Trajectories of Neoliberal Transformation European Industrial Relations Since The 1970s 1st Edition Lucio Baccaro Kindle & PDF Formats
Trajectories of Neoliberal Transformation European Industrial Relations Since The 1970s 1st Edition Lucio Baccaro Kindle & PDF Formats
DOWNLOAD EBOOK
Trajectories Of Neoliberal Transformation European
Industrial Relations Since The 1970s 1st Edition Lucio
Baccaro pdf download
Available Formats
https://ebookgate.com/product/cities-in-relations-trajectories-of-
urban-development-in-hanoi-and-ouagadougou-1st-edition-soderstrom/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/the-european-union-since-1945-2nd-
edition-alasdair-blair/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/french-relations-with-the-european-
union-1st-edition-helen-drake/
ebookgate.com
Industrial Cowboys Miller Lux and the Transformation of
the Far West 1850 1920 1st Edition David Igler
https://ebookgate.com/product/industrial-cowboys-miller-lux-and-the-
transformation-of-the-far-west-1850-1920-1st-edition-david-igler/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/fashions-of-a-decade-
the-1970s-jacqueline-herald/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/the-conservative-party-and-european-
integration-since-1945-at-the-heart-of-europe-1st-edition-n-j-crowson/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/lasik-the-evolution-of-refractive-
surgery-1st-edition-lucio-buratto/
ebookgate.com
Trajectories of Neoliberal Transformation
This book has both empirical and theoretical goals. The primary empir-
ical goal is to examine the evolution of industrial relations in Western
Europe from the end of the 1970s to the present. Its purpose is to evalu-
ate the extent to which liberalization has taken hold of European indus-
trial relations institutions through five detailed, chapter-length studies,
each focusing on a different country and including a quantitative analy-
sis. It offers a comprehensive description and analysis of what has hap-
pened to the institutions that regulate the labor market, as well as the
relations between employers, unions and states in Western Europe since
the collapse of the long postwar boom. The primary theoretical goal of
this book is to provide a critical examination of some of the central
claims of comparative political economy, particularly those involving
the role and resilience of national institutions in regulating and manag-
ing capitalist political economies.
LUCIO BACCARO
University of Geneva
CHRIS HOWELL
Oberlin College
University Printing House, Cambridge cb2 8bs, United Kingdom
One Liberty Plaza, 20th Floor, New York, ny 10006, usa
477 Williamstown Road, Port Melbourne, vic 3207, Australia
4843/24, 2nd Floor, Ansari Road, Daryaganj, Delhi – 110002, India
79 Anson Road, #06-04/06, Singapore 079906
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9781107018723
DOI: 10.1017/9781139088381
C Lucio Baccaro & Chris Howell 2017
Bibliography 223
Index 253
vii
1
Introduction
Trajectories of European Industrial Relations
As with most academic monographs, ours has both empirical and theoretical
goals. The primary empirical goal is straightforward enough: to examine the
evolution of industrial relations in Western Europe from the end of the 1970s
up to the present. The time period is designed to capture the break in post-
war political economy that began with the crisis of Fordist economic growth
experienced by most advanced capitalist societies in the 1970s and to trace
how national industrial relations systems have fared since. Our purpose is to
evaluate the extent to which liberalization has taken hold of European indus-
trial relations institutions. We undertake our examination through five detailed
chapter-length country studies – of Britain, France, Germany, Italy and Swe-
den – and quantitative analysis of these five countries plus an additional seven
Western European countries and three non-European ones. The book offers a
comprehensive description and analysis of what has happened to the institu-
tions that regulate the labor market and relations between employers, unions
and states in Western Europe since the collapse of the long postwar boom.
We argue that liberalization in the realm of industrial relations is best under-
stood as involving an expansion of employer discretion: greater influence and
control on the part of individual employers over wage determination, hiring
and firing and the organization of the workplace. Thus, liberalization should
be evident in the reconstruction of industrial relations institutions to expand
employer discretion. This is likely to include, but not be limited to, decentral-
ization and individualization of bargaining, deregulation of the labor market
and decollectivization, involving a decline in the strength, size, centralization
and coverage of class organizations, primarily trade unions. We also argue that
institutions are often quite plastic, in that the same institution can, under differ-
ent circumstances, come to function in a quite different manner than in the past.
Understood in this way, liberalization may also take place through the “conver-
sion” (Streeck and Thelen 2005) of existing institutions from discretion-limiting
1
2 Trajectories of European Industrial Relations
relatively minor changes along an existing path. This tendency was accentu-
ated in the initial formulations of the Varieties of Capitalism approach (Hall
and Soskice 2001b). Thus, institutions created in the quite distant past can con-
tinue to shape the behavior of actors in the present, and to make radical changes
in the direction of a given political economy unlikely.
It follows, and this is a third linked argument, that the field of CPE has tradi-
tionally been hostile to the idea that the main institutions of advanced capitalist
societies are undergoing similar transformations and becoming more alike. For
at least the last thirty years, the field has been dominated by approaches and
empirical studies that emphasize the enduring diversity and range of distinct
national capitalisms. The resilience of institutions has been used to argue for
continuing institutional heterogeneity in capitalist political economies, even in
the face of heightened international economic constraints. Even when institu-
tions have clearly undergone substantial change, the expectation of those work-
ing within the CPE field has tended to be that change will be shaped by local
interests and nationally specific factors, so that there is no reason to anticipate
common trajectories of change or common cross-national patterns; rather, the
institutional landscape of advanced capitalist societies is likely to remain char-
acterized by national diversity even in the face of powerful liberalizing pressures
(Thelen 2014).
There are good and legitimate reasons for all this. Any common trajectory of
capitalist political economies is likely to be hidden by the long periods of time
involved, by the incremental nature of most institutional change, by differences
in the timing of change over the last three decades or more, by a privileging
of form over function in the analysis of institutions and by habits of mind and
the sociology of knowledge production; most of us have made deep intellectual
investments in understanding comparative (usually national) difference, and
CPE has a laudable commitment to local knowledge. One can add that it derives
also from the gradual displacement of capitalism – as opposed to markets – as
an object of scholarly inquiry that has taken place within much of the social
sciences, and with it the inability to make sense of transformational change
across the advanced capitalist world. The simple reality is that contemporary
analysis of political economy has been much better at explaining differences
than identifying commonalities.
