, Past &
Present, 42, 1969, pp. 140–159.
Webster, J. B., ‘The Bible and the Plough’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 2, 1963,
pp. 418–434.
Wehler, Hans-Ulrich, ‘Bismarck’s Imperialism, 1862–1890’, Past & Present, 48, 1970, pp.
131–139.
Wilks, Ivor, ‘Ashanti Government’, in West African Kingdoms in the Nineteenth Century, eds.
Daryll Forde and P. M. Kaberry, London, 1967, pp. 206–238.
Wilks, Ivor, ‘Asante Policy Towards Hausa Trade in the Nineteenth Century’, in The
Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa, ed. Claude Meillassoux,
London, 1971, pp. 124–141.
Bibliography 369
Wolfson, Freda, ‘A Price Agreement on the Gold Coast:The Krobo Oil Boycott,
1858–1866’, Economic History Review, 6, 1953, pp. 68–77.
Wright, E. J., ‘Remarks on the Early Monetary Position in Sierra Leone, with
a Description of the Coinage Adopted’, Sierra Leone Studies, 3, 1954, pp. 136–146.
Wurie, A., ‘The Bundukas of Sierra Leone’, Sierra Leone Studies, 1, 1953, pp. 14–25.
Wylie, Kenneth C., ‘Innovation and Change in Mende Chieftaincy, 1880–96’, Journal of
African History, 10, 1969, pp. 295–307.
Zucarelli, François, ‘L’entrepôt fictif de Gorée entre 1822 et 1852’, Annales Africaines, 6,
1959, pp. 261–282.
Zucarelli, François, ‘Le recrutement des travailleurs sénégalais par l’état indépendant du
Congo (1888–1896)’, Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 47, 1960, pp. 475–481.
Chapter 5
An economic model of colonialism
Baldwin, R. E., ‘Patterns of Development in Newly Settled Regions’, Manchester School of
Economic and Social Studies, 24, 1956, pp. 161–179.
Bateman, M. J., ‘Aggregate and Regional Supply Functions for Ghanaian Cocoa,
1946–62’, Journal of Farm Economics, 47, 1965, pp. 384–401.
Beckford, G. L. F., ‘Secular Fluctuations in the Growth of Tropical Agricultural Trade’,
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 13, 1964, pp. 80–94.
Berg, Elliot J., ‘Real Income Trends in West Africa, 1939–1960’, in Economic Transition in
Africa, eds. Melville J. Herskovits and Mitchell Harwitz, London, 1964, pp. 199–238.
Bertrand, Raymond, ‘Construction et emploi d’un indice du rapport d’échange pour
l’Afrique occidentale française’, Revue Économique, 7, 1956, pp. 280–307.
Board of Trade, Statistical Abstract for the British Empire, London, 1889–1913, 1924–38.
Board of Trade, Statistical Abstract for the British Commonwealth, London, 1936–47.
Board of Trade, Statistical Abstract for the Commonwealth and the Sterling Area, London,
1947–60.
Cox-George, N. A., Finance and Development in West Africa, London, 1961.
Crowder, Michael, ‘West Africa and the 1914–1918 War’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 30, 1968,
pp. 227–245.
Dalton, George, ‘History, Politics and Economic Development in Liberia’, Journal of Eco-
nomic History, 25, 1965, pp. 569–591.
Durand, H., Essai sur la conjoncture de l’Afrique noire, Paris, 1957.
Helleiner, Gerald K., Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria,
Homewood, 1966.
Higgins, B. H., ‘The Dualistic Theory of Underdeveloped Areas’, Economic Development and
Cultural Change, 4, 1955, pp. 99–115.
Hymer, Stephen H., ‘The Political Economy of the Gold Coast and Ghana’, in Government
and Economic Development, ed. G. Ranis, New Haven, 1971, pp. 129–180.
Jones, William O., and Merat, Christian, ‘Consumption of Exotic Consumer Goods as an
Indicator of Economic Achievement in Ten Countries of Tropical Africa’, Food Research
Institute Studies, 3, 1962, pp. 35–60.
Lawson, Rowena M., Statistical Yearbook of the League of Nations, London, 1930–44.
Lawson, Rowena M., International Trade Statistics, London, 1931–38.
Lawson, Rowena M., ‘Engel’s Law and its Application to Ghana’, Economic Bulletin of
Ghana, 5, 1962, pp. 34–46.
League of Nations, International Statistical Yearbook, London, 1926–1927, 1929.
370 Bibliography
Chapter 6
Completing the open economy
Adomakoh, Albert, ‘The History of Currency and Banking in Some West African
Countries’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 7, 1963, pp. 3–17.
Akinola, R. A., ‘The Growth and Development of Ibadan: The Largest Yoruba Town’,
Bulletin of the Ghana Geographical Association, 2, 1966, pp. 48–63.
Ayorinde, J. A., ‘Historical Notes on the Introduction and Development of the Cocoa
Industry in Nigeria’, Nigerian Agricultural Journal, 3, 1966, pp. 18–23.
Bauer, P. T., West African Trade, Cambridge, London, 1954.
Bayly, Winder R., ‘The Lebanese in West Africa’, Comparative Studies in Society and History,
4, 1962, pp. 296–336.
Bederman, S. H., ‘Plantation Agriculture in Victoria Division, West Cameroons: An His-
torical Introduction’, Geography, 51, 1966, pp. 349–360.
Berg, Elliot J., ‘Backward-Sloping Labor Supply Functions in Dual Economies: The Africa
Case’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75, 1961, pp. 468–492.
Berg, Elliot J., ‘The Development of a Labour Force in Sub-Saharan Africa’, Economic
Development and Cultural Change, 13, 1965, pp. 394–412.
Berg, Elliot J., ‘The Economics of the Migrant Labour System’, in Urbanisation and Migration
in West Africa, ed. Hilda Kuper, Berkeley, 1965, pp. 160–181.
Berry, S. S., ‘Christianity and the Rise of Cocoa Growing in Ibadan and Ondo’, Journal of
the Historical Society of Nigeria, 4, 1968, pp. 439–451.
Bevin, H. J., ‘Some Notes on Gold Coast Exports, 1886–1913’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana,
4, 1960, pp. 13–20.
Birmingham, Walter, Neustadt, I., and Omaboe, E. N. eds., A Study of Contemporary
Ghana, 1, The Economy of Ghana, Evanston, 1966.
Boateng, E. A., ‘The Tarkwa Gold Mining Industry: A Retrospect’, Bulletin of the Ghana
Geographical Association, 2, 1957, pp. 5–9.
Bibliography 371
Fallers, L. A., ‘Comment’, Comparative Studies in Society and History, 4, 1962, pp. 334–336.
Fouquet, Joseph, ‘La traite des arachides dans le pays de Kaolack’, Études Sénégalaises, 8,
1958, pp. 1–262.
Frankel, S. H., Capital Investment in Africa, Oxford, 1938.
Fréchou, H., ‘Les plantations européennes en Côte d’Ivoire’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 8, 1955,
pp. 56–83.
Fréchou, H., ‘Le régime foncier chez les Soussous du moyen: Konkouré’, Cahiers de l’Insti-
tut de Science Économique Appliquée, 4, Supplement 129, 1962, pp. 109–198.
Gamble, David P., ‘History of the Groundnut Trade, 1829–1939’, in Contributions to
a Socio-Economic Survey of the Gambia, Colonial Office Research Department, London,
1949, pp. 55–69.
Girard, Jean, ‘De la communauté traditionnelle à la collectivité moderne en Casamance’,
Annales Africaines, 1963, pp. 135–165.
Gleave, Michael B., ‘Hill Settlements and their Abandonment in Western Yorubaland’,
Africa, 33, 1963, pp. 343–352.
Gleave, Michael B., ‘The Changing Frontiers of Settlement in the Uplands of Northern
Nigeria’, Nigerian Geographical Journal, 8, 1965, pp. 127–141.
Gleave, Michael B., ‘Hill Settlements and their Abandonment in Tropical Africa’, Transac-
tions of the Institute of British Geographers, 40, 1966, pp. 39–49.
Gould, Peter R., The Development of the Transportation Pattern in Ghana, Evanston, 1960.
Greenstreet, D. K., ‘The Guggisberg Ten-Year Development Plan’, Economic Bulletin of
Ghana, 8, 1964, pp. 18–26.
Greenstreet, D. K., ‘The Transport Department: The First Two Decades (1901–20)’, Eco-
nomic Bulletin of Ghana, 10, 1966, pp. 33–44.
Guèye, M’baye, ‘L’Affaire Chautemps (April 1904) et la suppression de l’esclavage de case
au Sénégal’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 27, 1965, pp. 543–559.
Guèye, M’baye, ‘La fin de l’esclavage à Saint-Louis et à Gorée en 1848’, Bulletin de l’IFAN,
B, 28, 1966, pp. 637–656.
Hancock, W. K., Survey of British Commonwealth Affairs 1918–1939, II, parts 1 and 2,
London, 1942.
Haswell, Margaret R., Economics of Agriculture in a Savannah Village, London, 1953.
Hawkins, E. K., Road Transport in Nigeria, London, 1958.
Hay, Alan M., ‘The Development of Road Transport in Nigeria, 1900–1940’, Journal of
Transport History, n.s., 1, 1971, pp. 95–107.