Our book builds upon recent work within the CPE field that has begun to
contemplate the possibility of more radical, transformative institutional change
(Campbell 2004; Hall and Thelen 2009; Streeck 2009; Streeck and Thelen
2005). The book takes issue with each of the core arguments of the field noted
above, proposing instead (i) that institutions are heavily dependent upon the
social, political and economic contexts within which they operate for the man-
ner in which they function and the outcomes they generate: (ii) hence that insti-
tutions can change quite rapidly, both in form and in function; and (iii) that a
careful examination of contemporary capitalist political economies reveals a
4 Trajectories of European Industrial Relations
were thus more willing to contemplate quite dramatic change, and that states –
often thought of as largely passive or ineffective actors in the current period –
were crucial players in creating the conditions for wide-ranging liberalization.
Chapter 10 steps back from the quantitative and case study evidence to locate
the liberalization of industrial relations within the broader framework of the
collapse of Fordism, explaining how the crisis of institutions enabling the trans-
mission of productivity increases into real wages and aggregate demand has led
to the emergence of different post-Fordist growth models, all characterized by
inherent instability.
We have each incurred substantial intellectual debts in the process of
researching and writing this book. We are extremely grateful to colleagues
who have read different portions of the manuscript and offered precious
advice. They include Kerstin Ahlberg, Conor Cradden, Colin Crouch, Frank
Dobbin, Marc Blecher, Pepper Culpepper, Steve Crowley, Christian Dufour,
Martin Höpner, Christian Ibsen, Anders Kjellberg, Michel Lallement, Marc
Lenormand, Olivier Mériaux, Sofia Murhem, Tommy Őberg, Jan Ottosson,
Markus Pettersson, Jonas Pontusson, Damian Raess, Veli-Pekka Säikkälä,
Tobias Schulze-Cleven, Marco Simoni, Fritz Scharpf, Wolfgang Streeck, Kathy
Thelen and Mark Vail.
Lucio Baccaro would like to thank in particular Chiara Benassi and Jonas
Pontusson for joint work that has inspired (and in the case of Chiara con-
tributed to) parts of the manuscript, and his wife Cosetta for putting up with
him throughout the process. Chris Howell would like to thank the countless
trade unionists and researchers who have read draft chapters, offered invalu-
able feedback and taken time to help with this research, and especially Rebecca
Givan for collaborative work that helped develop some of the early ideas that
inspired this book.
2
This chapter makes the theoretical case for institutional convergence, along a
neoliberal trajectory, among the political economies of Western Europe. We
will elaborate further below what we mean by neoliberal convergence, but it is
worth emphasizing at the onset the degree to which the field of CPE has tradi-
tionally been hostile to the notion of convergence. For more than thirty years,
for the great majority of those working in the field, the mission of CPE has been
all but conterminous with identifying and explaining the enduring diversity and
range of distinct national capitalisms. Many of the seminal works in the field
have argued that broad economic changes – whether understood as the product
of shifting regimes of accumulation, deindustrialization or the forces of global-
ization – are experienced differently and have very different effects in different
countries. The result has been that the dominant theoretical approaches in CPE
are dubious about the likelihood of common consequences, similar trajectories
or institutional convergence (Berger and Dore 1996; Campbell 2004; Garrett
1998; Hall and Soskice 2001b).
The absence of expectations of convergence in these analyses is primarily
a result of the centrality that has been accorded to institutions in the disci-
pline of CPE and the characteristics attributed to political–economic institu-
tions. Indeed, “the idea of persistence is virtually built into the definition of an
institution” (Thelen 2009, 474) and contemporary theories of CPE have, to a
large extent, been built on the back of institutionalist theorizing (Hall and Tay-
lor 1996). Institutions have provided middle range explanations for national
differences that mediate between broad structural explanations, which tend to
anticipate convergence in industrial society, and narrowly political arguments
about agency, which privilege partisan policy choices.
The remainder of this chapter is organized into three sections. The first sur-
veys the literature on institutional change within CPE to demonstrate its per-
sistent resistance to convergence arguments. The second section lays out our
6
Theorizing Institutional Change 7
theoretical edifice, “as illuminating as this framework has been on the question
of institutional reproduction, scholars working in this tradition have generally
had much less to say about institutional change over time.”
The VoC approach was, in many ways, the culmination of more than a gen-
eration of scholarship in CPE. It built upon the emphasis within that tradi-
tion on the resilience and diversity of national models of capitalism, with the
resilience explained by the path-dependent qualities of institutions. To this tra-
dition, it added theoretical rigor by embedding path dependence in arguments
about institutional complementarities and comparative institutional advantage.
And it further offered a micro-foundational argument to explain why actors
should be expected to defend existing institutions.
It should be said that there has always been some dissent from this empha-
sis upon cross-national diversity and limited institutional change within the
field of CPE (Coates 2005). Regulationist approaches to political economy,
whether in their French (Boyer 1990), British (Jessop 1990a) or American
(Kotz, McDonough and Reich 1994) versions, have been far more interested in
institutional change by virtue of their assumptions about the inherent instabil-
ity, conflictuality and dynamism of capitalism. This alternative view of the way
capitalism functions, one we share, is something to which we shall return later
in this chapter. For this tradition, and what gives it its name, the importance
of institutions is that they are mechanisms for permitting regulation. Regula-
tion was the “master-concept” developed to explain the period of largely stable
growth for three decades after the Second World War” (Neilson 2012, 161).
What resulted was essentially a punctuated equilibrium model that emphasized
temporal discontinuity and a degree of synchronicity across the advanced capi-
talist world in the timing of structural economic change: the form of economic
growth known as Fordism everywhere went into crisis at some point in the
1970s, to be replaced by post-Fordism, though one that went by almost as
many names as there were regulation theorists.
But even here, in an ironic example of theoretical convergence, distinct
national models of capitalism have come to dominate the landscape of regu-
lationist theorizing, particularly that associated with Robert Boyer (Boyer and
Saillard 2002, Part V). Delineating the core dynamics of the emerging growth
model (or “regime of accumulation”) gave way to identifying its institutional
prerequisites, with the unsurprising result that the focus of much regulationist
research has become the variety of national regulatory mechanisms: “Examin-
ing the extent of convergence in terms of the regulation of core capitalist forms
is lost from the research agenda, and instead the theme of national diversity
shifts attention to the contingent political struggles that endogenously generate
specific path-dependent national trajectories” (Neilson 2012, 169). Nonethe-
less, the regulationist tradition of political economy remains distinct in its
emphasis upon the changing physiognomy of capitalism itself and its inherent
crisis tendencies. As such, it remains an important theoretical tool, to which we
return in the last section of this chapter.
10 Arguing for Neoliberal Convergence
Quite recently, in part in response to the perception that the early formula-
tions of the VoC approach were somewhat static and functionalist, theorizing
and debate over the degree and form of institutional change have moved to the
center of the field of CPE. This has taken place on the back of a less function-
alist, more political reading of the dynamics of capitalist political economies,
one that emphasizes contingency, power, contestation, the fragility of the politi-
cal coalitions that undergird institutional construction (Streeck and Yamamura
2001, Streeck 2009) and the ideational preconditions for institutional embed-
ding (Blyth 1997, Culpepper 2008).
It bears mentioning that there always were internal differences within the
VoC literature. For example, while in Soskice’s account (1999), employers
in CME countries were conceptualized as having prestrategic preferences for
coordinating institutions, employers’ support was considered to be strategic as
opposed to prestrategic in Thelen’s account (2001), and contingent on labor’s
countervailing power. This second interpretation was from the very beginning
much closer to that of power resource theorists such as Korpi (2006a) or Streeck
(2009) than the first.
Over time, from this more political stream within the VoC approach have
come a renewed emphasis upon institutional experimentation, a less functional-
ist interpretation of the process of institutional reproduction and greater space
for actors to reassess their interests and contemplate institutional change (Hall
and Thelen 2009). It is also important to note that even in its original formu-
lation, this approach allowed for the possibility of convergence on the LME
variety of capitalism, noting that it is easier to deregulate CMEs than for LMEs
to develop coordinating mechanisms and musing that institutional reform in
one sphere “could snowball into changes in other spheres as well” (Hall and
Soskice 2001b, 63–64). We would argue, and our cases indicate, that the unrav-
eling of CMEs and the further liberalization of LMEs in the sphere of industrial
relations had been well under way for more than a decade when this statement
was written.
The most fully formulated argument in favor of gradual or incremental
transformation – in which an accumulation of small, barely perceptible changes
becomes transformational over time – came from Streeck and Thelen (2005).
They acknowledge that most institutional approaches understate the degree
and significance of change, that intensified competition and a greater commit-
ment to market liberalism have exerted real pressure on institutions and that
one cannot assume that economic actors will always seek to defend existing
institutions rather than modify them. They identify a series of mechanisms by
which incremental changes can have transformative effects (Streeck and The-
len 2005, 31). For example, the same institutions can take on new functions,
latent effects can be activated, existing institutions can atrophy and peripheral
institutions can take center stage. In a similar fashion, Campbell (2004) has
articulated a more “actor-centered institutionalism” (the term originates from
Scharpf (1997b)) in which entrepreneurial actors, working within existing sets
Theorizing Institutional Change 11
1 For example, Martin and Swank (2008) have argued that a significant degree of institutional
change is compatible with continued elements of policy divergence, and also emphasized the
role of regime design and of the public sector in the trajectory of institutions.
12 Arguing for Neoliberal Convergence
concludes that national industrial relations regimes are highly resilient to the
forces of neoliberalism and globalization. In contrast with this view, our argu-
ment is that institutions may change in a neoliberal direction while remaining
allomorphic.
Acemoglu and Robinson (2006)’s crucial distinction between de jure and de
facto power inherent in institutions is helpful here. De jure power is congealed
in institutional form; de facto power depends on the contingent force field in
which institutions operate. While in the case of some institutions de jure power
shapes outcomes pretty much directly, in the case of other institutions outcomes
are contingent on the de facto power balance among the actors involved. Most
industrial relations institutions rest on contract rather than law, with the result
that these institutions shape interactions among actors but rarely directly dic-
tate outcomes. For example, the outcomes of centralized bargaining may be
very different depending on whether the actors settle on high wage increases
commensurate with the ability to pay of the most dynamic sectors and on a rigid
wage structure, as in the Sweden of the Rehn–Meidner model, or whether they
settle on wage increases that match the productivity growth of the most sluggish
companies, as in the Ireland of the “Celtic Tiger” (Baccaro and Simoni 2007).
These institutional outcomes are independent of institutional form, which is
approximately the same, and are shaped by the bargaining power of the actors
involved. It is these characteristics of industrial relations institutions that con-
tribute to explaining why they are endemically internally contested, why their
functions depend crucially on the power games that are played in and around
them, and why they are likely candidates for processes of institutional change.
In fact, many institutions, and certainly those in the sphere of industrial rela-
tions, are highly plastic: In a new context, subject to a new set of pressures
and constraints, the same set of institutions can be reengineered to function
in a manner very different from that of the context in which they were cre-
ated: “formal institutions do not fully determine the uses to which they may be
put. This is one important reason why major change in institutional practice
may be observed together with strong continuity in institutional structures”
(Streeck and Thelen 2005, 17–18). Institutional plasticity permits mutation in
the function and meaning of existing institutions, producing different practices
and consequences in new contexts.
We certainly do not want to close off the possibility of institutional rupture:
the wholesale reconstruction of institutions as an existing set of institutions is
replaced with a new set. There are cases of this in our book. But the mechanisms
of institutional change can also be subtler (Streeck and Thelen 2005, 19–30).
Earlier or submerged characteristics of an institution, long dormant, can emerge
under new conditions. Parallel, once secondary institutions, which played only
a peripheral regulatory role during an earlier period, may emerge to take on
new importance in a different context. Thus, the hierarchical ordering in any
bundle of interdependent institutions can change as competing sets of institu-
tions have different valences for the actors concerned, which themselves shift
Capitalism, Convergence and Neoliberalism 15
over time. Mechanisms can also be created or given new significance that per-
mit actors to bypass or escape from institutions altogether, creating pathways
to new practices alongside the formal institutions. The key point about these
alternative mechanisms is that they require no change in institutional form,
in the institutional topography of a political economy, and so are difficult to
capture in quantitative analysis. A focus upon form alone will understate the
degree of institutional change.
The result is a range of characteristics of institutions that – like capitalism
itself – point in the direction of permanent reinvention, change and discontinu-
ity. Thus, resilience and continuity of institutional form is perfectly compatible
with convergence in institutional functioning. And far from a picture of limited
incremental change along an existing path, one can anticipate quite radical and
transformative change.