Helleiner, Gerald K., Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria,
Homewood, 1966.
Hill, Polly, The Gold Coast Cocoa Farmer: A Preliminary Survey, London, 1956.
Hill, Polly, ‘The History of the Migration of Ghana Cocoa Farmers’, Transactions of the His-
torical Society of Ghana, 4, 1959, pp. 14–28.
Hill, Polly, ‘The Migration of Southern Ghanaian Cocoa Farmers’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B,
22, 1960, pp. 419–425.
Hill, Polly, ‘The Migrant Cocoa Farmers of Southern Ghana’, Africa, 31, 1961, pp. 209–230.
Hill, Polly, The Migrant Cocoa-Farmers of Southern Ghana, Cambridge, 1963.
Hodder, B. W., ‘The Growth of Trade at Lagos (Nigeria)’, Tijdschrift voor Economische en
Sociale Geografie, 50, 1959, pp. 197–202.
Hogendom, J. S., The Origins of the Groundnut Trade in Northern Nigeria, University of
London, Ph.D. thesis, 1966.
Holas, B., ‘Le paysannat africain devant le problème des cultures industrielles: l’exemple des
Oubi (Côte d’Ivoire)’, Revue de l’Institut de Sociologie Solvay, 2, 1957, pp. 219–233.
Bibliography 373
Hopkins, A. G., ‘The Lagos Strike of 1897: An Exploration in Nigerian Labour History’,
Past & Present, 35, 1966, pp. 133–155.
Hopkins, A. G., ‘The Creation of a Colonial Monetary System: The Origins of the West
African Currency Board’, African Historical Studies, 3, 1970, pp. 101–132.
Hoyle, B. S., and Hilling, D. eds, Seaports and Development in Tropical Africa, London, 1970.
Jarrett, H. R., ‘The Strange Farmers of the Gambia’, Geographical Review, 39, 1949, pp.
649–657.
Kemian, Bakari, ‘Une ville de la République du Soudan: San’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 12,
1959, pp. 225–250.
Khuri, Fuad I., ‘Kinship, Emigration, and Trade Partnership among the Lebanese of West
Africa’, Africa, 35, 1965, pp. 385–395.
Kilby, Peter, ‘African Labour Productivity Reconsidered’, Economic Journal, 71, 1961, pp.
273–291.
Kôbben, A. J. F., ‘The Development of an Under-Developed Territory’, Sociologus, 8,
1958, pp. 29–40.
Köbben, A. J. F., ‘Le planteur noir’, Études Éburnéennes, 5, 1956, pp. 7–185.
Labouret, Henri, Paysans d’Afrique occidentale, Paris, 1946.
Leduc, M., Les institutions monétaires africaines: pays francophones, Paris, 1965.
Leubuscher, Charlotte, The West African Shipping Trade, 1909–1939, Leyden, 1963.
Lombard, J., ‘Cotonou, ville africaine’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 16, 1954, pp. 341–377.
Lombard, J., ‘Le problème des migrations “locales”, leur rôle dans les changements d’une
société en transition’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 22, 1960, pp. 455–466.
Loynes, J. B., The West African Currency Board, 1912–1962, London, 1962.
Mabogunje, Akin L., The Changing Pattern of Rural Settlement and Rural Economy in Egba
Division, South-Western Nigeria, University of London, M.A. thesis, 1958.
Mabogunje, Akin L., Urbanisation in Nigeria, London, 1968.
Mabogunje, Akin L., and Gleave, Michael B., ‘Changing Agricultural Landscape in South-
ern Nigeria: The Example of Egba Division 1850–1950’, Nigerian Geographical Journal, 7,
1964, pp. 1–15.
Mangolte, Jacques, ‘Le chemin de fer de Konakry au Niger (1890–1914)’, Revue Française
d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 55, 1968, pp. 37–105.
Mansell, Prothero R., ‘Migratory Labour from North-Western Nigeria’, Africa, 27, 1957,
pp. 251–261.
Martin, Anne, The Oil Palm Economy of the Ibibio Farmer, Ibadan, 1956.
McLaughlin, R. U., Foreign Investment and Development in Liberia, New York, 1966.
McPhee, Allan, The Economic Revolution in British West Africa, London, 1926.
Meillassoux, Claude, ‘The Social Structure of Modem Bamako’, Africa, 35, 1965, pp.
125–142.
Morgan, W. B., and Pugh, J. C., West Africa, London, 1969.
Newbury, C. W., ‘An Early Enquiry into Slavery and Captivity in Dahomey’, Zaire, 14,
1960, pp. 53–67.
Newbury, C. W., ‘The Government General and Political Change in French West Africa’,
St Antony’s Papers, 10, 1961, pp. 41–59.
Newlyn, W. T., and Rowan, D. C., Money and Banking in British Colonial Africa, Oxford,
1954.
Olusanya, G. O., ‘The Freed Slaves’ Homes: An Unknown Aspect of Northern Nigerian
Social History’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1966, pp. 523–538.
Omaboe, E. M., ‘Ghana’s National Income in 1930’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 4, 1960,
pp. 6–11 and pp. 22–23.
374 Bibliography
Osoba, S. O., ‘The Phenomenon of Labour Migration in the Era of British Colonial Rule:
A Neglected Aspect of Nigeria’s Social History’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria,
4, 1969, pp. 515–538.
Oyemakinde, J. O., A History of Indigenous Labour on the Nigerian Railway, 1895–1945, Uni-
versity of Ibadan, Ph.D. thesis, 1970.
Pehaut, Y., ‘L’arachide au Sénégal’, Études Sénégalaises, 2, 1952, pp. 5–25.
Pélissier, Paul, ‘Les paysans serères: essai sur la formation d’un terroir du Sénégal’, Cahiers
d’Outre-Mer, 6, 1953, pp. 105–127.
Pélissier, Paul, Les paysans du Sénégal: les civilisations agraires du Cayor à la Casamance, Saint-
Yrieix, 1966.
Perham, Margery ed., The Native Economies of Nigeria, London, 1946.
Perham, Margery ed., Mining, Commerce, and Finance in Nigeria, London, 1948.
Pim, A., The Financial and Economic History of the African Tropical Territories, Oxford, 1940.
Pitot, Albert, ‘L’homme et les sols dans les steppes et savannes de l’A.O.F.’, Cahiers d’Outre-
Mer, 5, 1952, pp. 215–240.
Portères, R., Aménagement de l’economie, agricole et rurale du Sénégal, Dakar, 1952.
Roberts, Stephen H., The History of French Colonial Policy, 1870–1925, London, 1929.
Roper, J. I., Labour Problems in West Africa, Harmondsworth, 1958.
Rouch, J., ‘Migrations au Ghana’, Journal de la Société des Africanistes, 26, 1956, pp. 33–196.
Rouch, J., ‘Problèmes relatifs à l’étude des migrations traditionnelles et des migrations
actuelles en Afrique occidentale’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 22, 1960, pp. 369–378.
Rudin, Harry R., Germans in the Cameroons, 1884–1914, New Haven, 1938.
Savonnet, Georges, ‘Une ville neuve du Sénégal: Thiès’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 9, 1956, pp.
70–93.
Savonnet, Georges, ‘La colonisation du pays Koulango (haute Côte d’Ivoire) par les Lobi
de haute-Volta’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 15, 1962, pp. 25–46.
Siddle, D. J., ‘War Towns in Sierra Leone: A Study in Social Change’, Africa, 38, 1968, pp.
47–55.
Smith, M. G., ‘Slavery and Emancipation in Two Societies’, Social and Economic Studies, 2,
1954, pp. 239–290.
Stanley, William R., ‘The Lebanese in Sierra Leone: Entrepreneurs Extraordinary’, African
Urban Notes, 5, 1970, pp. 159–174.
Suret-Canale, Jean, ‘La Guinée dans le système colonial’, Présence Africaine, 1959–60, pp. 9–44.
Suret-Canale, Jean, Afrique noire occidentale et centrale: l’ère coloniale (1900–1945), Paris, 1964.
Translated as French Colonialism in Tropical Africa, 1900–1945, London, 1971.
Swindell, Kenneth, ‘Diamond Mining in Sierra Leone’, Tÿdschrift voor Economische en Sociale
Geografie, 57, 1966, pp. 36–104.
Szereszewski, R., Structural Changes in the Economy of Ghana, 1891–1911, London, 1965.
Tamuno, Takena N., ‘Emancipation in Nigeria’, Nigeria Magazine, 82, 1964, pp. 218–227.
Tamuno, Takena N., ‘Genesis of the Nigerian Railway’, Nigeria Magazine, 83, 1964, pp.
279–292.
Tardits, Claude, ‘Développement du régime d’appropriation privée des terres de la palmer-
aie du Sud-Dahomey’, in African Agrarian Systems, ed. Daniel Biebuyck, London, 1963,
pp. 297–314.
Taylor, Wayne C., The Firestone Operations in Liberia, Washington, 1956.
Thomas, Benjamin E., ‘Trade Routes of Algeria and the Sahara’, University of California Pub-
lications in Geography, 8, 1957, pp. 165–288.
Thomas, Benjamin E., Transportation and Physical Geography in West Africa, Los Angeles,
1960.
Bibliography 375
Thomas, L. V., ‘L’organisation foncière des Diola’, Annales Africaines, 7, 1960, pp.