We are arguing, in short, that a focus upon institutional forms is likely to miss
the malleability of institutions – the degree to which a set of institutions can
appear largely unchanged but in fact come to perform in quite different ways
from before – and thus the extent of institutional convergence. As Kinderman
notes with regard to the German case (Kinderman 2005, 433), scholars have
tended to focus upon “continuity of structure, and having established this, have
inferred continuity of content.”
More than forty years ago, a Royal Commission investigating the state of
British industrial relations argued, in a famous formulation, that there were
“two systems of industrial relations. The one is the formal system embodied in
the official institutions. The other is the informal system created by the actual
behavior of trade unions, employer’s associations, of managers, shop stewards
and workers” (Royal Commission on Trade Unions and Employers’ Associa-
tions 1968, paragraph 46). It is this disjuncture between form and function,
structure and practice, that creates the empirical space for identifying institu-
tional convergence and for understanding the underlying trajectory of Euro-
pean industrial relations over the last three decades and more.
It is important to be careful and clear in any discussion of convergence. We
are not making a coarse argument for institutional convergence. There is limited
and conflicting evidence of convergence as identity, a glacial flattening of the
institutional landscape to an identical topography. We are not arguing, in other
words, that industrial relations in Sweden or Germany today resemble in some
clear-cut sense those in Britain, that the CME category has been emptied so that
the advanced capitalist world is populated solely by varieties of LME.
Convergence does not require the same institutional form, and indeed, dif-
ferent starting points and different mobilizational capacities on the part of class
actors make it unlikely that institutional forms will converge. Different insti-
tutional inheritances and actor identities from one country to the next will
pose different obstacles and create distinctive flashpoints and sources of con-
flict over institutional reconstruction (Hyman 2001; Locke and Thelen 1995),
even when the underlying source of institutional change – whether that be
16 Arguing for Neoliberal Convergence
from our analysis. First, the shift from explaining “varieties of capitalism” to
explaining “varieties of liberalization” seems to have been made without any
critical analysis of what went wrong and which aspects of the previous theo-
retical apparatus needed to be reconsidered, which leaves the external observer
with a feeling that the goalposts have been moved. Second, VoC scholars are
not ready to concede that the manufacturing sectors in formerly coordinated
market economies have undergone liberalization. They refer to renegotiated
coordination instead (see also Hall 2007). According to this new argument,
liberalization is essentially the result of a compositional shift in the economy.
While the manufacturing sector remains coordinated, it is shrinking in dimen-
sional terms due to deindustrialization. It is argued that the production regime
prevailing in the service sectors does not require the same institutional ecosys-
tem and institutional complementaries as manufacturing, but relies much more
heavily on the logic of market coordination. Thus, liberalization is the result of
the decline of manufacturing and the rise of services in capitalist economies. As
we argue in the German and Swedish chapters, our view is instead that liber-
alization has taken place first and foremost in the manufacturing sector itself,
and that the liberalization of manufacturing has had important consequences
for the growth models of countries, unleashing further reforms.
Recognizing the danger that “liberalization” can be used imprecisely, we
elaborate below how we are using the concept, and what it means in the spe-
cific sphere of industrial relations. At its core, arguing for a common trajectory
of liberalization of industrial relations for us means demonstrating that there
has been a steady expansion across the advanced capitalist world in employer
discretion, as constraints on employers – in the form of labor law and collec-
tive regulation – diminish. This is a more precise formulation of the oft-cited
demand on the part of employers for greater flexibility: that employers should
have greater discretion vis-à-vis labor and state actors.
It follows from the distinction between institutional form and institutional
functioning that liberalization should be visible in two movements, one having
to do with institutional processes and the other with institutional outcomes.
The former movement involves, first and foremost, deregulation: the elimina-
tion or relaxation of institutional barriers. Referring specifically to industrial
relations, deregulation eliminates constraints upon capital’s discretion through
the removal of legal or contractual restrictions at the workplace level, in the
broader labor market and in society.2 In many cases, the removal of institutional
constraints is a return to an earlier deregulated era. Institutional deregulation
involves one or more of the following: a shift from higher levels of collective
bargaining to lower ones, closer to the firm or workplace; greater recourse to
individual bargaining between employee and employer or unilateral employer
decision-making; a shrinking in the collective organization capacity of class
2 Traxler (1995, 3) employs the term “disorganization” in place of “liberalization” in his discussion
of change in industrial relations, but his dimensions of change are similar to those used here:
decentralization, deregulation and disorganization of the collective capacity of class actors.
Capitalism, Convergence and Neoliberalism 19
actors; and a restructuring of labor market institutions to reduce the level and
duration of unemployment benefits, make benefit payment contingent on active
search and willingness to accept available jobs, lower employment protection
and in general eliminate all mechanisms interfering with the free meeting of
demand and supply (Blanchard and Wolfers 2000; Blanchard 2006; Layard,
Nickell and Jackman 2005; Nickell 1997; Nickell, Luca and Wolfgang 2005;
OECD 1994; Saint-Paul 2002; Siebert 1997; Traxler 1995).
Institutional deregulation may also operate through mechanisms that permit
class actors to bypass or ignore formal institutions and institutional rules, one of
the forms of institutional change noted above; this process, sometimes labelled
“derogation,” can be seen when unions and employers are given exemptions
from labor law or higher-level collective agreements under certain circum-
stances. For this reason, derogation tends to require a more active role on the
part of the state. An industrial relations system in which actors are allowed to
ignore institutional rules with impunity is subject de facto to deregulation.
The second form of institutional liberalization involves a transformation in
the role played by formally unchanged institutions from discretion-limiting to
discretion-enhancing. In contrast to a process of institutional deregulation, it
involves what Thelen has described as “institutional conversion,” as institutions
come to take on different functions and generate different outcomes (Thelen
2004, 36). Institutional conversion is made possible by the plasticity – the muta-
bility of function subject to context – that, as we noted above, is a characteristic
of institutions in the political–economic realm. An example would be central-
ized bargaining, once the linchpin of an alternative system to liberal capitalism
based upon a large and interventionist public sector and the political correc-
tion of market inequalities. However, with institutional conversion, centralized
bargaining can become an institutional device to produce outcomes, such as
real wage growth systematically trailing productivity increases, that the market
itself would be unable to produce. Another example of institutional conversion
might be a change in the functioning of works councils so that under new condi-
tions they come to encourage cooperation with an employer and identification
with the firm rather than serving as workplace agents of industrial unions. In
both cases, the formal institution remains unchanged, but under different con-
ditions, its very plasticity permits a conversion in function and behavior and is
likely to generate different outcomes.
Thus, to the extent that we see decollectivization and decentralization in the
form of institutions themselves, or a continuity in their form but a transforma-
tion in their content such that they contribute to the liberalizing outcomes noted
above, we can say that the trajectory of institutional change is in a neoliberal
direction.3 Liberalization as institutional deregulation can be captured empiri-
cally by looking at the form of institutions, whereas liberalization as the result
3 The starting point is also important. Decentralization of bargaining may be just as consequen-
tial when national bargaining gives way to sectoral bargaining as when sectoral bargaining is
replaced by firm-level bargaining.
20 Arguing for Neoliberal Convergence
of institutional conversion requires going beyond the form and looking at the
internal functioning and outcomes of institutions. For this reason, our book
provides both a quantitative analysis of trends in industrial relations indica-
tors, well suited to examining changes in institutional forms, and qualitative
case studies, better suited to capturing changes in the outcomes of institutions.
What liberalization as institutional deregulation and liberalization as institu-
tional conversion have in common is that they both allow increased employer
discretion in personnel and labor market strategies. Employer discretion has
three interrelated dimensions: (1) discretion in wage determination, that is, the
extent to which individual employers can adapt wage rates to the individual
circumstances and ability to pay of their firms, and use wage differentials to
recruit, motivate and retain key employees; (2) discretion in personnel man-
agement and work organization, for example, the ability to organize work time
flexibly to accommodate peaks and lulls in demand and to deploy labor across
functional specializations or job categories; (3) discretion in hiring and firing,
that is, the degree to which the employment relation approximates the model
of employment at will. The metric, therefore, of the liberalization of industrial
relations institutions is the extent to which they expand employer discretion
over time. We make no claim here as to how employers will use their greater
discretion along each of these dimensions, only that they will prefer greater
discretion to less.
We argue that, despite heterogeneous institutional sets and country-specific
developmental trajectories, there is substantial evidence that industrial relations
systems across Western Europe have been transformed in a common neoliberal
direction, in other words, toward greater employer discretion in employment
relations. Streeck (2009) has usefully distinguished between “Williamsonian”
and “Durkheimian” institutions. Not all institutions are coordinating devices
that allow economies of transaction costs and credible commitment by actors.
Some institutions are obligatory and limit actors’ discretion in accordance with
collectively shared social values and goals. On the evidence presented in the
remainder of this book, while the coordinating properties of institutions have
managed to survive in some cases, their obligatory properties have been relaxed
everywhere.
for the emergence of post-Fordist growth, in which growth was sustained not
by real wage increases, but by greater household indebtedness and by stronger
reliance on foreign demand.
We will deal with the crisis of Fordist wage-led growth and the emergence of
new growth models in the final chapter of this book. In this section we empha-
size two changes. First, in line with power resource theory, the weakening of
organized labor has meant that employers are more free to act on their own
first-order preferences, irrespective of labor preferences and the need to work
within shared collective institutions. Second, employers are less likely to have
an interest in supporting collective industrial relations institutions, and this as
a result of deep-seated changes in the growth model over the last three decades
that have had the effect of reducing the importance of collective institutions
inherited from the earlier Fordist era.
One of great strengths of theorizing within political economy in the last two
decades has been renewed emphasis upon employers and the firm, whether
through the focus upon employer coordination (Soskice 1990), historical
research into the role played by business interests in the construction of Fordist-
era labor and welfare institutions (Swenson 2002) or the attention paid to the
coordination needs of firms (Hall and Soskice 2001b). A political economy
of capitalism should never need to bring capital back in! Yet as the field has
evolved, a particular set of assumptions about employer interests and prefer-
ences has become near-hegemonic. These emphasize the extent to which insti-
tutions are the product of the rational coordination needs of firms rather than
the balance of power among economic actors, and thus employers will have lit-
tle incentive to dismantle those institutions when that balance changes. Those
same coordination needs are anticipated to produce cross-class alliances around
shared interests, rather than persistent class conflict over institutional construc-
tion and reconstruction.
These theoretical shifts reflect an abandonment of the power resource
approach to political economy that was once dominant in the field (Korpi
1983). That approach deserves more attention, as Korpi (2006b) has more
recently argued, because it problematizes employer preferences and introduces
an explanation for the quite rapid shifts in business attitudes toward longstand-
ing industrial relations institutions that we observe empirically. It suggests that
preferences are shaped by “the strategic context within which actors operate”
(Hacker and Pierson 2004, 193) so that inferring a first-order preference from
the behavior of business misses the degree to which support for a policy or insti-
tution might reflect acquiescence to a balance of power rather than a particular
preference ordering.4 To exemplify: Firms may have a prestrategic preference
for nonmarket coordination (as assumed by early VoC theorizing) or may settle
4 For an exploration of this set of issues, see the fascinating exchange between Peter Swenson
on one side and Jacob Hacker and Paul Pierson on the other (Hacker and Pierson 2002, 2004;
Swenson 2004a, 2004b).
Industrial Relations Liberalization and Capitalist Growth 23
5 The literature here is enormous. For a sampling of the most ambitious work see Harvey (1989);
Kotz, McDonough and Reich (1994); Lash and Urry (1987); Offe (1985); and Piore and Sabel
(1984). For an overview, see also Amin (1994).
3
1 For Australia and the United States, the union density series are constructed by splicing two
series in the Visser database (2013): one based on administrative data on union membership
(available for earlier years) and the other based on labor market surveys (for later years). An
adjustment factor has been calculated by dividing the administrative data by the survey data
for the period of overlap between the two series. The adjustment factor was then applied to the
administrative-source data for earlier years, while for later years the survey-based data have been
used.