199–223.
Toupet, C., ‘Quelques aspects de la sédentarisation des nomades en Mauritanie sahélienne’,
Annales de Géographie, 73, 1964, pp. 738–745.
Tricart, Jean, ‘Deux types de production agricole aux environs d’Odienne (haute Côte
d’Ivoire)’, Bulletin de l’IFAN, B, 19, 1957, pp. 284–294.
Tricart, Jean, ‘Le café en Côte d’ivoire’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 10, 1957, pp. 209–233.
Udo, R. K., ‘Disintegration of Nucleated Settlement in Eastern Nigeria’, Geographical
Review, 55, 1965, pp. 53–67.
Udo, R. K., ‘British Policy and the Development of Export Crops in Nigeria’, Nigerian
Journal of Economic and Social Studies, 9, 1967, pp. 299–314.
United Africa Company, ‘The Production of Palm Oil and Palm Kernels in Nigeria’, Statis-
tical and Economic Review, 1, 1948, pp. 15–31.
United Africa Company, ‘Produce Goes to Market. Nigeria: Palm Produce, Groundnuts’,
Statistical and Economic Review, 3, 1949, pp. 1–37; 4, 1949, pp 1–45.
United Africa Company, ‘The Manilla Problem’, Statistical and Economic Review, 3, 1949,
pp. 44–56; 4, 1949, pp. 59–60.
United Africa Company, ‘Merchandise Trading in British West Africa’, Statistical and Eco-
nomic Review, 5, 1950, pp. 1–36; 6, 1950, pp. 1–40.
United Africa Company, ‘Produce Goes to Market: The Hides and Skins Trade of
Nigeria’, Statistical and Economic Review, 8, 1951, pp. 27–48.
United Africa Company, ‘Trading on the Gambia’, Statistical and Economic Review, 11,
1953, pp. 1–40.
Verdier, R., ‘Problèmes fonciers ivoiriens’, Penant, 73, 1963, pp. 404–411.
Verdier, R., ‘Problèmes fonciers nigeriens’, Penant, 74, 1964, pp. 587–593.
Villien-Rossi, Marie-Louise, ‘Bamako, capitale du Mali’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 16, 1963, pp.
379–393.
Walker, G. J., Traffic and Transport in Nigeria, London, 1957.
Webster, J. B., ‘Agege: Plantations and the African Church, 1901–1920’, Nigerian Institute
of Social and Economic Research, Conference Proceedings, 1962, pp. 124–130.
Wilson, Charles, The History of Unilever, 2 vols, London, 1954.
Wondji, Christophe, ‘La Côte d’Ivoire occidentale: période de pénétration pacifique
(1890–1908)’, Revue Française d’Histoire d’Outre-Mer, 50, 1953, pp. 346–381.
Wrigley, C. C., ‘Economic and Social Developments’, in A Thousand Years of West African
History, eds. J. F. A. Ajayi and Ian Espie, London, 1965, pp. 423–439.
Zuccarelli, François, ‘Le régime des engagés à temps au Sénégal (1817–1848)’, Cahiers
d’Études Africaines, 2, 1962, pp. 420–461.
Chapter 7
The open economy under strain
Abbott, George C., ‘A Re-examination of the 1929 Colonial Development Act’, Economic
History Review, 24, 1971, pp. 68–81.
Abbott, John C., ‘Agricultural Marketing Boards in the Developing Countries’, Journal of
Farm Economics, 49, 1967, pp. 705–722.
Adeyoju, S. K., ‘The Benin Timber Industry Before 1939’, Nigerian Geographical Journal,
12, 1969, pp. 99–111.
Akpala, Agwu, ‘The Background of the Enugu Colliery Shooting Incident in 1949’, Journal
of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 3, 1965, pp. 335–364.
376 Bibliography
Allen, Christopher, ‘African Trade Unionism in Microcosm: The Gambia Labour Move-
ment, 1939–67’, in African Perspectives, eds. C. H. Allen and R. S. Johnson, Cambridge,
1970, pp. 393–426.
Amin, S., Trois expériences africaines de développement: le Mali, la Guinée et le Ghana, Paris,
1965.
Amselle, Jean-Loup, ‘Les réseaux marchands Kooroko’, African Urban Notes, 5, 1970, pp.
143–158.
Baldwin, K. D. S. The Niger Agricultural Project, Cambridge, MA, 1957.
Baldwin, K. D. S., ‘Land Tenure Problems in Relation to Agricultural Development in the
Northern Region of Nigeria’, in African Agrarian Systems, ed. Daniel Biebuyck, London,
1963, pp. 65–82.
Ballard, John A., ‘The Porto Novo Incidents of 1923: Politics in the Colonial Era’, Odu, 2,
1965, pp. 52–75.
Bauer, P. T., ‘Origins of the Statutory Export Monopolies of British West Africa’, Business
History Review, 28, 1954, pp. 197–213.
Bauer, P. T. West African Trade, Cambridge, 1954.
Beckett, W. H., Akokoaso, London, 1944.
Berg, Elliot J., ‘The Economic Basis of Political Choice in French West Africa’, American
Political Science Review, 54, 1960, pp. 391–405.
Berg, Elliot J., and Butler, Jeffrey, ‘Trade Unions’, in Political Parties and National Integration in
Tropical Africa, eds. James S. Coleman and Carl G. Rosberg, Berkeley, 1964, pp. 340–381.
Binet, Jacques, ‘Marchés En Pays Soussou’, Cahiers d’Études Africaines, 3, 1963, pp. 104–114.
Birmingham, Walter, ‘An Index of Real Wages of the Unskilled Labourer in Accra,
1939–1959’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 4, 1960, pp. 2–6.
Blanckenburg, Peter von ed., ‘The Transformation of African Peasant Farming to
a Modem Agricultural Economy’, Journal of Foreign Agriculture, Special Publication 3,
1965.
Bohannan, Paul, and Dalton, George eds, Markets in Africa, Evanston, 1962.
Bonnefonds, Atsé-Léon, ‘La transformation du commerce de traite en Côte d’Ivoire
depuis la dernière guerre mondiale et l’indépendance’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 21, 1968,
pp. 395–413.
Booker, H. S., ‘Debt in Africa’, African Affairs, 48, 1949, pp. 141–149.
Bray, Jennifer M., ‘The Economics of Traditional Cloth Production in Iseyin, Nigeria’,
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 17, 1969, pp. 540–551.
Bray, Jennifer M., ‘The Craft Structure of a Traditional Yoruba Town’, Transactions of the
Institute of British Geographers, 46, 1969, pp. 179–193.
Buell, Raymond L., The Native Problem in Africa, 1 and 2, Harvard, 1928.
Capet, Marcel, Traité d’économie tropicale: les économies d’A.O.F., Paris, 1958.
Carney, David E., Government and Economy in British West Africa, New York, 1961.
Charle, E. G., ‘English Colonial Policy and the Economy of Nigeria’, American Journal of
Economics and Sociology, 26, 1967, pp. 79–92.
Cohen, Abner, ‘Politics of the Kola Trade’, Africa, 36, 1966, pp. 18–36.
Cohen, Abner, Custom and Politics in Urban Africa: A Study of Hausa Migrants in Yoruba
Towns, London, 1969.
Coleman, James S., Nigeria: Background to Nationalism, Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1958.
Conway, H. E., ‘Labour Protest Activity in Sierra Leone during the Early Part of the
Twentieth Century’, Labour History, 15, 1968, pp. 49–63.
Cox-George, N. A., ‘Studies in Finance and Development: The Gold Coast (Ghana)
Experience, 1914–1918’, Public Finance, 13, 1958, pp. 146–177.
Bibliography 377
Davies, J. H., ‘Manufacturing Industry in Sierra Leone’, Nigerian Institute of Social and Eco-
nomic Research Conference Proceedings, 1962, pp. 142–151.
Despois, J., ‘Problèmes techniques, économiques, et sociaux des oasis sahariennes’, Revue
Tunisienne de Sciences Sociales, 2, 1965, pp. 51–57.
Doctor, K. C., and Gallis, H., ‘Size and Characteristics of Wage Employment in Africa:
Some Statistical Estimates’, International Labour Review, 93, 1966, pp. 149–173.
Dresch, Jean, ‘Les investissements en Afrique noire’, Présence Africaine, 13, 1952, pp. 232–241.
Egboh, Edmund O., ‘Central Trade Unionism in Nigeria (1941–1966)’, Genève-Afrique, 6,
1967, pp. 193–215.
Egboh, Edmund O., ‘The Early Years of Trade Unionism in Nigeria’, Africa Quarterly, 8,
1968, pp. 59–69.
Egboh, Edmund O., ‘Trade Unions in Nigeria’, African Studies, 27, 1968, pp. 35–40.
Ehrlich, Cyril, ‘Marketing Boards in Retrospect: Myth and Reality’, in African Public Sector
Economics, Centre of African Studies, Edinburgh, 1970, pp. 121–145.
Eicher, Carl K., and Liedholm, Carl eds, Growth and Development of the Nigerian Economy,
Michigan, 1970.
Fievet, Maurice, ‘Salt Caravan’, Nigeria Magazine, 41, 1953, pp. 4–20.
Foltz, William G., From French West Africa to the Mali Federation, New Haven, 1965.
Galletti, R., Baldwin, K. D. S., and Dina, I. O., Nigerian Cocoa Farmers: An Economic Survey
of Yoruba Cocoa-Farming Families, Oxford, 1956.
Garlick, Peter C., ‘African-owned Private Enterprise Company Formation in Ghana’, Eco-
nomic Bulletin of Ghana, 4, 1960, pp. 1–10.
Garlick, Peter C., ‘The Development of Kwahu Business Enterprise in Ghana since 1874:
An Essay in Recent Oral Tradition’, Journal of African History, 8, 1967, pp. 463–480.
Garlick, Peter C., African Traders and Economic Development in Ghana, Oxford, 1971.
Graft-Johnson, J. C. de, African Experiment: Co-operative Agriculture and Banking in British
West Africa, London, 1958.
Grandin, Capitaine, ‘Notes sur l’industrie et le commerce du sel au Kawar et Agram’, Bul-
letin de l’IFAN, B, 13, 1951, pp. 488–533.
Green, R. H., ‘Four African Development Plans: Ghana, Kenya, Nigeria, and Tanzania’,
Journal of Modem African Studies, 3, 1965, pp. 249–279.
Green, R. H., and Hymer, S. H., ‘Cocoa in the Gold Coast: A Study in the Relations
between African Farmers and Agricultural Experts’, Journal of Economic History, 26, 1966,
pp. 299–319.
Greenstreet, D. K., ‘Public Administration: Development and Welfare in the British Terri-
tories of West Africa during the Forties’, Economic Bulletin of Ghana, 1, 1971, pp. 3–23.
Hauser, A., ‘Les industries de transformation de la région de Dakar’, Études Sénégalaises, 5,
1954, pp. 66–83.
Hauser, A., ‘Quelques relations des travailleurs de l’industrie à leur travail en A.O.F.’, Bul-
letin de l’IFAN, B, 17, 1955, pp. 129–141.
Hawkins, E. K., ‘The Growth of a Money Economy in Nigeria and Ghana’, Oxford Eco-
nomic Papers, 10, 1958, pp. 339–354.
Hay, Alan M., and Smith, Robert H. T. Interregional Trade and Money Flows in Nigeria,
Ibadan, 1970.
Hayter, Teresa, French Aid, London, 1966.
Helleiner, Gerald K. Peasant Agriculture, Government, and Economic Growth in Nigeria, Home-
wood, IL, 1966.
Hill, Polly, ‘Three Types of Southern Ghanaian Cocoa Farmer’, in African Agrarian Systems,
ed. Daniel Biebuyck, London, 1963, pp. 203–223.
378 Bibliography
Hill, Polly, ‘The Myth of the Amorphous Peasantry: A Northern Nigerian Case Study’,
Nigerian Journal of Economic and Social Studies, 10, 1968, pp. 239–260.
Hill, Polly, Studies in Rural Capitalism in West Africa, Cambridge, 1970.
Hilton, T. E., ‘Industrialisation in the Ivory Coast’, Bulletin of the Ghana Geographical Associ-
ation, 10, 1965, pp. 16–28.
Hodder, B. W., ‘Distribution of Markets in Yorubaland’, Scottish Geographical Magazine, 81,
1965, pp. 48–58.
Hodgkin, Thomas, Nationalism in Colonial Africa, London, 1956.
Hopkins, A. G., ‘The Lagos Chamber of Commerce, 1888–1903’, Journal of the Historical
Society of Nigeria, 3, 1965, pp. 241–248.
Hopkins, A. G., ‘Economic Aspects of Political Movements in Nigeria and in the Gold
Coast, 1918–1939’, Journal of African History, 7, 1966, pp. 133–152.
Igbafe, Philip A., ‘The Benin Water Rate Agitation, 1937–39: An Example of Social Con-
flict’, Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, 4, 1968, pp. 355–375.
Ikime, Obaro, ‘The Anti-tax Riots in Warri Province, 1927–28’, Journal of the Historical
Society of Nigeria, 3, 1966, pp. 559–573.
James, Rudolph W., ‘The Changing Role of Land in Southern Nigeria’, Odu, 1, 1965, pp.
3–23.
Karp, Mark, ‘The Legacy of French Economic Policy in Africa’, in French-Speaking Africa,
ed. William H. Lewis, London, 1965, pp. 145–153.
Kilby, Peter, African Enterprise: The Nigerian Bread Industry, Stanford, 1965.
Kilby, Peter, Industrialization in an Open Economy: Nigeria, 1945–66, Cambridge, 1969.
Kilson, Martin, ‘Nationalism and Social Classes in British West Africa’, Journal of Politics, 20,
1958, pp. 368–387.
Kilson, Martin, ‘The Emergent Elites of Black Africa, 1900 to 1960’, in Colonialism in Africa
1870–1960, eds. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan, 2, The History and Politics of Colonialism
1914–1960, Cambridge, 1970, pp. 351–398.
Kimble, David, A Political History of Ghana 1850–1928, Oxford, 1963.
Laan, H. L. Van der, The Sierra Leone Diamonds, Oxford, 1965.
Lawson, Rowena M., ‘The Transition of Ghana’s Fishing from a Primitive to a Mechanized
Industry’, Transactions of the Historical Society of Ghana, 9, 1968, pp. 90–104.
Lawson, Rowena M., The Changing Economy of the Lower Volta, 1954–67, London, 1971.
Lelong, M-H., ‘La route du kola’, Revue de Géographie Humaine et d’Ethnologie, 1, 1948, pp.
35–44.
Lewis, Barbara, ‘Ethnicity, Occupational Specialization, and Interest Groups: The Trans-
porters’ Association of the Ivory Coast’, African Urban Notes, 5, 1970, pp. 95–115.
Lewis, W. A., Report on Industrialisation and the Gold Coast, Accra, 1953.
Little, K., West African Urbanization, Cambridge, 1965.
Lloyd, P. C., Africa in Social Change, Harmondsworth, 1967.
Lovejoy, Paul E., ‘The Wholesale Kola Trade of Kano’, African Urban Notes, 5, 1970, pp.
129–142.
Mabogunje, Akin L., ‘The Evolution and Analysis of the Retail Structure of Lagos,
Nigeria’, Economic Geography, 40, 1964, pp. 304–323.
May, Ranald S., ‘Direct Overseas Investment in Nigeria 1953–63’, Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 12, 1965, pp. 243–266.
McLoughlin, Peter F. M. ed., African Food Production Systems, Baltimore, 1970.
Melamid, Alexander, ‘The Geography of the Nigerian Petroleum Industry’, Economic Geog-
raphy, 44, 1, 1968, pp. 37–56.
Bibliography 379
Mersadier, Yves, ‘La crise de l’arachide sénégalaise au début des années trente’, Bulletin de
l’IFAN, B, 28, 1966, pp. 826–877.
Milbum, Josephine F., ‘The 1938 Gold Coast Cocoa Crisis: British Business and the Colo-
nial Office’, African Historical Studies, 3, 1970, pp. 57–74.
Miracle, Marvin P., and Fetter, Bruce, ‘Backward-Sloping Labour Supply Functions and
African Economic Behaviour’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 18, 1970, pp.
240–251.
Morgenthau, Ruth S., Political Parties in French-Speaking West Africa, Oxford, 1964.
November, András, ‘L’évolution du mouvement syndical en Afrique occidentale, Paris, 1965.
Ojo, G. J. O., ‘The Changing Patterns of Traditional Group Farming in Ekiti,
North-Eastern Yoruba Country’, Nigerian Geographical Journal, 6, 1963, pp. 31–38.
Ojo, G. J. O., ‘Trends Towards Mechanised Agriculture in Yorubaland’, Nigerian Geograph-
ical Journal, 6, 1963, pp. 116–129.
Oluwasanmi, H. A., Agriculture and Nigerian Economic Development, London, 1966.
Papy, L., ‘La vallée du Sénégal: agriculture traditionnelle et riziculture mechanisée’, Cahiers
d’Outre-Mer, 4, 1951, pp. 277–324.
Pélissier, P., ‘‘L’arachide au Sénégal: rationalisation et modernisation de sa culture’, Cahiers
d’Outre-Mer, 4, 1951, pp. 204–236.
Pfeffermann, Guy, ‘Trade Unions and Politics in French West Africa during the Fourth
Republic’, African Affairs, 66, 1967, pp. 213–230.
Pfeffermann, Guy, Industrial Labour in the Republic of Senegal, New York, 1968.
Poleman, T. T., ‘The Food Economies of Urban Middle Africa: The Case of Ghana’, Food
Research Institute Studies, 2, 1961, pp. 121–174.
Quarcoo, A. K., and Johnson, Marion, ‘Shai Pots: The Pottery Industry of the Shai People
of Southern Ghana’, Baessler-Archiv, 16, 1968, pp. 47–88.
Ramboz, Y-C., ‘La politique caféière de Côte d’Ivoire et la réforme de la caisse de sta-
bilisation des prix du café et du cacao’, Revue Juridique et Politique, 19, 1965, pp.
194–218.
Rhodie, Sam, ‘The Gold Coast Cocoa Hold-up of 1930–31’, Transactions of the Historical
Society of Ghana, 9, 1968, pp. 105–118.