2 Ghent countries provide strong selective incentives for union membership, since unemployment
insurance is voluntary and managed by trade unions but heavily subsidized by the state (Roth-
stein 1992, Van Rie, Marx and Horemans 2011).
table 3.1. Union Density Rates
Country 74–78 79–83 84–88 89–93 94–98 99–03 04–08 09–11 %11–74 %08–79 %11–89
Australia 44.76 44.98 43.85 40.51 30.75 23.84 20.00 18.37 −58.97 −55.53 −54.66
Austria 58.46 55.44 50.56 45.58 39.98 35.86 31.48 28.30 −51.59 −43.22 −37.91
Belgium 52.42 53.00 51.78 53.98 55.20 50.56 52.98 50.83 −3.03 −0.04 −5.83
Canada 34.50 35.04 34.60 34.78 33.56 30.52 29.68 29.90 −13.33 −15.30 −14.03
Denmark 71.80 79.32 76.74 75.96 76.60 73.70 69.90 68.65 −4.39 −11.88 −9.62
Finland 65.88 68.60 70.22 76.00 79.70 74.44 71.04 68.73 4.33 3.56 −9.56
France 21.40 17.62 12.82 9.96 8.60 8.02 7.66 7.90 −63.08 −56.53 −20.68
Germany 34.82 35.06 33.98 33.06 28.06 24.02 20.72 18.50 −46.87 −40.90 −44.04
Ireland 57.28 58.18 53.88 52.20 45.92 36.92 33.14 35.47 −38.08 −43.04 −32.06
Italy 48.98 47.90 41.60 39.00 37.22 34.38 33.56 35.13 −28.27 −29.94 −9.91
Netherlands 37.20 33.48 26.66 24.56 24.78 22.16 20.72 19.27 −48.21 −38.11 −21.55
Norway 53.66 57.58 56.94 58.14 56.48 54.54 54.36 54.57 1.69 −5.59 −6.15
Sweden 74.98 78.46 82.56 83.30 84.68 78.46 73.10 69.30 −7.58 −6.83 −16.81
UK 47.02 51.24 45.78 39.72 33.34 29.62 27.48 27.20 −42.15 −46.37 −31.52
USA 22.75 20.97 17.06 15.42 14.04 12.82 11.80 11.50 −49.44 −43.73 −25.42
Germany and UK
50
40
30
20
Germany UK
90
90
80
80
80
70
70
70
60
60
60
50
50
50
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
year year year
Norway Sweden
90
90
80
80
70
70
60
60
50
50
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
year year
UD Fitted values
figure 3.2. Union density in Belgium and the Nordic countries (with quadratic fit line)
a) LMEs
20 40 60 80
20 40 60 80
0
0
74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08 74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08 74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08
period period period
UK USA
20 40 60 80
20 40 60 80
0
private public
industrial manufacturing
public admininstration commerce
hotels
b) Continental Countries
20 40 60 80
20 40 60 80
0
74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08 74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08 74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08
period period period
Italy Netherlands
20 40 60 80
20 40 60 80
0
private public
industrial manufacturing
public admininstration commerce
hotels
20 40 60 80 100
20 40 60 80 100
74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08 74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08 74-78 84-88 94-98 04-08
period period period
Norway Sweden
20 40 60 80 100
20 40 60 80 100
private public
industrial manufacturing
public admininstration commerce
hotels
public administration (more strictly defined than the public sector at large);
commerce; and hotels, restaurants and catering. The latter two service sectors
tend to be labor-intensive and low-skilled. The union density rate is everywhere
higher in the public sector than in the private/manufacturing sector. In most
countries, public sector unionization has not declined (including in the United
States), but there are countries, such as Australia, Britain, Austria and Germany,
where public sector decline has proceeded in parallel with private sector decline.
In the Netherlands, it seems that public sector decline was greater than that in
the private sector. Furthermore, union density is everywhere especially low in
the labor-intensive service sectors (commerce and hotels, restaurants and cater-
ing), with the exception of Denmark, Finland and Sweden (all Ghent countries),
where private service unionization is above 50 percent.
If statistics on union density by sector are scarce, even scarcer are statis-
tics on the associational density of employer organizations (as a percentage of
employees). Table 3.2 reports the available data in the Visser database (Visser
2013). Although most data are available only from the early 2000s on, and for
Australia, Canada and the United States there are no data at all, there is no evi-
dence of a decline in employer association density. In Austria, employer density
remains constant at 100 percent throughout the period, while in other countries
32 Quantitative Analysis of Industrial Relations Change
the density rate seems to have increased slightly. In general, employer density
is higher than union density. A high employer density is especially important
for countries in which there is no legal extension of negotiated terms and con-
ditions of employment, and bargaining coverage depends on firms being mem-
bers of employer associations. A small decline of employer density is found in
Germany, Italy, Sweden and the United Kingdom.
Differently from trade union density (but perhaps consistent with trends in
employer density), there is no evidence of a cross-country decline in bargaining
coverage (proportion of employees who are covered by a collective bargaining
agreement). The relevant data are reported in Table 3.3. They suggest shrinking
coverage in countries in which bargaining coverage is strictly associated with
union coverage, such as the United Kingdom, Australia, the United States and
Canada. However, the decline of bargaining coverage is not a peculiarity of
the liberal market economies: Germany, too, has seen the coverage rate drop
from 85 percent in 1990 to 61 percent in 2010, and the rate is even lower
in manufacturing. The decline of bargaining coverage will be discussed in the
German chapter. It suffices to say here that in Germany collective bargaining
coverage is strictly dependent on the strength of employer associations. Exten-
sion clauses, while legally possible, have been used sparingly in recent years.
Some German employer associations have been experimenting with “member-
ship without contract” (a form of membership that does not imply firms being
bound by the industry contract) as a way to stop membership loss. In other
countries, bargaining coverage has increased slightly. Consequently, a gap has
opened between union membership coverage and collective bargaining cover-
age. This gap is particularly wide in France (85 percent), Austria (70 percent),
table 3.3. Collective Bargaining Coverage Rates
Country 74–78 79–83 84–88 89–93 94–98 99–03 04–08 09–11 %11–74 %08–79 %11–89
Australia 88.00 88.00 85.00 76.67 60.00 50.00 45.00 −48.86
Austria 95.00 95.00 95.00 98.00 98.00 98.75 99.00 99.00 4.21 4.21 1.02
Belgium 90.00 97.00 96.00 96.00 96.00 96.00 96.00 96.00 6.67 −1.03 0.00
Canada 37.60 37.96 37.28 38.10 35.48 32.24 31.68 30.20 −19.68 −16.54 −20.73
Denmark 81.00 82.00 83.00 84.00 84.00 83.00 85.00 3.66
Finland 77.00 77.00 77.00 85.00 85.00 86.50 88.30 89.50 16.23 14.68 5.29
France 76.00 78.95 88.30 94.50 92.00 92.00 16.53
Germany 85.00 85.00 85.00 85.00 75.18 68.84 64.70 61.55 −27.59 −23.88 −27.59
Ireland 44.40 41.90 42.20
Italy 85.00 85.00 85.00 85.00 85.00 85.00 85.00 85.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Netherlands 78.40 81.80 80.30 80.00 83.40 84.70 84.85 84.30 7.53 3.73 5.38
Norway 65.00 70.00 70.00 70.00 72.00 72.00 73.50 5.00
Sweden 84.00 85.00 85.00 87.50 91.50 94.00 92.25 91.00 8.33 8.53 4.00
UK 77.30 73.50 64.00 54.00 36.88 35.74 34.22 31.57 −59.16 −53.44 −41.54
USA 26.26 24.78 20.04 18.14 16.26 14.74 13.52 13.23 −49.61 −45.44 −27.05
34 Quantitative Analysis of Industrial Relations Change
the Netherlands (65 percent) and Italy (50 percent). It is the result of legal
clauses extending the terms and conditions set by the shrinking unionized sec-
tor. It generates a worrisome disconnect between a minority of unionized work-
ers and the majority of unorganized workers. As a result, unions become liable
to being accused of acting as insider organizations that exploit their privileged
position to set terms and conditions of employment to the exclusive benefit of
their members while unduly damaging the prospects of outsiders (Lindbeck and
Snower 1986, Saint-Paul 2002).
An important dimension in industrial relations is the bargaining structure
and specifically the degree of bargaining centralization, which is often mea-
sured by recording the main level of bargaining. In the Visser database, there
is an indicator capturing the main level of bargaining (thus providing an ordi-
nal measure of bargaining centralization/decentralization), which is coded as
follows (Visser 2013: 11):
5 = bargaining predominantly takes place at central or cross-industry
level and there are centrally determined binding norms or ceilings to be
respected by agreements negotiated at lower levels;
4 = intermediate or alternating between central and industry bargaining;
3 = bargaining predominantly takes place at the sector or industry level;
2 = intermediate or alternating between sector and company bargaining;
1 = bargaining predominantly takes place at the local or company level.
“Dominant level” means that the level accounts for two-thirds of the
total coverage rate. Table 3.4 reports the data on bargaining centraliza-
tion/decentralization based on the above coding scheme. Bargaining decen-
tralization has been fairly dramatic in the United Kingdom. In 1975–78 this
country had centralized bargaining, but bargaining was dramatically decen-
tralized afterward. A decline of centralization is also visible in Australia and
Canada, while in Ireland bargaining was highly centralized between 1988 and
2008 (Baccaro and Simoni 2007, Roche 2007) and then was decentralized with
the onset of the financial crisis (Roche 2011). The U.S. indicator suggests no
change, because the American bargaining structure has always been company-
based. A process of decentralization seems to have occurred in Denmark and
Sweden as well. In these countries wages and working conditions were centrally
determined in the 1970s, but bargaining moved to the industry level (with a pro-
gressively greater role of company-level bargaining) between the late 1980s and
early 1990s (Iversen, Pontusson and Soskice 2000). No change is reported for
Germany and Austria, while bargaining centralization seems to have increased
in Belgium and slightly in Italy from the 1990s, according to this measure of
main bargaining level.
It may be argued that the above measure of bargaining centralization
severely understates the extent of true bargaining centralization in Austria and
Germany, as well as in Sweden, Denmark and other countries. The country
chapters will document that the bargaining structure has changed dramatically
table 3.4. Collective Bargaining Centralization Scores
Country 74–78 79–83 84–88 89–93 94–98 99–03 04–08 09–11 %11–74 %08–79 %11–89
Australia 4.00 4.20 4.60 3.20 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 −50.00 −52.38 −37.50
Austria 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Belgium 3.40 4.20 4.80 4.60 4.20 4.60 4.60 4.67 37.25 9.52 1.45
Canada 2.00 1.20 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 −50.00 −16.67 0.00
Denmark 5.00 3.80 3.80 3.00 3.40 3.00 3.00 3.00 −40.00 −21.05 0.00
Finland 5.00 4.60 3.80 4.20 4.20 4.60 4.20 3.67 −26.67 −8.70 −12.70
France 3.00 2.40 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 −33.33 −16.67 0.00
Germany 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Ireland 2.80 2.20 2.60 5.00 5.00 5.00 5.00 1.00 −64.29 127.27 −80.00
Italy 3.40 3.40 2.40 2.80 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 −11.76 −11.76 7.14
Netherlands 3.60 3.60 3.20 3.40 3.00 3.40 3.20 3.00 −16.67 −11.11 −11.76
Norway 4.40 4.00 4.20 4.40 3.20 3.40 3.00 3.00 −31.82 −25.00 −31.82
Sweden 5.00 4.60 4.20 3.80 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 −40.00 −34.78 −21.05
UK 4.60 3.00 2.40 2.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 −78.26 −66.67 −50.00
USA 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
36 Quantitative Analysis of Industrial Relations Change
in Germany and Sweden, yet such change is not captured by focusing on the
main level of bargaining. While the main level of bargaining has remained at
the industry level, industry-level bargaining has been subject to erosion since
opportunities to bypass centrally negotiated provisions have increased. One
way to more realistically assess the extent of change is to factor in the impact
of “opening clauses,” legal or contractual norms that allow lower-level devia-
tions from the provisions of higher-level agreements.
The Visser database (Visser 2013, 11) includes a time-changing measure of
opening clauses (OC), reflecting mostly developments in manufacturing, which
is coded as follows:
5 = opening clauses are exceptional (one-off hardship clauses only, related
to specific cases of bankruptcy or restructuring);
4 = opening clauses exist, limited use, on work time only;
3 = opening clauses exist, limited use, also on pay;
2 = opening clauses exist, use is widespread, including pay;
1 = opening clauses are generalized; the sector agreement sets only a frame-
work for local bargaining or define only a default in case local negotiations
fail;
0 = does not apply (no sectoral or national agreements).