Richard-Molard, J., ‘A propos des plans d’équipement en Afrique noire’, Afrique et Asie,
16, 1951, pp. 9–38.
Robson, P., and Lury, D. A. eds, The Economies of Africa, London, 1969.
Saylor, Ralph G., The Economic System of Sierra Leone, Durham, NC, 1967.
Sokolski, A., The Establishment of Manufacturing in Nigeria, New York, 1965.
Suret-Canale, Jean, ‘L’industrie des oléagineux en A.O.F.’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 3, 1950,
pp. 280–288.
Suret-Canale, Jean, Afrique noire occidentale et centrale: l’ère coloniale (1900–1945), Paris, 1964.
Translated as French Colonialism in Tropical Africa, 1900–1945, 1971.
Thompson, Virginia, and Adloff, Richard, French West Africa, London, 1958.
Tricart, Jean, ‘Les échanges entre la zone forestière de Côte d’Ivoire et les savanes soudani
ennes’, Cahiers d’Outre-Mer, 9, 1956, pp. 209–238.
Udo, R. K., ‘Sixty Years of Plantation Agriculture in Southern Nigeria: 1902–1962’, Eco-
nomic Geography, 41, 1965, pp. 356–368.
United Nations, ‘The Textile Industry in the West African Sub-region’, Economic Bulletin
for Africa, 7, 1968, pp. 103–125.
Vinay, Bernard, L’Afrique commerce avec l’Afrique, Paris, 1968.
Wade, Aboulaye, Économie de l’ouest africain, Paris, 1964.
380 Bibliography
Wallerstein, Immanuel, ‘The Colonial Era in Africa: Changes in the Social Structure’, in
Colonialism in Africa, 1870–1960, eds. L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan, 2, The History
and Politics of Colonialism, 1914–1960, Cambridge, 1970, pp. 399–421.
Warren, W. M., ‘Urban Wage Rates and the Nigerian Trade Union Movement, 1939–60’,
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 15, 1966, pp. 21–36.
Wells, F. A., and Warmington, W. A., Studies in Industrialization: Nigeria and the Cameroons,
London, 1962.
Whetham, Edith H., ‘Diminishing Returns and Agriculture in Northern Nigeria’, Journal of
Agricultural Economics, 17, 1966, pp. 151–158.
White, H. P., ‘Internal Exchange of Staple Foods in the Gold Coast’, Economic Geography,
32, 1956, pp. 115–125.
Wilson, Charles, Unilever 1945–1965, London, 1968.
Yesufu, T. M., An Introduction to Industrial Relations in Nigeria, Oxford, 1962.
Zahan, Dominique, ‘Problèmes sociaux posés par la transplantation des Mossi sur les terres
irriguées de l’Office du Niger’, in African Agrarian Systems, ed. Daniel Biebuyck,
London, 1963, pp. 392–403.
INDEX
342; Sahara and Atlantic 139; see also cattle 192, 194, 282; see also livestock
England; Great Britain Cayor 191
British & African Steam Navigation centralisation 240
Company 199 ceramics 93–94; see also pottery
British Ant-Slavery Movement, The 162 Ceylon 259
British Cotton Growing Association Chad, Lake 55, 88, 119, 213,
248, 263 230, 246
Broglie, Duc de 163 Chamberlain, Joseph 213, 215, 241,
brokers 109, 110, 157, 293 310, 315
Brown, George W. 45 chambers of commerce 212
Brunschwig, Henri 209 change, economic 48, 125, 134, 165, 345;
Buduma people 230–231 colonialism 31, 227; open economy 36,
bullion 129, 259 40, 238, 277, 344; open economy
Butler, Jeffrey 329–330 1930–45 322; open economy
1945–60 338
Cadamosto, Alvise 100 change, social 30, 46, 197; open economy
Cadbury Bros (firm) 252 277–278, 281, 287, 350
Caillié, R. 172 change, structural 46, 322
Cairo 92, 129, 130 Chargeurs Réunis 252
Caisse Centrale de la France d’Outre-Mer chartered companies 139–141, 154–155, 215
340 Childe, V. Gordon 73, 84
Caisses: de compensation 319; de soutien 341; Choiseul, Duc de 139
de stabilisation 341 Clapperton, Hugh 109
camels 118, 120, 126, 128, 130, 131 Clark, J. Desmond 73
Cameroons 65, 263; imperialism 190, 210, Clarkson, Thomas 162
214; Sahara and Atlantic 150, 160, 171 Clifford, Governor Hugh C. 266
Canada 209 climate 57–58, 79, 265
canoe houses 197 closed economies 30, 50, 219–223, 350
canoes 118, 119, 231, 249, 258 cloth (money) 129, 136, 159, 170, 304;
Cape Coast 202, 300 strips of 113–114, 116; see also currencies;
Capet, Marcel 298 money
capital 229; colonialism 221, 224; clothing 93; see also textiles
commercial 116, 117, 253; domestic coal (coal mines) 249, 263, 324
economy 88, 102, 110, 124; economic cocoa 188–189; colonialism 220, 224,
growth 166–167; external slave trade 227–228; open economy 266, 269, 271,
164; imperialism 174–175, 186, 201, 275, 278; open economy 1930–45
204; open economy 265–266, 288, 293, 308–309, 317, 320; open economy
306, 345; open economy 1930–45 322; 1945–60 327, 341; open economy,
open economy 1945–60 336; open domestic 298–299; open economy,
economy, expatriate role 244, 256; expatriate role 248, 252; open economy,
public 246; trans-Atlantic 137, 140, 143, specialisation 292–293
146, 153, 157–158; trans-Sahara 133 coercion 206, 229, 240, 285, 330
capital market 96, 113, 116 coffee 138, 188, 227–228; open economy
capitalism 124, 193 271, 298–299, 308, 319, 341
Capitalism and Slavery 162 Cohen, Abner 306
caravans 93, 107–109, 111–112, 131, Cohen, Robin 329
134, 180 coins 160, 200, 201, 258, 259; see also
Caravans of the Old Sahara 45 currencies; money; silver
Carde, Govenor Jules G. H. 316 Colbert, Jean Baptiste 140
Carolina 137 Colonial Development Act 315
carriers 118, 277; see also porters Colonial Development and Welfare Acts
Cary, Joyce 248 (C.D.W.) 316, 331, 337
Casamance 136, 191 Colonial Development Corporation
cash payments 256, 258 (C.D.C.) 337
384 Index
colonialism 3, 23–25, 27, 30–34,37–38, 40, purchasers 160, 169, 300; Sahara and
47, 164, 166, 218–219, 291; open and Atlantic 126, 167, 169
closed economies 219–223; open continuous markets 101–102
economy 1900–60 223–224, 226–237 contracts and kinship 49, 64, 103, 111
colonies: colonialism 226–227, 229; control: alien 64; domestic economy 102,
imperialism 179, 188, 206–208, 212, 110; governmental 260; imperialism 181,
215; open economy 240–241, 243, 261 196, 201; open economy 306, 326, 335;
Colonies Françaises d’Afrique (C.F.A.) 340 political 247; Sahara and Atlantic
comité de surveillance 319 133, 135
commerce, legitimate see legitimate controversy (economic) 250–251
commerce Convention People’s Party (C.P.P.) 325, 330
commercial law, pre-colonial 103n121 co-operation 204; open economy 270, 274,
Commission of Enquiry 326 279; open economy 1930–45 321; open
communal labour 65 economy 1945–60 327, 331, 334, 347;
communications 118, 157 open economy, expatriate role 240–241
Communist Party 324–325, 326 co-operatives 310, 316, 317
communities 58, 88, 96, 98–99, 117, 248, copper (currency) 89, 113, 129, 160, 200;
271; farming 292 see also currencies; money
Compagnie des Indes 140 Coser, Lewis A. 347
Compagnie des Indes Occidentales costs 176; domestic economy 68–69,
140, 145 102–104, 123–124; imperialism 188;
Compagnie du Guinée 140 labour 79, 95; open economy 267, 298;
Compagnie du Sénégal 140, 211, 251 open economy 1930–45 310; open
Compagnie Française de L’Afrique economy 1945–60 332, 333; open
Équatoriale 211 economy, expatriate role 239, 247, 249;
Compagnie Française de L’Afrique production 65, 89, 305, 308; Sahara and
Occidentale (C.F.A.O.) 251, 252, Atlantic 124, 137, 142–143, 153–154,
332–333 164, 169
companies, chartered 139–141, 154–155, 214 costs, transport 11, 28, 95, 119–121, 191,
compensation (financial) 100, 143, 164, 194, 333
190, 259, 319, 342 Cotonu 246
competition: colonialism 227; domestic cottage industries 304
economy 102, 111; open economy 266, cotton (cotton goods) 93, 167, 194, 229,
272; open economy 1930–45 310, 313, 252; imperialism 178–179, 186; open
320; open economy 1945–60 332–333; economy 272–273, 286, 316, 318;
open economy, domestic 297–299, 302, trans-Atlantic 135, 138, 143, 145, 159
306; open economy, expatriate role 246, Coupland, Sir Reginald 162
252–255, 260; Sahara and Atlantic 140, Cowrie shells (currency) 113–114, 116,
145, 159, 164, 169; see also imperialism 128–129, 160, 182, 200
Conakry 246, 312 Cox-George, N. A. 232
concessions 156; colonialism 223, 237; crafts 61, 72, 89, 95, 170, 302, 304–305
open economy 263–267; open economy credit: domestic economy 110, 116–117;
1945–60 326, 329, 331, 340; open imperialism 196, 198; open economy
economy, expatriate role 247 257, 261, 306, 316; Sahara and Atlantic
conflicts 62, 86, 185, 204, 207, 217, 222; 133, 143–144, 146, 157–158
see also hostilities credit system 158, 182
Congo 150, 246, 264, 267 crises 236, 246, 261, 313, 314; see also
Consolidated African Selection Trust 263 imperialism
construction 93, 247, 328 crisis of adaptation 23–24, 27–28
consumer goods 220, 229, 255, 283, Cropper, James 165
302, 323 crops 62, 74–75, 76, 78, 79, 188, 299; cash
consumer imports 175–176, 236 271; export 65, 72
consumers 221, 229; domestic economy Cuba 151, 161, 164
102–104, 109; open economy 258, 305; cucenawa (second generation slaves) 70
Index 385
cultivation 75, 76, 282; extensive and diseases 137; open economy 265, 277,
intensive 9–10, 36 316–317, 327; see also domestic
currencies 113–116, 229; imperialism 182, economy; malaria
200, 202; open economy 252, 258–260, disputes (commercial) 198, 205–206,
340; Sahara and Atlantic 129, 160 212, 266
Curtin, Philip D. 148, 151 distribution 124, 158, 179, 201
customs duties; see taxes distributive system 57, 131, 297, 305,
306–307
Dahomey 67, 107, 154; colonialism 224, diversification: colonialism 222–223, 227,
227; imperialism 191, 193, 205, 210, 230; imperialism 174, 182; open
215; open economy 250, 263, 319 economy 1930–45 308; open economy
Dahomey and the Slave Trade 160 1945–60 328, 332, 343; open economy,
Dakar 55, 202, 246–247; open economy domestic 299, 304
1945–60 323, 325, 334; open economy, Djenne 62, 107, 109, 119
domestic 300; open economy, Doherty, J. H. 293
specialisation 296 Doherty, Chief T. A. 293–294
Dalton, George 49, 97–98, 115 dollars 340
dancing 53 domestic economy 8–14, 46, 50, 51–54,
Danes in W. Africa 180 349–350; colonialism 222, 267;
Danquah, J. B. 321–322, 325 distributive system 96–105, 107–122;
data 2–4; see also sources external trade 17; imperialism 175;
Davies, K. G. 140 internal constraints on growth 122–124;
Dawodu, W. A. 248 open economy 36, 39, 278, 287,
debts: colonialism 223, 236; domestic 297–307; open economy 1930–45 322;
economy 103, 105, 117; open economy open economy 1945–60 327;
264, 340; Sahara and Atlantic 129, pre-colonial 8–14; production 71–77,
157–158 79–84, 86–90, 92–96; resources 54–55,
defence 63, 153, 154, 159 57–59, 61–71; Sahara and Atlantic 126,
deferred rebate system 253 129, 153, 169, 172
deficits 224, 260, 261 domestic production 166, 167
de Gaulle, General Charles 331 donkeys 118, 121
Delcourt, André 140 draught animals 81, 120
demand (consumer) 99, 100, 102, 186, ‘dual mandate’ 241, 265, 321
236, 344 Dual Mandate in British Tropical Africa 241
demarcation disputes, commercial 205 Dumett, R. A. 214
demography see population Durand, Huguette 319
demonstrations 309, 311, 312, 324, 329 Dutch in W. Africa 63, 136, 138, 159,
depressions 182, 185, 198, 205, 207, 179–180, 265
307, 320 Dutch West India Company 139
development 57, 241, 337; agricultural 288; duties: colonialism 220, 229; imperialism
economic 168, 343; planning 322; 191, 195; open economy 1930–45 314,
projects 235, 342; see also 320; open economy 1945–60 335, 339;
underdevelopment open economy, expatriate role 242;
Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets Sahara and Atlantic 141, 155, 162, 165;
in West Africa, The 46 see also tariffs
Diagne, Blaise 321
diamonds 228, 263, 265 earnings 176, 220, 221, 232
diasporas 110, 111 Economic History of Liberia, The 45
Dike, K. O. 46, 196 economic model (of colonialism) 30–31
Dioula people (traders) 107, 110, 122, 271, economic performance 283, 321, 344
305, 325 economic policy, colonial 32, 37
discontent 69, 242, 314, 321, 323, 324, Economic Revolution in British West Africa,
329; colonial 38 The 45, 238
discrimination 67, 112 economies of scale 254–255
386 Index
Edu, Alhaji S. L. 328 expatriate firms 37–39, 131, 201, 221; open
education 337; see also training economy 344; open economy 1930–45
efficiency (inefficiencies) 119, 223; 309, 319, 321; open economy 1945–60
imperialism 183, 205; open economy 328, 331–334, 342; open economy,
264, 286; Sahara and Atlantic 128, 131, domestic 297; open economy,
143, 162 specialisation 295
Efik people 156–157 expatriates 198, 207; colonialism 220, 222;
Egypt 209, 215, 246 open economy 240–244, 246–262,
Ejirin 100 271–272; open economy 1930–45 310;
Ekpe 157 open economy, domestic 299; open
Elder, Dempster & Co. Ltd 252 economy, export growth 287, 289; see
electricity 339 also missionaries
elites 310, 322 expectations 176, 223, 323, 330, 347
emancipation 279–280, 281; see also experiments 186, 188, 266, 316
abolition expertise (experts) 240, 332
emergencies 243, 317 exploitation 228; domestic economy 54,
emigration 170, 171 70, 83; open economy 241, 254, 256,
empiricism, political 240 265; Sahara and Atlantic 133, 152, 154,
employees 140, 292, 295, 311, 312, 323 168–169
employers 68, 69, 275, 295, 330 export crops 76, 82, 84, 268, 338
employment 66, 168, 221–222; imperialism export growth 285–289
175, 196; open economy 284, 294–295, export markets 236
299, 328; see also underemployment export prices 153
England 139, 156; see also Britain; Great export processing 317, 334
Britain export production (producers) 75,
enterprises 270, 271, 343, 344 327, 342
entrepôts 309; domestic economy 109–110, export trade 28; colonialism 227, 232; open
117–118; imperialism 196, 198; Sahara economy 247; Sahara and Atlantic 135,
and Atlantic 131, 153, 155, 158–160, 137, 159, 168, 172; see also imperialism;
166, 168 open economy
entrepreneurs: domestic economy 52, 66, exporters 192
68, 103; imperialism 175, 178, 189, 192; exports 65, 261, 322, 334; volume of
open economy 1945–60 328, 333; open 235, 237
economy, domestic 298; open economy, exports, overseas 187
expatriate role 239, 246; open economy, external trade 14–22, 24, 34, 37, 50;
export growth 288–289 abolition of external slave trade 161–165;
Enugu 246 domestic economy 114; imperialism
environment 10 180–181, 184, 200; international trade
Ephraim, Duke 157 and economic growth 165–172; open
epidemics 59 economy 253, 306, 310; trans-Atlantic
Epstein, T. Scarlett 115 134–148, 150–161; trans-Saharan
esusu (Yoruba credit association) 116 126–131, 133–134
European Economic Community Eygpt 184
(EEC) 340 Eyo, Nsa (Willy Honesty) 158
Everaert, J. 144
evidence 2–4, 46, 48, 51; imperialism 180, Fabre et Fraissinet 199, 252
205; open economy 239, 250, 297, 304, Fage, J. D. 177
341; Sahara and Atlantic 129, 146, 171; Faidherbe, General Louis 215
see also data families 198; domestic economy 65–66,
exchange 47–49, 155; bills of 147; domestic 112; open economy 270–271, 295;
economy 96, 103, 113, 116; external Sahara and Atlantic 144, 146, 152
261; internal 250 family labour 95, 274, 286, 304
expansion 103, 110, 224, 332; economic famines 59, 76
171; trade 62 Fanta people 88
Index 387
farmers 61, 70, 76, 152; migrant 269; open economy 345; open economy 1930–45
economy 345; open economy 1930–45 318–320; open economy 1945–60
308–310, 321; open economy 1945–60 334–335, 340–341; open economy,
322–323, 325–327, 341–343; open Sahara and Atlantic 139, 163; and
economy, export growth 286–287; open partition of West Africa 27–28
economy, specialisation 293, 296 Frankel, S. H. 243
farming 65, 72, 77, 189 Franklin, Benjamin 331
female labour 66, 175n5 free trade 141, 145, 162, 243, 318; see also
females, see women trade, free
Federation of French West Africa 227 Freetown 188, 202, 203, 204, 246, 247
fertilisers 237, 327, 338 freight 128, 147, 248, 253, 334; ocean 183
fertility 59 Freycinet, Charles de 213, 215
Fez 131 frontiers 111, 186, 221, 222, 230, 274, 306
Fezzan 130 Fulani people 62, 77, 86, 274