By combining the measures of bargaining level and opening clause, it is possible
to produce an adjusted measure of bargaining centralization/decentralization
that takes into account the fact that even when bargaining remains formally
centralized, opportunities for derogation may increase. The new measure is
based on the main level of bargaining weighted by the extent of opening clauses
according to the following coding scheme:
level × 1.0 if oc = 5
level × 0.8 if oc = 4
level × 0.6 if oc = 3
level × 0.4 if oc = 2
level × 0.2 if oc = 1
level × 0.0 if oc = 0.
This coding scheme generates a variable equaling 5 (maximum score) if bar-
gaining is highly centralized and opening clauses are exceptional, and 0 (min-
imum score) if bargaining is decentralized. When the main bargaining level is
intermediate or alternating between the sectoral and the company levels (score
2), the opening score weight is divided by two. For example, a country scor-
ing 2 on the level dimension, in which opening clauses are exceptional, obtains
an adjusted score of 1. This alternative measure of centralization seems better
suited to account for the erosion of formally unchanged bargaining structures.
As revealed by Figure 3.4, in the case of Germany the adjusted measure suggests
a decentralizing trend that parallels the decline in trade union density, while the
measure of main bargaining level registers no change (see Figure 3.4).
of them
species
is the
waggons
mongoose by
is neglected
Although
for him
run
so probably lions
on As
in in use
hill be
through summer is
are or antelopes
such solemnity in
It spread suitable
of horn very
light
or would seen
thigh is more
with the
birds West
that
than
the the
are
the leopard
out A
thus
weigh
making
came
been whole
IVETS
of 313 principally
The on J
there horse
INDIAN
Ant years
any
off the and
Good Add
the belly
300 before
of into
the
courage and to
white
the of which
and while at
similar swallow
but
Prince ILD R
the food of
result
Lawrence
AND
is far
The a once
X of and
CAT Wishaw in
in
appearance educate
ORCUPINE him
without
heavy In
leaning from
their
The air
cold smaller
of their
country h■
whole and
rodents forwards
but only
one shore
of Omsk manœuvres
refuse altered
of
the
is showing carried
and ears
days
and
is
Dubois shoot
outside in
to it herds
climb
it were wherever
down
on Humboldt zebras
at order will
is gets
when
The and
corresponding that
and
those steps
Aye general
hard many
her
were
away by combat
timid Hamburg of
left countries
the rather YÆNA
of LACK a
in protect the
produced a
gorilla
the its
the common Scholastic
they
as
is
England foxes
In
of HE
one more weight
MOUSE of
as
by and
the Opossum in
East or Asia
particularly
leaf
of bird
and
by Their taproot
an
of eye grubs
The
kills sucker
be of figure
Rabies
underneath
domesticated the
BALUCHI droves
American This
twenty draw
with
pure be
themselves the
the the
of top
Musk
the In
These
are of gives
It of Those
which
them C back
feed horse
best is friends
the be in
all tabby
see
and as
the that
over
backs
the elephant
and
whalers species
trunks the
African
closed bats
never fly
the is dam
haunts
where
at to bears
continents
kind stud
T This helpless
the of
the expected
invariably the
to value R
man
of both
Parson wastes a
pure or herds
domesticated inside is
state a B
of look and
One
in they
jaws
sexes
one of hunting
Few
St observes Somaliland
UENONS drawn
of fur
my and
when to for
in of
and its
more the up
Boer
in he
Dandie 190 in
it colour of
would shower
behind the
other any
as a of
their
ground YEARLING
numbers when
is the dogs
are
the
Smith nurseries
were
the
of
the more
its has
grew the
He the D
less fever
sudden bluish
extinct
His Of
this he
or
a inside
haunt for of
obey
hands meat
Co 166 like
it or
a
drifting of
They
have down
the as
tapirs
by
discovered open
high so
to
attaches the a
Jews
purchasing W
the
tail
also ages
have
however It inoffensive
white
It of retracted
of
A E nearly
covers to did
than near
in found disposition
the
C are
food that as
with was
Highbury easy
large living
but
Such ground creatures
of When animals
long The
a sable for
of
of
allied the
grown R the
the mice
as J
advance the
are claws
one Neither
at
DOGS white
enemies
Derbyshire old
most at is
rivers a alter
into
on
their upon offspring
man
the and
and
pet
the In
When by sixty
BLACK 375
will lately
Dean olive
often it in
keeping different of
to which 159
in the which
silver of
like He rat
Zoological
and
which
of
continent the
There G LONG
male quantities
in great
men and S
related
Capuchins entirely
game
and
is pick all
to other
lemmings of
for
Photo and
and
hand
of RACCOON long
the
of of equatorial
went
from
in a
never
the
or
creature in stake
eternal
In
never
both aphides
and feline H
Devon be other
belonging a
head by spines
cheek
roars trees
ground inhabitants
habits
any
OG of fox
long of
dog a Photo
found and
take
coast generally
Bears
signal hands
wholly
elephant a six
and a Rudland
one with
on owner
or parallel
the
of almost
of creeps
beetle
his
in Notting
in
of
cub
the pair
chase
to
Man in but
a Asiatic on
disposed fall
slayer killed Humped
this from
feet usually
Domesticated
both to
Bengali of others
bought the L
comes drops
died a
Hagenbeck the
24 is
from
Under OMMON
such
but Bath
is live to
such and
of Finchley are
more hibernate
Pig
Fruit the
ears not months
in
beauty
work
Photo
the
Persian number
but of but
country a dreaded
Southern In
and colour
to Among considerable
can tree
bright guns
Anschütz
specimens
it and in
and
of in the
of
seek
recognised
have
margins
long
powers
OMMON to
Mammalia amusing 2
in on above
GUTIS is the
the sit
of
they carry
to
the
the and
of feet of
and as the
its escaped as
hedgehog found by
teeth the
to rounded and
is
are
and fossils
such breed
though pair
distance both
dogs
a The thinking
reeds
are
In are monkeys
dinners
the
absolutely
raja
in
in
Common a
on S
These by how
its remaining
in animals
Mr
age kind
other have
animals
to if more
left about under
different by
is Sons killed
suckled North
pieces a
of were inhabitant
Photo
HE obtained be
record
an habit the
hyæna differing
of man
and
that in largest
a Reid
Zambesi eating
up
when a
Then
born who
very Roman
are they
then
steal unavailing gradually
there one It
Jackals the
long Romans of
and
is
altitude P
of Hyæna
he VOLE
full still
family the
Bactrian 100
the South
resort