finance 242, 275 funds 110, 253, 316, 335, 336, 343
firearms 88; see also guns Fyfe, Christopher 157, 203
Firestone Rubber Company 264
First World War 215, 229, 235–236, Gabon 210
241–242, 253, 263–264, 272 Gaiser, G. L. 202
Firth, Raymond 49 Gallagher, John 209
fishing (fish) 87, 88, 229, 299, 306, Gallieni, Joseph 215
307, 318 Gambia: colonialism 224, 227; imperialism
flexibility 109, 188, 308, 338 183, 191, 214; open economy 243, 275,
flooding 77, 87 298, 312, 319
floodland cultivation 77; see also irrigated Gao 62, 92, 109, 119
agriculture Garlick, Peter 306
flour 229, 298 general- and special-purpose currencies
Fogel, Robert, W. 249 113–116
Fonds d’Aide et Co-opération (F.A.C.) 337 Gatling gun 206
Fonds d’Investissement pour le Genoa 134, 142–143
Développement Économique et Social Germany 179–180, 199, 208–212, 215,
(F.I.D.E.S.) 336–337 227, 242, 263
food 68, 75, 87, 93–94, 316 Gertzel, Cherry J. 207, 257
Fonds National de Régularisation des Ghadames 131
Cours des Produits d’Outre-Mer 341 Ghana 131, 169, 304
foodstuffs: colonialism 229–230; domestic Ghat 131
economy 72, 82, 86, 99, 123; Ghezo 192–193
imperialism 176, 178; open economy gin 159, 179
270, 272–273; open economy 1945–60 Gladstone, W. E. 241
327–328; open economy, domestic Glover, John H. 215
298–299; open economy, export growth goats 302
286–287; open economy, specialisation gold: colonialism 228, 235; domestic
292, 296; preserved 129 economy 55, 64, 89–90, 92, 113;
forced labour 70, 272, 279, 285, 331 imperialism 178, 184, 188; open
foreign commerce see external trade economy 263, 299, 340; Sahara and
forests 57, 77, 79, 175 Atlantic 128–129, 135–136, 146, 160
formalism and substantivism 6 Gold Coast: colonialism 224, 228–232,
Forster & Smith 203 235; domestic economy 64, 88; open
Fouta Djallon 215 economy 266–267, 269–270, 272, 275,
Fouta Toro 83 285, 345; open economy 1930–45 309,
Fox, Charles James 165 312, 317, 319–320; open economy
France: colonialism 224, 226, 231; 1945–60 323, 326, 331, 336, 342; open
expatriate role 240, 242; imperialism economy, domestic 300, 302, 306; open
179–180, 186, 199, 208, 210–213; open economy, expatriate role 241, 246–250,
388 Index
256, 261; open economy, export growth Hancock, W. K. 45, 221, 262, 267
288; open economy, specialisation Haratin people 282
292–293; Sahara and Atlantic 135–136, harbours 241, 244, 247, 250
155, 157, 159–160, 171; see also Harcourt, Lewis V. 264
imperialism hardware 159, 167, 179
Gold Coast Transport Dept. 284 Hardy, Georges 45
Goldie, George D. Taubman 215 haulage, commercial 248; see also freight
gold standard 259 Hausa people 272–273, 293, 300, 305–306;
goods 48; domestic economy 72, 97, 99, domestic economy 70, 107–108,
102; imported 286; indigenous 285, 287; 110, 122
Sahara and Atlantic 128, 146 Hausaland 62
Goody, Jack 81 headloading (head-loading) 119, 249, 280;
Gonja 120 see also porters
Gorée 279 Helleiner, Gerald K. 232, 235, 272, 285
Gourou, Pierre 79 Hill, Polly 46, 269
governments 309, 322, 345 hired labour, see wage labour
grains 72, 299 Hodder, B. W. 99
Grand Bassam 210 Hogendorn, Jan S. 269
grants 315, 335, 339 Holt, John & Co 202, 205
grants-in-aid 243 Honesty, Willy, see Eyo Nsa
Great Britain 191; see also Britain; England Honfleur 144, 146
Great Colonial Loan 315 horses 120, 126
Great Depression 183 hostilities 143, 229, 252, 266, 309
‘great divergence’ 20 Houphouët-Boigny, Félix 325, 326, 330
Grey, Henry, Earl 242 households 65–66, 82, 84, 97, 99,
groundnuts 32–33; colonialism 220, 224, 156, 174
227–228, 236; imperialism, legitimate human resources 54–71
commerce 175, 177–179, 183; Hunter, J. M. 61
imperialism, partition 186, 188–191, 193, hunting 73, 87–88
200; open economy 266, 269, 272–275; Huntington, Ellsworth 55
open economy 1930–45 308, 317–318; huza 270
open economy 1945–60 341; open Hymer, Stephen H. 232
economy, domestic 298, 300; open
economy, expatriate role 252; open Ibadan 63, 105, 293, 306, 328
economy, export growth 286–287; open Iberia 74
economy, specialisation 292–293 Idjil 92, 93
growth, economic 48, 113, 165–172, 177, Ibo people 90, 325
239, 337 Ife 64
guarantees 158, 273 Iferuan 131
Guèye, Lamine 321 Igbira people 94
Guèye, Youssouf 83 Ikime, Obaro 257
Guggisberg, Governor F. Gordon 315, 337 Ilorin 180
guilds 95 immigrants 156, 274, 275
Guinea 190, 224, 228, 235, 252, 294, immigration 295
338–339 Imoudu, Michael 312
guinea corn 136, 299 Imperial Chemical Industries 332
Gulf of Guinea 58 imperialism 23–30, 31, 32, 47, 173–174,
gum 135–136, 146, 167, 178, 184, 206, 230 215–217; legitimate commerce 174–185;
gunpowder 159, 179 partition 185–186, 188–214
guns 143, 159, 167, 179, 195, 206, 229 imperial preference 37, 319–320, 340
implements see tools
Haiti 151 imports 170, 261, 328, 334
halting places 131 In Salah 131
Hamburg 179, 212, 229, 247 incentives 271, 283, 324, 327
Index 389
migration 175, 270; domestic economy, economy, domestic 306; open economy,
distributive system 110–111; domestic expatriate role 244, 247–249, 252,
economy, production 83, 86, 88; 257–258; open economy, specialisation
domestic economy, resources 58, 64; 295; Sahara and Atlantic 128, 134
Sahara and Atlantic 151, 166 Mourides people 274, 292
military systems 287–288 multicentric economies 97–98
Miller Bros 251 munitions 159, 194
millet 136, 308 Murdock, George Peter 73
minerals (mineral trade) 227–228; domestic Murzuk 130
economy 89, 91–92; open economy 263, Musa, Mansa 92, 305
265; open economy 1945–60 325, 339; Muslim law and land-tenure 14–16, 83,
open economy, domestic 299; open 110–111, 280; see also Mourides people
economy, specialisation 294; see also Myint, H. 285, 286, 288
gold etc. myths 52, 53, 54, 57, 136
miners 312
mining 88–89, 221, 315; open economy Nana, Olomu 197, 257
263, 275, 278, 312–313, 332; Sahara and Nangodi 61
Atlantic 135, 137 Nantes 142, 144–147, 155, 163, 166–167,
mise en valeur des colonies françaises, La 241 179, 212
mise en valeur du Sénégal de 1817 à 1854, Napoleon I, Emperor of France 163
La 45 Napoleonic Wars 155, 163, 209
missionaries 127, 188, 198, 203, 207 National African Company 211
Mister Johnson 248 National Council of Nigeria and the
mithqals (dinars) 113–114 Cameroons (N.C.N.C.) 325
mixed farming 76, 77 nationalism 47, 291, 322, 344,
mobility 166; domestic economy 64, 84; 345, 347
open economy 277–278, 281; open natural resources 9, 54, 57–59, 62, 64;
economy 1945–60 338; open economy, production of 82; distributive system
domestic 306; open economy, expatriate 100, 122; imperialism 189, 193; open
role 244, 249; open economy, export economy 262
growth 287 navétanes 274
modernisation theory 5–6, 8 navigation, ocean 172
Mogador 131 Needham, Joseph 118
monetary systems 113, 220, 222–223, Neolithic Revolution 57, 73, 84, 87
258–260, 298, 340; see also currencies Netherlands (Dutch) 139, 179, 180
money 105, 117, 200, 201, 239 Netting, Robert McC. 65
monopolies 139, 144, 145, 162, networks 110, 112, 130, 156, 251, 293,
169, 252 307; distribution 96; trade 104
Monoprix stores 332 Newbury, C. W. 177, 180
Monrovia 259 Newton, John 158
Montesquieu, Charles, L. 69, 163 Niger 300, 302, 318
Moors people 84, 127, 172, 206 Niger agricultural scheme 315
Mopti 299 Niger Company 257, 258, 266, 273
moral communities 157, 158, 254 Niger Delta 191, 196, 205, 207
morality 168 Niger, River 79, 88, 114, 119, 130
Morgan, W. B. 76 Nigeria 65; colonialism 222, 228–231, 235;
Morocco 130 imperialism 186, 188, 210, 215; open
mortality 59, 61, 295 economy 263, 266–267, 269, 272–273,
Mossi people 107, 118 345; open economy 1930–45 309, 312,
motivation 283, 294 319; open economy 1945–60 328, 331,
motor transport 121; colonialism 229, 236; 336, 339; open economy, domestic 299,
open economy 270, 273, 280, 284; open 302, 304; open economy, expatriate role
economy 1930–45 308; open economy 242, 246–248, 250, 257–258; open
1945–60 327–328, 332, 338; open economy, export growth 285, 288; open
Index 393
Senegal railway 242, 246, 249, 274 slave trade 10, 14, 15, 16–18, 19–20,
Senegal, River 79, 119 23–24, 29, 54, 166, 231, 262, 277;
Senegambia: domestic economy 88, 114; abolition 161–165; consequences 18–19;
imperialism 175, 190–191, 193; open see also external trade; imperialism
economy 266, 274, 298; Sahara and slaveholders 282
Atlantic 157, 160, 171 slavery 3, 11–12, 14, 16–17, 23, 25, 29,
Senghor, Leopold 325 32–33, 35–36, 184, 259, 278–279,
Serer people 77, 274 281, 306
services (service industries) 48, 72, 97, 102, slaves 282, 306; destinations 151; domestic
167, 176, 334 economy 54, 62, 67–70, 93, 118; escaped
settlements 153, 189; domestic economy, 206; exchange 155; imperialism
distributive system 101, 111; domestic 174–175, 177–178, 190–191, 193–196;
economy, production 77, 88; domestic liberated 203; numbers 148, 150;
economy, resources 58, 62; open production of 159; Sahara and Atlantic
economy 275, 280, 295 128–130, 134–137, 169
settlers 166, 189, 317, 335 sleeping sickness 59, 118
Seven Years’ War 146 slumps 185, 234–235; open economy
Shai people 304 260–261; open economy 1930–45
Sharp, Granville 162 309–310, 312, 314, 319–320; open
sheep 302; see also livestock economy, expatriate role 242–243; open
Sheffield 143 economy, specialisation 296
Sheridan, R. B. 138, 167 smallpox 59
shifting cultivation 76, 77, 79, 273 Smith, Adam 69, 125, 141, 167, 208,
shipowners (shippers) 145, 154; see also 283, 285
steamships (steamers); transport, water smiths 90, 92
(ocean); vessels Société Commerciale de l’Ouest Africain
shipping (ships) 147, 155, 167,182, 199, (S.C.O.A.) 251, 313, 332–333
235, 252–253 Société des Amis des Noirs 163
Sierra Leone: colonialism 227–228, 232; Société Indigènes de Prévoyance (S.I.P.) 316
imperialism 183, 191, 210, 212, 215; societies 125, 134, 152, 274; indigenous
open economy 264–265; open economy 6–8, 33, 47, 50, 70–72, 76, 81, 83–84,
1930–45 312, 314, 319; open economy, 98, 100, 238, 275, 348, 350
domestic 298; open economy, expatriate soils 57, 59, 79, 81, 272, 327
role 243, 259; opopen economy 1930–45 Sokoto 109
338; Sahara and Atlantic 135–136, 157 soldiers 247
Sierra Leone Development Company (D.E. Songhai 67–68
L.C.O.) 315–316 Sorkawa people 88
Sierra Leone Development Corporation 263 sorting (unit of account) 160
Sierra Leone People’s Party (S.L.P.P.) 326 Soudan 316, 318
Sierra Leone Selection Trust 263 sources 2–4, 46, 48, 51, 136; colonialism
Sijilmasa 131 223, 232, 233, 234, 335; domestic
silver 89, 258; see also coins economy 53n7, 84, 96, 98; imperialism
skiffs 231 180–181, 205; open economy 239, 250,
skills: domestic economy 64, 88, 102; 297, 304, 341; Sahara and Atlantic 129,
imperialism 175, 178; open economy 146, 150, 170–171
263, 265, 275; open economy 1945–60 South America 74
328, 333–334; open economy, expatriate sovereignty, territorial 216, 305
role 255–256; Sahara and Atlantic Spain 129
171–172 special-purpose currencies 115
Slater, Governor Ransford 263 specialisation: domestic economy 73, 88,
slave raids (raiding) 16, 29, 80; domestic 95, 99; open economy 240, 270,
economy 70; Sahara and Atlantic 148, 291–296, 306; Sahara and Atlantic 125,
152–153, 156, 159–160, 170, 175 133, 146–147
slave revolts 70, 163, 197 specialists 204, 288, 327
Index 397
trade, free 208, 211–212, 213; see also free Tuareg people 118, 133
trade trypanosomiasis 10, 59, 84, 118
trade organisations 102, 103 Tunis 131
trade, overseas 224, 226 tyeddo (warriors) 193
Trade and Politics in the Niger Delta,
1830–1885, 46 underdevelopment 47, 52, 53, 58,
trade, regional 36–37 82, 287
trade routes: domestic economy 95, underemployment 61, 286, 315
104–107, 110, 112; imperialism 188; kola underpopulation 58, 59, 61, 123
nuts 301; livestock 303; Sahara and unicentric economies 98
Atlantic 127–128, 132–133, 143 United Africa Company (U.A.C.) 251,
trade, trans-Saharan 14–16, 18, 27, 29 332–333
trade unions (unions) 296, 311, 312, 325, United African Company 211n72
329–330 United Gold Coast Convention (U.G.C.
traders 235; domestic economy 102, 107; C.) 325
expatriate 266; export-crops 325; United Nations 324
frontiers 230, 249; imperialism 182, 185, United States of America (United States)
201; indigenous 254, 258, 333; open 166, 183, 340
economy 267, 345; open economy unrest, political 196; see also revolts, slave;
1930–45 321; open economy 1945–60 riots
322–323, 326; open economy, domestic Upper Guinea 152
306; open economy, specialisation 296; Upper Volta 300, 302, 304, 318
organisations 102–103; private 141–142, urbanisation 62, 63, 73
144, 145; professional 117; Sahara and usufructuary rights 270, 271, 273
Atlantic 140, 168; slave 54; state 107,
108; see also long-distance trade values 53, 54, 71, 86, 98, 116, 275
‘traditional’ societies see societies van Alstein, Pierre 145
training 255, 332; see also apprenticeships vegetable oils see groundnuts palm oil
transactions (transactional rules) 48–49, vegetables 190, 319
205, 258 vegetation zones 55–57
transport: domestic economy 95, 117–118, Venice 129, 134
120; imperialism 176, 180, 189, 191, vent-for-surplus 33, 35, 285, 287
193; open economy 277; open economy Verdier, Arthur 188, 265, 281
1930–45 315; open economy 1945–60 Verminck, C. A. 251
337; open economy, domestic 298–299, vessels 144, 155, 199, 247; see also ocean
304; open economy, expatriate role 244, transport; shipping (ships); steamships
248–250; Sahara and Atlantic 126, 169; (steamers)
see also costs villages de liberté 280
transport systems (transportation) 119, 122, Virginia 137
177, 206 Volta, River 119, 135
transport, water (ocean) 199, 200, 230–231 Volta River Project 339
travellers (travel): domestic economy
63–64, 67, 74, 92–94, 107; Sahara and wage-earners 296, 321, 322, 325, 326,
Atlantic 125, 133, 172 328, 345
tree crops 77, 235, 293, 308 wage labour 35–36, 68–75, 95, 277–278,
Trevor-Roper, Hugh 46n8, 76 283, 294–325
triangular trade 105, 146–147, 167 wages: domestic economy 68; open
tribute (tributive system) 153, 184, 193, 239 economy 266, 283–285; open economy
Tripoli 131 1930–45 311; open economy 1945–60
Tripolitania 130 323, 328–330; open economy,
True Whig Party 54 specialisation 294–295; Sahara and
trust (or credit) system 158 Atlantic 137, 143, 145
trust (trustworthy) 110, 111, 157, 261, 273 Wallace-Johnson, Isaac T. A. 321
trusteeship 265, 314 Walkden, John & Company 202
Index 399
warfare 143, 144, 153; see also conflict; imperialism 175, 184, 190, 213; Sahara
hostilities and Atlantic 127–129, 131
Wargla 131 wheel (in Africa) 12–13, 95, 117, 120–121
Warren, W. M. 329 wheat 298
water 59, 86; see also rainfall White, Lynn 81
water transport 118 wholesalers (wholesaling) 157, 160, 168,
waterways 191, 244, 248–249 199, 204, 293
wealth 282; domestic economy, distributive Whydah 133, 155, 156, 191, 196
system 100, 104, 111, 116; domestic Wilberforce, William 162, 165
economy, resources 58, 64, 70–71 Williams, Eric 162, 167–168
weapons 128–129 Woermann-Linie 199, 252
Weber, Max 49 Wolof people 114, 116, 274
Weeks, John F. 329 women 44, 171; domestic economy 65–66,
weights and measures 103, 160 75, 95, 102; open economy 257, 288,
welfare 70, 194, 233, 239; colonial 40 306; see also females
West Africa 58, 192, 236 woollen goods 179
West African Cocoa Control Board 320 workers 311; see also employees; labour
West African Currency Board (W.A.C.B.) force
260–261 working conditions (hours) 61, 284, 295
West African Produce Control Board Wrigley, Christopher 73
320, 342
West Coast 191, 199 yams 136
West Indies 137–138 Yoruba people, Yorubaland 63, 65, 75,
Western Sudan 246; domestic economy, 117, 175, 193, 206–207
distributive system 113, 117–118, 122;
domestic economy, production 88; Zinder 105
domestic economy, resources 55, 59; zongos (settlements) 111